Skip to main content

Full text of "Oversight of Civil Aeronautics Board practices and procedures : hearings before the Subcommittee on Administrative Practice and Procedure of the Committee on the Judiciary, United States Senate, Ninety-fourth Congress, first session .."

See other formats


OVERSIGHT  OF  CIVIL  AERONAUTICS  BOARD 
PRACTICES  AND  PROCEDURES 


HEARINGS 

BEFORE   THE 

SUBCOMMITTEE  ON 
ADMINISTRATIVE  PRACTICE  AND  PROCEDURE 

OF  THE 

COMMITTEE  ON  THE  JUDICIARY 
UNITED  STATES  SENATE 

NINETY-FOURTH  CONGRESS 

FIRST  SESSION 

ON 

OVERSIGHT  OF  CIVIL  AERONAUTICS  BOARD 

PRACTICES  AND  PROCEDURES 


VOLUME  1 


FEBRUARY  6,  14,  18,  19,  25,  AND  26, 
MARCH  4  AND  21,  1975 


Printed  for  the  use  of  the  Committee  on  the  Judiciary 


U.S.  GOVERNMENT  PRINTING  OFFICE 
WASHINGTON   :   1975 


WORTHEASTERN  UNIVERSITY  SCHOOL  of  LAW  LIBRARY 


COMMITTEE  ON  THE  JUDICIARY 

JAMES   O.   EASTLAND,   Mississippi,    Chairman 
JOHN  L.  McCLELLAN,  Arkansas  RO>L4N  L.  HRUSKA,  Nebrasl^a 

PHILIP   A.   HART,   Michigan  HIRAM  L.  FONG,  Hawaii 

EDWARD  M.   KENNEDY,   Massachusetts        HUGH    SCOTT,   Pennsylvania 
BIRCH   BAYH,    Indiana  STROM  THURMOND,  South  Carolina 

QUENTIN  N.  BURDICK,  North  DalvOta  CHARLES  McC.  MATHIAS,  Jr.,  Maryland 

ROBERT  C.   BYRD,  West  Virginia  WILLIAM  L.   SCOTT,  Virginia 

JOHN  V.  TUNNEY,  California 
JAMES  ABOUREZK,   South  Dakota 

Petee    M.  Stockett,  Chief  Counsel  and  Staff  Director 


Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure 
EDWARD  M.  KENNEDY,  Massachusetts,  Chairman 

PHILIP   A.    HART,   Michigan  STROM  THURMOND,  South  Carolina 

j  BIRCH   BAYH,   Indiana  CHARLES  McC.  MATHIAS,  Jr.,  Maryland 

^  QUENTIN  N.  BURDICK,  North  Dakota  HUGH    SCOTT,   Pennsylvania 

'  JOHN  V.  TUNNEY,  California 

Stephen    G.    Breyer,   Special  Counsel 

Thomas    M.    Susman,   Chief  Counsel 

Philip    J.    Bakes,  Jr.,  Assistant  Counsel 

Janet    F.    Alberghini,   Staff  Member 

Theresa    A.    Burt,   Staff  Member 

Caroline  J.  Croft,  Research  Assistant 

James  F.  Michie,  Investigator 

James    I.     Campbell,  Jr.,   Staff  Member 

Geoffrey  White,  Staff  Consultant 

Stephen    L.  Jones,  Minority  Counsel 

(n) 


^ 

o 


CONTENTS 

(See  also  List  of  Witnesses  and  Topical  Index  at  the  end  of  volume  3) 


OVERSIGHT    OF    CIVIL    AERONAUTICS    BOARD 
PRACTICES    AND    PROCEDURES 


Days  of  Hearings 

Feb.  6,  1975  OVERVIEW  OF  FEDERAL  ECONOMIC  REGULATION  OF 
DOMESTIC  AIR  TRANSPORT 

Feb.  14,  1975  COMPARISON  OF  UNREGULATED  INTRASTATE  AIR- 
LINES   WITH    REGULATED    INTERSTATE    AIRLINES 

Feb.  18,  1975  CAB  REGULATION  OF  ENTRY  INTO  DOMESTIC  AIR 
ROUTES  AND  INTO  THE  DOMESTIC  AIR  TRANSPORT 
INDUSTRY 

Feb.  19,  1975  CAB'S  HANDLING  OF  CONSUMERS.  SMALL  GROUPS, 
AND  CHARTERS  IN  THE  REGULATION  OF  DOMES- 
TIC AIR  TRANSPORT 

Feb.  25,  1975         CAB  REGULATIONS  OF  DOMESTIC  AIR  FARES   . 

Feb.  26,   1975         GENERAL  QUESTIONING  OF  THE  CAB  OFFICERS 

Mar  4,  1975  USES  OF  CAB'S  AUTHORITY  TO  IMMUNIZE  INTER- 
CARRIER  AGREEMENTS  FROM  THE  ANTITRUST 
LAWS 

Mar  21,  1975  INQUIRY  INTO  THE  FAILURE  OF  THE  CAB  TO  INVES- 
TIGATE FULLY  CERTAIN  VIOLATIONS  OF  THE  FED- 
ERAL CAMPAIGN  LAWS 


VOLUME  1 

Thursday,  February  6,  1975 

TESTIMONY 

Page 

Barnum,  John  W.,  Acting  Secretary,  U.8.  Department  of  Transportation..  4 

Prepared  statement 1^ 

Engman,  Lewis,  Chairman,  Federal  Trade  Commission 22 

Prepared  statement ^^ 

Kauper,  Thomas  E.,  Assistant  Attorney  General,  Antitrust  Division,  U.S. 

Department  of  Justice ^'* 

Prepared  statement 45 

Miller,  James  C,  III,  senior  stafE  economist,  Council  of  Economic  Ad- 
visers   ■.-  ^" 

Prepared  statement  of  Gary  L.  Seevers,  member.  Council  of  Econom^c 

Advisers,  and  Mr.  Miller ^^ 

Panel  of  economists :  Merton  J.  Peck,  professor  of  economics,  Yale  Uni- 
versity ;  Roger  G.  Noll,  professor  of  economics,  California  Institute  of 
Technology;  and  Thomas  G.  Moore,  senior  fellow.  The  Hoover  Institu- 
tion on  War.  Revolution,  and  Peace,  Stanford  University 68 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Peck "^9 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Moore 82 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Noll 84 

Kahn.  Alfred  E.,  Chairman,  New  York  State  Public  Service  Commission—  87 

Prepared  statement -,-  ^^ 

James,  George  W..  senior  vice  president  of  economics  and  finance.  Air 

Transport  Association  of  America 99 

Prepared  statement H^ 

(m) 


IV 

EXHIBITS 

Air  Transport  Association  prepared  exhibits  :  ^^^^ 

Example  of  connecting  and  thirougli-flight  complex,  eastbound 122 

Example  of  connecting  and  through-flight  complex,  westbound 123 

Monetary  value  of  travel  by  air  vs.  other  modes 124 

Dollar  value  of  time  savings  due  to  air  travel  rather  than  other  modes 

of  travel,  Birmingham,  Ala.,  to  Miami,  Fla.,  1970__ 124 

Average  fare  per  passenger  mile,  domestic  scheduled  services,  trunk  air- 
lines   (1938  dollars) 129 

Changes  in  air  fares  compared  with  other  U.S.  products  and  services--       130 
Average  fare  per  passenger  mile  (indexed  to  constant  1938  dollars)—      131 
Average  air  freight  rates  per  ton  mile,  domestic  operations,  U.S.  sched- 
uled airlines   (1940  constant  dollars) 132 

Distribution  of  trunk  airlines  scheduled  coach  fares,  year  ended  Sept. 

30,  1974,  48-state  data 133 

Income  characteristics  of  adults  who  have  flown  on  regular  passenger 

airline 134 

1974  load  factors,  nonstop  services — Boston-Detroit  market 135 

Distribution  of  airline  passenger  traffic  by  number  of  city-pairs  (year 

ended  June  1974) —       136 

Percent  of  transported  passengers  who  are  not  through  or  connecting, 

by  flight  distances  (for  city-pairs  with  nonstop  service) 137 

ATA  airline  cost  index,  U.S.  trunks  and  local  service  carriers,  3d  quar- 
ter, 1974 138 

Air  Transport  Association,  "The  Consequences  of  Deregulation,"  (Apr.  25, 

1974)   139 

Flight/segment  load-factor  distribution,  U.S. -certificated  airlines,  48- 
state  services,  Aug.  1973 161 

U.S.  scheduled  airline  1973  routes  (city-pairs)  risking  loss  of  service 
as   a   consequence  of  deregulation    (in   order  from   least   to   most 

unprofitable)    171 

Air  Transport  Association,  letter  from  George  James,  senior  vice  president 
of  economics  and  finance,  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  8, 

1975,  replying  to  Senator  Kennedy's  letter  of  May  2,  1975 380 

Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  letter  from  Alan  Greenspan,  chairman,  to 
Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  1,  1975,  evaluating  the  ATA 

study,  "Consequence  of  Deregulation" 382 

Council  on  Wage  and  Price  Stability,  letter  from  Albert  Rees,  director,  to 
Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  1,  1975,  evaluating  the  ATA 

study.  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" 394 

Douglas,  George  W.,  professor  of  economics.  University  of  Texas,  prepared 

statement 437 

Drake,  John  W.,  professor  of  air  transportation.  School  of  Aeronautics  and 
Astronautics,  Purdue  University,  letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
dated  May  15,  1975,  evaluating  the  ATA  study.  "Consequences  of  Deregu- 
lation"         4J0 

Kennedy,  Senator  Edward  M.,  letter  to  George  W.  James,  senior  vice  presi- 
dent of  economics  and  finance,  Air  Transport  Association,  dated  Fel).  7. 

1975,  requesting  a  study  on  the  consequences  of  deregulation 139 

Kennedy,    Senator  Edward  M.,  letter  to   George  W.   James,   senior  vice 
president  of  economics  and  finance.  Air  Transport  Associatioyi,  dated 
May  2,  1975.  commenting  on  the  ATA's  "Consequences  of  Deregulation"-       379 
Kennedy,  Senator  Edward  M.,  sample  letter  requesting  independent  eval- 
uations of  the  ATA  study,  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" 380 

Keeler,  Theodore  E.,  assistant  professor  of  economics,  Universitv  of  Cali- 
fornia at  Berkeley,  letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  June  4, 

1975,  evaluating  the  ATA  study,  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" _'       421 

Peltzman.  Sam.  professor  of  business  economics,  University  of  Chicago, 
letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  5,  1975,  evaluating  the 
ATA  study,  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" 423 


Sherman,  Roger,  professor  of  economics,  University  of  Virginia,  letter  to 

Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  12,  1975,  evaluating  the  ATA     Pa&e 
study,  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" 426 

Whinston,  Andrew,  professor  of  economics,  management  and  computer  sci- 
ence, letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  9,  1975,  evaluat- 
ing the  ATA  study,  "Consequences  of  Deregulation" 430 


Friday,   February   14,    1975 

TESTIMONY 

Panel  of  California  intrastate  airlines :  Lawrence  A.  Guske,  assistant 
controller,  Pacific  Southtvcst  Airlines;  and  Robert  W.  Clifford,  presi- 
dent, Air  California 444 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Guske 449 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Clifford 450 

Panel  of  economists :  William  A.  Jordan,  professor  of  managerial  eco- 
nomics, York  University ;  and  John  R.  Suuimerfield,  president,  Summer- 
field  Associates 452 

Prepared  statement  of  Dr.  Jordan 464 

Prepared  statement  of  Dr.  Summerfield 487 

O'Melia,  Richard  J.,  Acting  Chairman,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 494 

Prepared  statement 498 

Panel  of  interstate  airlines :  Morton  Ehrlich,  vice  president  for  planning 
and  chief  economist.  Eastern  Airlines;  Randall  Malin,  vice  president  of 
market  planning,  American  Airlines;  and  Morris  Shipley,  vice  president 

of  governmental  affairs.  Delta  Air  Lines 512 

Prepared  statement  of  Dr.  Ehrlich 519 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Malin 521 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Shipley 523 

Murphy,  Charles,  executive  director,  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission 525 

Prepared  statement 529 

EXHIBITS 

American  Airlines,  prepared  exhibits : 

Short-haul  operating  costs  and  earnings  of  American  Airlines,  Boston- 
Washington  and  New  York-Washington  routes 522 

Short-haul  operating  costs  and  earnings  of  American  Airlines,  Boston- 
Washington  and  New  York-Washington,  offering  PSA-type  service—       522 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  prepared  exhibits : 

Comparison  of  fare  rates  for  CAB-regulated  and  non-CAB-regulated 

carriers  in  selected  markets,  Jan.  1975 502 

Domestic   Passenger   Fare  Investigation — Phase   7    (excerpts),   Apr. 

1971   502 

Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation — Phase  9    (excerpts),  Mar. 

1974  503 

General  Passenger  Fare  Investigation,  Nov.  1960  (excerpts) 508 

Jordan,  William  A.,  prepared  exhibits : 

PSA's  coach   fares  compared   with   CAB-authorized   1st  class  fares 

for  three  major  California  city-pairs,  1949 467 

PSA's    coach    fares    compared    with    CAB-authorized    coach    fares 

for  three  ma.1or  California  city-pairs,  1965 468 

PSA's    coach    fares    compared    with    CAB-authorized    coach    fares 

for  three  major  California  city-pairs,  Jan.  29,  1975 468 

Increases  in  coach  fares  from  late  1969  to  early  1975 ;  PSA  compared 

with  CAB-authorized  fares  for  three  major  California  city-pairs 469 

Southwest's  coach  fares  compared  with  CAB-authorized  coach  fares 

for  three  major  Texas  city-pairs,  Nov.  15,  1974 471 

Comparison  of  PSA,  CAB-authorized  and  Canadian  coach  fares,  Los 

Angeles-San  Francisco  vs.  Montreal-Toronto,  June  1965  and  Jan.  29, 

1975  473 

Comparison  of  competitive  bid  rates  with  CAB-authorized  rates,  cate- 
gory B  international  operations,  Aug.  4,  1959  vs.  Feb.  10,  1961 475 


VI 

Jordan,  William  A.,  prepared  exhibits — Continued 

Average  annual  output  per  employe  (PSA  compared  with  total  trunk     Page 

carriers  and  Western  Air  Lines),  1965 480 

One-way  coach  prices  for  Dallas-Houston  and  Dallas-San  Antonio 
service:  Southwest  Airlines,  Braniff  Airways,  and  Texas  Interna- 
tional Airlines,  June  1971-Dec.  1974 485 

Top  100  origin-destination  city-pairs  in  order  of  passenger  rank,  CAB- 
certificated    and    California/Texas    intrastate    airlines    (scheduled 

service,   1972) 486 

Summeriield,  John  R.,  prepared  exhibits  : 

Dollar  cost  saved  by  PSA  due  to  exclusively  intra-California  service—      490 
Summerfield.  John  R.,  president,  Summerheid  Associates,  letter  to  subcom- 
mittee, dated  Feb.  28, 1975  : 

Response  to  the  testimony  of  Dr.  Jordan 490 

Response  to   tentative  subcommittee  staff  memorandum   concerning 

intrastate/interstate  fare  comparison 515 

Texas  Aeronautics  Commission,  prepared  exhibits  : 

Southwest  Airline  service  awakened  sleeping  air  travel  markets  in 

Texas,   1971-1972 532 

Dallas-Houston  market:   average  daily  local  passengers  carried  in 

each  direction,  by  carrier,  1967-73 533 

Subcommittee  staff,  interstate/intrastate  fare  comparison :  tentative  staff 

conclusions    515 

Comparison  of  intrastate  and  interstate  routes  of  similar  distances, 
Feb.   1975 517 

Tuesday,   February  18,   1975 

TESTIMONY 

Panel  of  airlines :  William  A.  Hardenstine,  senior  vice  president — sales, 
World  Airways ;  Raymond  J.  Rasenberger,  counsel,  North  Central  Air- 
lines ;  Harvey  J.  Wexler,  senior  vice  president,  Continental  Airlines ; 
Edwin  I.  Colodny,  executive  vice  president,  marketing  and  legal  affairs, 
Allegheny  Airlines;  Andrew  M.  DeVoursney,  group  vice  president,  fi- 
nance and  planning.  United  Air  Lines;  and  Stuart  G.  Tipton,  senior  vice 

president.  Federal  affairs.  Pan  American  World  Airways 537 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Hardenstine 565 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Rasenberger 573 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Wexler 580 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Colodny 620 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  De  Voursney 629 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Tipton 637 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board  :  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman  ;  G.  Joseph 

Minetti,  Member,  and  Lee  R  West,  Member 646 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  O'Melia 660 

Panel  of  government  officials  :  Donald  I.  Baker,  Deputy  Assistant  Attorney 
General,  Antitrust  Division,  U.S.  Department  of  Justice;  and  William 

A.  Kutzke,  Counsel,   U.S.  Department  of  Transportation 664 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Baker 679 

Prepared  statement  of  John  W.  Snow,  Deputy  Assistant  Secretary  for 
Policy,  Plans,  and  International  Affairs,  U.S.  Department  of  Trans- 
portation (submitted  by  Mr.  Kutzke) 688 

Gagnon,    James,    chairman,    ad    hoc    committee   on    air   service.    Airport 

Operators  Council  International 695 

Prepared  statement 704 

EXHIBITS 

Allegheny  Airlines  prepared  exhibits  : 

50  percent  of  Allegheny's  passengers  are  generated  in  only  11  percent 

of  the  city-pairs  it  serves 626 

29  percent  of  Allegheny's  passengers  on  its  Pittsburgh-Philadelphia 
nonstop  flights  come  from  other  than  the  local  market,  July 
1974   627 

51  percent  of  Allegheny's  passengers  on  its  Chicago-Pittsburgh  non- 
stop flights  come  from  other  than  the  local  market,  July  1974 628 


VII 

Airport  Operators  Council  International,  prepared  exhibits  : 

Flowchart  of  the  CAB's  route  hearing  process  as  proposed  by  the     P^se 
CAB'S    staff 699 

Samples  of  high-load  factor  operations,  1973  and  1974 725 

Profit  leverage  created  by  increased  load  factor 726 

Pacific  Southwest  Airlines'  load  factor  history,  1967  to  fiscal  year 
1972  728 

Airport  Operators  Council  International,  letter  from  Donald  G.  Shay, 
president,  to  Senator  Kennedy,  dated  March  4,  1975,  clarifying  the  posi- 
tion of  the  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI 720 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  material  inserted  in  the  record  for  clarification : 
14  C.F.R.  sec.  399.60  (1974),  standards  for  determining  priorities  of 

hearing  650 

Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  Service  to  Small  Communities   (March 

1972),    excerpt 673 

Continental  Airlines,  prepared  exhibits  : 

Comparative  U.S.  and  foreign  coach  fares 587 

Continental  Airlines,  James  L.  Mitchell,  vice  president  for  regulatory  pro- 
ceedings, prepared  statement  (March  31,  1975),  in  response  to  the  testi- 
mony of  Dr.  Jordan  on  February  14,  1975 587 

California  intrastate  air  service,  1946-65,  by  carrier  and  by  city 593 

Pacific  Southwest  Airlines'  route  structure,  June  1965 594 

Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  and  Air  California,  route  structure,  1975- _       595 
Relationship  of  international  to  system  revenues  and  profit-selected 

trunks,  1973 600 

Continental   Airlines,    prepared   statement   in   response   to   the   prepared 

statement  of  Dr.  Jordan  of  April  21,  1975 617 

International  Air  Transport  Association.  Knut  Hammarskjold,  director 
general,  address  to  the  world  conference  on  tourism  and  air  transport 

(Feb.  10,  1975),  excerpts 754 

Jordan,  William  A.,  professor  of  managerial  economics,  York  University, 
prepared  statement  (April  21,  1975)  in  response  to  the  prepared  state- 
ment by  Mr.  Mitchell  of  Continental  Airlines  (March  31,  1975) 601 

Maryland  Department  of  Transportation,  Robert  J.  Aaronson,  State  Avia- 
tion Administrator,   prepared   statement 730 

Dulles  International  Airport's  primary  and  secondary  service  areas 

within  metropolitan  Baltimore/Washington 736 

Estimated  1975  Baltimore/Washington  passengers  using  Baltimore/ 
Washington    airport    under    adequate    nonstop    service    conditions 

(top  50  markets) 739 

Used  and  unused  nonstop  authority  in  Baltimore/Washington's  top 

50  markets 740 

Puerto  Rico,  Rafael  Hernandez-Colon,  Governor,  prepared  statement 743 

New  York-San  Juan  market,  load  factors,  1968-74 747 

Increases  in  lowest  regular  New  York-San  Juan  fares  and  proposed 

1975    fares 748 

Comparison  of  New  York-San  Juan  fares  with  other  vacation  markets, 

Feb.    1975 749 

Comparison  of  New  York-San  Juan  yields  with  other  vacation  mar- 
kets, Feb.  1975 750 

Airline  unadjusted  results,  mainland-Puerto  Rico/Virgin  Islands  mar- 
kets, year  ended  June  30.  1974 751 

Pan  American's  own  projections  indicate  that  passenger  fare  increases 
ranging  from  27  to  67  percent  would  be  required  at  Pan  American's 
high  expense  and  investment  levels  to  achieve  a  12  percent  rate  of 

return    752 

Comparative  indirect  expen.ses  levels,  fiscal  1974  vs.  calendar  1971 753 

United  Air  Lines,  letter  from  Andrew  De  Voursney,  group  president  of 
finance  and  planning,  to  Senator  Kennedy,  dated  Feb.  28,  1975,  concern- 
ing the  effect  of  deregulation  upon  small-town  service 635 

United  Air  Lines,  letter  from  William  R.  Nesbit,  corporate  economist,  to 
the  subcommittee,  dated  Apr.  29,  1975,  concerning  the  effect  of  dereg- 
ulation upon  small-town  service 636 


U.S.  Department  of  Transportation,  letter  from  John  W.  Snow,  Acting 
Assistant  Secretary  for  Congressional  and  Intergovernmental  affairs,  to 
Senator  Kennedy,  dated  Apr.  25,  1975,  responding  to  several  followup     Page 

questions  by  Senators  Kennedy  and  Thurmond 690 

Distribution  of  travelers  along  the  California  coast  and  the  Northeast 

coast,  by  mode  of  travel,  1968  and  1970 694 

Virginia  Aviation  Transportation  and  Airports  Study  Commission,  letter 
from  Paul  W.  Manns,  chairman,  to  Senator  Kennedy,  dated  Febru- 
ary 11,  1975 755 

World  Airways,  prepared  exhibits : 

CAB  filing  fees  for  12  months  ended  June  30,  1974 566 

Documents  necessary  for  a  single  travel  group  charter  flight 566 

Summary  of  World's  1967  proposal  for  a  $75  transcontinental  service—  567 

Instructions  for  travel  group  charter  application 571 

VOLUME  2 

Wednesday,   February   19,   1975 

TESTIMONY 

Panel  of  consumers'  groups:  Patricia  Kennedy,  traffic  analyst.  Aviation 
Consumer  Action  Project ;  Jens  Jurgen  Wegscheider,  Travel  Informa- 
tion Bureau;  and  Mark   Silbergeld,  attorney.   Consumers   Union 761 

Prepared  statement  of  Ms.  Kennedy 832 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Wegscheider 840 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Silbergeld 848 

Panel  of  travel  clubs  and  charter  carriers :  Edward  J.  McDevitt,  Air  Club 
International;  G.  F.  Steedman  Hinckley,  chaii-man  and  chief  executive 
oflScer,  Overseas  National  Airways ;  and  Robert  Beckman,  attorney.  Air 

Europe  International -- _" 866 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  McDevitt 949 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Hinckley 951 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Beckman 1052 

Yohe,  Jack,  Director,  Office  of  the  Consumer  Advocate,  Civil  Aeronautics 

Board    1053 

Prepared    statement 1119 

EXHIBITS 

Air  Club  International,  prepared  exhibits : 

Order  74-9-70  (1970) —       869 

American  Airlines,  Randall  Malin,  vice  president,  marketing  planning, 
letter  to  the  subcommittee,  dated  Apr.  4,  1975,  concerning  inter  alia  cross 

subsidy 1141 

Aviation  Consumer  Action  Project,  prepared  exhibits  : 

Consumer   information   pamphlets 764 

Passenger   rules   tariff,   No.   380,   failure   to  operate   on   schedule  or 

failure  to  carry i 772 

Examples  of  a  major  airline's  advertisement  campaign 792 

CAB  Order  72-11-106  (1972),  ACAP  vs.  Trans  World  Airlines 804 

CAB  Order  73-6-9   (1973) 811 

Letter  from  Reuben  B.  Robertson  III,  and  Martin  M.  Temkin,  at- 
torneys from  Herbert  A.  Goldberg,  to  CAB,  dated  Jan.  21,  1974, 
reouesting    final    decision    in    the    case    of   American   Airlines   vs. 

Herbert   A.    Goldberg -- 826 

"How  to  Join  Airline  Club  :   8- Year  Wait,"  Wa.shington   Star-News, 

Jan.    27,    1974 - 829 

Consumers  Union,  prepared  exhibits  : 

"How  Airlines  Overcharge  on  Connecting  Flights,"  Consumers  Re- 
ports, May  1972 — 850 

"CAB  Tallies  Complaints  Against  U.S.  Airlines,"  Consumers  Reports, 

Aug.   1972 — 855 

"  'Discount'  Air  Fares :  A  Maze  of  Overcharges,"  Consumers  Reports, 

Oct.    1972 — 856 

"CAB  Speaks  Softlv  But  Wields  No  Stick,"  Consumers  Reports,  Nov. 
1972   861 


IX 

Consumers  Union,  prepared  exhibits — Continued 

"A  Small  Step  Toward  Fairer  Air  Fares,"  Consumers  Reports,  Jan.     I'aee 
1973   861 

"Still  Searching  for  a  Correct  Air  Fare,"  Consumers  Reports,  Feb. 
1973  861 

"Meet  the  New  Elite:   Airline  Club  Members,"   Consumers  Reiwrts, 
Apr.     1973 863 

"CAB  Cites  Airlines  for  Overcharging,"  Consumers  Reports,  June  1973_      864 
"Most   Airlines   in    Same   Place  on    Scorecard   of  Complaints,"    Con- 
sumers Reports,  Oct.  1973 865 

Cathy,  Henry  D.,  Jr.,  Director  of  Transportation,  New  Castle,  Delaware, 
and  William  H.  Comer,  Sr.,  Airport  Manager,  Greater  Wilmington  Air- 
port,   prepared    statement 1129 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  prepared  exhibits : 

Jaclv  Yohe,  Office  of  Consumer  Affair.s,  Consumer  Complaint  Survey 

(1973)    - 1063 

Jack    Yohe,    Director,    Office   Affairs,    "A   White   Paper   on   Airlines' 

Handling  of  Baggage  Claims"   (Oct.  1973) 1073 

CAB  Order  E-24198  (1966),  Baggage  Liahility  Rules  Case 1103 

CAB,  letter  to  scheduled  U.S.  air  carriers,  Feb.  1975,  regarding  tariff 

complexity   1111 

CAB,  letter  from  Jack  Yohe,  Director,  Office  of  the  Consumer  Advo- 
cate, dated  Dec.  12,  1974,  to  consumers 1116 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  letter  from  Jack  Yohe,  Director,  Office  of  the 
Consumer  Advocate,   to   Senator  ICdvvard  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Apr.   14, 

1975,  listing  the  budgets  of  the  CAB  departments 1055 

Civil    Aeronautics    Board,    "Notice    of    Proiwsed    Rulemaking :    Baggage 

Delay  and  Loss  Compensation,"  Mar.  6,  1975 1124 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  "Notice  of  Propo.sed  Rulemaking:  Construction, 
Publication,  Filing,  and  Posting  of  Tariffs  of  Air  Carriers  and  Foreign 

Air  Carriers,"  Mar.  6,  1975 1127 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  James  L.  Weldon,  Jr.,  Acting  Director,  Bureau 
of  Enforcement,  to  Senator  Kennedy,  dated  Apr.  10,  1975,  in  response  to 
Senator  Kennedy's  letter  of  Mar.  25,  1975,  concerning  the  allocation  of 

BOE  effort  between  various  kinds  of  carriers 1132 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  reference  material  inserted  in  the  record  by 
the  subcommittee : 

Summary   of   investigative  time   of  the   Bureau   of  Enforcement   by 

category  of  investigation,  1971-74 '. 760 

Kennedy,  Senator  Edward  M..  letter  to  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chair- 
man, Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  dated  Mar.  25,  1975,  containing  several 

followup    questions 1131 

Kohn,   Eugene   H.,   Docktor  Pet   Centers,   prepared   statement    (Feb.   25, 

1975)    1130 

"I'm  Suzie,  Don't  Fly  Me!  Facts  About  Air  Travel  for  Pets"___ 1130 

Overseas  National  Airways,  prepared  exhibits  : 

CAB  Order  E-19492   (1963) 967 

"CAB  Knew  of  $!/>  Billion  North  Atlantic  Rebating  in  1971,"  Travel 

Trade  Gazette,  Feb.  1975 978 

"Airlines  Admit  to  Paying  Travel  Agents  Kickbacks,"  New  York  Times, 

Dec.  21,  1974 979 

"Airlines    Plan    to    Settle    Kickback    Investigation    Given   to   Justice 

Unit,"  Wall  Street  Journal,  Feb.  13,  1975 980 

Complaint  of  National  Air  Carrier  Association  Against  Airlift  Inter- 
national and  Seaboard  World  Airlines,  dated  Feb.  14,  1975 983 

Advance  booking  round  trip  charters  under  proposed  S.  421 993 

Examples  of  affirmative  NACA  proposals  to  CAB  relating  to  charter 

rules,  1969  to  1974 994 

CAB   Order  74-11-122    (1974) 995 

Comparison  of  S.  421  and  CAB's  TGC  mode 998 

"CAB  :  Can  This  Agency  Be  Saved?"  Air  Transport  World,  Jan.  1975--     1000 
The  development  of  the  intra-European  charter  market  and  its  rele- 
vance in  projecting  trends  in  other  world  markets 1003 


TtJESDAY,  February  25,  1975 

TESTIMONY 

Page 

Nader,    Ralph 1150 

Prepared  statement 1163 

Panel  of  Administration  officials :  John  W.  Snow,  Deputy  Assistant  Secre- 
tary for  Policy,  Plans,  and  International  Affairs,  L^.S'.  Department  of 
Transportation;  Donald  I.  Baker,  Deputy  Assistant  Attorney  General, 
Antitrust  Division,   U.S.  Department  of  Justice;  and  George  C.  Eads, 

Assistant  Director,  Cotmcil  of  Wage  and  Price  Stability 1179 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Snow 1200 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Baker 1203 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Eads 1211 

Finney,  Thomas  D.,  Jr.,  counsel.  Continental  Airlines 1220 

Prepared  statement 1237 

Muse,  M.  Lamar,  president.  Southwest  Airlines 1242 

Prepared  statement 1250 

Dingivan,  Edward  A.,  vice  president.  National  Air  Carriers  Association. ^  1260 

Prepared  statement 1282 

EXHIBITS 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  materials  inserted  in  the  record  for  clarification : 

Estimates  of  cost  per  passenger,  charter  service,  for  .-^e'ected  markets.     1279 
Keeler,  Theodore  E.,  assistant  professor  of  economics,  Univ.  of  California 

at  Berkeley,  prepared  statement 1296 

Airline  costs  and  fares  for  30  city-pairs  (1968  prices) 1300 

Fares,  costs,  and  regulation 1304 

Keeler,  Theodore  E.,  "Airline  Regulation  and  Market  Performance'".-     1305 

Load  factors — California  intrastate  vs.  trunk,  1951  to  1970 1315 

Airline  costs  and  fares  for  30  city-pairs  (1968  prices) 1317 

Airline  costs  and  prices  with  a  50-percent  load  factor  (1968  prices )__     1318 

1972  fares  and  costs 1319 

Nader,  Ralph,  prepared  exhibits : 

Conn,  Stephen,  "Airlines  and  Alaska  :  The  Ever- Weakening  Thread"--     1168 

"Convention  of  Association  of  Village  Council  Presidents" 1171 

"Alaska  Aviation  Industry  Is  Really  Riding  High"  (Feb.  1975) 1174 

"New  Air  Cargo  Center  Opens"  (Feb.  1975) 1177 

Nader,  Ralph,  Answers  to  Questions  of  Senator  Thurmond 1177 

National  Air  Carriers  Association,  prepared  exhibits : 

CAB  Order  74-10-106  (Oct.  30,  1974)   (North  Atlantic  lATA  fares)—     1263 
Statements  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  on  passenger  fare  matters 
to  be  negotiated  at  the  lATA  North  Atlantic  Traffic  Conference  in 

Fort  Lauderdale   (June  1974) 1276 

Sample  comparison   of   scheduled   normal   fares   with   charter   rates 

(March  1975) 1285 

National  Air  Carrier  Association,  Edward  J.  Driscoll,  president,  letter 
to    the    subcommittee,    dated    May    6,    1975,    concerning   suggested 

changes  to  the  charter  restrictions 1286 

"Briefs"  regarding  U.S.  supplementals'  safety  record  over  the  last 

decade  1288 

National  Transportation  Safety  Board,  press  release,  Apr.  17,  1975 1295 

Southwest  Airlines,   prepared  exhibits : 

Passengers   in   Dallas-Houston,    Dallas-San   Antonio,    and   Houston- 
San  Antonio    (1965-72) 1252 

Southwest  Airlines,   M.   Lamar  Muse,  president,  letter  to  subcommittee, 

dated  May  7,  1975,  describing  new  service  to  Harlingen,  Tex 1253 

Southwest  Airlines.  Paul  Y.  Seligson,  attorney,  letter  to  the  subcommittee, 

dated  May  9,  1975,  describing  new  service  to  Harlingen,  Tex 1257 

U.S.  Department  of  Justice,  prepared  exhibits: 

Indictment  in  United  States  v.  Braniff  Airways,  Inc.,  crim.  No.  SA-75 

(W.D.  Tex.,  filed  Feb.  14,  1973) 1190 


XI 

Wednesday,  Febeuaby  26,  1975 

TESTIMONY 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board :  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman ;  Whitney 

Gillilland,    Vice   Chairman;    G.   Joseph   Minetti,   member;   and  Lee  R.  Page 

West,  member 1^23 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  O'Melia 1386 

EXHIBITS 

Browne,  Secor,  former  Chairman,  CAB,  minutes  of  a  telephone  interview 
with  the  subcommittee  staff  on  February  28,  1J)75  (original  staff  notes 
and  the  version  corrected  by  Mr.  Browne) 1361 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman,  letter  to 
Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Apr.  11,  1975,  concerning  the  develop- 
ment of  efficiency  standards  for  airlines 1350 

Additional    comments    of   members    G.    Joseph    Minetti    and    Lee   R. 


West 


1351 


CAB,    Bureau    of    Economics,    submission    in    the    mainland    United 

States-Puerto  Rico  Case  (1975) 1593 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  William  B.  Caldwell,  Jr.,  Director,  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights,  letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Apr.  3, 
1975,  responding  to  Senator  Kennedy's  letter  of  March  25,  1975,  request- 
ing an  explanation  of  BOR  practice  of  highlighting  of  "effect  on  indus- 

trv's  rate  of  return"  in  memos  to  the  Board 1374 

Civii  Aeronautics  Board,  John  E.  Robson,  Chairman,  letter  to  Senator 
Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  May  30,  1975,  concerning  disclosure  of  CAB 

officials  prior  business  relations  and  contacts  with  outsiders 1385 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman,  letter  to 
Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  April  11, 1975,  in  response  to  Senator 
Kennedy's  letter  of  Mar.  17,  1975  concerning  inaugural  flights,  gratuities, 

and  travel  vouchers  of  CAB  officials 1392 

CAB,  Phyllis  T.  Taylor,  Acting  Chief,  Minutes  Section,  memorandum 
to  the  General  Counsel,  CAB,  dated  Dec.  6,  1966,  on  the  subject  of 
the   rules   applicable   to  the   participation   by   Board   personnel  in 

inaugural  ceremonial  flights  (notation  8932) 1398 

CAB,  John  H.  Warner,  General  Counsel,  memorandum  to  the  Executive 
Director,  dated  Jan.  9,  1964.  on  the  subject  of  the  rules  applicable 
to  the  participation  by  Board  personnel  in  inaugural  or  ceremonial 

flights    I'lO'^ 

Comptroller  General  of  the  U.S.,  letter  opinion  to  the  Chairman  of 
the  CAB,  dated  May  20,  1958  (37  Comp.  Gen.  776)  concerning  cere- 
monial  flights 1409 

CAB,  memorandum  from  the  Board's  minutes  files  entitled  "Inaugural- 
Ceremonial  Flights"  (undated) 1414 

CAB,  Regulation  Policy  Statement  No.  19,  to  Part  399  of  the  Regu- 
lations  (14  CFR  399  et  seq)    (1963) 1419 

CAB,  Regulation  Policy  Statement  No.  6,  to  Part  223  of  the  Regu- 
lations   (14  CFR  223  et  seq)    (1958) 1426 

CAB,  Regulation  Policv  Statement  No.  21.  to  Part  399  of  the  Regu- 
lations (14  CFR  399  et  seq)    (1964)    (excerpt) 1431 

CAB,  Andrew  J.  Anessi.  Chief,  Tariffs  Section,  Bureau  of  Economics, 
letter  to  Marion  F.  Curran.  Director — Special  Transportation  and 
Sales  Agreements.  Pan  American  World  Airways,  dated  April  24, 

1973,   approving  an   inaugural  flight  to  Caracas.   Venezuela 1436 

CAB,    news    release   of   May    7,    1973,    describing   the   dedication    of 

certain  aviation  facilities  in  Oakland 1441 

CAB,  sections  360  to  367A  of  the  Regulations,  relating  to  reimburse- 
ment of  CAB  employees  for  travel  expenses  (1973) 1444 

CAB,  Brief  for  Timm  in  the  case  of  Aviation  Consumer  Action  Project 

V.  Timm,  No.  74-1945   (D.C.  Cir.  1975) 1553 

CAB,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  complaints  alleging  the  illegality  of 
"VIP"  treatment  by  20  airlines  in  favor  of  certain  persons  and 
I)etitions  for  enforcement  (1974) 1582 


XII 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  materials  inserted  in  the  record  by  the  subcom- 
mittee for  clarification : 

Tables  showing  the  return  on  investment  of  the  airlines  as  a  group     Pa&e 

(1947-74)    and  by  carrier    (1962-71) 1332 

CAB,  Ralph  L.  Wisner,  Chief  Administrative  Law  Judge,  memorandum 
to  Robert  Timm,  Chairman,  CAB,  dated  April  2,  1973,  listing  route 
cases  unheard  "pursuant  to  informal  instructions  of  the  Chairman's 
office    in    connection    with    the    unofficial    moratorium    on    route 

eases"    ^^^^ 

Example  of  a  CAB  staff  memo  highlighting  the  topic  "Effect  on  Indus- 
try's Rate  of  Return" 1368 

Lazarus,  Monte,  former  assistant  to  Secor  Browne,  former  Chairman,  CAB, 
minutes  of  a  telephone  interview  with  the  subcommittee  staff  on  Feb- 
ruary  27,    1975    (original    staff   notes    and    the    version    corrected    by 

Mr.    Lazarus) 1363 

Lockheed-California  Co.,  Grayden  M.  Paul,  director,  airline  requirements, 
letter  to  the  subcommittee,  dated  Mar.  21,  1975,  containing  cost  estimates 
of   operating   the   L-lOll-l    for   various    distances   with   various   load 

factors    1336 

Mcintosh,  Colin,  "Airline  Profits  .  .  .  Why  Delta?  .  .  .  And  Why  Not 
Eastern?"  Air  Transport  World,  July  1974  (inserted  by  the  subcommittee 

for    clarification) 1345 

Pan  American  World  Airways,  Patrick  W.  Lee,  attorney,  letter  to  the  sub- 
committee, dated  June  19,  1975,  replying  to  the  submission  of  the  CAB's 

Bureau  of  Economics  in  the  letter  of  Apr.  11,  1975 1663 

Wisner,  Ralph  L.,  former  Chief  Administrative  Law  Judge,  CAB,  minutes 
of  a  telephone  interview  with  the  subcommittee  staff  on  February  25, 
1975  (original  staff  notes  and  the  version  corrected  by  Mr.  Wisner) 1359 

VOLUME  3 

Tuesday,  March  4,  1975 

TESTIMONY 

Panel  of  airlines :  Randall  Malin,  vice  president,  marketing  planning, 
American  Airlines;  Edward  A.  Beamish,  senior  vice  president,  corpo- 
rate planning.   United  Air  Lines;  and  Richard   S.  Mauer,  senior  vice 

president  and  general  counsel.  Delta  Air  Lines 1699 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Malin 1^4 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Beamish 1T27 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.   Mauer 1732 

Baker.  Donald  I.,  Deputy  Assistant  Attorney  General,  Antitrust  Divi- 
sion,   U.S.    Department    of   Justice 1737 

Prepared  statement 1742 

Panel  of  community  representatives :  Erie  A.  Taylor,  director  of  avia- 
tion, Clark  County,  Nevada;  and  Robert  J.  Aaronson.  administrator. 
State  Aviation  Administration,  Maryland  Department  of  Transporta- 
tion          1753 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Taylor 1764 

Prepared   statement  of  Mr.   Aaronson 1777 

Civil    Aeronautics    Board :    Richard    J.    O'Melia,    Acting   Chairman,    and 

Robert   Timm,    member 1781 

Prepared  statement  of  Mr.  O'Melia 1795 

Gilstrap,  Roderic  W.,  first  vice  president,  Air  Line  Pilots  Association 2150 

Prepared  statement 2151 

EXHIBITS 

Air  Line  Pilots  Association,  International,  J.  J.  O'Donnell,  president,  pre- 
pared statement 2221 

American  Airlines,  prepared  exhibits : 

CAB,  James  L.  Weldon,  Jr.,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  letter  to  James 
W.  Callison,  Delta  Air  Lines,  dated  Dec.  17,  1974,  denying  Delta 
Air  Lines'  petition  for  an  enforcement  proceeding  against  American 

Airlines 1722 

American  Airlines,  Richard  J.  Fahy,  Jr.,  attorney,  letter  to  the  subcom- 
mittee, dated  Mar.  13,  1975,  commenting  upon  the  prepared  exhibits  of 
Clark  County,  Nevada 1776 


XIII 

Bower,  Richard  S.,  professor  of  business  economics,  Dartmouth  College, 

special  study  for  the  subcommittee  on  the  appropriate  return  on  equity     Page 

in  the  airline  industry 2284a 

Trunk  airlines,  ratio  of  market  value  of  stock  to  book  value,  and 

return  on  book  value,  by  carrier,  1964-73 2284g 

Table  showing  association  of  market  price  per  share/book  value  per 

share  with  return  on  book  equity 2284k 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  William  B.  Caldwell,  Jr.,  Director,  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights,  letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Feb.  28, 
1975,  categorizing  8,057  interairline  agreements  submitted  to  the  CAB, 

1967-74  1790 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  materials  inserted  in  the  record  by  the  subcom- 
mittee for  clarification  and  documentation  : 

CAB  Order  70-11-35  (Nov.  6,  1970),  rejecting  the  "cluster"  agreement 

between  American,  TWA,  and  United 1800 

CAB  Order  71-8-91  (Aug.  19,  1971),  approving  the  "transcontinental 

economic  agreement"  between  American,  TWA,  and  United 1805 

CAB  Order  72-11-6  (Nov.  2,  1972),  approving  first  extension  of  the 

"transcontinental  economic  agreement" 1818 

CAB  Order  73-7-147  (July  27,  1973),  approving  the  2d  extension  of  the 

"transcontinental  economic  agreement" 1846 

CAB  Order  72-6-70  (June  16,  1971),  approving  the  N.Y.-San  Juan 
"economic"     agreement    between    American,     Eastern,     and    Pan 

American   1884 

CAB  Order  72-11-7  (Nov.  2,  1972),  approving  the  first  extension  of  the 

N.Y.-San  Juan  "economic"  agreement 1892 

CAB  Order  73-8-59  (Aug.  10,  1973),  approving  the  2d  extension  of  the 

N.Y.-San  Juan  "economic"  agreement 1902 

CAB  Order  7a-10-110  (Oct.  31,  1973),  approving  the  "20-market  fuel- 
related  agreement"  and  the  "transcontinental  fuel-related  agree- 
ment" between  American,  TWA,  and  United 1913 

CAB  Order  74-7-105  (July  24,  1974)  approving  the  2d  extension  of  the 
"20-market  fuel-related  agreement"  and  the  "transcontinental  fuel- 
related  agreement" 1927 

CAB  Order  75-1-140  (Jan.  31,  1975),  approving  the  3d  extension  of  the 
"20-market  fuel-related  agreement"  and  the  "transcontinental  fuel- 
related  agreement" 1957 

Capacity  Reduction  Agreements  Case,  initial  decision 1984 

Clark  County,  Nevada,  prepared  exhibits  : 

TraflBc  in  the  Las  Vegas-New  York  market,  the  Las  Vegas-Chicago 
market,  and  for  the  Las  Vegas  station,  before  and  after  the  capacity 

reduction  agreements   were  initiated 1769 

Actual  vs.  standard  load  factors.  Las  Vegas-Denver,  Jan.-Mar.  1974__     1770 
Las  Vegas  markets  subject  to  capacity  reduction  agreements  and  dura- 
tion of  agreements 1772 

Bar  graph  showing  deleterious  effect  of  capacity  reduction  agreements 

in  Las  Vegas-New  York  and  Las  Vegas-Chicago  markets 1773 

Load  factors  in  Las  Vegas'  agreement  markets  compared  with  other 

load   factor  standards 1773 

Bar  graph  showing  actual  vs.  standard  load  factors.  Las  Vegas-Denver 

market.  Jan.-Mar.   1974 1774 

Las  Vegas-Denver  agreement  cost  Las  Vegas  $1  million   (excluding 

gambling) 1775 

Clark  County,  Nev.,  Richard  P.  Taylor,  attorney  for  Erie  Taylor,  letter 
to  the  subcommittee,  dated  Mar.  27,  1975,  commenting  upon  American 

Airlines'  letter  of  Mar.  13,  1975 1776 

Delta  Air  Lines,  R.  S.  Maurer,  senior  vice  president  and  general  counsel, 
letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Mar.  7,  1975,  concerning 

E^st  coast-Florida  load  factors.  Mar.  1974-Feb.  1975 1710 

Delta  Air  Lines.  R.  S.  Maurer,  senior  vice  president  and  general  counsel, 
letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  Mar.  21.  1975,  commenting 

generally  on  the  antitrust  immunity  for  interairline  agreements 1735 

Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  sees.  412,  414.  49  U.S.C.  sees.  1382,  1384  (1970) 

(inserted  in  the  record  by  the  subcommittee  for  clarification) 1782 


XIV 

Karth,  Joseph  E.,  Congressman,  Fourth  District,  Minnesota,  prepared  state-     Page 

ment  on  the  mutual  aid  pact 2228 

Kimbriel,  Harry  A.,  Jr.,  vice  president,  Alliance  One,  prepared  statement--     2234 
Moser,  Herbert  H.,  vice  president,  Merrill  Lynch,  Pierce,  Fenner  &  Smith 

Inc.,  prepared  statement '_     2240 

Personal  outlays  on  transportation  and  recreation  services  as  percent- 
age of  disposable  personal  income,  1968  dollars,  1953-74 2242 

Personal  consumption  expenditures  on  purchased  transportation  as 

percent  of  disposable  personal  income,  1950-72 2243 

Cyclicality  of  domestic  trunk  traffic,  1953-69 2244 

Relative  weight  of  factors  contributing  to  increase  in  traffic,  1962-66__     2244 
Seasonality  of  North  Atlantic  and  Mainland-Hawaii  scheduled  air 

traffic 2246 

Distribution  of  travel  by  purpose  of  trip,  for  automobile  and  airplane, 

1972    2247 

Characteristics  of  nonbusiness  travel,  by  automobile  and  airplane,  1972     2248 
Income  distribution  of  travelers,  for  automobile  and  airplane,  1972___     2249 

Domestic  trunk  and  North  Atlantic  traffic,  1970-74  (by  month) 2250 

Distribution  of  1971  domestic  trunk  coach  traffic,  by  fare  plans 2252 

North  Atlantic  traffic,  scheduled  vs.  charter,  1967,  1970,  and  1973 2253 

New  York-London,  summer  roundtrip  fares,  1972-74 2254 

Travel  agents'  commissions  and  reservations  and  sales  expense  as  a 

percentage  of  total  passenger  revenues 2255 

Capital  and  stock  structure  comparisons,  U.S.  trunk  airlines  and  man- 
ufacturing corporations,  1961-73 2256 

Airline  increases  in  employment  costs  outpace  those  of  other  U.S.  in- 
dustries,   1965-70 2257 

Trunk  passenger  load  factors,  1963-74 2258 

Trunk  airline  stock  prices  and  earnings,  1965-74 2260 

U.S.  population  distribution,  1961-80 2261 

Projection  of  families  by  income  class  percent  distribution,  1970-80 2262 

Income  propensity  and  elasticity  of  international  travel 2262 

Peltzman,  Sam,  professor  of  economics.  University  of  Chicago,  prepared 

statement   2265 

Trans  World  Airlines,  IMelvin  A.  Brenner,  vice  president,  marketing  plan- 
ning, prepared  statement  (Mar  4,  1975) 2155 

Industry  load  factors,  New  York-Los  Angeles  market,  before  and  after 

the  capacity  reduction  agreements 2158 

Trunk  airlines'  return  on  investment,  1955-74 2159 

Trunk  airlines'  load  factors,  year  ending  Sept.  30,  1973 2160 

Trunk  airlines'  load  factors,  Nov.  1973-Jan  1974  compared  with  Nov. 

1974-Jan.    1975 2161 

Brief  of  TWA  in  the  Capacity  Reduction  Agreements  Case,  CAB  docket 

22908  (filed  Feb.  7,  1975) 2162 

Trunkline  airlines'  rate  of  return  on  investment,  domestic  operations, 

by  carrier,  1967-71 2183 

Load  factors  in  the  transcontinental  agreement  markets,  1967-71,  com- 
pared with  the  load  factors  of  the  domestic  trunkline  operations.—     2185 

Percentage  changes  in  domestic  trunkline  trafSc,  1972-74 2198 

U.S.,  Circuit  Court  of  Appeals  for  the  D.C.  Circuit,  materials,  inserted  in 
the  record  by  the  subcommittee  for  clarification   and   documentation: 

Air  Line  Pilots  Ass'n.  v.  CAB,  475  F.2d  900  (D.C.  Cir.  1973) 1976 

United  States  v.  CAB, F.2d (D.C.  Cir.  1975) 2119 

U.S.  Department  of  Transportation,  John  W.  Barnum,  Acting  Secretary, 

prepared  statement  (Mar  4,  1975) <;— V""" 

U  S  Department  of  Transportation.  John  W.  Barnum,  Deputy  Secretary, 
letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  dated  July  24.  1974  evaluating 
the  ATA  Rtudv.  "Consequences  of  Deregulation"    (p.  139.  above)  _  --»t) 

U  S     General  Accounting  Office,  partial  response  to  Senator  Edward  M_ 

Kennedy's  request  for  an  evaluation  of  the  ATA  study,  "Consequences  of     ^^^ 

■npreo-nlation"   (p.  139,  above) . 7, ;?       "" 

Subcommittee  staff,  an  insert  for  the  general  reader  -Pjf -"^ ';7^„^7£ 

reduction  agreements"  and  giving  a  chronology  of  events  relevant  to  the     ^^^ 
hearings  of  this  day 


XV 

Fetoay,  March  21,   1975 
TESTIMONY 

Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  former  Assistant  Chief,  Formal  Proceedings  Divi-     Page 

siou,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 2303 

Burns,   Bernard  B.,   former  investigator,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,   Civil 

Aeronautics  Board 2323 

Rickey,  Robert  F.,  former  Assistant  Chief,  Investigation  Division,  Bureau 

of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 2326 

Weldon,  James  L.,  Jr.,  former  Chief,  Formal  Proceedings  Division,  Bureau 

of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 2329 

Hadlock,  Gerald  F.,  former  Deputy  Director,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  Civil 

Aeronautics  Board 2336 

Knudson,  John  V.,  former  investigator,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board 2344 

Edison,  Peter  C,  former  Assistant  Chief,  Informal  Compliance  Division, 

Bureau  of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 2348 

Rodriguez,  Elias  C,  former  Chief,  Informal  Compliance  Division,  Bureau 

of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 2349 

O'Melia,  Richard  J.,  Acting  Chairman,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board ;  formerly 

Director,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  CAB 2350 

Timm,  Robert  D.,  member.  Civil  Aeronautics  Board ;  formerly  Chairman, 

CAB   2374 

EXHIBITS 

Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  material  inserted  in  the  record  by  the  subcommit- 
tee for  clarification  or  documentation  : 
Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  memorandum  to  the  Director,  BOE,  dated  July 

12,  1973,  on  the  subject  of  "contributions :  analysis  of  Federal  Avia- 
tion Act  violations" 2304 

Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  memorandum  to  the  Director,  BOE,  dated  July 

13,  1973,  on  the  subject  of  "illegal  campaign  contributions :  methods 

of  proceeding" 2305 

Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  memorandum  to  the  Director,  BOE,  dated  July 
20,  1975.  on  the  subject  of  "investigation  of  illegal  unreported  cam- . 
paign  contributions:  proposed  action" 2307 

Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  memorandum  to  Chief,  Litigation  Division, 
CAB,  dated  July  25.  1973,  on  the  subject  of  "illegal  unreported  cam- 
paign contributions:  guide  for  questioning"  (showing  questions 
subsequently  deleted)   2312 

Alterman,  Stephen  A.,  memorandum  to  the  file  on  "Unreported  Cam- 
paign Contributions  Investigation,"  dated  July  31,  1973,  on  the  sub- 
ject of  "summary  of  action" 2317 

Memorandum  from  Assistant  Chief,  Legal  Division,  CAB.  to  Chief. 
Investigation  and  Audit  Division,  CAB,  dated  Feb.  28,  1975,  on  the 
subject  of  "special  audits/political  contribution  cases" 2336 

Memorandum,  dated  Nov.  5,  1973,  closing  one  of  the  campaign  contri- 
bution cases 2345 

O'Melia,  Richard  J..  Director,  BOE,  memorandum  to  Chairman,  CAB. 
dated  Aug.  8.  1973.  on  the  subject  of  "industrywide  survey  regarding 
political  contributions  by  air  carriers" 2355 

Timm.  Robert  D..  Chairman,  memorandum  to  Director,  BOB,  on  the 
subject  of  "industrywide  survey  regarding  political  contributions 
by  air  carriers" 2356 

Stout.  Joseph  W..  Jr..  memorandum  to  Chairman.  CAB.  dated  Mar.  7, 

1975.  on  the  subject  of  "political  contribu^^ion  investigation" 2364 

Example  of  field  report  of  the  "industrywide  survey  regarding  politi- 
cal contrihuHons  by  air  carriers"  (Julv  1973') 2367 

Stont,  Joseph  W..  Jr..  Chief.  Investisration  and  Audit  Division.  BOE.  to 
Director,  BOE,  dated  Mar.  18,  1974,  on  the  subject  of  "completed 

invpstisration  ca^es" 2368 

Gingerv.  William  M..  former  Director.  Bureau  of  Enforcement.  CAB.  letter 
to  the  .subcommittee,  dated  Februarv  15.  1975.  concerning  hi«  investiga- 
tion of  BOE^  investisrntion  of  the  failure  of  certain  airlines  to  report 
certain  campaign  contributions  in  1973 2300 


XVI 

Kennedy,  Senator  Edward  M.,  letter  to  Edward  H.  Levi,  U.S.  Attorney 
General,  dated  May  12,  1975,  requesting  an  investigation  to  determine 
w'lietlier  Federal  criminal  laws  were  violated  in  connection  with  sworn 
testimony  before  the  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Pro- 
cedure of  the  Senate  Committee  on  the  Judiciary  on  Mar.  21,  1975  and  in 
connection  with  the  CAB's  investigation  of  possible  corporate  iwlitical  Page 
contributions  by  air  carriers  in  1973 2385 


DEPOSITIONS  TAKEN  BY  THE   SUBCOMMITTEE 

Heye,  Thomas,  former  Administrative  Assistant  to  Robert  D.  Timm,  Chair- 
man, Civil  Aeronautics  Board  {deposition  taken  Mar.  27,  1975) 2387 

Stout,  Joseph  W.,  Jr.,  former  Chief,  Inv&stigation  and  Audit  Division, 
Bureau  of  Enforcement,  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  (deposition  taken  Apr. 
18,  1975)   2419 


List  of  witnesses  by  name  and  organization 2471 

Persons  who  submitted  additional  material  at  the  subcommittee's  request- _     2474 
Topical  index 2475 


Volume   1 


OVERVIEW  OF  FEDERAL  ECONOMIC  REGULATION  OF 
DOMESTIC  AIR  TRANSPORT 


THURSDAY,    FEBRUARY    6,     1975 

U.S.  Senate, 
Subcommittee  on  Administrative 

Practice  and  Procedure  of  the 

Committee  on  the  Judiciary, 

Washington^  D.C. 
The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  notice,  at  10:20  a.m.,  in  room 
2228,  Dirksen  Office  Building,  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy  (chair- 
man of  the  subcommittee)  presiding. 
Present :  Senator  Kennedy. 

Also  present :  Stephen  Breyer,  special  counsel ;  Philip  Bakes,  assist- 
ant counsel;  Thomas  M.  Susman,  chief  counsel;  and  Lewis  Beasley, 
assistant  to  Senator  Tliurmond. 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  subcommittee  will  come  to  order. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  SENATOR  KENNEDY 

The  Senate  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Pro- 
cedure is  today  continuing  the  examination  it  began  last  November 
of  the  procedures  and  practices  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  The 
subcommittee  has  scheduled  7  days  of  hearings  this  winter  to  look  into 
the  CAB's  activities  relating  to  rates,  entry,  enforcement,  and 
antitrust. 

Federal  regulation  of  transportation  began  in  the  1880's  with  two 
objectives :  First,  to  protect  the  consumer  from  concentrations  of  eco- 
nomic power,  and  second,  to  guarantee  that  essential  transportation 
would  be  available  to  all  Americans.  But  regulation  has  gone  astray. 
What  may  have  been  good  for  the  last  quarter  of  the  19th  century  is  a 
disaster  for  the  last  quarter  of  the  20th  century.  Either  because  they 
have  become  captives  of  regulated  industries  or  captains  of  outmoded 
administrative  agencies,  regulators  all  too  often  encourage  or  approve 
imreasonably  high  prices,  inadequate  service,  and  anticompetitive  be- 
havior. The  cost  of  this  regulation  is  always  passed  on  to  the  consumer. 
And  that  cost  is  astronomical. 

In  the  transportation  area  alone,  studies  have  estimated  the  cost 
to  the  public  of  Federal  regulation  to  be  $8  to  $16  billion  each  year. 
That  is  an  unreasonable  price  at  any  time.  It  is  wholly  unacceptable 
under  our  present  economic  conditions. 

President  Ford  is  asking  the  American  people  to  absorb  billions 
of  dollars  in  additional  living  costs  to  alleviate  our  energy  problems. 
At  the  same  time,  he  is  asking  Congress  to  freeze  or  reduce  spending 
on  social  programs  designed  to  ease  the  financial  burden  on  those  least 
able  to  cope  with  recession  and  inflation.  The  President  is  predicting 
a  frightening  unemployment  rate  of  over  8  percent  to  continue  during 
the  next  several  years. 

(1) 

51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  2 


Americans  are  being  asked  to  make  these  harsh  and  difficult  sacri- 
fices. Many  of  these  sacrifices  cannot  be  justified  on  their  own;  but 
they  stand  in  even  starker  contrast  with  the  continuing  drain  on  our 
economy  that  regulatory  agencies  impose. 

The  direct  effects  of  regulation  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  are 
translated  into  the  prices  the  public  pays  to  get  from  one  city  to  an- 
other— whether  for  business,  pleasure,  or  family  emergencies.  Some 
critics  have  estimated  that  as  a  direct  result  of  CAB  regulation  the 
public  pays  from  32  to  47  percent  in  excess  air  fares.  These  inflated 
costs  are  passed  on  to  the  consumer  by  the  sellers  of  goods  and  services 
who  must  utilize  the  airplane  to  transport  its  products  and  employees. 
CAB  economic  regulation  is  thus  of  vital  concern  to  every  American. 
Although  the  way  the  CAB  regulates  may  be  complex,  the  effects  of 
that  regulation  are  dramatic  and  clear. 

The  administration  has  asked  Congress  to  create  a  commission  to 
study  regulatory  reform.  While  I  support  that  proposal,  I  also  believe 
that  the  President  and  the  Congress  have  a  duty  to  propose  something 
concrete  to  bring  about  reform. 

Throughout  our  hearings  we  will  be  asking  two  questions  about 
the  CAB's  practices  and  procedures :  First,  are  they  effective  ?  Do  they 
result  in  reasonably  priced  air  transportation  for  the  consumer  and 
reasonable  incentives  for  the  airlines  to  provide  that  service?  Second, 
are  they  fair?  Do  they  give  the  public,  as  well  as  the  airlines,  an  ade- 
quate opportunity  to  present  their  points  of  view  before  important 
decisions  are  made  ? 

Last  November  the  subcommittee  began  this  process  by  examining 
the  CAB's  decision  to  set  minimum  charter  rates.  We  concluded  that 
in  this  instance  the  decisionmaking  process  operated  neither  fairly 
nor  effectively.  The  CAB's  actions  in  this  area  will  unjustifiably  add 
millions  of  dollars  to  the  public's  bill  for  air  travel.  Subsequently,  the 
Court  of  Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia  issued  an  indefinite 
stay  of  the  CAB's  minimum  charter  rate  policy. 

Today,  we  will  begin  with  a  broad  overview  of  CAB  policies  and 
procedures.  Next  week  we  will  examine  the  fares  and  service  provided 
by  intrastate  carriers,  and  the  performance  of  State  regulations  of 
airlines  who  are  not  regulated  by  the  CAB.  We  will  ask  why  State- 
regulated  airlines  in  California  and  Texas  provide  profitable,  unsub- 
sidized  service  at  fares  that  are  sometimes  50  percent  lower  than  those 
charged  bv  the  CAB-regulated  carriers.  We  want  to  know  the  reasons 
for  these  differences.  The  subcommittee  will  ask  whether,  as  is  so  often 
charged,  regulation  by  the  CAB  is  responsible  for  them. 

We  will  go  on  to  review  the  Board's  procedures  for  determining 
proper  rates.  In  the  past  14  months,  the  Board  has  granted  direct 
fare  increases  of  over  16  percent.  It  has  eliminated  special  fares  for 
children  and  vacationers,  producing  an  average  fare  increase  of  more 
than  20  percent.  Neither  inflation  nor  rising  fuel  costs  can  fully  ex- 
plain these  fare  increases. 

So  again  we  must  ask.  is  CAB  regulation  responsible?  Do  the 
Board's  procedures  ensure  that  low  airline  profits  lead  to  quick,  auto- 
matic, fare  increases,  while  high  airline  profits  are  neither  quicklv  nor 
automatically  translated  into  fare  cuts?  Do  its  ratemaking  procedures 
reward  the  inefficient,  unprofitable  carriers  with  industrywide  fare 


3 

increases  that  efficient  carriers  do  not  need  and  would  not  impose  in  a 
competitive  environmejit?  Do  the  Board's  procedures  work  to  produce 
rates  based  on,  in  the  words  of  tlie  P>deral  Aviation  Act  of  1958.  the 
"lowest  cost  consistent  with  the  furnishing  of  adequate  service"  ?  More 
fundamentally,  if  the  task  of  regulating  air  fares  is  so  inherently  com- 
plex that  imperfections  and  higher  costs  will  result  no  matter  what 
ratemaking  procedures  are  used,  then  we  will  ask  to  what  extent 
reform  can  be  accomplished  by  returning  the  determination  of  prices 
to  the  marketplace  and  the  laws  of  supply  and  demand. 

The  subcommittee  will  also  analyze  the  Board's  procedures  for 
awarding  routes.  It  has  been  claimed  that  a  more  flexible  entry  policy — 
a  policy  that  more  freely  awarded  routes  to  qualified  applicants — 
would  itself  help  keep  prices  low.  The  fear  of  attracting  competition 
may  also  act  as  an  additional  constraint  on  airline  pricing  policies.  Yet 
the  CAB  lias  adopted  precisely  the  opposite  appioach  in  recent  years. 
But,  it  has  never  decided  to  adopt  this  policy  formally,  as  required  by 
the  Administrative  Procedure  Act.  The  subcommittee  will  examine 
the  Board's  past  behavior,  as  well  as  its  recently  announced  proposals 
for  procedural  change,  to  detemnne  whether  both  the  public  and  the 
industry  are  being  adequately  served  by  Board  actions. 

The  subcommittee  will  also  look  at  the  CAB's  use  of  its  enforcement 
powers.  We  will  ask  whether  the  agency  has  devoted  disproportionate 
resources  to  stamping  out  low-fare  transportation  charters — air  travel 
clubs  that  put  pleasure  travel  within  the  reach  of  millions  of  average 
citizens — while  doing  little,  if  anything,  about  airline  overcharge. 

Finally,  the  subcommittee  will  look  at  the  Board's  use  of  its  power 
to  grant  antitrust  exemption  to  several  carriers  who  reached  agree- 
ments to  curtail  service  competition  in  selected  markets.  Has  the  Board 
imposed  safeguards  sufficient  to  assure  that  the  public  will  not  suffer 
unnecessary  curtailment  of  service  ?  Have  the  reduced  costs  of  the  car- 
riers who  have  curtailed  service  been  passed  on  to  those  consumers  who 
now  receive  that  reduced  service?  Does  the  CAB  too  easily  ignore  the 
policies  of  the  antitrust  laws,  allowing  the  airlines  to  engage  in  collu- 
sive action  to  divide  up  markets  and  profits  ? 

The  scope  of  these  hearings  is  broad  and  our  time  is  limited.  But 
we  have  been  substantially  aided  by  the  cooperation  of  the  airlines, 
several  executive  agencies,  and  the  CAB  itself.  Even  before  these  hear- 
ings were  announced  last  December,  the  airlines  and  the  CAB  were 
compiling  data  and  submitting  responses  to  detailed  and  extensive 
questionnaires  from  the  subcommittee.  Some  of  our  questioTis  asked 
for  data  and  analyses  that  neither  the  CAB  nor  the  airlines  had  pre- 
viously compiled. 

The  responses  have  been  immeasurably  helpful  to  the  subcommittee. 
The  Board,  executive  agencies,  and  the  airlines  have  had  an  oppor- 
tunity to  reexamine  their  own  assumptions  in  preparing  for  these 
hearings.  Just  last  week,  I  am  happy  to  report,  the  Board  itself 
announced  that  it  was  establishing  an  internal  study  group  to  re- 
examine its  functions  and  the  need  for  regulation.  T  hope  that  study 
croup  will  pay  dose  attention  to  the  evidence  we  Avill  be.  developing  in 
these  hearings.  The  subcommittee  will  certninlv  monitor  the  progress 
of  the  group's  work  and  will  closely  study  its  final  report. 

The  Department  of  Transportation,  the  Department  of  Justice,  the 
President's  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  and  the  Council  on  Wage 


and  Price  Stability  have  lent  substantial  assistance  to  our  efforts.  They 
have  developed  concrete  proposals  for  reform  that  will  be  explained 
by  them  during  the  course  of  these  hearings. 

Today,  we  will  hear  from  several  government  agencies,  some  experts 
on  economic  regulation,  and  representatives  of  the  scheduled  airline 
industry.  These  witnesses  have  been  asked  to  tell  us  whether  there  is 
a  need  for  reform  and  to  suggest  the  direction  reform  should  take. 
Thus,  today's  hearing  will  provide  an  overview  of  the  major  problems 
involved  in  airline  regulation.  Proposals  for  reform  will  be  set  before 
the  public  by  various  witnesses,  and  these  proposals  will  provide  a 
framework  for  the  examination  that  will  continue  more  specifically 
in  the  future  hearings  this  month  and  next. 

Our  first  witness  this  morning  is  Mr.  John  Barnum,  who  came  to 
Washington  from  his  New  York  law  practice  in  1971  to  become  Gen- 
eral Counsel  of  the  Department  of  Transportation.  In  1973,  he  assumed 
the  job  of  Deputy  Secretary  of  Transportation  and  is  presently  Acting 
Secretary  of  Transportation. 

As  I  indicated  in  my  opening  statement,  the  DOT,  both  Mr.  Barnum 
and  Mr.  Binder,  have  been  extremely  helpful  to  us  in  preparing  for 
these  hearings. 

We  are  pleased  to  have  you  with  us  and  we  look  forward  to  your 
testimony  this  morning. 

STATEMENT  OF  JOHN  W.  BARNUM,  ACTING  SECRETARY  OF  TRANS- 
PORTATION, ACCOMPANIED  BY  WILLIAM  A.  KUTZKE,  OFFICE 
OF  THE  GENERAL  COUNSEL,  DEPARTMENT  OF  TRANSPORTATION 

Mr.  Barnum.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  thank  you  for  the 
kind  words  concerning  Assistant  Secretary  Binder  and  Assistant 
Secretary  Snow,  who  are  not  available  at  this  time. 

I  would  like  to  introduce  William  A.  Kutzke  who  has  been  on  the 
firing  line  for  the  DOT  in  the  CAB  proceedings  in  which  the 
Department  participates. 

I  would  also  thank  you  for  your  invitation  to  present  the  views  of 
the  Administration  on  the  important  subject  of  regulation  of  air 
transportation  and  how  it  can  be  improved. 

The  Department  is  vitally  interested  in  the  issue.  Since  DOT's  in- 
ception in  1967,  we  have  participated  in  many  proceedings  before  the 
Civil  Aeronautic  Board.  In  our  Board  filings,  the  Department  has 
been  a  strong  advocate  of  improving  the  economic,  performance  of 
air  transportation  through  increased  reliance  on  competitive  market 
forces.  The  unifvinff  theme  that  runs  through  virtually  all  of  our 
filings  before  the  CAB  is  that  greater  reliance  on  competitive  market 
forces  will  improve  the  economic  performance  of  the  industry  and  re- 
sult in  lower,  more  cost  related  rates,  will  reduce  excess  capacitv,  and 
will  provide  the  air  traveling  public  with  a  wider  and  more  desirable 
range  of  service  and  price  options. 

I  believe  we  are  now  at  a  regulatory  watershed.  For  the  past  several 
months,  the  Administration  has  been  reviewing  the  transportation 
regulatory  system  with  a  view  to  improving  both  performance  and 
economic  efficiency.  The  reform  proposals  presently  being  prepared  by 
the  Administration  mark  a  major  departure  from  the  regulatory 
regime  we  have  relied  upon  in  the  past.  The  Administration  will 


submit  to  Congress  in  the  near  future  a  proposal  which  will  funda- 
mentally redirect  our  air  transportation  reoulatory  policy.  Your  hear- 
ings, therefore,  come  at  an  opportune  moment.  Today  I  will  outline 
the  Administration's  position  on  reguhation  of  air  transportation. 

The  need  for  an  air  regulatory  reform  act  is  demonstrated  both  by 
economic  research  and  by  our  experience.  At  present,  for  example,  air 
carriers,  sliippers,  and  passengers  frequently  face  a  web  of  restrictive 
government  regulations  which  stifle  competition,  discourage  innova- 
tion, and  foster  inefficiency.  In  many  respects,  tlie  present  air  regu- 
latory structure  is  outdatecl,  inequitable,  inefficient,  uneconomical,  and 
sadly  irrational.  It  often  misplaces  incentive  and  disincentive,  disorts 
competitive  advantage,  protects  inefficient  carriers  from  effective 
competition,  over-restricts  market  entiy,  artifically  inflates  rates  and 
misallocates  our  Nation's  resources.  Under  the  current  system,  many 
consumers  pay  an  artificially  inflated  price  for  air  transportation 
because  rate  setting,  unnecessary  entry  restriction,  capacity  agi:eements 
and  other  forms  of  shelter  from  competition  sanctioned  by  the  Board 
protect  the  least  efficient  carriers,  permit  rates  substantially  above  an 
efficient  cost  level  and  distort  competitive  market  forces.  The  resulting 
economic  waste  and  associated  inefficiency  is  substantial. 

The  present  air  regulatory  system  is  the  product  of  a  different  era. 
While  the  needs  and  conditions  on  which  air  regulation  was  first  pre- 
dicted some  40  years  ago  have  changed,  the  goals  and  practices  of 
government  regulation  Jiave  not.  It  is  unfortunately  a  truism  that 
regulation  begets  further  regidation  and  that  regulations  outlive  their 
rationale. 

I  fully  agree  with  the  statements  you  made  in  your  opening  remarks 
that  regulatory  practices  developed  40  years  ago  are  not  suitable  to  the 
last  quarter  of  this  century. 

In  19-38,  when  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  Avas  passed,  goveniment 
assistance  through  protection,  subsidy,  promotion,  and  regulation  was 
a  necessary  factor  in  the  development  of  a  new  and  strujrgling  in- 
dustry. Tliirtv-seven  years  later,  conditions  have  changed.  The  air 
tra.vei  marketis  mature.  Traffic  has  grown.  Growth  has  led  to  stability. 
The  industry  is  vigorous.  But  this  i-egulatory  system  which  protected 
it  and  made  it  that  way  has  not  kept  pace. 

The  problems  once  faced  have  bee]i  largely  solved,  ^ow  we  are  faced 
with  problems  that  are  a  by-product  of  that  success.  The  promotion 
which  once  fostered  growth  now  causes  inefficiency.  The  restrictions 
whicli  once  guaranteed  stability  now  retard  competition.  The  regu- 
latoiT  protection  which  once  insured  existance  now  prevents  sayings. 

We  need  a  better  system  which  comes  closer  to  producing  optimum 
social  and  economic  results,  one  which  maximizes  efficiency,  economies, 
and  consumer  options  and  which  produces  the  best  mix  bet^^  een  low 
cost  and  high  quality  service. 

cab's  first  major  power:  fares 

The  most  pressing  problems  in  the  airline  regulator}'  field  cluster  in 
three  broad  areas — ratemaking  and  pricing  flexibility,  market  entrv^ 
and  exit,  and  anticompetitive  agreements.  Each  area  is  in  need  of  re- 
form. Let  me  identify  what  we  see  as  the  future  direction  which  the 
Administration  suggests. 


6 

A  major  difficulty  with  CAB  policy  has  been  ratemaking  and  the 
carrier  inability  to  raise  and  lower  rates  in  response  to  the  demands 
of  the  marketplace.  This  in  turn  forces  carriers  into  costly  and  un- 
economic service  competition,  deprives  the  traveling  public  of  the 
range  of  price  and  service  options  which  would  otherwise  be  available, 
and  results  in  substantial  economic  waste  and  inefficiency. 

Section  404  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  requires  carriers  to  estab- 
lish just  and  reasonable  rates.  Section  1002  permits  the  Board  to 
prescribe  maximum  or  minimum  rates  if  it  is  of  the  opinion  that  the 
rates  charged  are  unjust,  unreasonable,  preferential,  or  discriminatory. 
In  deciding  whether  a  rate  is  too  high  or  low  the  Board  takes  into 
account,  among  other  factors,  whether  the  rate  is  compensatory,  pro- 
viding the  carrier  with  sufficient  revenue. 

The  result  of  the  Board  administration  of  these  sections  has  been 
the  elimination  of  price  competition,  thereby  restricting  competition 
to  service.  Passengers  find  airlines  competing  for  their  patronage 
through  elaborate  cuisines,  free  drinks,  attractive  stewardesses,  multi- 
colored planes,  and  piano  bars.  But  they  do  not  have  a  menu  where 
different  quality  service  is  related  to  different  prices.  This  is  a  serious 
loss. 

Many  passengers  would  prefer  the  opportunity  to  select  carriers 
based  on  price  in  addition  to  type  of  service.  Some  passengers  would 
prefer  high-load  factor,  low-frill,  low-fare  service.  Others  are  willing 
to  pay  for  more  comfortable  and  more  costly  service.  Present  pro- 
cedures do  not  produce  that  variety  of  price  and  service  options.  Often, 
present  regulation  causes  fares  well  above  those  which  would  occur 
in  a  more  competitive  air  transportation  market.  With  prices  fixed  at 
levels  above  market  rates,  carriers  compete  on  the  basis  of  service. 
Such  service  competition  produces  substantial  unused  capacity  and 
unnecessarily  low-load  factors,  presently  averaging  about  57  percent 
in  the  domestic  market.  In  the  transcontinental  market,  for  example, 
rates  are  set  sufficiently  high  to  permit  the  carriers  to  earn  a  reasonable 
return  with  load  factors  in  the  mid-40-percent  range.  DOT  believes 
that  many  transcontinental  passengers  would  prefer  the  minor  incon- 
veniences associated  with  higher  load  factors  in  return  for  less  expen- 
sive tickets.  In  a  more  competitive  market,  carriers  would  respond  by 
providing  such  low-cost  service. 

One  recent  study  showed  that,  at  an  average  load  factor  of  75  per- 
cent, prices  could  be  27  percent  lower  than  at  a  50-percent  load  factor. 
While  75-percent  load  factors  are  unrealistic  in  most  markets,  this 
example  illustrates  the  potential  savings  associated  with  pricing 
flexibility. 

"zone  or  reasonableness"  for  fares 

Present  Board  policies  encourage  lower  than  optimal  load  factors. 
dot's  testimony  in  the  CAB's  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation 
showed  that  when  load  factors  increase  beyond  a  break-even  level 
(defined  to  include  profits),  carriers  schedule  additional  capacity, 
thereby  lowering  load  factors  to  the  break-even  level  again. 

Because  of  this  inflexibility,  in  the  Dojriestic  Paasenger  Fare  Investi- 
gation, DOT,  among  other  things,  urged  the  Board  to  establish  a  15- 
percent  "zone  of  reasonableness"  above  and  below  the  fare  structure 
curve.  The  zone  would  not  apply  in  monopoly  markets,  as  defined  by 


the  CAB,  where  the  Board  would  continue  to  review  and  suspend 
rates.  Within  the  zone,  carriers  would  be  permitted  to  compete  on  the 
basis  of  price,  free  from  regulatory  interference.  Outside  the  zone,  the 
Board  could  continue  to  suspend  rates  it  believed  unlawful  under  its 
ratemakino;  standards. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  wouldn't  some  of  the  stronger  official  car- 
riers just  lower  their  rates  until  they  drive  the  competition  out? 

Mr.  Barnum.  That  might  be  the  result  if  you  didn't  simultaneously 
make  a  change  with  respect  to  your  entry.  If  you  do  make  the  con- 
comitant change  in  entry,  in  the  event  you  suggest  another  carrier 
would  come  into  that  market,  when  rates  rise  above  a  competitive  level. 

Senator  Kennedy.  But  how  can  a  carrier  come  back  in?  I  would 
think  it  would  take  a  very  considerable  amount  of  investment,  and 
once  they  get  right  back  in,  the  fare  could  be  lowered  again  to  drive 
them  out.  I  would  think  the  people  would  bet  the  idea  pretty  quickly 
after  two  or  three  people  lose  their  shirts. 

INIr.  Barnum.  Many  of  the  markets  you  are  talking  about  are  mar- 
kets that  could  be  served  or  not  served  by  existing  carriers. 

The  easy  case,  of  course,  is  a  market  in  which  a  carrier  serves  both 
end  points  anyway,  let's  say  New  York-Cincinnati.  TWA  may  be 
serving  Cincinnati  from  Chicago,  and  New  York  from  a  number  of 
places.  It  drops  the  New  York-Cincinnati  leg  for  one  reason  or 
another,  or  perhaps  it  is  not  now  in  the  New  York-Cincinnati  leg.  But 
if  other  carriers  were  to  raise  fares  as  you  suggest,  TWA  would 
promptly  go  right  back  into  the  New  York-Cincinnati  market.  That 
is  the  easy  case. 

The  more  difficult  case  would  be  a  market  where  a  carrier  did  not 
have  a  base  at  one  of  the  end  points. 

In  any  event,  you  must  have  a  different  practice  with  respect  to 
entry  in  order  to  make  rate  flexibility  meaningful  and  to  avoid  the 
very  result  you  are  talking  about. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  do  you  know  they  just  wouldn't  go  ahead 
and  charge  the  ceiling,  too.  Perhaps  if  one  carrier  found  out  that 
another  is  going  up  to  the  ceiling,  the  first  carrier  would  say,  well, 
since  Airline  X  is  charging  the  ceiling  and  getting  a  good  return 
on  investment,  I  think  we  will,  too,  and  then  we  would  end  up  having 
the  same  kind  of  competition  that  you  have  outlined  earlier? 

Mr.  Barnu:\i.  Well,  I  think  you  would  find  there  would  be  a  number 
of  carriers  that  would  charge  a  higher  rate  at  those  times  of  the  day; 
for  example,  where  there  is  such  a  demand  that  they  can  get  it. 

But  what  we  would  like  to  see  happen  is  illustrated  in  the  hypotheti- 
cal case  of  Chicago-Los  Angeles.  It  may  be  that  the  6  p.m.  flight  would 
find  a  rate  toward  the  high  end  of  the  zone  because  there  is  high 
demand  for  it,  there  are  a  lot  of  people  that  want  to  fly  at  that  time, 
and  indeed  the  major  carriers,  the  trunkline  carriers,  might  charge 
the  same  rate  at  the  high  end  of  the  scale.  But  price  flexibility  would 
permit  them  to  charge  a  lower  rate  during  the  middle  of  the  day  when 
they  could  attract  people  to  use  planes  now  operating  with  a  lower 
load  factor,  such  as  the  2  p.m.  flight,  when  there  is  not  such  a  great 
demand.  You  could  get  price  flexibility  which  would  spread  out  the 
demands  of  the  airline  and  increase  the  load  factor,  which  is  what  we 
are  really  shooting  at. 


8 

The  limits  of  the  zone  we  proposed  in  DPFI  ensure  that  neither 
dramatic  price  increases  nor  destructive  price  competition  would  en- 
sue. The  Department  position  rested  on  the  premise  that  greater  reli- 
ance on  market  forces  would  result  in  the  establishment  of  rates  based 
on  costs  and  would  afford  the  public  a  wider  and  better  range  of  price 
and  service  options.  We  emphasize  that  the  lack  of  price  competition 
in  the  air  industry  was  the  primary  cause  of  "seat  wars"  and  other 
service  competition  which  resulted  in  undue  unused  capacity  and  in- 
flated cost  levels. 

In  its  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  decision,  the  Board 
did  recognize  that  fares  should  be  more  closely  alined  to  costs.  It 
largely  adopted  our  conclusion  that  low  fares  for  short-haul  passengers 
should  not  be  subsidized  by  higher  fares  for  long-haul  passengers. 

SMALL    TOWN    SERVICE     (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  now,  I  come  from  a  part  of  the  country 
where  we  had  up  to — well,  the  last  8  or  9  years  we  had  service  into  a 
number  of  smaller  communities  in  Massachusetts.  We  had  air  service 
into  New  Bedford,  Worcester,  Springfield,  down  in  Hyannis,  and  of 
course  that  was  replicated  in  a  variety  of  different  smaller  communi- 
ties all  over  northern  New  England. 

As  you  are  probably  aware.  Northeast  flew  in  New  England  and 
then  they  got  their  ticket  to  go  down  to  Miami  and  they  primarily 
focused  on  that,  and  they  claimed  at  least  to  use  cross  subsidy.  They 
abandoned  New  England  routes.  I  think  there  is  one  flight  a  day  in 
through  Hyannis  and  the  Islands,  and  the  smaller  airlines  have  taken 
over,  and  let  me  say  quite  frankly  they  have  been  very  good,  at  least 
in  our  part  of  the  country,  at  least  in  the  areas  of  New  England  in 
which  I  have  traveled. 

But  if  you  reject  the  cross-subsidy  argument  aren't  you  just  saying 
that  you  are  virtually  abandoning  some  of  these  smaller  communities, 
that  maybe  they  will,  as  took  place  down  on  Cape  Cod,  with  Down- 
East  Air  Lines  or  Pilgrim  Air  Lines  that  fly  out  to  Provincetown ; 
aren't  you  really  saying  to  smaller  communities — and  I  am  sure  this 
is  true*  in  other  parts  of  the  country— you  fellows  are  on  your  own. 
If  there  is  an  enterprising  smaller  company  that  can  put  together  the 
financing  and  find  the  pilots  and  all  the  rest,  maybe  you  will  get  good 
service,  but  otherwise  you  are  on  your  own.  Aren't  you  telling  that  to 
hundreds  of  smaller  communities  all  over  the  country  by  this 
suggestion  ? 

Mr.  Barnum.  I  think  not.  I  think  we  should  avoid  confusing  a  num- 
ber of  the  subelements  of  the  cross-subsidy  question. 

The  principal  issue  addressed  bv  the  Board  in  the  Domestic  Pas- 
senger Fare  Investigation  proceeding  I  am  talking  about  came  up  in 
the  context  of  fare  construction  and  the  way  in  which  an  airline  should 
build  up  its  fares  related  to  its  cost :  A  certain  amount  to  ticket  the  pas- 
senger ;  a  certain  amount  per  mile  for  the  first  500  miles ;  and  a  de- 
creasing amount  for  further  miles.  ,  . 

We  felt  at  that  time  the  long-haul  passenger  was  subsidizing  the 
short-haul  passenger.  For  example,  because  the  passenger  going  from 
New  York  to  San  Francisco  had  very  few  other  ways  in  which  to  take 
that  trip,  the  airlines  were  able  to  charge  him  a  higher  fare  relative 


to  cost  than  they  were  in  the  situation,  say,  from  Boston  to  New  York, 
where  there  were  alternative  means  of  transportation  and  where  the 
air  carrier  had  to  take  into  account  the  fares  of  Amtrak  and  of  inner- 
city  buses.  Because  of  the  intermodal  competition,  the  shorter  haul 
fares  were  lower  and,  to  a  degree,  we  felt,  cost-subsidized  by  the  long 
hauls.  That  is  just  an  economic  analysis  of  what  it  costs  the  air  carrier 
to  operate  long  haul  and  short  haul.  That  is  the  cross  subsidization 
that  we  objected  to.  and  the  CAB  objected  to,  in  Phase  9  of  the  Domes- 
tic Passenger  Fare  Investigation. 

I  think  that  position  is  entirely  appropriate  and  I  don't  think  your 
question  was  really  criticizing  that  kind  of  position  on  cross- 
subsidization.  So  I  would  like  to  put  that  asifle  for  a  minute. 

I  would  also  like  to  put  aside  the  problam  created  by  seasonal 
demands.  When  you  talk  about  the  Islands  and  Cape  Cod — and  I  fly 
those  same  flights  myself — you  are  talking  about  a  seasonal  demand, 
and  that  obviously  presents  a  separate  problem. 

But  let's  talk  now  about  the  smaller  communities  that  are  in 
jeopardy  of  not  getting  continued  service,  if  that  service  is  not  eco- 
nomic and  cannot  be  cross-subsidized  by  the  profitable  routes  that  the 
carrier  services.  Now,  of  course,  there  is  at  the  present  time  a  local 
subsidy  operation  available  to  the  CAB.  It  is  exercised  now  at  the 
level  of  about  $68  million  last  year  and  about  $66  million  in  the  forth- 
coming budget.  By  and  large,  local  subsidies  have  been  going  down, 
relatively,  as  inflation  has  come  along. 

To  the  extent  that  a  trunk  line  cannot  economically  serve  a  smaller 
community,  we  do  not  think  it  should  be  required  to  continue  to  pro- 
vide that  service.  In  the  last  5  years,  we  have  seen  a  dramatic  sub- 
stitution of  second  level  service  for  some  of  the  trunkline  service  that 
previously  existed.  The  very  region  of  the  country  you  are  talking 
about  is  a  dramatic  example  of  that.  Allegheny  has  provided  substi- 
tuted service  in  a  number  of  cities  that  it  previously  served  or  that 
Mohawk  served  prior  to  the  Allegheny-Mohawk  merger.  New  England 
speaks  very  well  to  the  point  that  many  carriers  in  a  less  regulated 
climate  would  be  prepared  to  come  in  and  provide  the  service  that 
you  are  talking  about. 

The  specific  proceeding  before  the  CAB  on  New  England  service 
laid  out  a  good  record  where  service  could  be  provided  by  trunk  car- 
riers and  secondary  carriers,  and  it  also  gave  you  some  evidence  that 
intercity  passenger  services  such  as  buses  were  available  to  get  people 
from  Bangor  to  New  York  or  Bangor  to  Boston  and  there  was  not 
the  need  for  certificated  air  service  as  existed  in  some  other  parts  of 
the  country. 

I  agree  with  you  that  it  is  something  we  have  to  keep  our  eye  on, 
but  I  don't  believe  you  should  permit  cross-subsidy  as  the  answer. 

Would  you  like  me  to  pursue  that? 

Senator  Kexxedy.  Why  don't  vou  continue.  We  will  come  back  to 
this. 

DESTRUCTIVE    COMPETITION 

Mr.  Barnum.  The  Board  was  unwilling  at  that  time,  however,  to 
adopt  the  broader  principle  of  pricing  flexibility,  constrained  only  by 
costs. 


10 

Senator  Kennedy.  In  reaching  this  position  you  must  have  done 
some  work  or  some  studies  that  would  give  you  some  assurances  that 
you  wouldn't  have  cutthroat  competition  in  this  kind  of  thing  and 
drive  people  out  of  the  market.  Have  you  studied  this  in  reaching  this 
decision  on  pricing  flexibility  and  expediting  decisionmaking?  What 
about  cutthroat  competition  that  would  destroy  the  competition  basi- 
cally ?  You  are  satisfied  that  that  won't  be  the  case  ? 

Mr.  Barnum.  We  are.  We  did  do  just  that  examination  and  we 
submitted  some  of  that  evidence  in  Phase  9  in  the  Domestic  Passenger 
Fare  Investigation. 

I  think  if  you  combine  this  with  easier  entry  provisions,  you  would 
not  get  the  cutthroat  competition  to  drive  competitors  out.  We  are 
not  talking  about  requiring  the  CAB  to  permit  destructive  price 
competition.  If  you  will  permit  greater  flexibility  entry,  you  will 
get  threshold  pricing  in  these  markets  so  that  the  carriers  who  are 
in  these  markets  will  price  at  a  level  just  high  enough  to  discourage 
the  other  carriers  able  to  come  in  from  coming  in  because  the  very 

startup  costs  will  prevent  them  from  coming  in  and  making  it 

Senator  Kennedy.  "S'ou  think  that  this  threshold  cost  is  the  most 
effective  cost  for  the  consumer? 

Mr.  Barnum.  That  has  got  to  be  the  most  effective  cost  to  the 
consumer;  yes. 

Now,  there  has  to  be  a  basic  cost  element  in  here  that,  of  course, 
we  in  the  Department  of  Transportation  are  always  mindful  of.  We 
are  not  just  talking  about  selling  oranges.  We  are  talking  about  selling 
air  transportation.  There  has  to  be  a  very  basic  and  substantial  cost 
here  for  safety.  We  are  mindful,  as  I  am  sure  you  are,  of  the  ingre- 
dients of  operating  an  airline.  We  are  not  in  any  way  inviting  you  to 
open  up  the  pricing  of  transportation  so  that  safety  would  be 
derogated. 

Another  procedural  problem  associated  Avith  pricing  is  CAB  delay 
in  deciding  whether  rates  are  reasonable. 

SAFETY     AND    COMrETITION 

Senator  Kennedy.  Have  you  got  any  study  about  the  performance 
of  new  carriers  in  the  area  of  competition  on  the  basis  of  safety  ?  Have 
you  drawn  any  conclusion  or  made  any  study  of  how  much  of  an 
issue  tliat  would  be  or  Avliether  that  is  a  question  to  be  resolved? 

Mr.  Barnum.  It  hasn't  been  an  issue  among  trunk  carriers  because 
there  haven't  been  any  new  trunk  carriers.  It  is  an  issue  when  we  talk 
about  air  taxies,  and  "this  is  a  very  serious  problem.  I  am  afraid  our 
record  of  accidents  of  air  taxies  is  not  as  good  as  we  would  like.  A 
lot  of  these  people  are  starting  up  and  do  not  have  all  the  elaborate 
safety  practices  and  manuals  the  trunk  carriers  have  been  able  to 
develop  over  the  years. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Wliat  about  intrastate  carriers,  in  terms  of  safety. 
Isn't  that  a  problem  ? 

Mr.  Barnum.  I  think  the  safety  record  of  the  principal  intrastate 
carriers  is  excellent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  But  how  will  you  make  sure  that  is  going  to  be 
the  case  in  other  places? 

Mr.  Barnum.  Well,  of  course,  the  FA  A  has  broad  authority  with 
both  certification  of  types  of  aircraft  and  maintaining  the  operating 


11 

status  of  aircraft.  That  is  really  more  an  FAA  function.  It  would 
address  itself  to  any  type  of  aircraft  being  operated,  I  agree  Avith 
you,  however,  that  it  is  something  we  should  continue  to  keep  our 
eye  on,  but  given  that  mandate  to  the  FAA,  I  think  we  can  put  it  to 
one  side. 

Mr.  Barxum.  I  made  reference  to  the  CAB  and  its  procedural  delay 
in  deciding  whether  rates  are  reasonable.  We  believe  the  CAB  should 
be  required  to  render  a  final  decision  on  rate  proposals  promptly. 
Also,  streamlined  procedures  should  enable  the  Board  to  dispose  of 
some  cases  on  the  basis  of  pleadings  alone,  without  formal  hearings. 
Large-scale  investigations  such  as  the  DPFI  may  take  longer,  of 
course. 

The  Administration  strongly  supports  greater  pricing  flexibility 
for  the  airline  industry.  We  expect  that  our  legislation  will  incorpo- 
rate proposals  for  pricing  flexibility  and  expedited  decisionmaking. 

cab's  secoxd  major  power  :  industry  extry  and  route  entry 

Another  major  problem  with  the  present  regulatory  system  is  the 
Board's  restrictive  entr}^  and  exit  policies.  These  policies  have  also 
restricted  competition  and  increased  costs  to  consumers. 

Section  401  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  gives  the  CAB  control  over 
entry  into  the  industry;  the  Board  is  given  authority  to  determine 
which  carriers  may  operate  in  scheduled  interstate  service  and  on 
which  routes  they  may  operate.  The  applicant  must  be  found  fit, 
willing,  and  able  to  perform  the  service  properly,  and  the  transporta- 
tion must  be  required  by  public  convenience  and  necessity.  CAB  per- 
mission is  also  required  for  exit. 

In  practice,  industry  entry  has  been  tightly  controlled.  Other  than 
the  16  carriers  operating  when  the  1938  act  took  effect,  there  has  not 
been  a  single  new  trunk  carrier  certificated  in  the  Board's  history. 
Through  merger,  the  16  original  trunks  have  shrunk  in  number  to  10 
which  account  for  90  percent  of  the  total  domestic  market.  The  Board 
has.  however,  certified  local  service  carriers,  some  of  which  are  now  as 
large  as  the  smaller  trunks. 

Until  recently,  and  especially  in  the  late  sixties,  existing  carriers 
were  granted  applications  for  ncAv  routes,  thereby  substantially  re- 
ducing the  number  of  monopoly  markets.  In  the  last  few  years,  how- 
ever, the  CAB  has  put  into  effect  a  de  facto  moratorium  on  route 
awards.  Xew  route  applications  have  not  been  set  for  hearing;  proc- 
essing applications  which  had  ben  set  for  hearing  has  ben  delayed. 
The  restrictive  policy  with  respect  to  new  carrier  entry  into  the  in- 
dustry has  now  been  matched  by  a  restrictive  policy  with  respect  to 
new  route  entry  for  established  carriers. 

The  economic  result  of  a  restrictive  CAB  policy  is  that  carriers  do 
not  enter  and  leave  markets  solely  for  business  and  profit  reasons.  New 
firms  are  discouraged  by  the  standards  applied  and  by  the  results 
they  see.  including  the  high  cost  of  the  application  process  and  the 
delay  in  Board  decisionmaking.  The  Board  has  protected  incumbent 
carriers  rather  than  encouraged  healthy  competition.  As  a  result,  in 
the  majority  of  trunk  markets,  most  passengers  are  carried  by  only 
one  or  two  airlines. 

The  administration  does  not  necessarily  believe  that  additional 
carriers  are  required  on  every  route  to  improve  the  working  of  the  air 


12 

transportation  system.  We  do  believe,  however,  that  the  present  system 
removes  the  ability  of  the  carriers  to  adjust  services  and  realine  the 
markets  they  serve  as  economic  conditions  warrant.  This  results  in 
increased  costs  to  the  public. 

The  present  system  also  does  not  recognize  the  importance  of  poten- 
tial competition  as  an  economic  force.  Thus,  the  carriers  on  an  existing 
route  need  not  be  concerned  about  new  competition  unless  the  Board 
has  a  route  case  pending.  In  such  circumstances,  the  existing  carriers 
may  be  less  diligent  in  providing  the  type  of  service  and  price  and 
quality  options  desired  by  the  public  than  they  would  be  if  they  were 
aware  that  a  competitor  could  enter  at  any  time  to  provide  new  or 
better  service. 

cab's   charter  restrictions 

Another  way  of  improving  competition  is  by  liberalizing  charter 
rules  and  thereby  offering  the  consumer  a  broader  range  of  price  and 
service  options. 

Senator  Kexnedy.  Is  your  view  consistent  with  the  minimum 
charter  floor  the  DOT  was  pushing  last  year  ? 

Mr.  Barxum.  I  would  like  to  clarify  the  minimum  charter  floor.  I 
believe  that  as  a  result  of  the  hearings  you  held  in  November,  efforts 
were  made  to  portray  as  much  controversy  within  the  administration 
as  possible,  and  there  was  a  good  deal  of  confusion. 

I  think  that  what  we  were  saying 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  we  are  glad  to  get  the  real  story,  now. 

Mr.  Barnum.  At  that  time  we  were  talking  in  the  context  of  Ad- 
ministration's seven  point  action  plan  that  was  directed  to  the  inter- 
national flag  carriers.  It  dealt  with  the  ways  in  which  we  could  im- 
prove the  economic  climate  and  practices  of  Pan  Am  and  TWA  and 
those  international  carriers  that  were  suffering  from  the  economic 
circumstances  of  a  flat  or  decreasing  international  market  and  huge 
fuel  cost  increases.  We  did  consider  among  other  things,  the  relation- 
ship between  scheduled  fares  on  the  North  Atlantic  and  charter  fares. 
At  that  time  there  was  still  debate  as  to  what  the  scheduled  fares 
should  be,  and  lATA  had  not  yet  come  in  with  a  total  package  for 
CAB  approval.  It  was  difficult  for  lATA  to  come  in  with  a  package 
for  scheduled  fares  because  they  did  not  have  any  idea  where  charter 
fares  would  be. 

We  thought  that  to  aid  lATA  agreement  or  at  least  to  facilitate 
informed  decision  by  the  scheduled  carriers,  it  would  be  useful  if  there 
were  from  the  CAB  some  indication  of  criteria  for  a  floor,  if  you 
will,  at  which  charters  would  operate. 

Now,  what  has  been  misunderstood  here  is  that  we  were  not  talking 
about  having  a  charter  fare  level  that  would  permit  all  charter  oper- 
ators, efficient  and  inefficient,  to  make  a  profit.  What  we  were  talking 
about  was  some  indication  as  to  where  charter  rates  would  be  so  that 
the  scheduled  carriers  could  predicate  their  fares  in  relation  to  the 
charter  floor. 

There  is  a  debate  still  raging  as  to  the  degree  of  CAB's  authority  to 
set  a  charter  floor  either  by  notice  or  proceeding,  and  that  I  think  we 
best  leave  to  the  CAB  and  the  courts  to  thrash  out. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Senator  Cannon  has  introduced  the  bill  to  make 
charter  service  more  widely  available,  which  I  had  the  pleasure  to  join 
him  on  [S.  421].  Do  you  support  that  legislation? 


13 

INIr.  Barnum.  We  are  going  to  be  testifying  before  Senator  Cannon 
next  week.  We  are  in  the  process  of  developing  onr  position  on  that 
bill.  There  is  much  in  it  that  we  have  supported  in  the  past  with 
respect  to  ITC's  and  other  forms  of  charter.  We  have  opposed  the 
CAB  proposal  to  drop  affinity  charters,  and  I  am  glad  to  see  the  CAB 
has  delayed  its  decision  in  that  respect. 

We  do  think,  particularly  at  a  time  when  we  are  interested  in  getting 
more  people  into  fcAver  planes,  that  the  charter  business  is  one  way  in 
which  we  should  be  able  to  increase  low-cost  transportation  with  sub- 
stantial savings  in  energy.  We  are,  therefore,  encouraged  to  see  Senator 
Cannon  and  yourself  and  others  focusing  on  this  very  important  issue, 
and  we  will  address  it  specifically  in  the  next  week. 

Senator  Kennedy.  INIr.  Ginther  is  here,  who  is  the  staff  director  of 
the  aviation  subcommittee.  So  you  will  be  seeing  a  lot  of  him  next 
week. 

Mr.  Barnum.  The  Administration  believes  a  fundamental  shift  is 
required  away  from  over-protection  of  existing  carriers  to  one  which 
focuses  on  consumer  needs  and  requires  that  more  weight  be  placed 
on  competitive  principles  in  evaluating  new  applications  for  entry. 
We  also  believe  that  the  CAB  should  not  be  permitted  to  delay  deci- 
sionmaking as  a  means  of  limiting  entry. 

SMALL    TOWN    SERVICE     (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Route  exit  has  in  some  cases  also  been  restrained  by  the  CAB. 
While  we  recognize  the  importance  of  service  to  communities  of  vary- 
ing sizes,  carriers  should  not  be  forced  to  lose  money  or  operate  on 
the  assumption  that  other  routes  will  subsidize  those  producing  in- 
adequate revenue.  Cross-subsidies  are  inefficient  economically  and  in 
practice  do  not  work. 

AVhere  communities  deem  service  essential,  the  carriers  operate  at 
a  loss,  and  the  route  does  not  justify  Federal  subsidy,  alternatives 
must  be  considered.  These  alternatives  include  replacement  services  by 
another  carrier  or  subsidies  by  the  community  itself. 

In  this  regard,  I  should  note  that  we  will  not  propose  any  immediate 
changes  in  the  local  subsidy  program.  However,  we  believe  the  CAB 
has  an  obligation  to  identify  the  cost  of  such  subsidies  by  route  and 
by  city.  This  has  not  been  done. 

The  Administration  strongly  supports  liberalization  of  entry  into 
the  air  carrier  industry  and  our  forthcoming  proposal  will  provide 
for  substantial  entry  and  exit  liberalization. 

CHAOS 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  do  you  respond  to  the  point  that  this  is 
going  to  let  a  lot  of  fly-by-night  outfits  come  in  and  skim  the  cream 
off  the  top  on  the  most  heavy  traveled  routes,  and  lead  to  instability 
in  these  major  market  areas? 

Mr.  Barnum.  Putting  aside  the  safety  question,  I  think  that  my 
comments  earlier  about  threshold  prices  are  my  first  answer. 

My  second  answer  is  you  really  can't  startup  an  airline  overnight 
and  start  providing  the  kind  of  cutthroat,  cut  price  service  that  you 
are  talking  about.  The  CAB,  of  course,  is  going  to  have  to  certificate 
them  as  a  carrier  and  the  FAA  authorize  them  to  operate.  I  think  it 
would  be  a  rather  fool-hardly  enterprise  for  someone  to  invest,  even 
on  a  lease  basis,  in  the  expensive  equipment  that  would  be  required 


14 

to  provide  air  transportation.  It  is  not  a  business  susceptible  to  a 
fly-by-night  operation. 

Senator  Kennedy.  So  I  gather  you  have  considered  the  possibility 
that  instability  and  disruption  of  service  might  occur,  and  you  are 
satisfied  that,  on  that  point  at  least,  there  is  no  real  difficulty  with  more 
competition. 

Mr.  Barnum.  Yes.  I  am  certainly  satisfied  in  that  respect.  I  ani  also 
satisfied  that,  given  the  economics  of  the  air  carrier  industry,  the  likeli- 
hood of  a  fly-by-night  operation  and  being  able  to  skim  the  cream  off 
a  major  market  in  the  face  of  already  entrenched  competition  from 
name  carriers  is  not  very  realistic. 

Obviously,  it  is  something  that  needs  to  be  watched  very  carefully. 
But  I  would  not  say  that  the  activities,  for  example,  of  PSA  and 
Southwest — going  into  the  intrastate  market  at  what  was  initially 
about  a  40  percent  cut  below  scheduled  fares — demonstrate  an  unde- 
sirable result.  I  think  it  is  a  very  good  result.  If  that  is  the  consequence 
of  a  fly-by-night  entry,  I  would  say  that  would  be  good. 

Or,  for  example,  where  carriers  operate  in  very  high  density  mar- 
kets, this  kind  of  service  is  likely  to  be  air  shuttle-type  service  at  which 
they  have  hourly  service  and  they  may  or  may  not  have  a  high  load 
factor,  depending  on  whether  or  not  they  have  to  add  an  extra  plane 
a  day.  It  is  basically  a  no-frill  service,  and  I  would  welcome  that.  But  I 
would  not  be  concerned  about  there  being  a  fly-by-night  entry  into  that 
market. 

If  another  one  of  the  major  trunk  lines  saw  a  market  that  it  thought 
it  could  impact  and  enter  under  our  relaxed  entry  provisions  and  pro- 
vide a  shuttle  from  New  York  to  Detroit,  for  instance,  I  think  that 
would  be  very  helpful. 

Our  air  carriers  are  very  concerned  as  to  how  they  can  keep  their 
aircraft  operating.  Their  goal  is  to  get  up  to  11  or  12  hours  a  day.  They 
will  schedule  aircraft  not  because  of  where  people  want  to  go  to,  but 
where  they  can  move  airplanes,  where  they  can  continue  using  them 
into  the  night.  For  example,  if  they  go  west  at  a  particular  time  of  day, 
do  they  get  there  in  time  to  be  able  to  fly  on  the  west  coast  at  a  particular 
time?  How  do  they  position  their  planes?  Those  are  very  important 
considerations  in  the  total  operation  of  an  airline. 

To  the  extent  you  give  carriers  freedom  of  entry,  or  more  entry  than 
they  have  now,  you  will  enhance  their  ability  to  use  their  aircraft  and 
to  react  quickly  as  the  market  changes  or,  as  indeed,  as  their  competi- 
tors decide  to  move  in  or  out  of  a  market. 

But  I  would  not  regard  the  possibility  of  a  fly-by-night  operation  as 
derogating  from  the  services  of  a  scheduled  carrier. 

cab's    third    major    power:    antitrust   immunity CAPACITY 

REDUCTION    AGREEMENTS    AND    OTHERS 

I  would  like  to  move  on  to  the  third  area  where  regulatory  practices 
can  be  improved. 

One  of  the  most  objectionable  features  of  present  CAB  regulation 
is  the  approval  of  capacity  reduction  agreements  in  our  domestic  mar- 
kets. At  present,  under  section  412  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act,  if  the 
Board  finds  capacity,  pooling  and  other  anticompetitive  agreements 


15 

not  adverse  to  the  public  interest,  it  may  approve  them ;  in  so  doing, 
it  immimizes  them  from  action  under  the  antitrust  statutes. 

Capacity  agreements  were  originally  justified  because  of  immediate, 
short  term,  severe  financial  distress.  The  Board  has  since  permitted 
use  of  capacity  agreements  to  resolve  problems  of  unused  capacity,  fuel 
allocation,  and  low  profits  in  certain  markets.  By  apportioning  ca- 
pacity, such  agreements  effectively  determine  market  share.  As  a  result 
of  Board  actions,  capacity  limitation  agreements  have  proliferated  to 
the  point  where  about  29  percent  of  the  revenue  passenger  miles  of  the 
three  largest  carriers  are  now  covered  by  capacity  agreements.  One 
economic  effect  is  that,  given  the  level  of  service  provided,  fares  in 
covered  markets  are  excessive.  One  can  scarcely  imagine  agreements 
more  anticompetitive  in  their  effect.  Such  problems  are  far  better  re- 
solved through  market  forces  operating  in  a  competitive  environment. 

DOT  opposed  the  capacity  agreements  before  the  Board  and  has 
joined  with  the  Antitrust  Division  of  the  Justice  Department  to 
oppose  approval  of  the  agreements  before  the  District  of  Columbia 
Court  of  Appeals. 

In  contrast,  some  agreements  arguably  subject  to  challenge  under 
antitrust  laws  do  serve  valid  transportation  objectives.  These  include 
interline  agreements,  airline  scheduling  committee  agreements  at  con- 
gested airports,  equipment  leases,  fuel  supply  agreements,  reservation 
and  ticketing  arrangements  and  technical  agreements  with  foreign  air 
carriers. 

We  distinguish  between  the  two  types  of  agreements,  the  one  anti- 
competitive in  a  way  w^iich  contributes  to  economic  inefficiency,  the 
other  which  meets  necessary  transportation  objectives.  The  Adminis- 
tration believes  that  anticompetitive  agreements  such  as  those  for  ca- 
pacity limitation  should  be  restricted  or  eliminated  but  that  agree- 
ments which  serve  efficient  transportation  needs  should  be  continued. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  the  agreements  are  not  in  restraint  of  trade 
then  they  don't  violate  the  antitrust  law  in  any  event.  These  areas  that 
you  have  outlined  seem  to  be  reasonable  agreements,  so  why  do  you 
need  the  exemption,  in  any  event? 

Mr.  Barnum.  There  are  some  agreements  between  carriers  that  we 
think  are  appropriate,  that  either  arguably  or  clearly  might  result  in 
litigation.  They  might  be  regarded  as  allocation  of  market  or  market- 
share  agreements.  Some  of  the  joint  fare  agreements  they  have  could 
be  regarded  as  price  fixing  or  market-share  agreements. 

Senator  Kennedy.  As  I  understand  the  lawyers,  it  is  only  if  an  inter- 
carrier  is  unreasonable,  that  the  exemption  is  necessary.  If  it  is  rea- 
sonable it  does  not  violate  the  antitrust  laws,  even  though  it  is  an 
agreement  ? 

Mr.  Barnum.  What  constitutes  reasonableness  under  the  Sherman 
Act  is  a  very  tough  test  to  pass.  Even  putting  aide  merger  agreements, 
just  agreements  with  respect  to  ticketing  costs  or  even  use  of  airport 
at  a  particular  time  could  be  regarded  as  an  anticompetitive  or  an 
agreement  in  violation  of  the  Sherman  Act.  "Wliat  constitutes  reason- 
ableness in  the  Sherman  Act  is  not  what  a  non-antitrust  lawyer 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  be  reassured  by  what  the  Department 
of  Justice  has  said  ?  Do  you  think  tliey  have  a  fair  opinion  in  temis  of 
the  governmental  policy,  and  that  their  input  would  be  guided  by  the 
legal  arm  of  the  Government? 


16 

Mr.  Barnum.  I  would  be  very  pleased  to  have  their  input.  I  do  not 
think,  however,  you  would  find  any  disagreement  between  us  as  to 
the  meaning  of  reasonableness  insofar  as  agreements  between  competi- 
tors is  concerned.  So  far  as  existing  law  requires,  I  think  you  will  find 
there  is  agreement. 

However,  we  distinguish  the  two  types  of  agreements,  and  I  will 
say  we  should  continue  antitrust  immunity  for  certain  types  of  agree- 
ments. In  our  judgement,  however,  the  airline  industry  is  strong 
enough  to  survive  and  prosper  without  blanket  antitrust  immunity. 

Section  408  of  the  act  authorizes  the  Board  to  approve  mergers. 
Mergers  may  be  permitted  unless  the  Board  finds  that  they  will  be  in- 
consistent with  the  public  interest,  would  create  a  monopoly  and 
thereby  restrain  competition,  or  would  jeopardize  another  nonpaity 
carrier.  In  our  view,  the  standard  used  by  the  Board  in  determining 
whether  mergers  or  consolidations  are  approved  should  be  changed  to 
require  that  competitive  principles  be  weighed  against  transportation 
needs. 

In  dot's  filings  to  date,  we  have  encouraged  the  CAB  to  find  less 
anticompetitive  solutions  to  many  of  the  problems  I  have  discussed. 
It  is  now  clear  that  more  decisive  reform  is  necessary.  In  times  of 
inflation,  recession,  and  energy  difficulties,  the  Nation  can  ill  afford  the 
extravagances  created  by  the  present  air  regulatory  system.  The 
administration  proposal  will  get  to  the  heart  of  the  difficulties  in  each 
of  the  areas  discussed  by  changing  the  regulatory  structure  which 
helped  produce  them.  The  air  regulatory  reform  bill  which  we  will 
present  will  address  each  of  these  issues  in  detail  and  will  implement 
the  basic  policy  objectives  which  I  have  outlined  in  my  testimony. 

We  look  forward  to  working  with  the  subcommittee  to  explore  each 
of  these  areas  in  more  detail.  We  share  the  desire  to  modernize  our 
regulatory  structure  and  let  the  fresh  air  of  competition  make  our 
transportation  industry  operate  more  efficiently  at  lower  cost  to  the 
consumers  we  serve. 

Thank  you  very  much,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  if  I  can  answer  any 
additional  questions,  of  course,  I  would  be  more  than  pleased  to  try  to 
do  so. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  we  want  to  thank  you  for  your  presenta- 
tion, and  I  think  it  is  really  an  indication  of  the  desire  of  the  Depart- 
ment of  Transportation  to  carry  forward  what  President  Ford  out- 
lined in  his  state  of  the  Union  address  in  identifying  the  regulatory 
agencies  as  a  matter  of  concern,  and  trying  to  make  them  more  effec- 
tive, and  obviously,  as  far  as  your  Department  is  concerned,  you  are 
willing  to  move  ahead  in  these  directions  even  prior  to  the  time  of  the 
development  of  a  commission  to  deal  with  it.  I  think  that  that  is  really 
a  credit  to  the  De^^artment. 

Mr.  Barnum.  Thank  you. 

NEED    FOR    LEGISLATION 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let  me  ask  you — are  you  satisfied  these  steps  can 
be  taken  without  new  le<rislation? 

Mr.  Barnum.  I  think  that  new  legislation  would  accelerate  the  steps 
that  we  have  outlined.  Most  of  the  things  that  we  have  discussed  could 
be  done  by  the  Board — to  approach  entry  and  exit,  for  instance — dif- 


17 

ferently  than  it  is  done.  Certainly,  in  our  judgment,  the  Board  has 
authority  to  provide  greater  price  flexibility  than  it  has  in  the  past, 
I  think  in  general  they  could  do  much  of  what  we  recommend  under 
existing  law. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  there  anything  they  could  not  do  under  their 
existing  statute? 

Mr.  Barnum.  No;  I  think  they  could  adopt  as  Board  practice,  if 
you  will,  the  time  limits  that  we  have  suggested  with  respect  to  entry 
and  exit  and  rate  changes.  They  have  not.  As  I  stated,  some  of  the 
proceedings  have  been  unnecessarily  protracted  or  put  on  the  shelf, 
which  has  frustrated  much  of  the  innovation  that  we  think  is  avail- 
able to  the  industry. 

I  would  urge  this  subcommittee — if  you  find  the  Congress  is  not 
prepared  to  make  substantive  amendments  to  the  act — to  point  out 
ways  in  which  you  believe  that  the  existing  law  and  the  practices 
appropriate  under  the  existing  law  liave,  in  fact,  not  been  followed. 

Senator  Kennedy.  "Why  do  you  not  think  that  the  CAB  has  seen  the 
problem  the  way  that  you  have  seen  it  here  and  moved  on  its  own  into 
these  particular  areas?  You  have  no  monopoly  or  expertise  or  under- 
standing of  these  particular  issues.  What  is  your  view  about  why  they 
have  not  moved  into  these  particular  areas  before  ? 

Mr.  Barnum.  Well,  as  I  mentioned  in  my  statement,  the  CAB 
evolved  from  an  aq-ency  that  was  established  to  encourage  a  new  indus- 
try as  it  was  growing,  an  industry  which  required  a  certain  amount  of 
encouragement  and  protection,  and  which  required  a  certain  amount 
of  regulation  so  that  there  Avould  not  result,  in  its  early  days,  the  type 
of  cutthroat  competition  which  you  have  described  or  the  type  of  fly- 
by-niijht  entry  into  the  marketplace.  But  T  think  now  that  the  industry 
is  stabilized.  Nonetheless,  many  of  the  things  "v\e  think  the  CAB  should 
do  differently  it  is  continuing  to  do  the  same  way  it  did  when  the 
industry  was  developing.  The  way  they  address  a  problem  today  is 
the  way  they  addressed  it  10  years  ago.  I  think  we  have  gone  past  the 
point  where  we  should  continue  business  as  usual  with  respect  to  the 
air  carrier  industry. 

APPOINTMENT   OF    CAB   MEMBERS 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  part  of  the  problem  has  been  the 
appointment  process,  the  selection  of  people  that  have  been  selected 
and  have  had  a  strong  orientation  toward  the  industry,  perhaps? 

What  role,  if  any,  does  the  DOT' have  in  making  recommendations 
for  the  CAB? 

I  am  not  trying  to  personalize  this,  but  I  am  interested  in  what  your 
impression  would  be,  not  limited  to  any  particular  administration,  but 
just  as  a  practice. 

Mr.  Barnum.  AVell,  I  share  A^our  concern  in  this  respect.  I  think  that 
I  would  judge  the  CAB  by  its  rules  and  not  by  its  personalities. 

I  think  that  the  Board  could  be  a  more  effective  instrument  in  the 
regulation  of  air  transportation,  and  it  may  very  well  be  that  those 
who  constitute  the  Board  are  an  essential  ingredient  in  making  it  more 
eft'ective.  I  think  it  is,  in  part,  the  tradition  into  which  each  new  mem- 
ber of  the  Board  steps  as  he  joins  the  Board  and  finds  out  the  way 
they  have  done  things  in  the  past  and  the  rules  of  the  past.  And  I  think 


51-146  O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  : 


18 

the  CAB  is  guided  in  part  by  stare  decisis,  its  own  decisions  in  the 
past,  A  new  member  has  not  been  given  a  mandate  by  Congress  to 
change  what  the  Board  has  been  doing  in  the  past. 

For  someone  to  join  the  CAB,  and  to  go  in  there  and  say,  "No;  that 
is  all  wrong,  the  statute  means  otlierwise'" — I  think  he  would  be  trying 
to  upset  a  great  deal  that  the  courts  have  written  about  and  the  Board 
has  written  about,  and  certainly,  as  a  newcomer  he  would  feel  he  had 
better  find  out  how  the  Board  works, 

1  think  also  the  Board  has  been  concerned  about  continued  prosper- 
ity in  the  air  industr}',  and  properly  so.  To  the  extent  that  it  has  put 
siich  great  emphasis  on  that,  however,  I  think  that  lias  been  a  mis- 
take. I  think  making  a  goal  of  12  percent  return  on  investment  as  a 
principal  guiding  factor  in  Board  decisions  is  a  mistake.  I  would  be 
much  more  interested  in  seeing  the  Board  trying  to  focus  more  on 
increasing  load  factors  in  its  pi"icing  decisions  and  as  a  result  both 
saving  energy  and  mailing  the  carriers  more  profitable. 

With  respect  to  our  role  in  the  Department  as  to  who  goes  on  the 
CAB,  we  are  consulted,  of  course,  by  the  "\ATiite  Plouse  in  connection 
with  CAB  appointments  and  asked  for  recommendations  and  asked  to 
comment  on  people  that  have  been  recommended  by  others. 

Senator  Kennedy,  Are  you  listened  to  over  there  ? 

Mr.  Barxum.  I  think  so. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Good. 

As  the  result  of  our  November  hearings,  the  staif  marie  some  sug- 
gestions wdth  regard  to  procedures  in  establishing  a  minimum  rate 
policy,  and  I  understand  you  had  some  people  looking  at  these  recom- 
mendation and  determining  how  they  might  be  implemented.  T  am 
just  wondering  if  you  are  prepared  to  say  anything  about  that  today? 

Mr,  Baknum.  Not  at  this  time,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  ^\^ill  you  let  us  know  at  the  earliest  possible  time 
what  are  your  reactions  to  those  recommendations? 

Mr.  Barnuim,  I  would  like  to  advise  you  promptly  or  as  promptly  as 
I  can  just  what  our  timing  is  with  respect  to  commenting  on  those 
recommendations. 

[The  comments  referred  to  are  contained  in  a  letter  from  DOT  to 
Senator  Kennedy  which  is  printed  at  the  end  of  Mr.  Kutkze's  testi- 
mony on  February  18,  1975,  See  below,  pp.  691-92.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  suppose  on  the  matters  that  you  have  mentioned 
here  this  morning,  which  are  extremely  significant,  that  you  will  be 
developing  those  proposals  and  reconnnendations  in  greater  detail? 

Mr.  Barnum.  Yes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Will  you  keep  us  informed  how  those  are  being 
developed  ? 

Mr.  BARNu:\r.  We  are  in  the  process  of  discussing  with  the  other 
agencies  of  the  executive  branch  the  various  details  of  the  three  main 
areas  that  I  have  outlined  to  you.  I  would  hope  that  we  could  continue 
to  hnve  the  dialog  betAveen  our  several  agencies  and  vour  staff  and  Mr. 
Ginther  and  the  staff  of  the  Commerce  Committee.  We  want  to  achieve 
somethin<i  that  is  meaningful  and  realistic  in  terms  of  positive  enact- 
ment and  that  will  addr-ess  the  basic  issues  that  we  see. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  we  ha-^-e  enjoyed  that  cooperation  in  the 
past,  and  A^e  have  no  reason  to  feel  that  it  would  not  continue  in  the 
future.  For  that,  we  are  very  appreciative.  T  think  it  is  a  strong  indica- 
tion of  the  ability  of  the  Congress  to  work  with  the  administration 


19 

and  the  agencies.  We  appreciate  that  and  we  have  found  it  very  in- 
fo raiative  and  very  helpful. 

I  want  to  thank  you  very^  much.  That  has  been  a  good  presentation. 

]Mr.  Barnum.  Thank  30U,  INlr.  Chairman. 

Prepared  Statement  of  John  W.  Barnum 

Thank  you  for  your  invitation  to  present  the  views  of  the  Administration  on  the 
important  subject  of  regulation  of  air  transportation  and  how  it  can  be  improved. 

The  Department  is  vitally  interested  in  the  issue.  Since  DOT'S  inception  in 
1967,  we  have  participated  in  many  proceedings  before  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board.  In  our  Board  filings,  the  Department  has  been  a  strong  advocate  of  im- 
proving the  economic  performance  of  air  transportation  through  increased  re- 
liance on  competitive  market  forces.  The  unifying  theme  that  runs  through  vir- 
tually all  of  our  filings  before  the  CAB  is  that  greater  reliance  on  competitive 
market  forces  will  improve  the  economic  performance  of  the  industry  and  result 
in  lower,  more  cost  related  rates,  will  reduce  excess  capacity  and  will  provide 
the  air  traveling  public  with  a  wider  and  more  desirable  range  of  service  and 
price  options. 

I  believe  we  are  now  at  a  regulatory  watershed.  For  the  past  several  months, 
the  administration  has  been  reviewing  the  transportation  regulatory  system  with 
a  view  to  improving  both  performance  and  economic  efiiciency.  The  reform  pro- 
posals presently  being  prepared  by  the  administration  mark  a  major  departure 
from  the  regulatory  regime  we  have  relied  upon  in  the  past.  The  administration 
will  submit  to  Congress  in  the  near  future  a  proposal  which  will  fundamentally 
redirect  our  air  transportation  regulatory  policy.  Your  hearings,  therefore  come 
at  an  opportune  moment.  Today  I  will  outline  the  administration's  position  on 
regulation  of  air  transportation. 

The  need  for  an  air  regulatory  reform  act  is  demonstrated  both  by  economic 
research  and  by  our  experience.  At  present,  for  example,  air  carriers,  shippers, 
and  passengers  frequently  face  a  web  of  restrictive  government  regulations  which 
stifle  competition,  discourage  innovation,  and  foster  inefficiency.  In  many  respects, 
the  present  air  regulatory  structure  is  outdated,  inequitable,  inefficient,  uneco- 
nomical and  irrational.  It  often  misplaces  incentive  and  disincentive,  distorts 
competitive  advantage,  protects  ineflScient  carriers  from  effective  competition, 
over-restricts  market  entry,  artifically  inflates  rates  and  misallocates  our  Na- 
tion's resources.  Under  the  current  system,  many  consumers  pay  an  artificially 
inflated  price  for  air  transportation  because  ratesetting,  unnecessary  entry  re- 
strictions, capacity  agreements  and  other  forms  of  shelter  from  competition  sanc- 
tioned by  the  Board  protect  the  least  eflScient  carriers,  permit  rates  substantially 
above  an  eflScient  cost  level  and  distort  competitive  market  forces.  The  resulting 
economic  waste  and  associated  inefficiency  is  substantial. 

The  present  air  regulatory  system  is  the  product  of  a  different  era.  While  the 
needs  and  conditions  on  which  air  regulation  was  first  predicated  some  40  years 
ago  have  changed,  the  goals  and  practices  of  government  regulation  have  not.  It 
is  unfortunately  a  truism  that  regulation  begets  further  regulation  and  that  regu- 
lations outlive  their  rationale. 

In  1938,  when  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  was  passed,  government  assistance 
through  protection,  subsidy,  promotion  and  regulation  was  a  necessary  factor  in 
the  development  of  a  new  and  struggling  industry.  Thirty-seven  years  later,  con- 
ditions have  changed.  The  air  travel  market  is  mature.  Traffic  has  grown.  Growth 
has  led  to  stability.  The  industry  is  vigorous.  But  the  regulatory  system  which 
protected  it  and  made  it  that  way  has  not  kept  pace. 

The  problems  once  faced  have  been  largely  solved.  Now  we  are  faced  with  prob- 
lems that  are  a  byproduct  of  that  success.  The  promotion  which  once  fostered 
growth  now  causes  inefficiency.  The  restriction  which  once  guaranteed  stability 
now  retard  competition.  The  regulatory  protection  which  once  insured  existence 
now  prevents  savings. 

We  need  a  better  system  which  comes  closer  to  producing  optimum  social  and 
economic  results,  one  which  maximizes  efficiency,  economies  and  consumer  op- 
tions and  which  produces  the  best  mix  between  low-cost  and  hisrh-quality  service. 

The  most  pressing  problems  in  the  airline  regulatory  field  cluster  in  three  broad 
areas :  ratemakins:  and  pricing  flexibiUtv,  market  entry  and  exit,  and  anticom- 
petitive agreements.  Each  area  is  in  need  of  reform.  Let  me  identify  what  we  see 
as  the  major  difficulties  involved,  the  actions  DOT  has  taken,  and  the  future 
direction  which  the  administration  suggests. 


20 

A  major  difficulty  with  CAB  policy  has  been  ratemaking  and  the  carrier  in- 
ability to  raise  and  lower  rates  in  response  to  the  demands  of  the  marketplace. 
This  in  turn  forces  carriers  into  costly  and  uneconomic  service  competition,  de- 
prives the  traveling  public  of  the  range  of  price/service  options  which  would 
otherwise  be  available,  and  results  in  substantial  economic  waste  and  inefBciency. 

Section  404  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  requires  carriers  to  establish  just 
and  reasonable  rates.  Section  1002  permits  the  Board  to  prescribe  maximum  or 
minimum  rates  if  it  is  of  the  opinion  that  the  rates  charged  are  unjust,  unreason- 
able, preferential  or  discriminatory.  In  deciding  whether  a  rate  is  too  high  or 
low  the  Board  takes  into  account,  among  other  factors,  whether  the  fare  is  com- 
pensatory, providing  the  carrier  with  sufficient  revenue. 

The  result  of  the  Board  administration  of  these  sections  has  been  the  elimina- 
tion of  price  competition,  thereby  restricting  competition  to  service.  Passengers 
find  airlines  competing  for  their  patronage  through  elaborate  cuisine,  free  drinks, 
attractive  stewardess,  multicolored  planes,  and  piano  bars.  But  they  do  not  have 
a  menu  where  different  quality  service  is  related  to  different  prices.  This  is  a 
serious  loss. 

Many  passengers  would  prefer  the  opportunity  to  select  carriers  based  on  price 
in  addition  to  type  of  service.  Some  passengers  would  prefer  high  load-factor, 
low-frill,  low-fare  service.  Others  are  willing  to  pay  for  more  comfortable  and 
more  costly  service.  Present  procedures  do  not  produce  that  variety  of  price/ 
service  options.  Often,  present  regulation  causes  fares  well  above  those  which 
would  result  in  a  more  competitive  air  transportation  market.  With  prices  fixed 
at  levels  above  market  rates,  carriers  compete  on  the  basis  of  service.  Such  serv- 
ice competition  produces  substantial  unused  capacity  and  unnecessary  low  load- 
factors,  presently  averaging  about  57  percent.  In  the  transcontinental  market, 
for  example,  rates  are  set  sufficiently  high  to  permit  the  carriers  to  earn  a  rea- 
sonable return  with  load  factors  in  the  mid-40  percent  range.  DOT  believes  that 
many  transcontinental  passengers  would  prefer  the  minor  inconveniences  asso- 
ciated with  higher  load  factors  in  return  for  less  expensive  tickets.  In  a  more 
competitive  market,  carriers  would  respond  by  providing  such  low  cost  service. 

One  recent  study  showed  that  at  an  average  load  factor  of  7.5-percent  prices 
could  be  27  percent  lower  than  at  a  50-percent  load  factor.  While  75-percent  load 
factors  are  higher  than  DOT  has  recommended  in  most  markets,  this  example 
illustrates  the  potential  savings  associated  with  pricing  flexibility. 

Present  Board  policies  encourage  lower  than  optimal  load  factors.  DOT's 
testimony  in  the  CAB's  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  (DPFI)  showed 
that  when  load  factors  increase  beyond  a  break-even  level  (defined  to  include 
profits),  carriers  schedule  additional  capacity,  thereby  lowering  load  factors  to 
the  break-even  level  again. 

Because  of  this  inflexibility,  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation. 
DOT,  among  other  things,  urged  the  Board  to  establish  a  15-percent  "zone  of 
reasonableness"  above  and  below  the  fare  structure  curve.  The  zone  would  not 
apply  in  monopoly  markets,  as  defined  by  the  CAB,  where  the  Board  would 
continue  to  review  and  suspend  rates.  Within  the  zone,  carriers  would  be  per- 
mitted to  compete  on  the  basis  of  price,  free  from  regulatory  interference.  Out- 
side the  zone,  the  Board  could  continue  to  suspend  rates  it  believed  unlawful 
under  its  ratemaking  standards.  The  limits  of  the  zone  ensure  that  neither 
dramatic  price  increases  nor  destructive  price  wars  would  ensue.  The  Depart- 
ment position  rested  on  the  premise  that  greater  reliance  on  market  forces 
would  result  in  the  establishment  of  rates  based  on  costs  and  would  afford  the 
public  a  wider  and  better  range  of  price/service  options.  We  emphasized  that  the 
lack  of  price  competition  in  the  air  industry  was  the  primary  cause  of  "seat 
wars"  and  other  service  competition  which  resulted  in  undue  unused  capacity, 
inflated  cost  levels,  and  too  rapid  obsolescence  of  equipment. 

In  its  DPFI  decisions,  the  Board  did  recognize  that  fares  should  be  more 
closely  aligned  to  costs.  It  largely  adopted  our  conclusion  that  low  fares  for 
short-haul  pnssengers  should  not  be  subsidized  by  higher  fares  for  long-haul 
passengers.  The  Board  was  unwilling  at  that  time,  however,  to  adopt  the  broader 
principle  of  pricing  flexibility,  constrained  only  by  costs. 

Another  procedural  problem  associated  with  nririnsr  is  CAB  deiav  in  deciding 
whether  rates  are  reasonable.  We  believe  the  CAB  should  be  required  to  render 
a  final  decision  on  rate  proposals  promptly.  Also,  streamlined  Procedures  should 
enable  the  Board  to  dispose  of  some  cases  on  the  basis  of  piead'n.n'c  alone,  with- 
out formal  hearings.  Large  scale  investigations  such  as  the  DPFI  may  take 
longer,  of  course. 


21 

The  administration  strongly  supports  greater  pricing  flexibility  for  the  airline 
industry.  We  expect  that  our  legislation  will  incorporate  proposals  for  pricing 
tlexibility  and  expedited  decisionmaking. 

Another  major  problem  with  the  present  regulatory  system  is  the  Board's 
restrictive  entry  and  exit  policies.  These  policies  have  also  restricted  competition 
and  increased  costs  to  consumers. 

Section  401  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  gives  the  CAB  control  over  entry  into 
the  industry;  the  Board  is  given  authority  to  determine  which  carriers  may 
operate  in  scheduled  interstate  service  and  on  which  routes  they  may  operate. 
The  applicant  must  be  found  fit,  willing,  and  able  to  perform  the  service  properly, 
and  the  transportation  must  be  required  by  public  convenience  and  necessity! 
CAB  permission  is  also  required  for  exit. 

In  practice,  industry  entry  has  been  tightly  controlled.  Other  than  the  16 
carriers  operating  when  the  1938  Act  took  effect,  there  has  not  been  a  single  new 
trunk  carrier  certificated  in  the  Board's  history.  Through  merger  the  16  original 
trunks  have  shrunk  in  number  to  10  which  account  for  90  percent  of  the  total 
domestic  market.  The  Board  has,  however,  certified  local  service  carriers,  some 
of  which  are  now  as  large  as  the  smaller  trunks. 

Until  recently,  and  especially  in  the  late  sixties,  existing  carriers  were  granted 
applications  for  new  routes,  thereby  substantially  reducing  the  number  of  mono- 
poly markets.  In  the  last  few  years,  however,  the  CAB  has  put  into  effect  a  de 
facto  moratorium  on  route  awards.  New  route  applications  have  not  been  set  for 
hearing ;  processing  applications  which  had  been  set  for  hearing  has  been  delayed. 
The  restrictive  policy  with  respect  to  carrier  entry  has  now  been  matched  by  a 
restrictive  policy  with  respect  to  route  entry. 

The  economic  result  of  a  restrictive  CAB  policy  is  that  carriers  do  not  enter 
and  leave  markets  solely  for  business  and  profit  reasons.  New  firms  are  dis- 
couraged by  the  standards  applied  and  by  the  results  they  see,  including  the  high 
cost  of  the  application  process  and  the  delay  in  Board  decisionmaking.  The  Board 
has  protected  incumbent  carriers  rather  than  encouraged  healthy  competition. 
As  a  result,  in  the  majority  of  trunk  markets,  most  passengers  are  carried  by  only 
one  or  two  airlines. 

The  administration  does  not  necessarily  believe  that  additional  carriers  are 
required  on  every  route  to  improve  the  working  of  the  air  transportation  system. 
We  do  believe,  however,  that  the  present  system  removes  the  ability  of  the  car- 
riers to  adjust  services  and  realine  the  markets  they  serve  as  economic  conditions 
warrant.  This  results  in  increased  costs  to  the  public. 

The  present  system  also  does  not  recognize  the  importance  of  potential  compe- 
tition as  an  economic  force.  Thus,  the  carriers  on  an  existing  route  need  not  be 
concerned  about  new  competition  unless  the  Board  has  a  route  case  pending.  In 
such  circumstances,  the  existing  carriers  may  be  less  diligent  in  providing  the 
type  of  service  and  price/quality  options  desired  by  the  public  than  they  would 
be  if  they  were  aware  that  a  competitor  could  enter  at  any  time  to  provide  new 
or  higher  quality  service. 

Another  way  of  improving  competition  is  by  liberalizing  charter  rules  and 
thereby  offering  the  consumer  a  broader  range  of  price  and  service  options. 

The  administration  believes  a  fundamental  shift  is  required  away  from  over- 
protection  of  existing  carriers  to  one  which  focuses  on  consumer  needs  and  re- 
quires that  more  weight  be  placed  on  competitive  principles  in  evaluating  new 
applications  for  entry.  We  also  believe  that  the  CAB  should  not  be  permitted  to 
delay  decisionmaking  as  a  means  of  limiting  entry. 

Route  exit  has  in  some  eases  also  been  restrained  by  the  CAB.  While  we  recog- 
nize the  importance  of  service  to  communities  of  varying  sizes,  carriers  should 
not  be  forced  to  lose  money  or  operate  on  the  assumption  that  other  routes  subsi- 
dize those  producing  inadequate  revenue.  Cross-subsidies  are  ineflBcient  econom- 
ically and  in  practice  do  not  work. 

W^here  communities  deem  service  essential,  the  carriers  operate  at  a  loss,  and 
the  route  does  not  justify  federal  subsidy,  alternatives  must  be  considered.  These 
alternatives  include  replacement  services  by  another  carrier  or  subsidies  by  the 
community  itself. 

In  this  regard,  I  should  note  that  we  will  not  propose  any  immediate  changes 
in  the  local  subsidy  program.  However,  we  believe  the  CAB  has  an  obligation  to 
identify  the  cost  of  such  subsidies  by  route  and  by  city.  This  has  not  been  done. 

The  administration  strongly  supports  liberalization  of  entry  into  the  air  car- 
rier industry  and  our  forthcoming  proposal  will  provide  for  substantial  entry 
and  exit  liberalization. 


22 

One  of  the  most  objectionable  features  of  present  CAB  regulation  is  the  ap- 
proval of  capacity  reduction  agreements  in  our  domestic  markets.  At  present, 
under  section  412  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act,  if  the  Board  finds  capacity,  pooling 
and  other  anticompetitive  agreements  not  adverse  to  the  public  interest,  it  may 
approve  them  ;  in  so  doing,  it  immunizes  them  from  action  under  the  antitrust 
statutes. 

Capacity  agreements  were  originally  justified  because  of  immediate,  short-term, 
severe  financial  distress.  The  Board  has  since  permitted  use  of  capacity  agree- 
ments to  resolve  problems  of  unused  capacity,  fuel  allocation,  and  low  profits  in 
certain  markets.  By  apportioning  capacity,  such  agreements  effectively  deter- 
mine market  share.  As  a  result  of  Board  actions,  capacity  limitation  agreements 
have  proliferated  to  the  point  where  about  29  percent  of  the  revenue  passenger 
miles  of  the  three  largest  carriers  are  now  covered.  One  economic  effect  is  that, 
given  the  level  of  service  provided,  fares  in  covered  markets  are  excessive.  One 
can  scarcely  imagine  agreements  more  anticompetitive  in  their  effect.  Such  prob- 
lems are  far  better  resolved  through  market  forces  operating  in  a  competitive 
environment. 

DOT  opposed  the  capacity  agreements  before  the  Board  and  has  joined  with 
the  Antitrust  Division  of  the  Justice  Department  to  oppose  approval  of  the  agree- 
ments before  the  District  of  Columbia  Court  of  Appeals. 

In  contrast,  some  agreements  arguably  subject  to  challenge  under  antitrust 
laws  do  serve  valid  transportation  objectives.  These  include  interline  agreements, 
airline  scheduling  committee  agreements  at  congested  airports,  equipment  leases, 
fuel  supply  agreements,  reservations  and  ticketing  arrangements,  and  technical 
agreements  with  foreign  air  carriers. 

We  distinguish  between  the  two  types  of  agreements,  the  one  anticompetitive 
in  a  way  which  contributes  to  economic  inefficiency,  the  other  which  meets  neces- 
sary transportation  objectives.  The  administration  believes  that  anticompetive 
agreements  such  as  those  for  capacity  limitation  ."-hould  be  restricted  or  eliminated 
but  that  agreements  which  serve  efficient  transportation  needs  should  be 
continued. 

Section  408  of  the  Act  authorizes  the  Board  to  approve  mergers.  Mergers  may 
be  permitted  unless  the  Board  finds  that  they  will  be  inconsistent  with  the  public 
interest,  would  create  a  monopoly  and  thereby  restrain  competition,  or  would 
jeopardize  another  nonparty  carrier.  In  our  view,  the  standard  used  by  the  Board 
in  determining  whether  mergers  or  consolidations  are  approved  should  be  changed 
to  require  that  competitive  principles  be  weighed  against  transportation  needs. 

In  DOT'S  filings  to  date,  we  have  encouraged  the  CAB  to  find  less  anticompeti- 
tive solutions  to  many  of  the  problems  I  have  discussed.  It  is  now  clear  that  more 
decisive  reform  is  necessary.  In  times  of  inflation,  recession  and  energy  difficul- 
ties, the  Nation  can  ill  afford  the  extravagances  created  by  the  present  air  regula- 
tory system.  The  administration  proposal  will  get  to  the  heart  of  the  difficulties 
in  each  of  the  areas  discussed  by  changing  the  regulatory  structure  which  helped 
produce  them.  The  air  regulatory  reform  bill  which  we  will  present  will  address 
each  of  these  issues  in  detail  and  will  implement  the  basic  policy  objectives  which 
I  have  outlined  in  my  testimony. 

We  look  forward  to  working  with  the  subcommittee  to  explore  each  of  these 
areas  in  more  detail.  We  share  the  desire  to  modernize  our  regulatory  structure 
and  let  the  fresh  air  of  competition  make  our  transportation  industry  operate 
more  efficiently  at  lower  cost  to  the  consumers  we  serve. 

Senator  Kkxxedy.  Our  second  witness.  Mr.  Eiicrman.  since  February 
1973.  has  served  as  chairman  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission.  ITe 
has  directed  particular  attention  to  the  asrency's  responsibilities  in  the 
area  of  antitrust  laAv  enforcement.  He  is  outspoken  on  recfulatory 
reform,  and  we  are  anxious  to  have  his  views  on  CAB  regulation. 


STATEMENT   OF  LEWIS   ENGMAN.    CHAIRMAN, 
FEDERAL   TRADE   COMMISSION 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Last  year  in  November  when  I  was  asked  to  present  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission's  vieAvs  on  governmental  restraints  in  the  market- 


23 

place,  I  expressed  concern  that,  like  so  many  fashionable  topics,  it 
would  be  the  subject  of  much  discussion  but  little  action.  It  is  grati- 
fying, therefore,  to  know  that  concern  with  this  vital  subject  has  con- 
tinued into  the  Mth  Congiess,  and  I  commend  this  committee  for  its 
role  in  continuing  the  inquiry. 

At  a  time  when  rising  prices  threaten  the  welfare  of  every  American, 
it  would  be  folly  indexed,  if  we  were  to  fail  to  address  this  one  area 
where  such  large  efficiencies  appear  to  be  available  to  us  without  off- 
setting economic  costs. 

I  am,  therefore,  pleased  to  be  here,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  to  have  this 
opportunity  to  offer  my  views  on  Federal  regulations  affecting  the 
airline  industry. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  have  an  extensive  statement  here,  and  I  want 
you  to  proceed  in  whatever  way  you  feel  comfortable,  but  if  you  want 
to  highlight  it  or  summarize  it,  t  think,  that  will  be  helpful. 

Mr.  Engman.  I  normally  do  that,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  I  think  this 
Avill  not  take  long. 

Lest  someone  else  feel  compelled  to  say  it  for  me,  I  must  state  at 
the  outset  that  I  am  no  expert  on  the  technical  aspects  of  the  airline 
industry.  I  suggest,  however,  that  one  need  be  no  expert  to  perceive 
that  something  is  amiss  with  the  Avay  the  Government  currently  con- 
strues its  responsibility  toward  the  American  consumer  of  air 
transportation. 

As  spokesman  for  an  agency  broadly  charged  with  insuring  that  the 
consumer  receives  the  best  that  the  marketplace  can  provide  for  him, 
I  find  this  situation  disturbing. 

The  Fedeial  Trade  Commission  is  committed  to  the  principle  that 
people  are  best  served  by  the  effective  operation  of  a  free  and  com- 
petitive open  market. 

Today,  those  conditions  are  conspicuously  absent  in  our  airline 
industry.  They  are  absent  because,  over  35  years  ago,  the  Congress, 
after  examining  the  needs  of  a  then  infant  industry  struggling  to  raise 
capital,  decided  that  the  public  welfare  demanded  an  exception  to  the 
principle  of  competition — demanded  that  the  airline  industry  be  given 
partial  immunity  from  the  antitrust  laws  and  from  the  rigors  of  price 
competition.  The  arguments  mustered  in  support  of  that  decision  were 
essentially  two :  That  it  was  necessary  to  insure  the  industry  against 
cutthroat  competition,  and  that  it  was  necessary  to  provide  service 
to  localities  which  would  not  otherwise  receive  it. 

I  was  not  around  at  that  time.  I  did  not  hear  the  arguments  made  for 
and  against  what  was  done.  But  \yhatever  arguments  were  made  at 
that  time  and  whatever  industry  conditions  they  reflected  as  you  indi- 
cated, should  be  of  little  consequence  to  us  today.  For  the  relevant 
question  now  is,  where  has  it  all  brought  us  ? 

There  can  be  little  doubt  that  much  of  what  was  intended  has  been 
achieved.  Wliether  it  is  because  of,  or  in  spite  of,  regulation,  I  do  not 
know,  but  today  we  have  beyond  question  the  most  comprehensive  air 
transportation  network  in  the  world.  Moreover,  despite  the  current 
depleted  condition  of  several  of  our  major  carriers,  the  industry  over 
the  years  has  been  characterized  by  extraordinary  stability. 

SERVICE    COMPETITION    AND   EXCESS   FLIGHTS 

But  these  objectives  have  been  achieved  at  a  very  high  cost.  Our 
system,  which  severely  inhibits  price  competition  and  restricts  entry, 


24 

has  led  to  a  fare  structure  on  many  routes  which  economists  a^ree  is 
far  hig;her  than  that  which  would  prevail  if  the  industry  were  charac- 
terized by  price  competition  and  free  entry.  Several  conditions  flow 
from  this  fact. 

The  absence  of  any  real  price  competition  coupled  with  higher  than 
competitive  rates  leads  to  large  amounts  of  nonprice  competition.  One 
important  type  of  nonprice  competition  is  in  terms  of  frequency  of 
flights.  This  in  turn  leads  to  large  amounts  of  excess  capacity.  It  is 
not  unusual  today  for  several  planes  to  fly  almost  identical  schedules 
each  with  a  small  fraction  of  its  seats  filled  on  some  flights. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  makes  two  of  us.  I  have  done  a  lot  of  flying. 

I  just  found  that  out  last  Thursday  evening  when  I  was  flying  to 
San  Francisco.  There  were  two  major  flights  within  5  minutes  of  each 
other,  both  going  nonstop  to  San  Francisco  from  Dulles  Airport. 
Noticing  that  we  had  these  particular  hearings,  I  looked  at  both  of 
them,  and  the  first  class  in  both  were  full  and  the  rest  about  one-third 
full,  and  they  landed  within  5  minutes  of  each  other.  I  have  a  staff 
assistant  who  is  consultant  for  our  Health  Committee,  who  makes  the 
trip  once  a  month,  and  he  has  been  doing  a  little  informal  review  of  this 
as  well,  and  has  found  the  exact  same  thing.  He  finds  it  going  both 
ways.  The  point  is  well  made. 

Mr.  Engman.  I  have  noticed  the  same  situation.  It  is  also  true  with 
other  pairs  of  markets ;  Chicago,  for  instance. 

In  short,  what  we  have  is  economic  waste — the  classic  cost-plus  syn- 
drome. The  air  passenger  who  finds  himself  next  to  an  empty  seat  may 
be  pleased  with  this  state  of  affairs.  He  is  able  to  spread  out  a  little. 
But  I  wonder  how  pleased  he  would  be  if  he  were  aware  that  he  had 
paid  not  only  for  the  seat  he  was  sitting  in,  but  for  the  seat  his  briefcase 
was  sitting  in,  too. 

In  addition,  fixed  rates  have  created  a  sort  of  phony  war,  a  war  in 
which  airlines  compete  for  business,  not  on  the  basis  of  price,  but  on 
the  basis  of  scheduling  and  comfort.  All  of  us  today  have  standing 
invitation  to  fly  Cheryl  or  Karen  or  Trixie  or  even  Bruce.  Those  invita- 
tions are  no  more  or  less  than  confessions  on  the  part  of  the  airlines 
that  our  decision  as  to  Avhich  to  fly  ]:)retty  much  boils  down  to  whether 
Cheryl  is  more  attractive  than  Bruce. 

This  bogus  competition  along  with  creature  comforts  and  the  pres- 
sure to  raise  the  number  of  flights  can  be  explained  by  the  simple  eco- 
nomics of  the  airline  industry.  We  start  with  an  increase  in  fares.  In 
the  absence  of  price  competition,  each  airline  tends  to  compete  away 
the  "profits"  from  the  fare  increase  by  engaging  in  various  forms  of 
increased  nonprice  competition. 

More  frills  are  added.  Witness  the  great  free-drink  battles  of  recent 
times  or  the  lounge  wars  of  some  time  back.  Often  flight  frequencies 
are  also  incrensed.  Unfortunately,  this  tends  to  reduce  overall  load  fac- 
tors on  all  the  planes.  Rates  of  return  go  down,  and  soon  we  are  told  a 
new  fare  increase  is  "required"  to  maintain  the  existing  rates  of  return. 
The  whole  nonj^roductive  cycle  starts  all  over  again. 

ANALOGY    TO    SECURITIES    INDUSTRY 

The  situation  is  analogous  to  that  which  existed  in  the  securities  in- 
dustry a  few  years  ago  when  it  was  operating  on  fixed  rates  across  the 
board.  Since  brokerage  houses  could  not  offer  the  customer  lower  rates. 


^25 

they  offered  frills — counseling  services  and  the  like.  The  brokerage 
houses  argued  that  these  frills  were  Avorth  the  extra  money,  but  the 
institutional  investors  knew  better,  and  they  made  the  brokers  give 
them  the  equivalent  of  rebates  under  the  table.  The  American  consumer 
of  air  transportation  does  not  have  that  power.  I  wonder  how  he  would 
act  if  he  did. 

Comfort  and  scheduling  are  undoubtedly  worth  something  to  con- 
sumers. But  are  they  worth  the  price  he  must  pay  for  them?  Obviously, 
they  are  worth  nothing  to  those  who  cannot  afford  to  fly  because  of  the 
high  prices.  There  is  evidence  which  suggests  also  that  they  are  not 
worth  it  even  to  those  who  can  and  do  fl}'.  If  it  were  true,  given  the 
choice,  some  people  would  choose  to  pay  the  higher  rates  for  deluxe 
or  frequent  service,  why  does  the  industry  and  the  Government  shy 
away  from  giving  them  that  choice?  For  surely  that  has  been  the  pat- 
tern in  recent  years. 

RESTRICTIOXS    OX    CHARTERS 

Our  current  system  of  regulation  has  prevented  the  entry  of  new 
carriers  walling  to  fly  for  less.  And  it  has  frustrated  charter  operations 
willing  to  lay  on  "barebone"  service  at  a  fraction  of  the  going  rates. 

It  is  argued  that  these  limitations  are  necessary  to  prevent  so- 
called  undue  diversion  from  the  scheduled  carriers.  We  can  recognize 
that  argument  for  what  it  is.  "Diversion"  would  not  occur  if  people 
thought  frequent  flights  and  frills  were  worth  the  price. 

Do  not  misunderstand  me.  I  have  nothing  against  Cadillacs.  But 
I  question  the  equity  of  a  system  that  forbids  the  sale  of  Pintos.  And 
I  also  wonder  about  a  system  which  permits  producers  of  a  "big 
ticket"  item  like  air  transportation  to  avoid  the  issue  of  price  except 
when  it  is  to  tell  the  consumer  that  a  special  rate  awaits  him  if  he  is 
leaving  on  a  Wednesday  morning,  i)lans  to  remain  at  his  destination 
for  precisely  53  days,  is  carr\'ing  no  luggage,  and  is  a  charter  member 
of  the  Flat  Earth  Society. 

COST    OF   REGULATION 

It  may  be  impossible  to  get  a  precise  measure  of  how  much  our  system 
of  regulation  actually  costs  the  airline  customer  and  the  American 
public.  But  we  can  get  a  rough  idea  from  examining  prices  in  those  few 
markets  where  regulated  carriers  face  competition  from  intrastate 
carriers  not  subject  to  Federal  regulation.  Tavo  such  markets  currently 
exist  in  California  and  Texas,  as  the  acting  Secretary  indicated,  and 
you  have  doubtless  already  heard  and  read  much  about  them.  Suffice  it 
to  say  that  the  unregulated  intrastate  carrier  entered  the  market  with 
substantially  lower  fares  in  each  instance.  In  the  case  of  Texas,  the 
price  differential  remains  today  with  the  result  that  consumers  are 
offered  a  lower  cost  alternative — offered  it,  I  might  add,  by  a  financi- 
ally successful  airline.  Southwest  Airlines.  In  the  case  of  "California, 
the  low-cost  competition  offered  by  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  forced 
the  interstate  carriers  to  appeal  for  and  finally  to  get  from  the  Govern- 
ment permission  to  lower  their  rates  to  the  level  of  the  competition. 
But  you  need  only  step  across  the  State  line  to  appreciate  the  local 
character  of  this  consumer  benefit.  It  still  costs  much  more  to  fly  the 
226  miles  from  Los  Angeles  to  Las  Vegas  than  it  does  to  fly  the  347 
miles  from  Los  Angeles  to  San  Francisco. 


26 

The  cost  to  the  consumer  of  continued  regulation  is  suggested  also 
by  a  1972  economic  study  in  which  the  costs  of  airline  operations  were 
compared  with  fares  for  flights  between  30  different  pairs  of  cities. 
These  comparisons  showed  that,  in  markets  where  there  was  no  com- 
petition from  an  unregulated  carrier,  fares  exceeded  costs,  costs  being 
defined  to  include  a  7.5  percent  return  on  investment,  from  47  percent 
to  8-4  percent.  Since,  with  competition,  fares  could  be  expected  roughly 
to  parallel  costs,  this  wide  variation  would  seem  to  suggest  that 
the  experiences  in  Texas  and  California  do  not  reflect  unique 
circumstances. 

These  then  are  at  least  some  of  the  costs  that  have  been  imposed  on 
the  public  in  stressing  stability  and  comprehensive  service.  Whether 
one  has  been  worth  the  other  is  a  policy  question  which  Congress 
should  consider. 

But  any  weighing  of  costs  and  benefits  surely  should  be  preceded  by 
a  close  examination  of  their  relationship.  For  it  can  be  argued  that 
many  of  the  costs  incurred  were  not  necessary  to  the  attainment  of  the 
benefits  intended. 

SMALL    TOW^N    SERVICE     (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Consider  first  the  benefit  of  comprehensive  service — that  is,  service 
to  parts  of  the  country  where  traffic  is  too  light  to  support  a  scheduled 
airline.  It  is  often  argued  that  high  fares  on  heavily  traveled  routes 
are  needed  to  subsidize  losses  on  sparser  runs  which  the  regulated 
carriers  are  required  to  fly.  I  frankly  have  to  tell  you  I  do  not  know 
how  much  of  this  "cross-subsidization''  actually  occurs,  but  assuming 
that  there  is  some,  it  has  the  effect  of  putting  tlie  entire  industry  on  a 
de  facto  cost-plus  system  of  return,  a  system  which  experience  has  in- 
dicated is  a  very  poor  check  on  inefficiency.  Also,  requiring  one  air 
passenger  to  subsidize  the  flight  of  another  raises  a  serious  question  of 
equity.  If  it  is  a  desirable  thing  to  have  air  service  between  two  small 
towns,  why  should  only  one  class  of  citizens  be  asked  to  bear  the  cost 
of  it? 

Finallv.  the  svstem  raises  the  question  of  resource  allorntion.  for 
there  can  be  no  question  that  a  subsidy  paid  from  high  fares  on  heavily 
traveled  routes  causes  misallocation  of  resources. 

Higher  fares  on  denser  routes  inhibit  travel  on  those  routes.  The 
"right"  amount  of  air  travel  on  those  routes  would  be  the  amount 
which  people  would  buy  at  a  price  which  just  covered  all  costs  of  pro- 
viding the  service.  Higher  prices  will  cause  them  to  buy  less  than  that 
amount.  And  the  resulting  loss  to  society  is  the  same  as  it  would  be 
had  the  higher  price  been  the  result  of  private  price  fixing  or 
monopoly. 

I  express  no  view  on  the  question  of  whether  some  flights  should  be 
directly  subsidized.  I  suggest  simply  that  if  we  are  to  have  a  system 
under  which  some  people  subsidize  service  to  others,  we  should,  at  the 
very  least,  be  able  to  identify  its  costs  so  that  we  can  intelligently 
examine  alternate  forms  of  subsidy  and  so  that  we  can  periodically 
reassure  ourselves  that  the  benefits  are  worth  the  costs. 

DESTRUCTIVE    COMPETITION 

The  other  pillar— in  addition  to  comprehensive  service — on  which 
our  current  regulatory  system  stands  is  the  need  to  prevent  "cut- 


27 

throat'"  competition  which  could  threaten  the  industry's  stability  and 
perhaps  result  in  a  single-firm  monopoly. 

This  has  not  happened  in  California,  and  I  see  no  reason  to  expect 
that  it  would  be  a  general  problem. 

The  number  of  firms  present  in  any  industry  depends  largely  on 
whether  there  are  large  economies  of  scale  relative  to  market  demand. 
If  there  are,  there  will  be  only  a  few  firms  in  the  industry.  In  the 
most  extreme  cases,  there  may  be  only  one. 

But  the  airline  industry  does  not  have  large  economies  of  scale. 
The  basic  unit  of  production  is  the  airplane  itself.  Economic  studies 
indicate  that  an  efficient  airline  can  be  run  with  only  a  few  of  them. 
They  can  be — and  are — easily  shifted  from  one  route  or  one  carrier  to 
another. 

Single  firm  service  may  emerge  on  some  lightly  traveled  routes  be- 
cause of  the  small  size  of  the  market.  But  it  is  doubtful  that  such  firms 
could  charge  monopoly  prices  because  of  the  constant  threat  of  entry 
by  other  firms,  if  it  were  permitted.  The  ability  to  shift  planes  easily 
from  one  market  to  another  makes  the  threat  of  entry  quite  credible 
in  this  industr^\ 

Much  of  what  I  have  just  said  you  have  doubtless  heard  from 
others.  The  question  is,  "what  do  we  do  about  it  ?" 

CAB  asks  airlines  for  data  on  their  liquor  costs.  I  know  what  they 
are  doing. 

That  is  one  of  the  purposes  of  these  hearings,  and  because  the 
answer  to  the  question  of  what  we  can  do  about  it  is  really  not  all  that 
clear,  perhaps,  but  there  are  two  points,  Mr.  Chairman,  which  are 
quite  clear  to  me. 

First,  I  believe  that  no  one  is  going  to  be  able  to  provide  a  complete 
answer  until  we  have  a  better  accounting  of  the  costs  and  benefits  of 
the  current  system.  At  present,  neither  the  Federal  Trade  Commis- 
sion, nor  the  Congress  nor  the  American  public  has  any  idea  of  what 
the  current  system  of  regulation  costs  or  what  it  produces.  My  interest 
in  this  question  as  a  Federal  official  is  not  as  important  as  my  interest 
as  an  air  traveler — incidentally,  with  three  young  sons — and  as  a  tax- 
payer since  I,  along  with  millions  and  millions  of  other  Americans, 
am  paying  the  bills. 

COST    OF    REGULATIOX 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  cannot  really  tell  how  much  they  would 
save  the  consumer  ? 

INIr.  ExGMAX.  The  precise  number  is  one  which  is  beyond  our  ability 
to  knoAv.  As  you.  ]Mr.  Chairman,  cited  a  study  which  I  have  cited  iii 
the  past,  the  question  of  $17-$18  billion  range,  that  has  been  cited 
across  the  board,  that  of  course  includes  surface  transportation,  too, 
studies  indicating  the  range  from  48-84  percent  overcharging  on  the 
30  selected  flights  indicated  there,  and  certainly  we  are  talking  about 
hundreds  of  thousands  and  probably  millions  of  dollars  each  year. 

I  think  in  terms  of  specifics  as  to  some  of  these  cost  questions,  such 
as  to  whether  or  not  how  much  do  we  really  know,  how  much  cross 
subsidies  do  we  really  have  going  on,  or  is  this  a  kind  of  issue  that 
has  just  been  raised  to  tend  to  confuse  the  issue  would  be  helpful,  and 
we  have  to  work  to  continue  to  improve  the  information  we  have 
available  to  us. 


28 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  have  the  ability  or  does  the  Federal 
Trade  Commission  have  that  kind  of  ability,  to  develop  figures  on 
this? 

Mr.  Engman.  We  have  a  large  staff  of  economists,  Mr.  Chairman, 
who  are  kept  busy  by  a  number  of  investigations  and  studies  which 
the  Congress  asks  us  to  undertake,  primarily  in  the  antitrust  enforce- 
ment area.  We  do  not  have  immediate  access  to  some  of  the  data  that 
the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  does.  But  to  the  extent  Congress,  in  terms 
of  providing  us  with  resources  and  money,  are  interested  in  us  pro- 
ceeding with  the  further  investigation  so  some  of  these  economic  ele- 
ments, speaking  for  myself,  and  I  am  sure  on  behalf  of  the  Commis- 
sion, would  be  more  than  happy  to  comply. 

That  is  the  first  point  and  the  data  point. 

Second,  in  terms  of  what  I  am  clear  about  in  answering  this  ques- 
tion of  what  we  should  do.  my  experience  has  led  me  to  conclude  that 
the  free  enterprise  system  is  the  best  regulator  of  all.  I  can  see  nothing 
about  the  airline  industry  which  would  suggest  to  me  that  in  1975, 
Government  regulation  of  the  airline  industry  is  providing  the  con- 
sumer with  more  for  his  money  than  the  free  market  would  provide. 
Therefore,  I  suggest  you  listen  to  proponents  of  regulation  with  an 
open  mind,  as  I  have  done.  But  I  submit,  giveii  the  conditions  that 
exist  today  in  the  industry  and  in  regulated  industries  in  general, 
that  the  competitive  market  should  be  made  the  point  of  departure 
for  the  debate  and  that  the  burden  of  proof  should  rest  with  those 
who  argue  against  competition  rather  than  those  who  would  return 
to  it.  The  burden  should  also  be  on  those  who,  in  the  name  of  reform, 
stop  short  of  this  goal. 

There  will  be  doomsayers  who  will  forecast  the  direct  consequences 
of  deregulating  rates  and  entry.  Typically,  they  will  be  based  on  the 
reductio  ad  absurbum  case  in  which  at  12 :47  on  a  Wednesday  after- 
noon, we  shift  from  total  regulation  to  open  competition.  It  need  not 
occur  that  way.  If  the  Congress  were  to  determine  that  a  move  in  the 
direction  of  the  free  market  were  warranted,  it  could  easily  enough  be 
accomplished  in  stages.  There  is  ample  precedent.  Several  years  ago 
the  SEC  was  looking  at  an  analogous  situation  in  the  securities  in- 
dustry. Brokers  then  operating  on  a  fixed  rate  basis  argued  bitterly 
that  negotiated  rates  would  be  a  disaster.  The  SEC  rejected  that  argu- 
ment and  decided  to  move  ahead,  not  all  at  once,  but  on  a  staged  basis. 
Beginning  with  purchases  of  over  $500,000,  rates  were  left  to  the 
forces  of  the  market. 

SAFETY   AND    COMPETITION 

Senator  Kennedy.  But  you  did  not  really  have  the  issue  of  life, 
sustaining  your  industry.  If  you  made  a  mistake  in  tliat,  it  was  just  a 
matter  of  brokers'  fee.  Here  in  terms  of  safety  it  is  people's  lives. 

Mr.  Engman.  We  are  not  talking  about  safety.  I  am  talking  about 
the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  The  requirements  for  safety  are  handled 
by  the  Federal  Aviation  Administration.  If  I  agree  with  what  I  have 
read  in  the  papers,  perhaps  there  ought  to  be  some  tightening  up  of 
regulation  over  there,  wliich  is  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Depart- 
ment of  Transportation.  But  that  kind  of  safety  regulation  which  we 
are  all  in  favor  of,  the  traveling  public,  does  not  come  under  the 
jurisdiction  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 


29 


THE    POSSIBILITY    OF    CHAOS 


Senator  Kennedy.  With  the  newer,  costly  equipment  and  the  addi- 
tional energy  costs,  in  considering  open  entry  and  competition  in  fares, 
are  we  not  talking  about  a  situation  which  is  inviting  chaos? 

Mr.  Engman.  i  am  not  at  all  sure  that  would  be  the  situation,  Mr. 
Chairman.  We  do  not  really  know  what  would  happen,  perhaps. 

I  suggest  part  of  the  problem  in  the  existing  market  is  that  some 
carriers — for  example,  Pan  Am  is  not  permitted  to  compete  in  some 
of  the  more  lucrative  routes.  I  was  happy  to  see  that  the  Department 
of  Justice  recently  suggested  to  CAB  that  that  might  be  one  of  the 
answers  to  Pan  Am's  problem. 

But  as  my  earlier  testimony  suggested,  the  present  system,  which 
prohibits  price  competition,  in  fact  encourages  the  type  of  situation 
to  exist  with  overcapacity,  and  that  leads  to  costs  higher  than  they 
otherwise  would  be,  and  bad  profit. 

Obviously  there  may  be  some  differences,  but  even  in  the  securities 
industry  back  a  few  years  ago,  we  had  a  bear  market,  falling  volume 
on  the  stock  exchange,  but  there  were  really  no  disasters  that  came 
about  as  a  result  of  the  abolition  of  the  fixed-rate  fee  system.  It  was 
done  in  a  series  of  stages  until  finally  the  system  was  abolished  alto- 
gether. It  is  not  a  pure  analog}',  but  it  seems  to  me  a  similar  approach 
might  be  taken  toward  the  airlines. 

I  suggest  a  scheduled  return  to  the  free  market  over  2  years  or  4 
years  or  whatever  period  Congress  deems  appropriate.  This  would 
put  the  fundamental  arguments  in  support  of  regulation  on  trial. 
And  it  could  be  done  in  a  manner  that  would  allow  the  decision  as  to 
how  far  to  go  to  be  based  on  fact  and  proven  results  rather  than  on 
theory. 

My  own  guess  is  that  we  would  make  it  all  the  way  back  to  "regula- 
tion" by  the  free  market  and  that  we  would  be  better  off  for  it. 

Thank  you  very  much,  Mr.  Chairman,  I  will  be  more  than  happy  to 
attempt  to  respond  to  any  questions  that  you  might  have. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much. 

I  value  very  highly  your  testimony  and  your  comments. 

We  in  the  Congress  have  been  very  impressed  with  the  efforts  that 
you  have  made  in  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  in  attempting  to 
bring  about  a  variety  of  reforms.  I  think  you  are  aware  that  a  few 
years  ago  wo  had  some  hearings  on  various  procedures  and  practices 
within  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  and  made  a  number  of  recom- 
mendations. I  must  say  that  I  have  been  enormously  impressed  with 
what  has  been  achieved  under  your-  leadership  in  the  Commission. 

jNIr.  Engman.  Thank  you. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  that  has  been  of  great  value  to  the 
American  public. 

NEED    FOR    LEGISLATION 

I  am  wondering  whether  you  think  a  number  of  these  points  that 
you  have  raised  here  can  be  done,  a  number  of  these  reforms  can  be 
achieved  without  additional  legislation.  You  have  seen  very  sub- 
stantial reform  within  your  own  agencies  without  corresponding 
legislation,  I  believe,  and  I  am  just  wondering  whether  you  feel  these 
other  points  that  you  have  raised  here  this  morning  can"  be  done  like- 
wise without  legislation  ? 


30 

Mr.  Engman.  It  is  a  good  point,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Let  me  say  first  of  all  that  I  think  honesty  would  compel  me  to  say 
that  although  a  great  deal  of  the  impetus  at  the  Federal  Trade  Com- 
mission could  come  from  the  Commission,  I  think  a  number  of  things 
we  have  been  able  to  accomplish,  in  my  view  the  past  few  years,  have 
been  the  result  of  the  cooperation  and  assistance  of  the  Congress,  not 
only  in  terms  of  holding  hearings  on  certain  questions,  and  particu- 
larly recently  again  in  terms  of  assisting  us  with  some  kind  of  addi- 
tional legislative  authority.  But  I  do  appreciate  your  remarks. 

I  think,  as  Secretary  Barnum  indicated,  there  is  quite  a  bit  that 
could  be  done  under  the  existing  legislation.  Certainly  a  different 
approach,  a  more  liberalized  approach  could  be  taken  by  the  Board 
with  respect  to  limitations  on  entry.  I  certainly  feel  that  under  section 
1002  of  their  act  they  have  the  ability  to  not  suspend  proposed  fare 
decreases  by  various  airlines,  and  that  would  be  a  step  in  the  right 
direction,  they  could  encourage  price  competition,  price  quality 
option,  and  although  I  am  not  an  aviation  regulatory  expect,  I  believe 
that  thev  could  give  serious  consideration  on  their  own  to  adopting 
the  kind  of  proposal  which  Mr.  Barnum  outlined  this  morning  with 
respect  to  establishing  a  zone  of  reasonableness  Avith  respect  to  pricing. 

I  do  suggest  there  are  some  inbred  difficulties  within  any  institution 
after  a  period  of  time,  and  because  of  the  value  of  precedent  and 
because  the  agency  was  initially  established  in  effect  to  promote— and 
it  still  views  as  one  of  its  functions—  the  airline  industry  in  the  Ignited 
States. 

With  that  kind  of  objective  and  that  kind  of  of  gloss  written  over 
their  responsibilities,  let  me  say,  I  am  not  optimistic  that  substantial 
changes  will  be  made  or  sufficient  changes  will  be  made  by  the  Board. 

APPOINTMENT    OF    CAB    MEMBERS 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  some  of  the  problem  is  the  appoint- 
ment process  ?  We  talked  a  little  bit  about  that  earlier. 

Mr.  Engman.  I  heard  the  discussion  on  that. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  would  you  change  that  ? 

Mr.  Engman.  Let  me  first  confess  that  my  focus  on  it  with  respect 
to  this  system  of  regulation  basically  has  been  an  institutional  one  and 
I  have  not  given  a  great  deal  of  thought  to  the  earlier  questions,  and  1 
cannot  really  speak  from  firsthand  knowledge  as  to  Avhat  that  process 
has  been  with  respect  to  that  agency. 

I  know  as  far  as  my  own  process  went  that  the  Commerce  Committee 
I  thought  did  a  good,  extensive,  thorough  job  of  analysing  qualifica- 
tions in  the  examinations  I  have  seen  them  undertake,  and  I  think  it  is 
the  responsibility  of  Congress  to  do  that.  Whether  or  not  that  has  been 
done  sufficiently  with  respect  to  some  of  the  areas,  I  frankly  do  not 
know.  But  I  think  there  is  a  role  for  improvement  of  the  process.  I 
happen  to  believe  there  is  nothing  we  have  around  that  is  so  sacred 
(hat  we  cannot  improve  it  unless  it  is  something  like  the  first  amend- 
ment. As  a  result  of  that,  I  think,  there  may  be  an  admirable  approach 
there. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Fine.  Very  helpful.  We  want  to  thank  you  very 
much  for  your  presentation. 

Mr.  Engman.  Thank  you  very  much,  Mr.  Chairman,  for  the  oppor- 
tunity to  be  here. 


31 

Prepared  Statement  of  Lewis  A.  Engman 

Last  year  when  I  was  asked  to  present  the  Federal  Trade  Commission's  views 
on  governmental  restraints  in  the  marketplace,  I  expressed  concern  that,  like  so 
many  voguish  topics,  it  would  be  the  subject  of  much  discussion  but  little  action. 
It  is  gratifying,  therefore,  to  know  that  concern  with  this  vital  subject  has  con- 
tinued into  the  94th  Congress,  and  I  commend  this  subcommittee  for  its  role  in 
continuing  the  inquiry. 

At  a  time  when  rising  prices  threaten  the  welfare  of  every  American,  it  would 
be  folly  indeed  if  we  were  to  fail  to  address  this  one  area  where  such  large 
efficiencies  appear  to  be  available  to  us  without  offsetting  economic  costs. 

I  am,  therefore,  pleased  to  be  here,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  to  have  this  oppor- 
tunity to  offer  my  views  on  Federal  regulations  affecting  the  airline  industry. 

Lest  someone  else  feel  compelled  to  say  it  for  me,  I  must  state  at  the  outset 
that  I  am  no  expert  on  the  technical  aspects  of  the  airline  industry.  I  suggest, 
however,  that  one  need  be  no  expert  to  perceive  that  something  is  amiss  with  the 
way  the  Government  currently  construes  its  responsibility  toward  the  American 
consumer  of  air  transportation. 

As  spokesman  for  an  agency  broadly  charged  with  ensuring  that  the  consumer 
receives  the  best  that  the  marketplace  can  provide  for  him,  I  find  this  situation 
disturbing. 

The  Federal  Trade  Commission  is  committed  to  the  principle  that  people  are 
best  served  by  the  effective  operation  of  a  free  and  competitive  open  market. 

Today,  those  conditions  are  conspicuously  absent  in  our  airline  industry.  They 
are  absent  because,  over  35  years  ago,  the  Congress,  after  examining  the  needs 
of  a  then  infant  industry  struggling  to  raise  capital,  decided  that  the  public  wel- 
fare demanded  an  exception  to  the  principle  of  competition — demanded  that  the 
airline  industry  be  given  partial  immunity  from  the  antitrust  laws  and  from  the 
rigors  of  price  competition.  The  arguments  mustered  in  support  of  that  decision 
were  essentially  two :  that  it  was  necessary  to  ensure  the  industry  against  "cut- 
throat" competition  and  that  it  was  necessary  to  provide  service  to  localities 
which  would  not  otherwise  receive  it. 

I  was  not  around  at  that  time.  I  did  not  hear  the  arguments  made  for  and 
against  what  was  done.  But  whatever  arguments  were  made  at  that  time  and 
whatever  industry  conditions  they  reflected  should  be  of  little  consequence  to  us 
today.  For  the  relevant  question  now  is  where  has  it  all  brought  us? 

There  can  be  little  doubt  that  much  of  what  was  intended  has  been  achieved. 
Whether  it  is  because  of,  or  in  spite  of,  regulation,  I  do  not  know,  but  today  we 
have  beyond  question  the  most  comprehensive  air  transportation  network  in  the 
world.  Moreover,  despite  the  current  depleted  condition  of  several  of  our  major 
carriers,  the  industry  over  the  years  has  been  characterized  by  extraordinary 
stability. 

But  these  objectives  have  been  achieved  at  a  very  high  cost.  Our  system,  which 
severely  inhibits  price  competition  and  restricts  entry,  has  led  to  a  fare  structure 
on  many  routes  which  economists  agree  is  far  higher  than  that  which  would 
prevail  if  the  industry  were  characterized  by  price  competition  and  free  entry. 
Several  conditions  flow  from  this  fact. 

The  absence  of  any  real  price  competition  coupled  with  higher  than  competitive 
rates  leads  to  large  amounts  of  nonprice  competition.  One  important  type  of 
nonprice  competition  is  in  terms  of  frequency  of  flights.  This  in  turn  leads  to 
large  amounts  of  excess  capacity.  It  is  UQt  unusual  today  for  several  planes  to  fly 
almost  identical  schedules  each  with  a  small  fraction  of  its  seats  filled  on  some 
flights.  In  short,  there  is  economic  waste — the  classic  cost-plus  syndrome.  The 
air  passenger  who  finds  himself  next  to  an  empty  seat  may  be  pleased  with 
this  state  of  affairs.  He  is  able  to  spread  out  a  little.  But  I  wonder  how  pleased 
he  would  be  if  he  were  f^ware  that  he  had  paid  not  only  for  the  seat  he  was 
sitting  in,  but  for  the  seat  his  briefcase  was  sitting  in,  too. 

In  addition,  fixed  rates  have  created  a  sort  of  phony  war,  a  war  in  which 
airlines  compete  for  business,  not  on  the  basis  of  price,  but  on  the  basis  of 
scheduling  and  comfort.  All  of  us  today  have  standing  invitations  to  fly  Cheryl 
or  Karen  or  Trixie  or  even  Bruce.  Those  invitations  are  no  more  or  less  than  con- 
fessions on  the  part  of  the  airlines  that  our  decision  as  to  which  to  fly  pretty 
much  boils  down  to  whether  Cheryl  is  more  attractive  than  Bruce. 

This  bogus  competition  along  with  creature  comforts  and  the  pressure  to  up 
the  number  of  flights  can  be  explained  by  the  simply  economics  of  the  airline 
industry.  We  start  with  an  increase  in  fares.  In  the  absence  of  price  competition 
each  airline  tends  to  compete  away  the  "profits"  from  the  fare  increase  by 
engaging  in  various  forms  of  increased  nonprice  competition. 


32 

More  frills  are  added.  Witness  the  great  free  drink  battles  of  recent  times 
or  the  lounge  wars  of  some  time  back.  Often  flight  frequencies  are  also  in- 
creased. Unfortunately,  this  tends  to  reduce  overall  load  factors  on  all  the 
planes.  Rates  of  return  go  down,  and  soon  a  new  fare  increase  is  "required"  to 
maintain  the  existing  rates  of  return.  The  whole  non-productive  cycle  starts 
all  over  again. 

The  situation  is  analogous  to  that  which  existed  in  the  securities  industry 
a  few  years  ago  when  it  was  operating  on  fixed  rates  across  the  board.  Since 
brokerage  houses  could  not  offer  the  customer  lower  rates,  they  offered  frills, 
counseling  services  and  the  like.  The  brokerage  houses  argued  that  these  frills 
were  worth  the  extra  money,  but  the  institutional  investors  knew  better  and 
they  made  the  brokers  give  them  the  equivalent  of  rebates  under  the  table.  The 
American  consumer  of  air  transportation  doesn't  have  that  power.  I  wonder  how 
he  would  act  if  he  did. 

Comfort  and  scheduling  are  undoubtedly  worth  something  to  consumers.  But 
are  they  worth  the  price  he  must  pay  for  them?  Obviously,  they  are  worth 
nothing  to  those  who  cannot  afford  to  fly  because  of  the  high  prices.  There  is 
evidence  which  suggests  also  that  they  are  not  worth  it  even  to  those  who  can 
and  do  fly.  If,  given  the  choice,  some  people  would  choose  to  pay  the  higher  rates 
for  deluxe  or  frequent  service,  why  does  the  industry  and  the  Government  shy 
away  from  giving  them  that  choice?  For  surely  that  has  been  the  pattern  in 
recent  years. 

Our  current  system  of  regulation  has  prevented  the  entry  of  new  carriers 
willing  to  fly  for  less.  And  it  has  frustrated  operations  willing  to  lay  on  "bare- 
bones"  service  at  a  fraction  of  the  going  rates. 

It  is  argued  that  these  limitations  are  necessary  to  prevent  "undue  diversion" 
from  the  scheduled  carriers.  We  can  recognize  that  argument  for  what  it  is. 
"Diversion"  would  not  occur  if  people  thought  frequent  flights  and  frills  were 
worth  the  price. 

Do  not  misunderstand  me.  I  have  nothing  against  Cadillacs.  But  I  question  the 
equity  of  a  system  that  forbids  the  sale  of  Pintos.  And  I  wonder  about  a  system 
which  permits  producers  of  a  "big  ticket"  item  like  air  transportation  to  avoid 
the  issue  of  price  except  when  it  is  to  tell  consumer  that  a  si>ecial  rate  awaits 
him  if  he  is  leaving  on  Wednesday  morning,  plans  to  remain  at  his  destination 
for  precisely  53  days,  is  carrying  no  luggage  and  is  a  charter  member  of  the  Flat 
Earth  Society. 

It  may  be  impossible  to  get  a  precise  measure  of  how  much  our  system  of 
regulation  actually  costs  the  airline  customer  and  the  American  public.  But  we 
get  a  rough  idea  examining  prices  in  those  few  markets  where  regulated  carriers 
face  competition  from  intrastate  carrers  not  subject  to  Federal  regulation.  Two 
such  markets  currently  exist  in  California  and  Texas,  and  you  have  doubtless 
already  heard  and  read  much  about  them.  SuflBce  it  to  say  that  the  unregulated 
intrastate  carrier  entered  the  market  with  substantially  lower  fares  in  each 
instance.  In  the  ca.se  of  Texas,  the  price  differential  remains  today  with  the  result 
that  consumers  are  offered  a  lower  cost  alternative — offered  it,  I  might  add,  by  a 
financially  successful  airline,  Southwest  Airlines.  In  the  case  of  California,  the 
low  cost  competition  offered  by  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  forced  the  interstate 
carriers  to  appeal  for  and  to  get  from  the  government  permission  to  lower  their 
rates  to  the  level  of  the  competition.  But  you  need  only  step  across  the  state  line 
to  appreciate  the  local  character  of  this  consumer  benefit.  It  still  costs  much 
more  to  fly  the  226  miles  from  Los  Angeles  to  Las  Vegas  than  it  does  to  fly  the 
347  miles  from  Los  Angeles  to  San  Francisco. 

The  cost  of  the  consumer  of  continued  regulation  is  suggested  also  by  a  1972 
economic  study  in  which  the  costs  of  airline  operations  were  compared  with 
fares  for  flights  between  30  different  pairs  of  cities.  These  comparisons  showed 
that,  in  markets  where  there  was  no  competition  from  an  unregulated  carrier, 
fares  exceeded  costs,  including  a  7%  percent  return  on  investment,  by  from  47 
percent  to  84  percent.  Since,  with  competition,  fares  could  be  expected  roughly  to 
parallel  costs,  this  wide  variation  would  seem  to  suggest  that  the  experiences  in 
Texas  and  California  do  not  reflect  unique  circumstances. 

These  then  are  at  least  some  of  the  costs  that  have  been  imposed  on  the  public 
in  stressing  stability  and  comprehensive  service.  Whether  one  has  been  worth 
the  other  is  a  policy  question  which  Congress  should  consider. 

But  any  weighing  of  costs  and  benefits  surely  should  be  preceded  by  a  close 
examination  of  their  relationship.  For  it  can  be  arsrued  that  many  of  the  costs 
incurred  were  not  necessary  to  the  attainment  of  the  benefits  intended. 


Consider  first  the  benefit  of  comprehensive  service,  that  is,  service  to  parts 
of  the  country  where  traffic  is  too  light  to  support  a  scheduled  airline.  It  is  often 
argued  that  high  fares  on  heavily  travelled  routes  are  needed  to  subsidize  losses 
on  sparser  runs  which  the  regulated  carriers  are  required  to  fly.  I  do  not  know 
how  much  of  this  "cross-subsidization"  actually  occurs,  but  assuming  that  there  is 
some,  it  has  the  effect  of  putting  the  entire  industry  on  a  de  facto  cost-plus  system 
of  return,  a  system  which  experience  has  indicated  is  a  very  poor  check  on 
inefficiency.  Also,  requiring  one  air  passenger  to  subsidize  the  flight  of  another 
raises  a  serious  question  of  equity.  If  it  is  a  desirable  thing  to  have  air  service 
between  two  small  towns,  why  should  only  one  class  of  citizens  be  asked  to  bear 
the  cost  of  it? 

Finally,  the  system  raises  the  question  of  resource  allocation,  for  there  can 
be  no  question  that  a  subsidy  paid  from  high  fares  on  heavily  travelled  routes 
causes  misallocation  of  resources. 

Higher  fares  on  denser  routes  inhibit  travel  on  those  routes.  The  "right"  amount 
of  air  travel  on  these  routes  would  be  the  amount  which  i>eople  would  buy  at  a 
price  which  just  covered  all  costs  of  providing  the  service.  Higher  prices  will 
cause  them  to  buy  less  than  that  amount.  And  the  resulting  loss  to  society  is  the 
same  as  it  would  be  had  the  higher  price  been  the  result  of  private  price  fixing  or 
monopoly. 

I  express  no  view  on  the  question  of  whether  some  flights  should  be  directly 
subsidized.  I  .suggest  simply  that  if  we  are  to  have  a  system  under  which  some 
people  subsidize  service  to  others,  we  should,  at  the  very  least,  be  able  to  identify 
its  costs  so  that  we  can  intelligently  examine  alternate  forms  of  subsidy  and  so 
that  we  can  periodically  reassure  ourselves  that  the  benefits  are  worth  the  costs. 
The  otlier  pillar — in  addition  to  comprehensive  service — on  which  our  current 
regulatory  system  stands  is  the  need  to  prevent  "cutthroat"  competition  which 
could  threaten  the  industry's  stability  and  perhaps  result  in  a  single-firm 
monopoly. 

This  has  not  happened  in  California,  and  I  see  no  reason  to  expect  that  it  w^ould 
be  a  general  problem. 

The  number  of  firms  present  in  any  industry  depends  largely  on  whether  there 
are  large  economies  of  scale  relative  to  market  demand.  If  there  are,  there  will  be 
only  a  few  firms  in  the  industry.  In  the  most  extreme  cases,  there  may  be  only  one. 
But  the  airline  industry  does  not  have  large  economies  of  scale.  The  basic 
unit  of  production  is  the  airplane  itself.  Economic  studies  indicate  that  an  efficient 
airline  can  be  run  with  only  a  few  of  them.  They  can  be — and  are — easily 
shifted  from  one  route  or  carrier  to  another. 

Single  firm  service  may  emerge  on  some  lightly  travelled  routes  because  of 
the  small  size  of  the  market.  But  it  is  doubtful  that  such  firms  could  charge 
monopoly  prices  because  of  the  constant  threat  of  entry  by  other  firms.  The  ability 
to  shift  planes  easily  from  one  market  to  another  makes  the  threat  of  entry  quite 
credible  in  this  industry.  Much  of  what  I  have  said  you  have  doubtless  heard  from 
others.  The  question  is  "what  do  we  do  about  it?"  This  is  obviously  a  complex 
area,  and  the  precise  answer  to  that  question  is  not  clear.  However,  two  points 
are  quite  clear  to  me. 

First,  I  believe  that  no  one  is  going  to  be  able  to  provide  a  complete  answer 
until  we  have  a  better  accounting  of  the  costs  and  benefits  of  the  current  system. 
At  present,  neither  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  nor  the  Congress  nor  the 
American  public  has  any  idea  of  what  the  current  system  of  regulation  costs  or 
what  it  produces.  My  interest  in  this  question  as  a  Federal  official  is  not  as  im- 
portant as  my  interest  as  an  air  traveller  and  a  taxpayer  since  I,  along  with 
millions  and  millions  of  other  Americans,  am  paying  the  bills.  Congress'  need  to 
know  is  greatest  of  all.  For  without  the  facts  on  the  table,  you  will  have  no 
frame  of  reference  against  which  to  compare  alternate  approaches. 

Second,  my  experience  has  led  me  to  conclude  that  the  free  enterprise  system 
is  the  best  regulator  of  all.  I  can  see  nothing  about  the  airline  industry  which 
would  suggest  to  me  that  in  1975,  Government  regulation  of  the  airline  industry 
is  providing  the  consumer  with  more  for  his  money  than  the  free  market  would 
provide.  Therefore,  I  suggest  you  listen  to  proponents  of  regulation  with  an  open 
mind,  as  I  have  done.  But  I  submit,  given  the  conditions  that  exist  today  in  the 
industry  and  in  regulated  industries  in  general,  that  the  competitive  market 
should  be  made  the  point  of  departure  for  the  debate  and  that  the  burden  of 
proof  should  rest  with  those  who  argue  against  competition  rather  than  with 
those  who  would  return  to  it.  The  burden  should  also  be  on  those  who,  in  the 
name  of  reform,  stop  short  of  this  goal. 


51-14G   O  -  76  -  pt.  : 


34 

There  will  be  doomsayers  who  will  forecast  the  direct  consequences  of  de- 
regulating rates  and  entry.  Typically  they  will  be  based  on  the  reductio  ad 
absurdum  case  in  which  at  12  :47  on  a  Wednesday  afternoon  we  shift  from  total 
regulation  to  open  competition.  It  needn't  occur  that  way.  If  the  Congress  were 
to  determine  that  a  move  in  the  direction  of  the  free  market  were  warranted, 
it  could  easily  enough  be  accomplished  in  stages.  There  is  ample  precedent. 
Several  years  ago  the  SEC  was  looking  at  an  analogous  situation  in  the  securi- 
ties industry.  Brokers  then  operating  on  a  fixed  rate  basis  argued  bitterly  that 
negotiated  rates  would  be  a  disaster.  The  SEC  rejected  that  argument  and  de- 
cided to  move  ahead,  not  all  at  once,  but  on  a  staged  basis.  Beginning  with  pur- 
chases of  over  $500,000,  rates  were  left  to  the  forces  of  the  market.  Though  this 
occurred  against  the  background  of  a  bear  market  and  falling  volume,  there  were 
no  disasters.  So  the  cutoff  level  for  negotiated  rates  was  lowered,  not  just  once 
but  again  and  again  at  i>eriodic  intervals  until  the  fixed  rate  system  was  abolished 
altogether. 

It  may  not  be  a  perfect  analogy,  but  it  seems  to  me  that  a  similar  approach 
could  be  taken  toward  the  airlines.  I  suggest  a  scheduled  return  to  the  free 
market  over  2  years  or  4  years  or  whatever  period  Congress  deems  appropriate. 
This  would  put  the  fundamental  arguments  in  support  of  regulation  on  trial. 
And  it  could  be  done  in  a  manner  that  would  allow  the  decision  as  to  how  far  to 
go  to  be  based  on  fact  and  proven  results  rather  than  on  theory. 

My  own  guess  is  that  we  would  make  it  all  the  way  back  to  "regulation"  by 
the  free  market  and  that  we  would  all  be  better  off  for  it. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Our  next  witness  is  the  Assistant  Attorney  Gen- 
eral for  the  Antitrust  Division,  the  Department  of  Justice,  Mr.  Kauper. 
He  formerly  served  in  the  Office  of  Legal  Counsel.  He  was  a  law  pro- 
fessor at  the  University  of  Michigan.  We  welcome  him  here  this 
morning. 

A  great  deal  of  attention  has  been  f  ocussed  on  the  Antitrust  Division. 
I  am  sure  you  know  how  important  your  own  work  is.  I  want  you  to 
know  that  we  in  the  Congress  think  so,  too. 

You  have  very  extensive  testimony  here.  I  am  just  wondering  how 
you  want  to  proceed.  I  want  to  give  you  a  fair  chance  to  present  it. 

STATEMENT  OF  THOMAS  E.  KAUPER,  ASSISTANT  ATTORNEY 
GENERAL,  ANTITRUST  DIVISION,  DEPARTMENT  OF  JUSTICE,  AC- 
COMPANIED BY  DONALD  BAKER  AND  KEITH  CLEARWATERS, 
DEPUTY  ASSISTANT  ATTORNEYS  GENERAL 

Mr.  Kauper.  Mr.  Chairman,  at  your  staff's  request  I  have  been 
sitting  out  there  marking  out  portions  of  it. 

So,  I  think,  what  I  will  try  to  do  is  to  go  through  it,  but  omitting 
very  substantial  parts. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  obviously  include  it  in  the  record. 

Mr.  Kauper.  I  am  accompanied  by  Deputy  Assistant  Attorney  Gen- 
eral Donald  Baker  on  my  right,  and  on  my  left  Deputy  Assistant  Attor- 
ney General  Keith  Clear  waters,  wlio  will  be  taking  part  in  these 
hearings. 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  am  happy  to  be  here  today  to  present  the  views  of 
the  Department  of  Justice  and  to  report  on  the  work  that  the  adminis- 
tration is  doing  on  economic  regulation  of  domestic  air  transportation. 

Airline  costs  affect  us  all  as  citizens,  taxpayers,  and  consumers.  They 
affect  us  when  we  buy  products,  when  we  carry  out  our  jobs,  and  when 
we  travel  for  pleasure.  Airline  costs  are  in  turn  directly  affected  by 
airline  regulation — for  it  is  regulation  which  tells  carriers  on  which 
routes  they  can  compete  and  what  means  of  competition  they  can  use. 
Basically,"  it  keeps  entry  tight,  while  allowing  carriers  to  compete  in 
terms  of  service  but  not  price.  The  result  is,  as  you  would  expect,  a  sys- 


36 

Icm  which  sets  both  price  and  service  at  levels  above  what  they  would 
be  in  a  competitive  market — in  other  Avords,  there  are  more  planes,  with 
more  empty  seats,  and  the  customer  pays  more  tlian  he  would  under  a 
regime  oi  open  competition. 

For  years  nobody  much  worried  about  CAB  price  and  enti-y  policies, 
because  we  were  in  a  continuing  trend  of  improving  equipment,  de- 
clining cost,  declining  prices,  and  rapidly  growing  traffic.  The  airline 
traveler's  Avorld  was  getting  better,  even  tliough  CAB  rate  and  entry 
regulation  was  probably  slowing  down  at  least  the  rate  at  which  fares 
declined,  and  encouraging  excess  capacity. 

Now,  ho\\'ever,  the  situation  has  changed.  Due  to  sharply  higher  fuel 
and  labor  costs,  airlines  have  been  requesting,  and  the  Board  has  ap- 
proved, a  A\hole  sei-ies  of  fare  increases,  which  have  come  at  a  time 
when  the  public  at  large  was,  if  anything,  less  able  to  pay  these  fai^es. 
At  the  same  time,  the  Board  has  actively  sought  to  cut  back  on  low- 
price  air  travel,  through  limitations  on  promotional  fares  and  restric- 
tions on  charter  activity.  The  result  of  all  this  has  been  to  raise  fares 
considerably  for  everyone  and  to  raise  them  enormously  for  certain 
classes  of  users.  The  overall  effect  has  been  to  produce  an  almost  un- 
precedented substantial  reduction  in  air  travel — more  empty  seats  on 
scheduled  flights  and  fewer  charter  flights.  The  i-eduction  in  demand 
has  tended  to  push  up  the  airlines'  miit  costs,  since  they  have  had  to 
spread  out  their  fixed  costs  over  fewer  passengers.  This  in  turn  hag 
provided  the  impetus  for  renewed  fare  increases,  a  situation  likely 
to  further  reduce  air  travel  and  hence  again  increase  unit  costs.  The 
resulting  spiral  of  increasing  fares  and  costs  means  that  the  smaller 
proportion  of  the  public  which  can  afford  to  fly  gets  reduced  service 
at  increased  prices. 

REGULATION    OF    FARES    AND    ROUTE    ENTRY 

We  in  the  administration  have  been  studying  for  some  time  how  to 
break  out  of  this  upward  spiral  of  prices  and  costs.  We  have  concluded 
that  the  most  hopeful  avenue  is  a  substantial  relaxation  of  existing 
price  and  entry  regulation,  which  forces  cairiers  to  offer  excessive 
amounts  of  unused  seats  at  excessively  high  fares.  That  system  of 
regulation  has  in  addition  prevented  innovative  newcomers  from 
coming  into  the  business  of  interstate  air  transportation,  in  the  interest 
of  protecting  the  established  carriers  against  new  competition.  We  be- 
lieve that  more  open  competitive  pricing,  if  given  a  chance,  would 
broaden  the  carriers'  entrepreneurial  opportunities  by  giving  them  a 
chance  to  compete  with  lower  fare?  as  well  as  Avith  extra  seats.  We  be- 
lieve that  it  would  tend  to  bring  interstate  air  transportation  more  into 
line  with  what  we  saw  in  California  and  Texas.  An  environment  of 
lower  fares  and  fuller  planes.  If  this  occurs— and  both  actual  experi- 
ence and  economic  theory  suggest  that  it  Avill — we  have  found  a  basis 
for  breaking  the  cycle  of  rising  costs  and  declining  service.  Lower 
prices  are  likely  to  come  quite  quickly  and  lower  prices  are  likely  to 
encourage  new  traffic  quite  quickly.  By  the  same  token,  liberalized 
entry  rules^an  environment  with  less  emphasis  on  route  protection — 
are  likely  to  get  onto  the  routes  those  carriers  who  are  most  efficient  at 
serving  them.  In  a  competitive  environment,  such  efficiencies  can  in 
turn  be  passed  on  to  the  traveler  in  the  form  of  lower  fares. 


36 

The  Department's  perspective  on  airline  regulatory  problems  is 
based  of  course  on  our  experience  in  enforcing  the  antitrust  laws  in  a 
great  variety  of  industries  having  a  diversity  of  cost  and  capital  char- 
acteristics, it  is  based  on  our  extensive  participation  before  the  CAB 
in  a  variety  of  proceedings.  And  it  is  based  on  our  experience  in  anti- 
trust enforcement  in  other  regulated  industries,  some  of  which  have 
economic  characteristics  similar  to  those  of  air  transportation.  Our 
experience  tells  us  that  regulated  firms  rarely  welcome  freer  entry  rules 
and  more  flexible  pricing.  They  generally  want  to  be  protected  from 
outsiders  and  protected  from  each  other  by  a  benevolent  regulator.  In 
the  airline  field,  regulated  firms  generally  have  opposed  pricing  flexi- 
bility and  offered  capacity  cartel  agreements  instead.  Yet  our  experi- 
ence also  tells  us  that  in  fact  competition  works  in  regulated  environ- 
ments much  more  efficiently  than  the  regulated  firms  generally  be- 
lieve; and  we  find  increasing  use  of  competition  in  place  of  direct 
regulation  as  a  tool  to  promote  efficiency  in  a  number  of  regulated  en- 
vironments—ranging from  wholesale  electric  power  to  securities 
markets. 

The  Department  is  currently  Avorking  with  the  Department  of 
Transportation,  the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  the  Council  on 
Wage  and  Price  Stability  and  the  Office  of  ^lanagement  and  Budget  to 
develop  detailed  administration  proposals  which  respond  to  this  reality 
in  the  transportation  sector.  We  hope  to  have  detailed  proposals  for 
air  transport  regulation  reform  for  presentation  to  the  Congress  in 
the  near  future.  At  this  point,  these  agencies  have  arrived  at  a  broad 
consensus  in  principle,  which  we  will  discuss  today. 

We  all  agree  that  regulation  of  rates  and  routes  has  been  excessive 
and  has  inflated  present  cost  and  fare  levels. 

We  believe  the  Government  should  regulate  the  airlines  where  neces- 
sary to  insure  the  safety  and  reliability  of  air  transportation — but  this 
clearly  does  not  require  direct  Government  regulation  of  airline  pricing 
and  entry  to  the  current  extent.  We  believe  the  focus  of  Government 
regulation  of  the  airlines  should  be  on  these  essentially  noneconomic 
goals,  with  clear  standards  and  ]5rocedures  which  insure  that  regula- 
tory powers  are  not  used  to  unnecessarily  limit  competition.  Even  if 
full  rate  regulation  is  deemed  necessary  to  deal  with  certain  problems — 
for  instance,  the  prevention  of  monopoly  pricing  in  certain  rnarkets — 
such  regulation  should  be  carefully  crafted  to  limit  and  clarify  goals, 
standards  and  procedures. 

Eeform  only  of  procedural — rather  than  substantive — provisions  of 
the  act  cannot  correct  the  fundamental  problem  of  its  ambiguous  and 
sometimes  conflicting  stated  objectives.  Procedural  reform  of  the  act 
might  well  be  desirable,  but  it  is  not  likely  to  be  successful  without 
a  narrowing  and  clarification  of  the  standards  the  Board  may  apply 
in  making  economic  decisions,  and  of  the  scope  of  airline  activities 
subject  to  those  decisions.  Such  a  redefinition  of  the  act's  economic 
goals  and  standards  would  be  a  substantial  improvement.  And  in  our 
view,  such  a  redefinition  Avould  call  into  question  the  continued  useful- 
ness of  much  of  present  economic  regulation. 

CAB    AUTHORITY    TO    GRANT    ANTITRUST    IMMUNITY 

The  administration  group  also  agrees  that  the  CAB  should  not  be 
given  broad  authority  to  immunize  from  the  antitrust  laws  all  the 


37 

private  ao:reements  and  mergers  it  approves.  Accordingly,  our  pro- 
posals will  provide  for  a  much  narrower  area  of  antitrust  exemption, 
and  for  a  merger  approval  approach  generally  modeled  on  the  Bank 
Merger  Act  of  1966. 

To  explain  the  basis  for  these  rather  broad  conclusions,  I  will  sketch 
briefly  the  circumstances  which  led  to  the  imposition  of  Federal  eco- 
nomic regulation  of  the  airlines,  describe  what  I  believe  to  be  the 
lessons  of  major  CAB  economic  regulatory  proceedings,  and  attempt 
to  outline  some  preliminary  conclusions. 

HISTORY    or     CAB    REGULATIOX 

Federal  regulation  of  air  transportation  has  developed  primarily 
along  two  paths :  one  set  of  statutes  which  regulate  safety,  airport  and 
airway  affairs,  and  another  specifically  directed  toward  the  regulation 
of  the  economics  of  air  transportation.  The  first  category  of  statutes 
has  been  the  responsibility  of  the  Department  of  Transportation  and 
the  National  Transporation  Safety  Board  for  several  years.  The  eco- 
nomic regulatory  system  which  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  adminis- 
ters is  now  embodied  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as  amended. 

The  origins  of  airline  economic  regulation  are  usually  traced  to  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938,  which  generally  followed  the  outline 
of  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act  in  setting  up  most  of  the  major  regula- 
tory features  of  today's  Federal  Aviation  Act.  Tliere  had  been  partial 
economic  regulation  of  air  carriers  prior  to  1938,  however.  After 
experimenting  with  several  different  means  of  administering  a  system 
of  subsidized  air  transport  of  mail,  the  Congress  determined  in  1930 
to  grant  the  Postmaster  General  broad  powers  over  the  routes,  rates, 
and  practices  of  carriers  carrying  airmail  under  contract  with  the 
Government.  In  1935,  the  Congress  broadened  this  regulation  to. pro- 
hibit carriers  with  airmail  contracts  from  engaging  in  any  service  on 
routes  other  than  their  airmail  routes  if  such  service  would  compete 
with  another  carrier  having  an  airmail  contract  on  that  route.  The 
predominance  of  mail  over  passenger  service  was  rapidly  diminishing 
throughout  this  period,  however,  and  by  1937  air  carrier  income  from 
passenger  service  was  twice  as  great  as  mail  income.  Unregulated  car- 
riers without  airmail  contracts  began  to  compete  with  airmail  carriers, 
who  naturally  complained  about  their  unregulated  competitors'  greater 
economic  freedom.  The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  which  ob- 
tained economic  regulatory  powers  over  motor  carriers  in  1935,  pressed 
for  the  extension  of  economic  regulation  over  all  air  carriers,  under  the 
general  theory  that  it  is  unfair  and  "chaotic"  foi'  unregulated  firms  to 
be  allowed  to  compete  with  regulated  firms. 

The  protection  of  a  subsidized  airmail  system  was  a  vital  objective 
of  the  drafters  of  the  1938  act.  Even  today,  a  very  high  percentage 
of  the  provisions  of  that  act,  as  amended,  still  are  concerned  with  the 
carriage  of  mail.  Today,  although  the  mail  system  is  of  crucial  im- 
portance, it  is  a  small  percentage  of  the  air  transportation  business. 
There  certainly  would  be  no  logical  basis  today  for  designing  the  entire 
air  transportation  system  around  the  mail  system,  because  the  needs 
of  the  Postal  Service  can  be  met  with  relatively  small  and  specific 
modifications  to  the  larger  air  system. 

Just  as  the  "chaotic"  conditions  generated  by  the  efforts  to  develop 
an  airmail  system  have  disappeared  today,  we  no  longer  experience 


38 

two  other  very  important  factors  which  led  to  the  creation  of  airline 
economic  regulation  in  1938.  The  Great  Depression  had  shaken  our 
society's  confidence  in  the  free  market  system,  and  led  to  a  number 
of  laws  which  substituted  direct  Government  economic  regulation  of 
business  organizations  for  the  maintenance  of  free  competition.  Also, 
air  transportation  in  the  1930's  was  thought  to  suffer  from  undue 
division  of  governmental  regulatory  authority  among  the  Commerce 
Department,  the  Post  Office  Department,  and  the  Interstate  Commerce 
Commission,  and  it  was  considered  a  very  important  function  of  the 
1938  act  to  combine  and  coordinate  all  of  these  functions  within  one 
agency. 

The  drafters  of  the  act,  however,  vehemently  denied  any  intention 
to  allow  the  Board  to  restrain  competition  or  create  monopolies.  The 
act  itself  directed  the  Board  to  maintain  "competition  to  the  extent 
necessary"  to  pursue  other  rather  inclusive  goals,  and  explicitly 
directed  the  Board  to  observe  conventional  antitrust  principles  in 
deciding  merger  and  interlocking  control  cases. 

The  act's  reliance  upon  competition  among  air  carriers  shows  that 
the  Congress  clearly  did  not  regard  air  transportation  operations  as 
having  "natural  monopoly"  characteristics  which  required  Govern- 
ment control  in  the  place  of  the  discipline  of  competition.  Instead 
of  detailed  control  of  the  rate  base,  regulation  was  extended  to  fares, 
entry  and  exit  from  specific  routes,  and  agreements  and  mergers. 

MERGERS REASONS    FOR 

The  first  category  of  major  CAB  economic  cases  are  those  in  which 
the  basic  structure  of  the  airline  industry  itself  was  at  issue.  In  the 
last  15  years,  the  Department  of  Justice  has  opposed  three  major 
trunk  air  carrier  merger  proposals,  which  had  they  been  approved, 
would  have  substantially  redrawn  the  route  map  of  the  U.S.  domestic 
system,  and  considerably  increased  the  already  very  great  concen- 
tration of  the  airline  industi^  in  the  hands  of  a  very  few  large  trunk 
air  carriers. 

Since  1962,  we  have  opposed  before  the  Board  the  proposed  mergers 
of  American  with  Eastern,  Western  with  American,  and  National 
with  Northwest. 

In  the  last  few  years,  the  Department  also  has  studied  several  other 
major  airline  merger  proposals  which  were  never  filed  and  litigated 
at  the  CAB.  .  . 

As  a  result  of  studying,  testing,  and  arguing  the  evidence  m  these 
cases,  we  have  come  to  the  conclusion  that  in  the  absence  of  economic 
regulation,  the  air  transportation  industry  probably  would  have  a 
reasonably  flexible,  competitive  structure  which  would  serve  the 
public  better  than  the  present  Government-controlled  structure.  Ex- 
perience under  economic  regulation,  and  in  unregulated  air  trans- 
portation where  available,  indicates  that  the  industry  tends  to  have 
a  "competitive"  structure,  rather  than  being  a  "natural  monopoly" 
which  must  be  regulated  in  the  interests  of  the  public. 

Evidence  is  quite  abundant  that  there  are  no  important  economies 
of  scale  in  air  transportation ;  that  is,  larger  firms  are  not  more  efficient 
or  less  costly  simply  because  of  their  size.  In  fact,  other  things  being 
equal,  the  largest  air  carriers  tend  to  have  a  higher  level  of  unit  costs, 


39 

and  there  are  some  indications  that  these  increased  costs  are  caused 
by  the  difficulties  of  managing  an  airline  of  very  large  size. 

The  airlines'  "right-of-way''  is  the  air  itself /and  their  "tracks,"  if 
any,  are  the  air  traffic  control  guideways  maintained  by  the  Federal 
Government.  Well  over  80  percent  of  the  airlines'  investment  is  in 
flight  equipment,  which  is  among  the  most  mobile  of  assets,  rather 
than  in  fixed  assets,  as  is  the  case  in  the  classical  "natural  monopoly." 
Not  only  does  this  make  competitive  service  economically  feasible,  but 
it  makes  duplication  of  routes  far  less  risky,  because  competitors  can 
more  easily  adjust  their  operations  by  rescheduling  an  aircraft  from 
one  city-pair  to  another — assuming  that  the  Government  does  not 
prevent  them  from  doing  so. 

In  view  of  this  conclusion,  why  have  so  many  mergers  been  pro- 
posed? Perhaps  the  most  important  reasons  for  mergers  among  the 
regulated  air  carriers  have  been  the  effects  of  regulation  itself.  Air 
carriers  know  that  when  they  hold  a  certificate,  it  is  the  nature  of 
economic  regulation  that  the  Board  will  to  a  greater  or  lesser  degree 
protect  them  from  entry  by  new  competitors  on  that  route.  Similarly, 
the  air  carriers  know  that  they  cannot  expand  onto  a  new  route  with- 
out obtaining  a  certificate.  Consequently,  any  certificated  air  carrier, 
no  matter  how  poorly  run  and  how  debilitated  financially  and  opera- 
tionally, has  one  very  valuable  asset — its  route  certificate.  This  asset 
typically  has  been  sold  by  merger  of  weak  carriers  into  stronger 
carriers.  As  a  result,  no  large  federally  certificated  air  carrier  has  gone 
out  of  business  other  than  through  merger  with  another  federally 
certificated  air  carrier.  Because  the  Board  has  allowed  virtually  no 
new  firms  to  join  the  ranks  of  the  certificated  air  carriers,  there  has 
been  a  steady  diminution  in  the  number  of  air  carriers  with  certificates 
from  the  Federal  Government. 

It  has  been  observed  that  during  the  period  when  California  intra- 
state airlines  were  essentially  free  from  economic  regulation,  many 
firms  entered  and  left  the  market,  but  none  of  them  left  tlie  market 
through  merger  One  very  careful  economic  study  of  this  phenomenon, 
and  the  contrast  between  unregulated  California  airlines  and  the  i-egu- 
lated  interstate  airlines  m^akes  a  convincing  and  apparently  unrebutted 
case  that  in  the  absence  of  economic  regulation  there  probably  would 
have  been  many  more  competing  airlines  in  the  United  States  than  the 
CAB  has  allowed  to  exist. 

As  long  as  new  certificates  are  not  freely  given,  one  would  expect 
that  there  would  be  some  transfer  of  certificates  as  carriers  seek  to 
reorganize  their  route  authorities.  However,  sale  or  trade  of  certificate 
authority  has  been  fairly  rare,  althouirh  not  unprecedented,  because 
until  lately  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  did  not  encourage  such 
"trafficking  in  certificates."  Eecently,  the  Board's  willingness  to  con- 
sider transfer  of  certificate  authority  has  led  to  a  number  of  "route 
swap"'  proposals.  Generally  speaking,  route  transfers — including  the 
reciprocal  route  transfers  currently  called  route  exchanges — are  merely 
partial  mergers.  Consequently,  as  with  mergere,  there  would  be  far 
fewer  route  transfers,  if  any,  in  the  absence  of  entry  restrictions. 

Other  asserted  reasons  to  renulate  entry  and  exit  from  air  trans- 
])ortation  markets  are  that  without  such  reqfulation,  there  ^^'ou^d  be 
"destructive,"  or  predatory  conduct  by  airline  firms,  and  "chaotic" 
conditions  Avould  constitut^^  a  sei-ious  public  detriment.  Let  us  examine 
these  fears  in  turn. 


40 

UNFAIR   COMPETITIOX 

In  order  for  predatory  conduct  to  pay  off.  it  is  necessary  for  a  firm 
to  go  through  two  processes :  First,  it  inust  drive  competitors  from  the 
market  by  using  predatory  practices,  such  as  below-cost  price  cuts. 
This  kind  of  conduct  is  costly  to  the  would-be  predator.  Second,  the 
predator  must  recoup  those  costs  by  using  the  resulting  freedom  from 
competition  to  behave  like  a  monopolist.  This  second  step  will  not  be 
possible  if  the  firms  which  were  driven  out  can  reenter  the  market 
quickly  and  easily.  As  I  have  explained,  entrv  into  air  transportation 
markets  generall}^  would  not  be  difficult  to  accomplish  quickly  if  there 
were  no  Government  restriction.  Accordingly,  the  economists  who  have 
Avritten  on  this  matter  have  concluded  that  the  prospects  for  profitable 
predatory  conduct  are  poor  in  this  industry.  Given  these  economic 
facts,  Government  regulation  of  entry  actually  can  cause  the  predator^' 
conduct  it  is  supposed  to  prevent.  A  Goveniment  pi'ohibition  on  entry 
can  be  the  most  effective  insurance  possible  for  a  predator  w^hicli  is 
trying  to  recoup  the  costs  of  predatory  conduct. 

SERVICE    COMPETITION 

Of  course,  if  predatory  conduct  should  take  place  in  the  airline  in- 
dustry, it  is  subject  to  the  antitrust  laws  just  as  it  is  in  another  in- 
dustry, if  it  is  not  somehow  immunized  by  Government  action.  In 
terms  of  pricing  policy,  the  key  point  here  is  that  the  economic 
characteristics  of  the  airline  industry  are  such  that  even  when  the 
Government  eliminates  price  competition,  carriers  still  have  the  in- 
centive to  compete,  and  will  compete  any  way  they  can,  if  only  through 
"frills''  which  are  loss  important  to  passengers  than  price.  Once  a  flight 
is  scheduled,  the  cost  of  carrying  additional  passengers  in  the  airplane 
is  very  low  compared  to  the  cost  of  flying  the  airplane  in  the  first 
place.  Thus,  the  marginal  passenger  on  a  flight  is  very  profitable — 
any  competitive  initiative  which  diverts  passengers  onto  an  airline's 
flight  may  pay  off  richly. 

In  scheduled  service,  it  appears  that  next  to  price,  the  variable  most 
important  to  the  passenger  on  a  scheduled  airline  flight  is  the  ability 
to  find  a  seat  on  a  flight  at  or  near  his  preferred  departure  time.  Conse- 
quently, when  the  price  is  fixed,  competitive  rivalry  is  diverted  into 
capacity  competition — competing  carriers  offer  large  numbers  of 
flights  in  an  attempt  to  cover  as  many  preferred  departure  times  and 
attract  as  many  customers  as  possible.  The  evidence  in  the  recent 
capacity  reduction  agreements  case  is  quite  convincing  that,  even  under 
the  present  system  of  uniform  fares,  carriers  do  not  have  the  incen- 
tive to  offer  ruinous  amounts  of  capacity  simply  because  of  this 
phenomenon.  But  it  is  clear  that  fare  regulation  has  caused  the  airlines 
to  offer  the  consumer  large  numbers  of  flights  and  empty  seats  instead 
of  cheaper  transportation.  Stated  another  way,  they  have  tended  to 
"compete  away"  the  "monopoly  profits"  generated  by  excessively  high 
regulated  fares. 

EVALUATION   OF  THE   DOMESTIC   PASSENGER  FARE   INVESTIGATION 

Allowing  price  competition  by  the  airlines  would  give  them  an  in- 
centive to  offer  consumers  a  choice  as  to  the  combination  of  fare  and 


41 

load  factor  they  want,  and  all  the  evidence  is  that  the  result  would  be 
that  lower  fares  would  be  available  to  the  users  of  scheduled  interstate 
flio:hts.  The  experience  of  the  intrastate  carriers  in  California  and 
Texas  confirms  this.  Of  cour.se,  higher  load  factors  also  would  be  in- 
volved— but  all  this  tells  us  is  that  the  public  would  rather  pay  con- 
siderably less  for  travel,  even  at  the  price  of  being  somewhat  less 
certain  of  getting  on  their  first  choice  of  flight.  Accordingly,  we  were 
disappointed  when  the  Board  rejected  the  arguments  of  the  Depart- 
ments of  Transportation  and  Justice  in  favor  of  allowing  air  carrier^ 
to  price  freely  within  a  "zone  of  reasonableness"  instead  of  requiring 
a  rigid  adherence  to  one  identical  fare  for  all  carriers  offering  servi  'p. 
in  a  particular  market. 

We  were  gratified  that  the  Board  decided  in  Phase  6  of  the  Domestic 
Passenger  Fare  Investigation  to  base  its  fare  decisions  upon  load  factor 
and  seating  configuration  standards  which  excluded  from  the  rate  base 
any  service  amenity  not  included  in  the  Board's  standards  for  such 
service.  Under  the  iPhase  6  policy,  the  fare  is  based  on  the  amount  of 
capacity  associated  with  a  standard  load  factor,  in  a  standard  aircraft 
configuration  set  by  the  Board,  rather  than  the  actual  load  factor  and 
configuration  of  a  particular  carrier  or  the  industry.  We  believe  this 
approach  can  allow  carriers  greater  freedom  to  experiment  with 
different  levels  of  capacity  and  types  of  service  without  being  deprived 
of  the  motive  to  keep  their  services  as  economical  as  possible.  In  Phase 
6  and  the  related  coach  lounge  proceeding,  we  argued  that  the  Board 
violated  the  spirit  of  its  Phase  6  policy  by  attempting  to  punish  a 
carrier  offering  a  different  type  of  service  by  requiring  that  carrier  to 
charge  a  different  fare,  rather  than  simply  requiring  that  carrier  to 
charge  a  fare  based  upon  the  more  economical  aircraft  configuration 
which  the  Board  adopted  as  its  standard.  This  was  the  first  proceeding 
in  recent  years  in  which  we  carried  our  disagreement  with  the  Board 
to  the  court  of  appeals,  and  this  ma.^ter  is  now  pending  rehearing  en 
banc  on  the  Board's  motion  after  a  decision  favorable  to  our  position. 

We  also  have  pending  in  the  court  of  appeals  a  review  of  the  Boards' 
decision  to  extend  rate  regulation  to  the  charter  field  for  the  first  time, 
despite  numerous  arguments  in  opposition. 

The  Board  generally  has  applied  a  specific  "rule  of  reason"  standard 
when  it  decides  whether  or  not  to  approve  an  agreement  which  restrains 
conipetition.  That  is,  if  an  agreement  would  have  substantial  anticom- 
petitive effects  under  established  antitrust  principles,  it  will  not  be 
approved  unless  approval  is  the  only  way  to  meet  a  serious  transporta- 
tion need  or  secure  important  public  benefits.  Until  very  recently,  the 
Department  of  Justice  has  not  participated  in  very  many  proceedings 
concerning  air  carrier  conduct  subject  to  regulation  by  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board.  In  recent  years,  we  have  opposed  capacity  restraint 
agreements  which  have  been  in  effect  in  several  markets  on  the  basis 
of  various  purported  justifications.  The  capacity  agreement  question, 
too,  is  pending  in  the  court  of  appeals. 

CAB   POWER   TO   GRANT   ANTITRUST   IMMUNITY 

Let  me  if  I  might  go  into  detail  briefly  on  the  issue  of  antitrust 
immunity,  which  is  one  of  the  questions  that  will  be  rising  later  here. 

Under  the  present  aviation  act,  the  Board  has  power  to  approve  or 
disapprove  mergers  (section  408),  control  relationships  (section  409), 


42 

and  agreements  among  air  carriers  (section  412).  Section  414  of  the 
Federal  Aviation  Act  provides  that  the  antitrust  laws  shall  not  apply 
to  persons  affected  by  CAB  orders  issued  under  these  three  sections  of 
the  act,  to  the  extent  "necessary  to  enable  such  person  to  do  anything 
authorized,  approved,  or  required  by  such  order."  (40  U.S.C.  1384.) 
The  public  interest  would  be  better  served  if  each  of  the  thr-ee  types  of 
transactions  as  to  which  the  Board  can  confer  immunity  were  evaluated 
under  the  standards  of  the  antitrust  laws,  rather  than  the  general 
"public  interest"  rubric  of  an  administrative  agency. 

It  would  be  desirable  to  remove  the  antitrust  immunity  provisions  of 
section  414  even  if  these  three  types  of  transactions  remain  subject  to 
administrative  review.  This  would  insure  that  the  administrative 
agency  would  not  follow  a  less  procompetitive  standard  than  that  of 
the  antitrust  laws ;  the  safest  way  to  do  this  is  to  eliminate  any  infer- 
ence that  the  Board's  approval  brings  immunity  from  an  antitrust 
lawsuit. 

The  existence  of  the  section  414  immunity  provision  creates  the 
possibility  of  a  lowering  of  competitive  standards  not  only  in  the  reg- 
ulated air  transportation  industry,  but  also  in  industries  not  regulated 
by  the  CAB.  In  a  recent  decision,  the  Supreme  Court  held  that  a 
private  antitrust  action  against  Hughes  Tool  Co.,  a  person  engaged  in 
aeronautics,  was  barred  by  the  Board's  approval  of  and  continuing 
jurisdiction  over  the  control  relationship  which  was  the  basis  of  the 
antitrust  complaint.  The  antitrust  complaint  had  centered  upon  the 
approved  transactions'  competitive  effects  in  the  commercial  aircraft 
manufacturing  industry,  not  in  the  air  transportation  industry  which 
is  regulated  by  the  Board. 

If  any  special  characteristics  of  air  transportation  require  departure 
from  the  undiluted  application  of  the  antitrust  laws,  such  departure 
should  be  effected  by  a  procedure  similar  to  that  of  the  Bank  Merger 
Act  of  1966.  Under  that  statute  a  specialized  regulatory  agency  first 
passes  upon  whether  a  merger  would  violate  the  antitrust  laws,  and 
whether  it  should  nevertheless  be  allowed  liecause  of  specific  over- 
riding public  benefits  which  could  not  be  obtained  by  any  other  means. 
The  transaction  is  then  subject  to  de  novo  review  by  the  United  States 
in  a  district  court. 

Let  me  if  I  might  now,  Mr.  Chairman,  just  very  briefly  address 
several  conclusions. 

There  are  a  variety  of  problems  that  we  have  addressed  in  the  state- 
ment. The  Department  of  Justice  and  other  litigants  sometimes  can 
help  maintain  a  degree  of  reliance  on  competition,  but  under  no  cir- 
cumstances do  we  believe  such  liticration  brines  optimum  results.  Par- 
ties seeking  to  influence  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  toward  more 
competitive  policies  are  hampered  by  the  vagueness  and  inclusiveness 
of  the  statutory  standards  among  which  the  Board  may  choose  to 
justify  its  decisions,  and  are  hampered  by  judicial  restraint  in  review- 
ing crucial  aspects  of  agencv  decisionmnkin.o-.  This  is  exacerbated  bv 
the  very  serious  costs  and  delays  of  litigating  economic  issues,  both 
before  the  Board  and  in  the  courts. 

These  problems  will  be  dealt  with  in  greater  detail  in  later  sessions 
of  these  hearings.  It  will  suffice  to  say  now  that  we  do  not  believe  the 
serious  problems  of  air  transport  economic  regulation  will  be  satis- 
factorily corrected  by  litisation  under  present  statutory  standards, 
although  such  litigation  can  help  somewhat. 


43 

Neither  do  we  believe  that  the  optimum  answer  lies  in  the  reform  of 
procedures  under  which  air  carrier  economic  regulation  is  carried  out. 
Unnecessary  regulation  is  still  expensive,  even  if  carried  out  under 
clear  standards  and  optimum  procedures.  It  would  be  possible  to  have 
a  much  narrower  statute  seeking  specific  goals  with  definite  safeguards 
for  competition  and  economic  efficiency.  In  air  transportation,  the 
fundamental  goal  would  be  the  provision  of  efficient  air  transportation 
to  the  public  by  qualified  common  carriers  using  safe  planes  and 
qualified  crews.  A  tightly  drawn  statute  would  prevent  the  Board  from 
limiting  competition  unless  is  made  findings  on  the  record  that  com- 
petition would  compromise  safety  or  reliability  of  service.  Even  under 
such  a  statute,  the  problem  of  preventing  regulation  from  pursuing 
other,  anticompetitive  goals  might  prove  difficult. 

Specifically,  we  believe  that  new  legislation  should  move  toward  the 
following  goals.  First,  entry  and  exit  restrictions  should  be  greatly 
liberalized.  Second,  rate  flexibility  should  be  introduced  through  a 
phased  process,  perhaps  initially  using  a  zone  of  reasonableness.  Eegu- 
latory  intrusion  with  regard  to  rates  within  that  zone  would  not  be 
permitted.  Finally,  existing  antitrust  immunity  should  be  removed, 
along  the  lines  suggested  earlier  in  this  statement. 

There  is  a  broad  consensus  that  reform  must  proceed  along  all  three 
of  these  fronts.  The  administration  has  thus  concluded  that  it  would 
be  appropriate  to  move  toward  much  more  reliance  upon  competition 
in  the  air  transportation  industry,  and  much  less  reliance  upon  Gov- 
ernment economic  regulation.  We  expect  to  present  specific  legislative 
proposals  within  a  short  time  to  the  Congress,  and  specifically  to  this 
committee. 

Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much.  We  will  include  all  of 
your  statement  in  the  record. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  I  understand  your  position  correctly  that  you 
would  eliminate  all  antitrust  exemptions? 

Mr.  Kauper.  Well,  I  think  there  are  several  parts  of  that  which  are 
still  under  some  review  as  to  precisely  how  it  should  be  done.  Our 
thinking  at  the  moment  is  that  there  may  be  some  forms  of  agree- 
ments where  a  procedure  not  unlike  the  Bank  INferger  Act.  pursuant 
to  which  the  matter  is  passed  upon  by  the  administrative  agency,  but 
then  subject  to  challenire  by  us  in  the  U.S.  district  court,  may  be  the 
best  way  of  identifying  those  particular  agreements  where  there 
seems  to  some  peculiar  transportaion  need,  where  perhaps  under  con- 
ventional antitrust  analysis,  there  might  otherwise  be  a  problem. 

I  think  it  is  true  that  a  number  of  kinds  of  agreements  which  we,  the 
administration,  feel  should  be  accepted,  probably  in  and  of  them- 
selves do  not  violate  the  antitrust  laws  in  any  event. 

However.  I  think  one  does  have  to  keep  in  mind  that  among  other 
things  we  are  a  litigious  country,  and  it  may  be  in  a  few  cases  the  pro- 
tection provided  by  that  sort  of  immunity  is  desirable  for  that  reason. 
We  are  working  those  detailed  provisions  out.  They  will  be  part  of  the 
proposals  coming  before  you. 

Senator  Kexnf.dy.  Proposals  made  by  whom  ? 

Mr.  Kauper.  By  the  administration,  as  part  of  the  whole  series  of 
administration  proposals  dealing  with  deregulation  in  this  area. 
Senator  Kennedy,  When  are  we  going  to  have  those  ? 


44 

Mr.  Kaiter.  I  think  the  specific  timeframe  is  about  6  weeks;  at 
lea^t  I  think  that  is  about  the  frame  we  are  working  on  now. 

Senator  Kennedy.  And  you  will  spell  out.  then,  as  I  understand  it, 
the  legislation  to  carry  this  forward  ? 

Mr.  Kaiper.  Yes.  it  is  our  expectation,  Mr.  Chairman,  those  will  be 
in  the  form  of  legislative  proposals. 

Senator  Kexxedt.  Are  you  satisfied  with  the  opportunity  for  the 
antitrust  division  to  participate  in  the  regulatory  agencies"  decision- 
making? 

Mr.  Kauper.  Well,  I  think  we  have  been  able  to  participate  in  the 
sense  of  being  a  formal  party.  That  is,  when  there  is  a  particular 
proceeding,  our  views  are  submitted.  We  have,  as  I  think  you  know, 
Mr.  Chairman,  put  a  good  deal  of  time  and  effort  and  resources  into 
exactly  that  sort  of  thing.  So  that  I  do  not  think — let  me  put  it  this 
way — I  do  not  think  the  agency  is  suffering  from  any  want  of  knowl- 
edge of  our  views.  In  fact,  they  probably  have  them  more  than  they 
would  care  for  them. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  suppose  the  real  question  is  the  power  to  have 
an  impact  on  the  decision. 

Mr.  Ivauper.  Well,  I  think  that  is  a  somewhat  different  question. 
Obviously  in  a  variety  of  these  areas,  once  the  agency  has  arrived  at 
its  decision,  the  ballgame  is  in  large  part  over  from  our  point  of  view. 
That  is,  at  that  point,  it  has  become  a  question  of  antitrust  immunity. 
There  are  some  instances  in  which  we  may  be  able  to  proceed  into  the 
appellate  courts.  That  is  still  a  matter  of  doing  it  by  way  of  review  of 
the  agency  decision,  with  all  the  appropriate  weight  an  appellate 
court  gives  to  an  agency  determination. 

So  I  think  the  suggestion  is  that  we  follow  a  procedure  that  would 
contemplate  that  we  ourselves  would  have  an  independent  ability  to 
go  to  court.  I  think  that  is  what  is  necessary.  There  is  implict  in  that, 
in  terms  of  our  powers,  that  they  are  not  adequate  at  the  present  time. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  you  going  to  recommend  that  Congress  give 
you  more  power  in  this? 

Mr.  Kauper.  Yes,  I  think  that  would  be  one  result  of  the  proposal. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  you  give  us  a  little  bit  better  idea  how  the 
consumers-  interests  will  be  served  with  this  opportunity  that  you 
describe  here  ? 

Mr.  Kauper.  Well,  I  think,  Mr.  Chairman,  it  is  our  feeling  the  con- 
sumer usually  benefits  in  a  whole  variety  of  ways  through  competi- 
tion, and  I  suppose  that  variety  would  be  present  here.  We  would 
anticipate  lower  fare  levels.  We  also  contemplate  that  the  consumer 
would  have  some  choice,  which  in  large  part  he  does  not  today  have. 
He  does  not  have  a  choice  as  to  whether  he  wants  a  meal  served  to 
him  on  a  given  plane  or  whether  he  does  not.  He  is  going  to  pay  for 
it  in  any  event.  He  does  not  have  any  choice  on  the  fare  structure. 

So  I  would  expect  we  would  see  improvement  not  only  when  he 
pays,  but  in  the  choices  available  to  him.  Those  are  the  normal  results 
of  competition,  and  I  see  no  reason  why  we  would  see  anything  dif- 
ferent here. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  if  this  is  carried  forward,  you  do  not  think 
it  will  make  it  more  difficult  for  the  airlines  to  make  agreements  with 
regards  to  passenger  interests,  such  as  common  baggage  handling  for 
connecting  flights  and  reservation  systems  ? 


45 

Mr.  Kauper.  It  should  not  make  those  things  more  difficult.  We 
are  as  concerned  as  anybody  that  the  joint  operations  which  are  in 
existence  and  provide  a  continuity  of  service  to  the  passenger  be 
continued.  That  is  not  the  major  concern  of  our  proposal. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  they  need  antitrust  exemptions  for  those 
agreements  ? 

Mr.  Kauper.  I  think  there  are  many  kinds  of  agreements,  and 
many  of  them  probably  do  not.  There  may  be  some  kind  of  arrange- 
ment with  respect  to  the  use  of  airports,  for  example,  that  might  lend 
themselves  to  antitrust  complaints,  that  might  technically  be  a  refusal 
to  deal  or  so  on  that  might  invite  a  challenge  by  a  third  party. 

Generally,  there  is  a  pretty  good  concensus  as  to  the  nature  of  these 
agreements,  and  it  is  simply  the  right  of  the  mechanics  of  doing  it. 
There  is  not  any  particular  disagreement  over  their  nature  or  whether 
they  should  be  permitted. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  are  you  doing  about  international  rate- 
setting  ? 

Mr.  Kauper.  I  did  not  come  up  here  today  with  all  of  the  prepara- 
tion on  international  affairs,  but  I  think  what  we  are  doing  at  the 
moment  is  participating  in  additional  administration  efforts  to  try 
to  reexamine  these  policies.  It  is  a  considerably  more  complicated 
process  and  that  is  one  of  the  reasons  we  have  not  addressed  that.  It  is 
complicated  by  the  bilateral  arrangements  between  governments  with 
respect  to  air  carriers  and  a  variety  of  things  that  make  that  a  more 
complex  matter.  I  think  all  I  can  say  on  that  today,  Mr.  Chairman, 
is  there  is  additional  work  going  on  on  the  whole  international  struc- 
ture and  the  fare-making  process.  I  would  hope  there  would  be  some 
additional  recommendations  coming  out  of  that. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  believe  that  this  system  is  really  a  sort 
of  price-fixing  cartel  ? 

Mr.  Kauper.  Well,  I  do  not  think  there  is  any  way  one  could  not  call 
it  a  price-fixing  cartel.  It  is  quite  clearly  that.  It  is  an  agreement  among 
airlines  with  respect  to  fares.  Whether  or  not  there  are  reasons  for 
that  particular  structure,  where,  after  all,  you  do  not  have  a  single 
government  in  charge  of  regulation,  but  certainly  it  functions  just  as 
any  other  cartel  would  in  setting  fares.  In  any  classic  definition  of 
cartel,  I  would  suppose  it  is  one. 

Senator  Kennedy.  OK. 

I  want  to  thank  you  very  much. 

Mr.  Kauper.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Kauper  follows :] 

Prepared    Statemen^t   of   Thomas   E.   Kauper.   Assistant   Attorney   General, 
Antitrust  Division.  Department  of  Justice 

Airline  Regulation  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  am  happy  to  be  here  today  to  present  the  views  of  the 
Department  of  Justice  and  to  report  on  the  work  that  the  Administration  is 
doing  on  economic  regulation  of  domestic  air  transportation. 

Airline  regulation  needs  review  at  this  time.  For  37  years,  we  have  operated 
under  a  statutory  arrangement  which  assumed  that  airline?;  were  like  railroads, 
requiring  extensive  rate  and  entry  regulation :  that  subsidized  mail  carriage  was  a 
dominant  concern  ;  and  that  the  airline  busniess  was  an  industry  requiring  special 
government  promotional  efforts  on  its  behalf.  We  all  know  that  much  has  hap- 
pened during  those  37  years.  We  know  that  airlines  are  not  like  railroads,  that 


46 

open  comretition  and  entry  policies  have  worked  in  California  and  Texas  to 
produce  higher  load  factors  and  lower  fares.  We  know  that  the  airlines  have 
become  the  leading  source  of  public  inter-city  transport  and  that  the  mail  busi- 
ness is  utterly  dwarfed  by  passenger  business. 

Airline  costs  affect  us  all  as  citizens,  taxpayers  and  consumers.  They  affect  us 
when  we  buy  products,  when  we  carry  out  our  jobs,  and  when  we  travel  for 
pleasure. 

Airline  costs  are  in  turn  directly  affected  by  airline  regulation — for  it  is 
regulation  which  tells  carriers  on  which  routes  they  can  conii)ete  and  what  means 
of  competition  they  can  use.  Basically,  it  keeps  entiy  tight,  while  allowing  car- 
riers to  compete  in  terms  of  service  but  not  price.  The  result  is,  as  you  would 
expect,  a  system  which  sets  both  price  and  service  at  leAcls  above  what  they 
would  be  in  a  competitive  market,  in  other  words,  there  are  more  planes,  with 
more  empty  seats,  and  the  customer  pays  more  than  he  would  under  a  regime  of 
open  comi>etition.  Thus,  competitive  operations  in  California  have  generally 
produced  fare  levels  that  were  40  percent  lower  than  the  CAB  approved  fare 
level,  while  the  carriers  have  enjoyed  considerably  higher  load  factors. 

For  years,  nobody  much  worried  about  CAB  price  and  entry  policies,  because 
we  were  in  a  continuing  trend  of  improving  equipment,  declining  cost,  declining 
prices  and  rapidly  growing  traffic.  The  airline  traveler's  world  was  getting  better, 
even  though  CAB  rate  and  entry  regulation  was  probably  slowing  down  at  least 
the  rate  at  which  fares  declined,  and  encouraging  excess  capacity. 

Now,  however,  the  situation  has  changed.  Due  to  sharply  higher  fuel  and  labor 
costs,  airlines  have  requested,  and  the  Board  has  approved,  a  whole  series  of 
fare  increases,  which  have  come  at  a  time  when  the  public  at  large  was  if  any- 
thing less  able  to  pay  these  fares.  At  the  same  time,  the  Board  has  actively  sought 
to  cut  back  on  low-price  air  travel,  through  limitations  on  promotional  fares  and 
restrictions  on  charter  activity.  The  result  of  all  this  has  been  to  raise  fares 
considerably  for  everyone  and  to  raise  them  enormously  for  certain  classes  of 
users.  The  overall  effect  has  been  to  produce  an  almost  unprecedented  substantial 
reduction  in  air  travel — more  empty  seats  on  scheduled  flights  and  fewer  charter 
flights.  The  reduction  in  demand  has  tended  to  push  up  the  airlines'  unit  costs, 
since  they  have  had  to  spread  out  their  fixed  costs  over  fewer  passengers.  This 
in  turn  has  provided  the  impetus  for  renewed  fare  increases,  a  situation  likely  to 
further  reduce  air  travel  and  hence  again  increa.se  unit  costs.  The  resulting  spiral 
of  increasing  fares  and  costs  means  that  the  smaller  proportion  of  the  public 
which  can  afford  to  fly  gets  reduced  service  at  increased  prices. 

We  in  the  Administration  have  been  studying  for  some  time  how  to  break  out 
of  this  upward  spiral  of  prices  and  costs.  We  have  concluded  that  the  most  hope- 
ful avenue  is  a  substantial  relaxation  of  existing  price  and  entry  regulation, 
which  forces,  or  at  least  strongly  urges,  carriers  to  offer  excessive  amounts  of 
unused  seats  at  excessively  high  fares.  That  system  of  regulation  has  in  addition 
prevented  innovative  newcomers  from  coming  into  the  business  of  interstate  air 
transportation,  in  the  interest  of  protecting  the  established  carriers  against  new 
competition.  We  believe  that  more  open  competitive  pricing,  if  given  a  chance, 
would  broaden  the  carriers'  entrepreneurial  opportunities  by  giving  them  a  chance 
to  compete  with  lower  fares  as  well  as  with  extra  seats.  We  believe  that  it  would 
tend  to  bring  interstate  air  transportation  more  into  line  with  what  we  saw  in 
California  and  Texas :  an  environment  of  lower  fares  and  fuller  planes.  If  this 
occurs — and  both  actual  experience  and  economic  theory  suggest  that  it  will — we 
will  have  found  a  basis  for  breaking  the  cycle  of  rising  costs  and  declining  serv- 
ice. Lower  prices  are  likely  to  come  quite  quickly  and  lower  prices  are  likely  to 
encourage  new  traffic  quite  quickly.  By  the  same  token,  liberalized  entry  rules — 
an  environment  with  less  emphasis  on  route  protection — are  likely  to  get  onto 
the  routes  those  carriers  who  are  most  eflicient  at  serving  them.  In  a  competitive 
environment,  such  efficiencies  can  in  turn  be  passed  on  to  the  traveler  in  the  form 
of  lower  fares. 

The  Department's  perspective  on  airline  regulatory  problems  is  based  of  course 
on  our  experience  in  enforcing  the  antitrust  laws  in  a  great  variety  af  industries 
having  a  diversity  of  cost  and  capital  characteristics.  It  is  based  on  our  extensive 
participation  before  the  CAB  in  a  variety  of  proceedings.  And  it  is  based  on  our 
experience  in  antitrust  enforcement  in  other  regulated  industries,  some  of  which 
have  economic  characteristics  similar  to  those  of  air  transportation.  Our  experi- 
ence tells  us  that  regulated  firms  I'arely  welcome  freer  entry  rules  and  more 
flexible  pricing.  They  generally  want  to  be  protected  from  outsiders  and  protected 
from  each  other  by  a  benevolent  regulator.  In  the  airline  field,  regulated  firms 


47 

generally  have  opposed  pricing  flexibility  and  offered  capacity  cartel  agreements 
instead,  let  our  experience  also  tells  us  that  in  fact  competition  works  in  reg- 
ulated environments  much  more  efficiently  than  the  regulated  firms  generally 
believe;  and  we  find  increasing  use  of  competition  in  place  of  direct  regulation 
as  a  tool  to  promote  efficiency  in  a  number  of  regulated  environments,  ranging 
from  wholesale  electric  power  to  securities  markets. 

The  Department  is  currently  working  with  the  Department  of  Transportation, 
the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  the  Council  on  Wage  and  Price  Stability  and 
the  Office  of  Management  and  Budget  to  develop  detailed  Administration  pro- 
posals which  respond  to  this  reality  in  the  transportation  sector.  We  hope  to 
have  detailed  proposals  for  air  transport  regulation  reform  for  presentation  to 
the  Congress  in  the  near  future.  At  this  point,  these  agencies  have  arrived  at  a 
broad  consensus  in  principle,  which  we  will  discuss  today. 

We  all  agree  that  regulation  of  rates  and  routes  has  been  excessive  and  has 
inflated  present  cost  and  fare  levels. 

We  believe  the  government  should  regulate  the  airlines  where  necessary  to 
ensure  the  safety  and  reliability  of  air  transportation — but  this  clearly  does  not 
require  direct  government  regulation  of  airline  pricing  and  entry  to  the  current 
extent.  We  believe  the  focus  of  government  regulation  of  the  airlines  should  be 
on  these  essentially  noneconomic  goals,  with  clear  standards  and  procedures 
which  ensure  that  regulatory  powers  are  not  used  to  unnecessarily  limit  competi- 
tion. Even  if  full  rate  regulation  is  deemed  necessary  to  deal  with  certain  prob- 
lems— for  instance,  the  prevention  of  monopoly  pricing  in  certain  markets — 
such  regulation  should  be  carefully  crafted  to  limit  and  clarify  goals,  standards 
and  procedures. 

The  present  Federal  Aviation  Act  does  not  identify  limited  specific  economic 
goals  and  set  forth  standards  and  procedures  to  achieve  those  goals  and  avoid 
undesirable  side  effects.  Rather,  it  offers  the  Board  an  open-ended  mandate, 
which  can  be — and  frequently  is — used  to  protect  carriers  rather  than  the  travel- 
ing public,  and  to  protect  operating  inefficiencies  which  ultimately  must  be  paid 
for  by  the  public. 

Reform  only  of  procedural  (rather  than  substantive)  provisions  of  the  Act 
cannot  correct  the  fundamental  problem  of  its  ambiguous  and  sometimes  conflict- 
ing stated  objectives. 

Procedural  reform  of  the  Act  might  well  be  desirable,  but  it  is  not  likely  to  be 
successful  without  a  narrowing  and  clarification  of  the  standards  the  Board 
may  apply  in  making  economic  decisions,  and  of  the  scope  of  airline  activities 
subject  to  those  decisions.  Such  a  redefinition  of  the  Act's  economic  goals  and 
standards  would  be  a  substantial  improvement.  And  in  our  view,  such  a  re- 
definition would  call  into  question  the  continued  usefulness  of  much  of  present 
economic  regulation. 

The  Administration  group  also  agrees  that  the  CAB  should  not  be  given  broad 
authority  to  immunize  from  the  antitrust  laws  all  the  private  agreements  and 
mergers  it  approves.  Accordingly,  our  proposals  will  provide  for  a  much  narrower 
area  of  antitrust  exemption,  and  for  a  merger  approval  approach  generally 
modeled  on  the  Bank  Merger  Act  of  1966  (which  allows  the  courts  to  adjudicate 
the  legality  of  a  merger  under  the  antitrust  laws,  subject  to  agency  participation 
on  broader  public  interest  issues). 

To  explain  the  basis  for  these  rather  broad  conclusions,  I  will  sketch  briefly 
the  circumstances  which  led  to  the  imposition  of  federal  economic  regulation  of 
the  airlines,  describe  what  I  believe  tojie  the  lessons  of  major  CAB  economic 
regulatory   proceedings,   and  attempt  to  outline  some  preliminary  conclusions. 

I.    A   BRIEF    HISTORY   OF   FEDERAL  ECONOMIC   KEGTJLATIOX    OF   AIR  TRANSPORTATION 

Federal  regulation  of  air  transportation  has  developed  primarily  along  two 
paths :  one  set  of  statutes  which  regulate  safety,  airport  and  airway  affairs,  and 
another  specifically  directed  toward  the  regulation  of  the  economics  of  air  trans- 
portation. Tl.e  first  category  of  statutes  has  been  the  responsibility  of  the  Depart- 
ment of  Transportation  and  the  National  TransiJortation  Safety  Board  for 
several  years.^  The  economic  regulatorj-  system  which  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board  administers  is  now  embodied  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as 
amended.* 


1  Federal   Aviation   Act  of  1958.   72   Stat.   7.31.  49   U.S.C.    1301   et  seq.  ;  Department  of 
Transportation  Act  1966,  80  Stat.  931,  49  U.S.C.  16.51. 
a  Id. 


48 

The  origins  of  airline  economic  regulation  are  usually  traced  to  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Act  of  1938,^  which  generally  followed  the  outline  of  the  Interstate 
Commerce  Act  in  setting  up  most  of  the  major  regulatory  features  of  today's 
Federal  Aviation  Act.  There  had  been  partial  economic  regulation  of  air  carriers 
prior  to  1938,  however.  After  experimenting  with  several  different  means  of 
administering  a  system  of  subsidized  air  transport  of  mail,  the  Congress  deter- 
mined in  1930  to  grant  the  Postmaster  General  broad  powers  over  the  routes, 
rates,  and  practices  of  carriers  carrying  air  mail  under  contract  with  the 
government.*  In  1935,  the  Congress  broadened  this  regulation  to  prohibit  car- 
riers with  air  mail  contracts  from  engaging  in  any  service  on  routes  other  than 
their  airmail  routes  if  such  service  would  compete  with  another  carrier  having 
an  airmail  contract  on  that  route.*  The  predominance  of  mail  over  passenger 
service  was  rapidly  diminishing  throughout  this  period,  however,  and  by  1937 
air  carrier  income  from  passenger  service  was  twice  as  great  as  mail  income." 
Unregulated  carriers  without  airmail  contracts  began  to  compete  with  airmail 
carriers,  who  naturally  complained  about  their  unregulated  competitors'  greater 
economic  freedom." 

The  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  v.'hich  obtained  economic  regulatory 
powers  over  motor  carriers  in  1935,**  pressed  for  the  extension  of  economic  regu- 
lation over  all  air  carriers."  under  the  general  theory  that  it  is  unfair  and 
"chaotic"  for  unregulated  firms  to  be  allowed  to  compete  with  regulator  firms.^" 

The  protection  of  a  sul)sidized  airmail  system  was  a  vital  objective  of  the 
drafters  of  the  1938  Act.  Even  today,  a  very  high  percentage  of  the  provisions  of 
that  Act,  as  amended,  still  are  concerned  with  the  carriage  of  mail.  Today, 
although  the  mail  system  is  of  crucial  importance,  it  is  a  small  percentage  of  the 
air  transportation  business.  There  certainly  would  be  no  logical  basis  today  for 
designing  the  entire  air  transportation  system  around  the  mail  system,  because 
the  needs  of  the  postal  service  can  be  met  with  relatively  small  and  specific 
modifications  to  the  larger  air  system. 

Just  as  the  "chaotic"  conditions  generated  by  the  efforts  to  develop  an  airmail 
system  have  disappeared  today,  we  no  longer  experience  two  other  very  important 
factors  which  led  to  the  creation  of  airline  economic  regulation  in  1938.  The 
Great  Depression  had  shaken  our  .society's  confidence  in  the  free  market  system, 
and  led  to  a  number  of  laws  which  substituted  direct  government  economic  regu- 
lation of  business  organizations  for  the  maintenance  of  free  conii>etition.  Also, 
air  transportation  in  the  1930's  was  thought  to  suffer  from  undue  division  of 
governmental  regulatory  authority  among  the  Commerce  Department,  the  Post 
OflSce  Department,  and  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission,  "  and  it  was  con- 
sidered a  very  important  function  of  the  1938  Act  to  combine  and  coordinate 
all  of  these  functions  within  one  agency."  Thus,  the  'caotic  and  destructive"  con- 
ditions which  frquently  are  thought  to  be  the  1938  Act's  genesis  are  now  only  a 
matter  of  history. 

As  this  history  indicates,  airline  regulation  must  be  viewed  against  the  partic- 
ular background  of  the  circumstances  which  created  it  in  order  to  understand 
its  goals.  Various  parties  involved  in  the  drafting  and  pas.sage  of  the  original 
1938  Act  made  references  to  their  desire  to  allow  regulation  of  "chaotic"  competi- 
tion among  air  carriers,  and  given  the  above  description  of  the  Act's  historical 
context,  such  as  desire  seems  understandable.  The  drafters  of  the  Act,  however, 
vehemently  denied  any  intention  to  allow  the  Board  to  restrain  competition  or 
create  monopolies."  The  Act  itself  directed  the  Board  to  maintain  "competition 
to  the  extent  necessary"  to  pursue  other  rather  inclusive  goals,"  and  explicitly 


3  52  Stat.  973. 

*46  Stat.   259    (1930). 

B49  Stat.  619. 

«C.  S.  Rhyne,  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  Annotated  (1939),  p.  35. 

T  Id.  32-33. 

s  Motor  Carrier  Act  of  1935,  49  U.S.C.  301  et  seq. 

9  Rhyne,  supra,  32-33. 

1"  The  ICC  advanced  similar  arjcuments  with  re.spect  to  competing  surface  modes.  Boies, 
Experiment  in  Mercantilism  :  Minimum  Rate  Regulation  by  the  ICC,  68  Colum.  L.R.  599, 
614-15  ;  J.  Meyer,  M.  Peck.  J.  Stenason,  C.  Zwich,  Economics  of  Competition  in  the  Trans- 
portation Industries  10  (1964)  ;  Report  of  the  Attorney  General's  National  Committee  to 
Study  the  Antitrust  Laws  269  (1955)  ;  Coordination  of  Motor  Transportation,  183  ICC 
263  (1932). 

^  As  noted  above,  certain  of  the  noneconomic  regulatory  functions  conferred  upon  the 
CAB's  predecessor  agency  were  later  transferred  to  other  agencies.  See  note  1,  supra. 

"H.  Rept.  vo.  22.54.  75th  Cong.,  3rd  Sess.,  April  28,  1938;  83  Cong.  Rec.  5960. 

"83   Cong.   Rec.   6729-32. 

"  Section  1,  49  U.S.C.  sec.  1301. 


.      49 

directed  the  Board  to  observe  conventional  antitrust  principles  in  deciding  merger 
and  interlocking  control  cases/^ 

The  Act  s  reliance  upon  competition  among  air  carriers  shows  that  the  Con- 
gress clearly  did  not  regard  air  transportation  operations  as  having  "natural 
monopoly"  characteristics  which  required  government  control  in  the  place  of  the 
discipline  of  competition.  Unlike  the  usual  statute  regulating  a  •"natural  monop- 
oly,' the  Act  does  not  require,  but  rather  prohibits,  government  control  of  the 
regulated  firms"  investment  in  equipment  or  facilities,  and  of  the  specific  services 
tliey  provide  under  their  certihcates."  Instead  of  detailed  control  of  the  rate 
base,  regulation  was  extended  to  fares,  entry  and  exit  from  specific  routes,  and 
agreements  and  mergers. 

Other  characteristics  of  the  original  1938  Act  seem  to  have  been  included 
largely  because  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act  was  taken  as  a  model.  Thus  the 
1938  Act  prohibited  discrimination,  preference  or  prejudice  among  various  users 
of  air  transportation,  requireu  joint  fares  for  connecting  trafiic,  and  allowed 
classification  of  regulated  air  carriers  into  various  categories. 

II.    THE   LESSONS   OF   MAJOR   CAB   ECONOMIC  PROCEEDINGS 

With  that  background  on  the  origins  of  the  present  Act,  I  will  now  turn  to  the 
way  it  has  been  administered,  and  what  we  have  learned  in  the  process. 

Market  structure 

The  first  category  of  major  CAB  economic  cases  are  those  in  which  the  basic 
structure  of  the  airline  industry  itself  was  at  issue.  In  the  last  15  years,  the 
Department  of  Justice  has  opposed  three  major  trunk  air  carrier  merger  pro- 
posals,^' which,  had  they  been  approved,  would  have  substantially  redrawn  the 
route  map  of  the  U.S.  domestic  system,  and  considerably  increased  the  already 
very  great  concentration  of  the  airline  industry  in  the  hands  of  a  very  few  large 
trunk  air  carriers. 

In  1962,  we  opposed  the  proposed  American-Eastern  merger  before  the  Board. 
The  hearing  exajniner  ruled  in  our  favor,  finding  that  consummation  of  the  merger 
would  create  an  airline  with  more  than  one-third  of  the  entire  domestic  airline 
industry's  business,  greatly  increase  existing  economic  concentration  in  the  air- 
line industry,  create  a  regional  monopoly  in  the  northeastern  United  States,  and 
create  numerous  city-pair  monopolies  within  that  region.  The  merger  proposal 
was  subsequently   withdrawn. 

Ten  years  later,  the  Department  opposed  the  merger  of  Western  Airlines  with 
American  on  similar  grounds,  although  there  was  very  little  actual  overlap 
between  the  American  and  Western  systems.  The  hearing  examiner  recom- 
mended disapproval,  essentially  on  nonantitrust  grounds,  and  the  merger  was 
withdrawn  after  the  Board  issued  an  order  disapproving  it. 

A  merger  proposal  between  National  Airlines  and  Northwest  Airlines,  which 
we  opposed  on  the  grounds  that  it  would  increase  concentration  in  the  trunk 
airline  industry  and  destroy  important  potential  comi^etition  between  the  two 
merger  partners,  also  was  withdrawn  after  the  hearing  examiner  issued  a  decision 
recommending  disapproval  on  antitrust  grounds.  In  the  last  few  years,  the 
Department  also  has  studied  several  other  major  airline  merger  proposals 
which  were  never  filed  and  litigated  at  the  CAB. 

These  merger  proposals  have  raised  very  serioug  questions  as  to  the  proper 
structure  of  the  industry,  both  as  to  the  need  for  the  proposed  merger  and  as 
to  its  likely  effect  on  competition  and  other  important  economic  processes.  As  a 
result  of  studying,  testing  and  arguing  the  evidence  in  these  cases,  we  have 
come  to  the  conclusion  that  in  the  absence  of  economic  regulation,  the  air  trans- 
portation industry  probably  would  have  a  reasonably  fiexible,  competitive 
structure  which  would  serve  the  public  better  than  the  present  government- 
controlled  structure.  Experience  under  economic  regulation,  and  in  unregulated 
air  transportation  where  available,  indicates  that  the  industry  tends  to  have  a 
"competitive"  structure,  rather  than  being  a  "natural  monopoly"  which  must  be 
regulated  in  the  interests  of  the  public. 


IS  Section  408(b),  49  U.S.C.  sec.  1378. 

"Section  401(e)(4),  49  U.S.C.  sec.  1371. 

"  See  American-Eastern  Merger.  Recommended  Decision  of  Hearing  Examiner  Ralph  L. 
Waser,  docket  13355,  November  27,  1962  ;  American- Western  Merger  Case,  orders  72-7-91 
and  72-7-92,  and  docket  22916,  June  13,  1972  ;  Northwest-National  Merger  Agreement, 
Recommended  Decision  of  Associate  Chief  Examiner  Robert  L.  Park,  docket  23852,  May  22, 
1972. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  5 


50 

Evidence  is  quite  abundant  that  there  are  no  important  economies  of  scale  in 
air  transportation  ;  that  is,  larger  firms  are  not  more  efficient  or  less  costly  simply 
because  of  their  size.  In  fact,  other  things  being  equal,  the  largest  air  carriers 
tend  to  have  a  higher  level  of  unit  costs,  and  there  are  some  indications  that 
these  increased  costs  are  caused  by  the  difficulties  of  managing  an  airline  of 
very  large  size.^^ 

The  reasons  for  this  are  apparent — the  airlines'  "right  of  way"  is  the  air  itself, 
and  their  "tracks"  if  any,  are  the  air  traflSc  control  guideways  maintained  by 
the  Federal  Government.  Well  over  80  percent  of  the  airlines'  investment  is  in 
flight  equipment,  which  is  among  the  most  mobile  of  assets,  rather  than  in  fixed 
assets,  as  is  the  case  in  the  classical  "natural  monopoly."  "  Not  only  does  this 
make  competitive  service  economically  feasible,  but  it  makes  duplication  of  routes 
far  less  risky,  because  competitors  can  more  easily  adjust  their  operations  by 
rescheduling  an  aircraft  from  one  city-pair  to  another — assuming  that  the  gov- 
ernment does  not  prevent  them  from  doing  so. 

In  view  of  this  conclusion  that  air  carriers  will  not  become  more  eflScient  or 
more  profitable  by  merging  to  become  larger,  why  have  so  many  mergers  been 
proposed?  Perhaps  the  most  important  reasons  for  mergers  among  the  regulated 
air  carriers  have  been  the  effects  of  regulation  itself.  Air  carriers  knovv  that 
when  they  hold  a  certificate,  it  is  the  nature  of  economic  regulation  that  the 
Board  will  to  a  greater  or  lesser  degree  protect  them  from  entry  by  new  com- 
petitors on  that  route.  Similarly,  the  air  carriers  knovv  that  they  cannot  expand 
onto  a  new  route  without  obtaining  a  certificate.  Consequently,  any  certificated 
air  carrier,  no  matter  how  poorly  run  and  how  debilitated  financially  ana  opera- 
tionally, has  one  very  valuable  asset — its  route  certificate.  This  asset  typically 
has  been  sold  by  merger  of  weak  carriers  into  stronger  carriers.  As  a  result,  no 
large  federally  certificated  air  carrier  has  gone  out  of  business  other  than  through 
merger  with  another  federally  certificated  air  carrier.  Because  the  Board  has 
allowed  virtually  no  new  firms  to  join  the  ranks  of  tlie  certificated  air  ca.riers, 
there  has  been  a  steady  diminution  in  the  number  of  air  carriers  with  certificates 
from  the  Federal  Government. 

It  has  been  observed  that  during  the  period  when  California  intrastate  airlines 
were  essentially  free  from  economic  regulation,  many  firms  entered  and  left  the 
market,  but  none  of  them  left  the  market  through  merger.  One  very  careful  eco- 
nomic study  of  this  phenomenon,  and  the  contrast  between  unregulated  California 
airlines  and  the  regulated  interstate  airlines  makes  a  convincing  and  apparently 
unrebutted  case  that  in  the  absence  of  economic  regulation,  there  probably  would 
have  been  many  more  competing  airlines  in  the  United  States  than  the  CAB  has 
allowed  to  exist.*" 

As  long  as  new  certificates  are  not  freely  given,  one  would  expect  that  there 
would  be  some  transfer  of  certificates  as  carriers  seek  to  reorganize  their  route 
authorities.  However,  sale  or  trade  of  certificate  authority  has  been  fairly  rare, 
although  not  unprecedented,  becau.se  until  lately  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  did 
not  encourage  such  "trafficking  in  certificates."  Recently,  the  Board's  willingness 
to  consider  transfer  of  certificate  authority  has  led  to  a  number  of  "route  swap" 
proposals. 

When  there  is  limited  entry,  we  believe  that  transfers  of  certificate  authority 
very  well  may  provide  a  practical  means  of  reorganizing  certificated  route  author- 
ity in  a  form  more  closely  aligned  with  the  economic  or  operational  requirements 
of  the  air  transportation  system.  The  carriers'  objective  in  a  route  swap  is,  of 
course,  to  increase  profits.  In  cases  where  the  increase  in  profits  would  take  place 
becau.se  the  route  can  be  served  more  efficiently  as  part  of  the  transferee's  route 
system,  we  believe  the  transfer  of  authority  may  well  be  in  the  public  interest. 

Tlie  motive  for  a  route  transfer,  however,  may  be  to  eliminate  competition,  as 
where  two  carriers  both  possess  authority  on  a  given  route,  and  one  proposes  to 


"In  the  American-Western  Merger  Case,  (locket  22916,  see  exhibits  DOT-T-1  ;  CO-RT- 
500,  pp.  7.  16-24;  CO-R-512-ol7  ;  CO-R-.528-529  ;  RW-120-12,5  ;  RW-SR-900  ;  BOR-R- 
100.  In  the  National-Northwest  Merger  Case,  docket  23852,  see  exhibits  DOT-T-1,  DJ-1, 
DJ-RT-1,  and  Transcript  pp.  1412-13. 

The  numerous  academic  studies  in  this  area  apparently  all  conc'ude  that  there  are  no 
economies  of  scale  in  the  airline  industry  above  the  size  of  the  very  smallest  air  carriers. 
See  sources  cited  in  G.  Douglas  and  .1.  Mil'er.  Economic  Regulation  of  Domestic  Air  Trans- 
port (1974),  pp.  14-15,  and  W.  .Tordan,  Airline  Regul.ition  in  America  (1970),  pp.  191-194. 

The  Board  itself  hf\s  endorsed  in  general  terms  the  conclusion  that  there  are  constant 
returns  to  scale  in  the  industry.  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation,  phase  5 — Dis- 
count Fares,  order  72-12-18  (December  5.  1972).  p.  48. 

"  \merican-Western  Case,  supra,  exhibit  D.T-RT-1,  p.  5  ;  see  also  order  72-12-18,  supra, 
p.  48. 

20  Jordan,  supra,  pp.  14-33. 


51 

transfer  its  authority  to  the  other,  eliminating  competition  between  the  route 
swap  partners  on  that  route.  In  such  cases  the  public  is  likely  to  be  injured  by 
the  xeduction  in  competition  on  that  route.  We  have  opposed  some  anticompeti- 
tive route  exchange  proposals,  notably  the  American-Pan  American  route  ex- 
change involving  Caribbean  and  South  Pacific  routes,"'  and  the  Pan  American- 
TWA  agreement,'-  which  involves  both  Atlantic  and  Pacific  routes. 
Generally  speaking,  route  transfers,  including  the  reciprocal  route  transfers  cur- 
rently called  route  exchanges,  are  merely  partial  mergers.  Consequently,  as  with 
mergers,  there  would  be  far  fewer  route  transfers,  if  any,  in  the  absence  of  entry 
restrictions.^^ 

We  have  seen  that  the  "natural  monopoly"  argument  for  regulating  entry  and 
exit  finds  no  support  in  the  facts  of  air  transportation  economics.  Other  asserted 
reasons  to  regulate  entry  and  exit  from  air  transportation  markets  are  that 
without  such  regulation,  there  would  be  "destructive,"  or  predatory  conduct  by 
airline  firms,  and  "chaotic"  conditions  would  constitute  a  serious  public  detri- 
ment. Let  us  examine  these  fears  in  turn. 

In  order  for  predatory  conduct  to  pay  off,  it  is  necessary  for  a  firm  to  go  through 
two  processe.< :  First,  it  must  drive  competitors  from  the  market  by  using  preda- 
tory practices,  such  as  below-cost  price  cuts ;  this  kind  of  conduct  is  costly  to  the 
would-be  predator.  Second,  the  predator  must  recoup  those  costs  by  using  the  re- 
sulting freedom  from  competition  to  behave  like  a  monopolist.  This  second  step 
will  not  be  possible  if  the  firms  which  were  driven  out  can  reenter  the  market 
quickly  and  easily.  As  I  have  explained,  entry  into  air  transportation  markets 
generally  would  not  be  difficult  to  accomplish  quickly  if  there  were  no  government 
restriction.  Accordingly,  the  economists  who  have  written  on  this  matter  have 
concluded  that  the  prospects  for  profitable  predatory  conduct  are  poor  in  this 
industry.-* 

Given  these  economic  facts,  governinent  regulation  of  entry  actually  can  cause 
the  predatory  conduct  it  is  supposed  to  prevent.  A  government  prohibition  on 
entry  can  be  the  most  effective  insurance  possible  for  a  predator  which  is  trying 
to  recoup  the  costs  of  predatory  conduct. 

Of  course,  if  predatory  conduct  does  take  place  in  the  airline  industry,  it  is 
subject  to  the  antitrust  laws  just  as  it  is  in  another  industry,  if  it  is  not  somehow 
immunized  by  government  action. 

In  the  New  England  sen'ice  investigation,  where  the  benefits  of  entry  and  exit 
regulation  for  small  (and  presumably  relatively  less  stable)  air  carriers  were 
directly  in  issue,  the  Administrative  Law  Judge  found  on  the  basis  of  the  record 
tliat  there  had  been  no  evidence  of  predatory  behavior.^^  The  proponents  of  entry 
and  exit  regulation  in  that  case  argued,  and  the  Board  agreed,^  that  there  is  a 
public  interest  in  "continuity  of  service"  which  requires  some  entry  and  exit 
regulation.  We  question  this  re.  ult,  in  view  of  the  Administrative  Law  Judge's 
uncontroverted  finding  that  although  commuter  carriers  had  entered  and  exited 
several  New  England  markets,  there  had  been  no  significant  lapses  of  service  to 
the  public  because  of  this  turnover."'  In  light  of  these  facts,  the  "continuity  of 
.service"  which  entry  and  exit  control  brings  is  not  an  assurance  of  service  to  the 
public,  but  an  assurance  of  tenure  to  the  carrier.  Essential  public  facilities  such 
as  grocery  stores  and  i  harmacies  do  not  enjoy  this  type  of  protection  from  com- 
petition, and  we  see  no  reason  why  air  carriers  should. 

Pricing 

The  Department  of  Justice  has  been  very  selective  in  participating  in  fare  pro- 
ceedings at  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,,  because  the  economics  of  the  industry 
change  rapidly  enough  to  seriously  limit  the  future  applicability  of  many  deci- 
sions as  to  specific  fare  levels.  As  a  result,  participation  in  complex  proceedings 
on  specific  fares  may  produce  considerably  less  important  benefits  than  one  would 
expect  from  the  same  expenditure  of  effort  in  a  structural  proceeding.  The 
Department  did  participate  in  the  Board's  recent  Dome.stic  Passenger  Fare  Inves- 
tigation (DPFI),  however,  because  we  believed  the  Board's  decisions  in  that  pro- 


=1  American  Airlines,  Inc.-Pan  American  World  Airways,  Inc.  Route  Exchange  Agree- 
ment,  docket   26245    (pending). 

22.\pplication  of  Pan  American  World  Airways,  Inc.  and  Trans  World  Airlines,  Inc.  for 
Approval  of  an  Agreement,  docket  27114,  et  al. 

23  See  American-Western  Merger  Case,  exhibit  DJ-RT-1,  supra,  pp.  6-10. 

=*  See  sources  cited  in  A.  Kahn,  The  Economics  of  Regulation,  pp.  219-20. 

^  Initial  Decision  of  Administrative  Law  Judge  Greer  M.  Murphy,  docket  22973,  July  9, 

ig?.-?.  p.  75. 

2«  Order  74-7-70,  July  17,  1974  ;  p.  15. 

"  Initial  Decision,  New  England  Service  Investigation,  supra,  p.  75. 


52 

ceeding  not  only  would  bring  important  revisions  in  the  level  and  structure 
of  all  domestic  airline  fares,  but  would  set  the  rules  under  which  that  level  and 
structure  would  be  set  for  many  years  to  come.  Largely  on  the  basis  of  compre- 
hensive evidence  produced  by  the  Department  of  Transportation,  we  became 
convinced  that  airlines  would  be  more  efficient  and  less  likely  to  engage  in  waste- 
ful service  competition — flying  empty  seats  and  piano  bars — if  the  Board  en- 
couraged them  to  compete  on  the  basis  of  price,  instead  of  preventing  them  from 
doing  so  by  fixing  one  fare  which  all  carriers  must  charge. 

The  key  point  here  is  that  the  economic  characteristics  of  the  airline  industry 
are  such  that  even  when  the  government  eliminates  price  competition,  carriers 
still  have  the  incentive  to  compete,  and  will  compete  any  way  they  can,  if  only 
through  "frills"  which  are  less  important  to  passengers  than  price.  Once  a  flight 
is  scheduled,  the  cost  of  carrying  additional  passengers  in  the  airplane  is  very 
low  compared  to  the  cost  of  flying  the  airplane  in  the  first  place.  Thus,  the  mar- 
ginal passenger  on  a  flight  is  very  profitable — any  competitive  initiative  which 
diverts  passengers  onto  an  airline's  flight  may  pay  off  richly. 

In  scheduled  service,  it  appears  that  next  to  price,  the  variable  most  important 
to  the  passenger  on  a  scheduled  airline  flight  is  the  ability  to  find  a  .seat  on  a 
flight  at  or  near  his  preferred  departure  time.  Consequently,  when  the  price  is 
fixed,  competitive  rivalry  is  diverted  into  capacity  competition — competing  car- 
riers offer  large  numbers  of  flights  in  an  attempt  to  cover  as  many  preferred 
departure  times  and  attract  as  many  customers  as  possible.  The  evidence  in  the 
recent  capacity  agreements  case  is  quite  convincing  that,  even  under  the  present 
system  of  uniform  fares,  carriers  do  not  have  the  incentive  to  offer  ruinous 
amounts  of  capacity  simply  because  of  this  phenomenon.  But  it  is  clear  that  fare 
regulation  has  caused  the  airlines  to  oft"er  the  consumer  large  numbers  of  flights 
and  empty  seats  instead  of  cheaper  transportation.  Stated  another  way,  they 
have  tended  to  "compete  away"  the  "monopoly  profits"  generated  by  excessively 
high  regulated  fares. 

Allowing  price  competition  by  the  airlines  would  give  them  an  incentive  to 
offer  consumers  a  choice  as  to  the  combination  of  fare  and  load  factor  they 
want,  and  all  the  evidence  is  that  the  result  would  be  that  lower  fares  would  be 
available  to  the  users  of  scheduled  interstate  flight.  The  experience  of  the  intra- 
state carriers  in  California  and  Texas  confirms  this.  Of  course,  higher  load  factors 
also  would  be  involved— but  all  this  tells  us  is  that  the  public  would  rather  pay 
considerably  less  for  travel  even  at  the  price  of  being  somewhat  less  certain  of 
getting  on  their  first  choice  of  flight.  Accordingly,  we  were  disappointed  when  the 
Board  rejected  the  arguments  of  the  Department  of  Transportation  and  Justice 
in  favor  of  allowing  air  carriers  to  price  freely  within  a  "zone  of  reasonableness" 
instead  of  requiring  a  rigid  adherence  to  one  identical  fare  for  all  carriers  offer- 
ing service  in  a  particular  market. 

We  were  gratified  that  the  Board  decided  in  phase  6  of  the  DrFI  to  base  its 
fare  decisions  upon  load  factor  and  seating  configuration  standards  which  ex- 
cluded from  the  rate  base  any  service  amenity  not  included  in  the  Board's  stand- 
ard for  such  service. 

Under  the  Phase  6  policy,  the  fare  is  based  on  the  amount  of  capacity  associ- 
ated with  a  standard  load  factor,  in  a  standard  aircraft  configuration  set  by 
the  Board,  rather  than  the  actual  load  factor  and  configuration  of  a 
particular  carrier  or  the  industry.  We  believe  this  approach  can  allow  carriers 
greater  freedom  to  experiment  with  different  levels  of  capacity  and  types  of 
service  without  being  deprived  of  the  motive  to  keep  their  services  as  economical 
as  possible.  In  Phase  6  and  the  related  coach  lounge  proceeding,^^  we  argued 
that  the  Board  violated  the  spirit  of  its  Phase  6  policy  by  attempting  to  punish 
a  carrier  offering  a  different  type  of  service  by  requiring  that  carrier  to  charge 
a  different  fare,  rather  than  simply  requiring  that  carrier  to  charge  a  fare 
based  upon  the  more  economical  aircraft  configuration  which  the  Board  adopted 
as  its  standard.  This  was  the  first  proceeding  in  recent  years  in  which  we 
carried  our  disagreement  with  the  Board  to  the  Court  of  Appeals,  and  this 
matter  is  now  pending  rehearing  en  banc  on  the  Board's  motion  after  a  decision 
favorable  to  our  position. 

We  also  have  pending  in  the  Court  of  Appeals  a  review  of  the  Board's 
decision  to  extend  rate  regulation  to  the  charter  field  for  the  first  time,  despite 
numerous  arguments  in  opposition. 


2"  ChicaKo-Los  Angeles  F.ire  Hednction  Case,  docket  25r-,H7,  now  pending  action  b.v  the 
court  of  appeals  as  Continental  Airlines,  Inc.  v.  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  D.C.  Cir.  Nos. 
73-1714,  73-1718. 


53 

Competitive  Restraints 

it  dP<^i<i^''f  ^  generally  has  applied  a  specific  "rule  of  reason"  standard  when 
It  decider  whether  or  liot  to  approve  an  agieement  which  restrains  competition. 
tftU\  .  '*"  agreemeut  would  have  substantial  anticompetitive  effects  under 
established  antitrust  principles,  it  will  not  be  approveu  unless  approval  is  the 
only  nay  to  meet  a  serious  transportation  need  or  secure  important  public  bene- 
nts.-  Until  very  recently,  the  Department  of  Justice  has  not  participated  in  very 
many  proceedings  concerning  air  carrier  conduct  subject  to  regulation  by  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  In  recent  years,  we  have  opposed  capacity  restraint 
agreements  which  have  been  in  effect  in  several  markets  on  the  basis  of  various 
purported  jusufications.  The  capacity  agreement  question,  too,  is  pending  in  the 
Court  of  Appeals. 

The  capacity  reduction  agreement  case,  in  which  we  participated  in  a  lengthy 
hearing  at  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  last  year,  dealt  with  several  issues  of 
general  competitive  significance,  and  we  believe  the  record  of  that  proceeding 
casts  further  doubt  on  the  need  for  the  existing  type  of  economic  regulation  in 
air  transi)oration.  Specifically,  proponents  of  capacity  agreements  were  able  in 
that  proceeuing  to  proauce  virtually  no  evidence  that  carriers  which  flood  the 
market  with  schedules  tend  to  attract  a  greater  proportion  of  passengers  from 
their  competitors,  so  that  even  under  the  present  fixed  price-no-entry  conditions 
of  the  regulated  air  transport  industry,  carriers  do  not  really  have  economic 
incentives  to  engage  in  ruinous  overschedaling. 

The  evidence  established  instead  that  overcapacity  and  misallocation  of  ca- 
pacity in  the  regulated  air  transportation  system  can  be  traced  to  economic 
regulation  actions  by  the  Board,  primarily  the  prescription  of  noncompetitive 
fares  which  allow  breakeven  operations  at  low  load  factors,  and  a  record  of 
"bailing  out"  carriers  which  make  improvident  competitive  decisions. 

The  capacity  case  was  unusual  in  that  the  Administrative  Law  Judge  ordered 
some  very  informative  discovery  into  the  decisionmaking  process  of  the  air  carrier 
proponents  of  capacity  restraint  agreements.  One  fact  that  emerged  was  that  if 
the  Board  were  to  strictly  enforce  its  Phase  6  load  factor  standards,  air  carrier 
management  would  reduce  the  level  of  excess  capacity  in  the  industry,  provided 
it  believed  that  the  Board  would  not  take  regulatory  action  to  protect  air  carrier 
profits  despite  their  failure  to  observe  the  load  factor  standards.^  Unfortunately, 
the  Board  has  on  occasion  acted  to  "bail  out"  individual  carriers  which  get  into 
trouble ;  the  carriers  know  this,  and  they  act  accordingly.  Thus,  even  an  enlight- 
ened and  potentially  effective  regulatory  policy  such  as  the  Board's  load  factor 
standard  can  be  impaired  or  negated  by  the  regulator's  natural  and  perhaps 
inevitable  proclivity  to  protect  the  firms  it  regulates. 

The  capacity  agreement  case  also  illustrates  another  generic  problem  with 
economic  regulation :  these  anticompetitive  agreements  were  instituted  not  in 
markets  where  any  economic  problem  existed,  but  in  the  largest,  more  profitable 
markets  of  the  largest  air  carriers.^^  Such  anticompetitive  restraints  were  neces- 
sary, argued  the  Board's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  in  order  to  produce  higher 
than  normal  profits,  in  some  markets,  profits  which  in  theory  could  be  used  to 
cross-subsidize  markets  in  which  average  profits  could  not  be  obtained.'^ 

Arguments  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  should  effect  a  sub  rosa  tax  upon 
one  class  of  consumers  for  the  benefit  of  another  illustrate,  we  believe,  the  un- 
fortunate results  of  giving  an  economic  regulatory  agency  quite  comprehensive 
powers,  and  only  the  vaguest  statutory  directives  as  to  how  those  powers  are  to  be 
exercised.  The  legislation  which  set  up  o^r  present  system  of  economic  regula- 
tion of  air  carriers  did  not  at  any  point  direct  the  Board  to  tax  some  consumers 
for  the  benefit  of  others,  but  it  did  provide  the  Board  with  the  tools  to  do  so 
and  with  a  set  of  conflicting,  vaguely  worded  objectives,  one  of  which  always 
could  be  selected  to  justify  such  anticompetitive  actions. 
Antitrust  Immunity 

Under  the  present  Federal  Aviation  Act,  the  Board  has  power  to  approve  or 
disapprove  mergers  (Sec.  408),  control  relationships  (Sec.  409),  and  agreements 


=9  Local  Cart^ffe  Ajrrepment  Ca^e  15  CAB  8.50  (lft.52>  ;  North  Atlnntic  Tourist  Com- 
mission Case,  Ifi  CAB  225,  226  (1952)  ;  Six  Carrier  Mutual  Aid  Pact,  29  CAB  158  (1959). 
The  Siinreme  Court  has  confirmed  the  annronriateness  of  nn  irientlcal  st-'ndnrd  in 
Fderal  Maritime  Commi/tnion  v.  fivenxka  Amerika  Linien.  ,390  TT.S.  2.'?8,  244.  246  (1967). 

sofnnncitv  Rpdnction  Apreement  Case,  docket  2290S  exhihit  D.T-A  and  testimony  of 
Rindnll   Mali".   tra"scrint  486-94  :   see  also  tran.scrint  2579.  1410-11. 

31  Docket  2290S.  Brief  of  the  TTnl+ed  Stntes  Department  of  .Tustice  to  the  Administrative 
Lnw  ,Tm1ee.  no.  18-2.3  ;  Replv  Brief,  np.  10-14. 

^Docket  22908,  Brief  of  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  to  the  .Administrative  Law 
Judge. 


54 

among  air  carriers  (Sec.  412).  Section  414  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  provides 
that  the  antitrust  laws  shall  not  apply  to  persons  affected  by  CAB  orders  issued 
under  these  three  sections  of  the  Act,  to  the  extent  "necessary  to  enable  such 
person  to  do  anything  authorized,  approved,  or  required  by  such  order."  (49  U.b.C. 
1384)  The  public  interest  would  be  better  served  if  each  of  the  three  types  of 
transactions  as  to  which  the  Board  can  confer  immunity  were  evaluated  under 
the  standards  of  the  antitrust  laws,  rather  than  the  general  "public  interest" 
rubric  of  an  administrative  agency.  .   ^     ^      ^, 

If  economies  of  scale  were  more  prevalent  in  the  air  transport  industry  than 
in  the  general  economy,  and  these  economies  were  considered  more  important  than 
the  advantages  of  having  an  unconcentrated  air  transport  industry,  there  might 
be  a  basis  for  applying  agency  review  and  antitrust  immunity  with  respect  to  the 
three  areas  subject  to  the  section  414  immunity  provision.  It  is  manifest,  how- 
ever, that  such  economies  of  scale  do  not  exist,  and  there  is  no  other  evidence 
that  anticompetitive  industry  structure  or  conduct  is  any  more  in  the  public 
interest  in  the  air  transport  industry  than  in  the  economy  in  general.  Thus,  these 
types  of  transactions  should  be  subject  to  the  standards  of  antitrust  law,  not 
administrative  law. 

It  would  be  desirable  to  remove  the  antitrust  immunity  provisions  of  section 
414  even  if  these  three  types  of  transactions  remain  subject  to  administrative 
review.  This  would  insure  that  the  administrative  agency  would  not  follow  a 
less  procompetitive  standard  than  that  of  the  antitrust  laws;  the  safest  way 
to  do  this  is  to  eliminate  any  inference  that  the  Board's  approval  brings  immunity 
from  an  antitrust  lawsuit.  See,  e.g.,  United  States  v.  Philadelphia  National  Bank, 
374  U.S.  321  (1963).  The  agency  thus  would  be  free  to  apply  a  higher  standard 
of  protection  for  competition  but  not  a  lower  one.  This  is  the  approach  of  the 
Atomic  Energy  Act  of  1954  (42  U.S.C.  Sec.  2135). 

The  existence  of  the  section  414  immunity  provision  creates  the  possibility  of 
a  lowering  of  competitive  standards  not  only  in  the  regulated  air  transportation 
industry,  but  also  in  industries  not  regulated  by  the  CAB.  In  a  recent  decision, 
the  Supreme  Court  held  that  a  private  antitrust  action  against  Hughes  Tool  Co., 
a  person  engaged  in  aeronautics,  was  barred  by  the  Board's  approval  of  and 
continuing  jurisdiction  over  the  control  relationship  which  was  the  basis  of  the 
antitrust  complaint.  The  antitrust  complaint  had  centered  upon  the  approved 
transactions'  competitive  effects  in  the  commercial  aircraft  manufacturing  in- 
dustry, not  in  the  air  transportation  industry  which  is  regulated  by  the  Board. 
(Hughes  Tool  Co.  v.  Trans  World  Airlines,  Inc.,  409  U.S.  363,  366).  Thus,  the 
effect  of  the  Court's  decision  may  be  to  allow  the  Board  to  create  immunity  from 
the  antitrust  laws — presumably  applying  the  standards  of  administrative  law — 
in  industries  where  it  has  only  limited  jurisdiction  to  protect  competition,  or  no 
jurisdiction  at  all. 

If  any  special  characteristics  of  air  transportation  require  departure  from  the 
undiluted  application  of  the  antitrust  laws,  such  departure  should  be  effected  by 
a  procedure  similar  to  that  of  the  Bank  Merger  Act  of  1966.  Under  that  statute 
a  specialized  regulatory  agency  first  passes  upon  whether  a  merger  would  violate 
the  antitrust  laws,  and  whether  it  should  nevertheless  be  allowed  because  of  spe- 
cific overriding  public  benefits  which  could  not  be  obtained  by  any  other  means. 
The  transaction  is  then  subject  to  de  novo  review  by  the  United  States  in  a  Dis- 
trict Court. 

III.     CONCLUSIONS 

The  Board  has  used  its  comprehensive  powers  and  amorphous  policy  mandate 
in  part  to  promote  what  it  perceives  as  stability  and  "financially  sound  condi- 
tions" in  the  industry.  Each  regulated  air  carrier  is  confined  to  a  particular  class 
or  type  of  service  on  particular  routes.  Along  with  mergers  and  route  protection, 
the  result  has  been  an  ever  dwindling  number  of  competitors  within  each  regu- 
lated category.  There  is  abundant  evidence  that  this  protection  against  competi- 
tion has  in  itself  led  to  considerably  higher  prices  and  lower  eflBciency  than 
would  be  available  in  the  absence  of  entry  control.*" 

This  imposes  .serious  economic  costs  directly  upon  consumers  of  air  transpor- 
tation, and  indirectly  upon  the  entire  economy.  In  addition  to  these  direct  costs, 
regulation  restricts  the  freedom  of  air  carriers  to  enter  and  leave  markets  as 
market  forces  indicate,  and  instead  require  them  to  go  through  expensive,  time- 


rs See  sources  cited  in  Douglas  and  Miller,  supra  42,  54 ;  172. 


55 

consuming  and  unpredictable  legal  processes  before  engaging  in  normal  rearrange- 
ments of  tlieir  operations.  This  has  generated  waste,  inflexibility,  and  insensitivity 
to  the  desires  of  consumers.  It  also  has  kept  out  of  the  industry  many  firms  which 
could  have  made  valuable  contributions. 

The  fare  policy  of  the  CAB  appears  to  have  taken  a  turn  for  the  better  in  some 
respects  as  a  result  of  the  DPFI.  As  I  have  explained  above,  actual  enforcement 
of  the  load  factor  standards  could  bring  considerable  progress  toward  breaking 
the  declining  load  factor,  escalating  price  cycle.  Also  in  the  DPFI,  the  Board 
found  that  cross-subsidization  is  inefllcient  and  adverse  to  the  public  interest, 
and  moved  to  reduce  the  cross-subsidization  inherent  in  the  present  fare  struc- 
ture."  As  the  discussion  above  indicates,  however,  it  remains  to  be  seen  whether 
the  Board  will  follow  through  on  these  principles  and  apply  them  everywhere 
they  need  to  be  applied. 

In  the  area  of  pricing  flexibility,  there  has  been  little  change.  The  Board 
reaffirmed  in  the  DPFI  the  practice  of  pricing  on  an  industry  average  basis  so 
that  all  regulated  carriers,  regardless  of  their  relative  efficiency,  will  continue 
to  survive,  and  none  will  have  too  great  an  incentive  to  develop  a  greater  level  of 
efficiency  than  that  of  its  fellow  regulatees.  This  "cost-plus"  pricing  policy  has 
deprived  consumers  of  a  variety  of  price  and  quality  options.  Given  the  carriers' 
tendency  to  engage  in  service  competition  which  the  Act  allows  the  Board  to 
regulate  only  indirectly,  the  result  is  not  even  high  profits — just  waste. 

All  of  these  problems,  plus  the  recent  economic  downturn  and  fuel  price  crisis, 
have  led  the  Board  in  recent  years  to  move  into  one  area  it  previously  had  largely 
avoided — the  approval  and  even  promotion  of  anticompetitive  agreements  such 
as  pooling,  capacity  restraint  agreements  and  "route  swaps"  which  in  reality 
amount  to  enforceable  agreements  not  to  complete.  The  common  goal  in  each  of 
these  recent  agreements  has  been  to  decrease  or  at  least  stabilize  competition  and 
increase  the  rate  of  return  in  the  industry.  The  result,  in  many  instances,  has  been 
a  serious  decline  in  the  quality  of  service  coupled  with  a  dramatic  increase  in 
prices  over  and  above  increases  required  by  costs  such  as  the  increased  cost  of 
fuel. 

What  can  be  done  about  this?  The  Department  of  Justice  and  other  litigants 
sometimes  can  help  maintain  a  degree  of  reliance  on  competition,  but  under  no  cir- 
cumstances do  we  believe  such  litigation  brings  optimum  results.  Parties  seeking 
to  infiuence  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  toward  more  competitive  policies  are 
hampered  by  the  vagueness  and  inclusiveness  of  the  statutory  standards  among 
which  the  Board  may  choose  to  justify  its  decisions,  and  are  hamjiered  by  judicial 
re-straint  in  reviewing  crucial  aspects  of  agency  decisionmaking.  This  is  exacer- 
bated by  the  very  serious  costs  and  delays  of  litigating  economic  issues,  both 
before  the  lioard  and  in  the  courts. 

These  problems  will  be  dealt  with  in  greater  detail  in  later  sessions  of  these 
hearings.  It  will  suffice  to  say  now  that  we  do  not  believe  the  serious  problems 
of  air  transport  economic  regmation  will  be  satisfactorily  corrected  by  litigation 
under  present  statutory  standards,  although  such  litigation  can  help  somewhat. 

Neither  do  we  believe  that  the  optimum  answer  lies  in  the  reform  of  procedures 
under  which  air  carrier  economic  regulation  is  carried  out.  Unnecessary  regula- 
tions is  still  expensive  even  if  carried  out  under  clear  standards  and  optimum 
procedures.  It  would  be  possible  to  have  a  much  narrower  statute  seeking  spe- 
cific goals  with  definite  safeguards  for  competition  and  economic  efficiency.  In 
air  transportation,  the  fundamental  goal  would  be  the  provision  of  efficient  air 
transportation  to  the  public  by  qualified  tommon  carriers  using  safe  planes  and 
qualified  crews.  A  tightly  drawn  statute  would  prevent  the  Board  from  limiting 
competition  unless  it  made  findings  on  the  record  that  competition  would  com- 
promise safety  or  reliability  of  service.  Even  under  such  a  statute,  the  problem 
of  preventing  regulation  from  pursuing  other,  anticompetitive  goals  might  prove 
difficult. 

Specifically,  we  believe  that  new  legislation  should  move  toward  the  following 
goals.  First,  entry  and  exit  restrictions  should  be  greatly  liberalized.  Second,  rate 
flexibility  should  be  introduced  through  a  phased  process,  perhaps  initially  using 
a  zone  of  reasonableness.  Regulatory  intrusion  with  regard  to  rates  within  that 
zone  would  not  be  permitted.  Finally,  existing  antitrust  immunities  should  be 
removed,  along  the  lines  suggested  earlier  in  this  statement. 

There  is  a  broad  consensus  that  reform  must  proceed  along  all  three  of  *^hese 
fronts.  The  Administration  has  thus  concluded  that  it  would  be  appropriate  to 


Order  74-3-82,  p.  72  (March  18,  1974). 


56 

move  toward  much  more  reliance  upon  competition  in  the  air  transportation  in- 
dustry, and  much  less  reliance  upon  government  economic  regulation.  We  expect 
to  present  specific  legislative  proposals  within  a  short  time  to  the  Congress,  and 
specifically  to  this  Committee. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  James  Miller,  currently  senior  staff  econ- 
omist for  the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  received  his  Ph.  D.  from 
the  University  of  Virginia  in  economics,  formerly  served  on  the  senior 
staff  for  the  Republican  Party  from  1969  to  1972.  In  1973-74  he  was 
an  assistant  associate  professor,  now  on  leave;  he  edited  a  number  of 
books,  including  economic  regulation  of  domestic  air  transport.  We 
also  received  a  statement  from  his  coauthor,  Mr.  George  Douglas 
which  we  will  make  a  part  of  the  record. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  George  Douglas,  professor  of  economics. 
University  of  Texas,  is  included  at  the  end  of  the  testimony  of  this 
day  (February  6,  1975),  p.  437,  below.] 

STATEMENT  OF  MR.  JAMES  MILLER,  SENIOR  STAFF  ECONOMIST, 
COUNCIL   OF   ECONOMIC   ADVISERS 

Mr.  Miller.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Chairman,  we  have  a  prepared  statement  that  I  ask  be  inserted 
into  the  record.  Mr.  Seevers  is  unable  to  be  here  and  sends  his  regrets. 
As  you  know,  today  the  Joint  Economic  Committee  is  hearing  testi- 
mony by  the  full  Council  on  the  economic  report. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  where  I  am  supposed  to  be,  too. 

Mr.  Miller.  In  our  testimony  we  deal  basically  with  three  issues. 
The  first  is  the  cost  of  airline  regulation.  The  second  is  the  efficiency 
of  a  hypothetical  totallj^  deregulated  market.  Finally,  we  outline,  as 
Messrs.  Barnum  and  Kauper  did,  the  kinds  of  proposals  the  admini- 
stration is  presently  discussing  in  formulating  a  legislative  package. 

On  several  occasions  this  morning,  questions  have  arisen  about  as- 
pects of  less  regulated  or  totally  deregulated  markets  that  many  people 
question.  We  deal  with  several  of  these  in  the  testimony.  I  would  like 
to  briefly  respond  here. 

SAFETY    AND    COMPETITION 

First,  on  the  question  of  safety,  the  Federal  Aviation  Administra- 
tion is  the  governmental  instrumentality  charged  with  regulation  of 
safety  in  the  airlines.  On  the  basis  of  theory  and  evidence,  there  is 
a  lot  of  question  the  allegation  that  economic  regulation  is  needed  to 
assure  safety  of  operations.  As  mentioned  in  the  testimony,  we  per- 
formed such  a  test  on  data  and  found  that  while  the  results  were 
statistically  insignificant,  meaning  that  regulation  had  no  effect  on 
safety,  the  nature  of  the  result  actualy  give  an  appearance  of  a  positive 
relationship  between  air  fatality  rates  and  the  airlines'  rate  of  return 
on  investment. 

I  agree  that  in  formulating  any  kind  of  regulatory  reform  measure 
one  should  be  very  cognizant  of  the  safety  issue,  but  I  do  not  believe 
economic  regulation  is  the  appropriate  means  of  assuring  air  safety. 


^      57 

SMALL-TOWN   SERVICE    (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Second,  with  respect  to  question  of  small  communities'  losing  air 
service  because  of  regulatory  reform,  this  first  presumes  that  there  is 
a  lot  of  cross-subsidy  going  on.  The  work  I  accomplished  with  my 
coauthor,  George  Douglas,  indicates  that  the  amount  of  cross-subsidy 
is  grossly  overstated.  Professor  George  Iliads  who  is  scheduled  to 
testify  later,  will  probably  have  some  additional  remarks  on  this  issue. 
We  have  also  observed  that  commuter  airlines  have  replaced  trunk  and 
local  service  carriers  quite  successfully.  We  have  no  reason  to  believe 
that  with  less  regulation  their  effectiveness  would  be  diminished. 

RELATIONSHIP    BETWEEN    FARE    AND    ROUTE    ENTRY    FLEXIBILITY 

The  question  of  pricing  flexibility  hinges  very  much  on  the  question 
of  entry.  On  the  low  side,  as  long  as  entry  is  relatively  free,  the  carrier 
which  is  trying  to  predatorily  jDrice  one  of  its  competitors  out  of  the 
market  stands  nothing  to  gain,  because  as  soon  as  it  runs  the  last  one 
out,  it  has  to  confront  the  possibility  of  a  new  entry.  On  the  high  side, 
it  is  again  important  that  entry  be  relatively  free.  A  carrier  wishing 
to  charge  excessively  high  fares  would  be  restrained  from  doing  so  be- 
cause of  the  threat  of  entry. 

On  fly-by-night  operators,  even  if  you  had  less  economic  regulation, 
you  would  still  have  the  constraints  of  safety  regulation.  This  would 
mean  that  such  operators  would  have  to  meet  safety  standards.  They 
might  by  fly-by-night  in  the  sense  of  going  in  the  market  and  leaving 
the  market  in  a  very  short  period  of  time,  but  I  do  not  see  what  real 
damage  that  would  do  to  the  consumer. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  suppose  the  damage  to  the  consumer  is  unre- 
liability. Here  is  one  carrier  in  the  market  one  day  making  his  reser- 
vations and  plans,  and  the  carrier  is  out  of  the  market  the  next. 

Mr.  Miller.  Senator,  I  do  not  think  we  should  underestimate  the 
value  of  a  reputation  in  something  like  tliis.  The  carrier  which  is  new 
to  the  market  will  be  viewed  skeptically.  It  is  through  trustworthy 
service  that  a  carrier  generates  new  traffic. 

NEED    FOR    LEGISLATION 

I  would  like  to  make  a  final  remark  about  the  issue  of  CAB  discre- 
tion. I  think  it  is  true  that  the  CAB  could  promulgate  many  of  the 
reforms  that  we  have  talked  about  this  morning  through  the  existing 
statute.  However,  I  do  not  think  it  will  do  so,  and  I  think  the  evidence 
of  regulation  in  the  past  is  a  very  forceful  argument  to  make  us 
skeptical  about  their  being  willing  to  move  forward  with  this  kind  of 
reform  in  the  future. 

Senator  Kennedy.  AVhy  is  that? 

Mr.  Miller.  I  think  incentives  the  regulator  faces  are  not  generally 
consistent  with  economic  efficiency.  I  think  the  statute  itself — for 
example,  the  declaration  of  policy,  section  102 — is  drawn  in  such  a  way 
as  to  give  emphasis  to  a  lot  of  different  conflicting  objectives.  A  regula- 
tor who  does  not  want  to  be  concerned  with  efficiency  can  find  an  eas}'^ 
excuse  for  not  doing  so. 


58 

Also,  as  a  matter  of  procedure,  even  if  you  had  a  compromising 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  five  economists  whose  sole  objective  was 
to  maximize  economic  efficiency,  to  the  extent  they  would  be  changing 
precedent  and  moving  in  very  new  directions,  I  would  imagine  there 
would  be  a  significant  protest  of  such  activity.  I  am  not  an  expert  on 
law,  but  I  am  not  confident  this  kind  of  activity  would  survive  court 
tests. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let  me  just  ask  you  from  the  point  of  view  of 
the  Council  whether  you  feel  from  that  vantage  point  that  the  idea  of 
greater  competition  in  terms  of  rates  and  entry  would  be  beneficial 
from  an  overall  economic  point  of  view  for  our  economy  or  from  the 
consumer  point  of  view. 

Mr.  Miller.  I  think  it  is  the  major  objective  of  the  Council  to  rec- 
ommend policies  or  present  analyses  which  focus  on  economic  efficiency 
questions  as  they  pertain  to  regulation  and  other  types  of  governmental 
controls.  This,  of  course,  counts  the  consumer  to  a  very  large  measure. 
After  all.  Senator,  the  ultimate  objective  of  production  is  consumption. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Could  you  develop  your  thoughts  briefly  on  the 
question  of  cross-subsidization.  Then  secondly,  it  is  really  an  unrelated 
question,  with  this  proliferation  of  new  airlines  and  different  prices, 
how  will  the  consumer  know  w^here  to  go  to  get  a  ticket,  will  we  have 
mass  confusion  or  do  you  think  this  is  a  manageable  problem  Would 
you  talk  on  those  two  questions  ? 

CHAOS 

Mr.  Miller,  I  will  be  glad  to.  Let  me  take  the  latter  first.  Informa- 
tion is  a  scarce  resource,  and  when  consumers  know  a  producer  charges 
a  specific  rate,  and  these  rates  are  not  likely  to  be  changed,  the  pro- 
ducer's reputation  is  enhanced.  Consumers  find  out  this  information; 
producers  advertise  as  well.  In  a  freely  competitive  airline  market, 
consumers  would  learn  the  prices  that  are  charged  and  the  carriers  that 
provide  good  service — the  same  way  as  in  existing  competitive,  un- 
regulated markets. 

CROSS-SUBSIDY     (SMALL    TOWN    SERVICE) 

NoAv,  on  the  question  of  cross-subsidy,  we  essentially  model  the  air- 
lines in  the  following  way  :  Because  there  is  a  lot  of  competition  today^ — 
most  markets  are  served  by  two  or  more  carriers — the  Board  is  really 
in  the  business  of  setting  the  quality  of  service.  They  set  the  price  and 
carriers  compete  on  the  frequency  of  schedules  and  other  means  so 
as  to  bring  the  cost  level  up  to  the  price  level.  For  example,  transcon- 
tinental markets  were  referred  to  a  few  minutes  ago  where  the  prices 
are  such  that  carriere  can  break  even  at  40  to  45  percent  load  factors. 
Carriers  do,  in  fact,  schedule  up  to  the  point  where  they  are  breaking 
even  at  those  load  factors.  If  the  Board  lowered  the  price,  then  the 
carriers'  break  even  point  would  be  higher.  They  would  restrict  sched- 
uling. This  would  drive  up  load  factors.  So  in  these  markets  the 
carriers  are  earning  neither  excess  profit  nor  losses. 

On  short-haul  markets  where  the  fare  taper  is  such  that  the  price — 
vis-a-vis  the  cost  of  a  constant  load  factor  service — is  too  low,  the  car- 
riers simply  cut  back  on  scheduling  and  provide  fairly  poor  service. 


Again,  in  these  markets  the  carriers  tend  to  earn  neither  excess  profits 
nor  losses. 

So  our  general  conclusion,  based  on  this  and  additional  information, 
is  that  there  is  not  much  cross-subsidy  actually  taking  place. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Very  fine.  Thank  you  very  much. 

[The  prepared  statement  submitted  by  Mr.  Miller  for  himself  and 
Mr.  Seevers  follows :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Gary  L.  Seevers,  Member,  Council  of  Economic 
Advisers  and  James  C.  Milleik,  Senior  Staff  Economist 

Economic  Effects  of  Regulation  of  the  Domestic  Air  Carriers  by  the  CAB 

Mr.  Chairman,  members  of  the  Committee :  We  are  pleased  to  appear  before  you 
today  to  discuss  the  economic  effects  of  regulation  of  the  domestic  air  carriers  by 
the  U.S.  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

For  a  number  of  years  the  Council  has  questioned  the  efficacy  of  airline  regula- 
tion and  suggested  certain  reforms.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  our  most  recent  eco- 
nomic report,*  published  just  two  days  ago,  contains  a  section  which  discusses 
airline  regulation  and  which  implies  that  certain  reforms  are  needed.  A  copy  of 
that  section  of  the  report  is  attached  as  an  appendix  to  this  testimony. 

In  the  remainder  of  this  testimony  we  outline  what  we  consider  to  be  the 
major  costs  of  CAB  regulation,  we  examine  the  economic  performance  of  a 
hypothetical  deregulated  air  carrier  market,  and  we  indicate  the  kinds  of 
regulatory  reforms  the  Administration  now  has  under  review. 

The  Costs  of  Airline  Regulation 

As  they  pertain  to  the  airlines,  economic  conditions  today  are  very  much 
different  from  what  they  were  in  1938,  when  airline  regulation  was  established. 
At  that  time,  the  U.S.  Government  was  attempting  to  promote  an  "infant"  in- 
dustry through  an  inefficient  system  of  airmail  subsidy.  Basically,  the  Govern- 
ment granted  contracts  to  air  carriers  and  prevented  competition  on  those 
routes  where  contracts  were  granted.  Recognizing  the  potential  for  excess  profits 
on  passenger  services  then  or  in  the  future,  carriers  would  "buy-in"  on  these 
contracts  for  extremely  low  rates.^  This  perfectly  rational  economic  behavior  on 
the  part  of  the  air  carrier  firms  was  then  cited  as  evidence  of  "destructive 
competition"  in  the  airline  industry  and  thus  a  need  for  governmental  interven- 
tion to  "rationalize"  competition."  It  was  also  said  that  governmental  controls 
were  needed  to  assure  safety  of  operations. 

Today,  the  domestic  airline  industry  is  no  longer  an  infant  industry  in  need 
of  promotion ;  having  increased  in  size  since  1938  some  250-fold,  by  most  stand- 
ards it  is  now  truly  "mature".  Mail  contracts  are  no  longer  the  vehicle  for  sub- 
sidy, and  as  a  percent  of  total  domestic  revenue  subsidy  has  declined  from 
31.6  percent  in  1939  to  less  than  1  percent  today.  Except  for  minor  payments  to 
Northeast  Airlines  in  the  mid-1960's,  the  trunk  carriers  have  been  completely 
off  subsidy  since  1959."  Air  safety,  which  until  1958  was  a  primary  CAB  con- 
cern, is  now  vested  with  the  Federal  Aviation  Administration  of  the  Department 
of  Transportation  (DOT)." 

Another  important  change  in  the  nature  of  the  industry  and  its  regulation  is 
that  the  principal  city-pair  markets  today  are  served  by  two  or  more  airlines.^ 


*  Economic  Report  of  the  President,  Washington,  GPO,  February  4,  1975. 

'  See  Richard  E.  Caves,  Air  Transport  and  Its  Regulators  :  An  Industry  Study.  Cam- 
brldpe.  Harvard  I'niversity  I'ress,  1962,  p.  124. 

-  Note  that  the  lesi.slative  "Declaration  of  Policy"  admonishes  the  Board  to  create 
"Competition  [only?]  to  the  extent  necessary  to  assure  the  sound  development  of  an  air- 
transportation  system  .  .  ."  [OrlRlnal  (1938)  language  now  contained  as  section  ia2(d) 
of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as  amended.] 

''  For  a  discussion  of  the  existing  subsidy  mechanism  and  its  deficiencies,  see  George  C. 
Ends,  The  Local  Service  Airlines  Experiment,  Washington,  The  Brookings  Institution, 
1972. 

*  Responsibility  for  investigating  air  accidents  was  transferred  from  the  CAB  to  the 
National  Transportation  Safetv  Board  in  igoO. 

■5  Note  that  from  1955  to  1971  the  percentage  of  total  revenue  pa.ssenger  miles  attributed 
to  markets  where  2  or  more  carriers  eacli  accounted  for  at  least  10  percent  of  the  market 
rose  from  55.6  percent  to  76.6  percent.  Sec,  George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C.  Miller  III, 
Economic  Regulation  of  Domrxtic  Air  Transiiort:  Theory  and  Policy,  Washington,  The 
Brooklnga  Institution,  1974,  p.  114. 


60 

Thus,  in  addition  to  no  longer  regulating  so  as  to  promote  an  infant  industry 
and  no  longer  regulating  air  safety,  the  Board  finds  itself  no  longer  preoccupied 
with  regulating  monopoly.  Instead,  its  primary  activity  is  regulating  comi)etition. 
But  under  CAB  regulation  this  competition  is  of  a  rather  special  sort :  It  is  mani- 
fest almost  totally  in  dimensions  other  than  price. 

A  potential  price-cutter  in  a  CAB-regulated  market  faces  significant  costs  in 
carrying  out  such  an  initiative.  First,  the  carrier  must  announce  the  new  rate  at 
least  30  days  in  advance,  thereby  alerting  its  competition  to  the  intended  action.' 
Second,  there  is  the  simple  cost  of  publishing  the  new  tariff  with  the  Board,  as 
legally  required.  Third,  any  fare  decrease  is  likely  to  be  protested  by  competitors 
as  being  unreasonably  low,  discriminatory,  preferential,  prejudicial,  or  simply 
an  instance  of  "unfair  competition."  Thus,  the  price-cutter  nearly  always  must 
make  an  affirmative  case  before  the  Board  that  the  new  rate  is  justified,  and 
this,  of  course,  costs  money. 

The  new  rate  may  be  rejected  outright  or  set  down  for  investigation.  If  it  is 
rejected,  then  of  course  any  advertising  by  the  carrier  about  the  prospective 
lower  rates  is  lost,  and  perhaps  on  balance  creates  ill  will  because  the  carrier 
is  unable  to  deliver.  If  the  rate  is  suspended,  the  carrier  may  either  withdraw 
the  initiative  or  pursue  it  further.  If  the  rate  reduction  is  pursued,  then  signifi- 
cant procedural  costs  must  be  absorbed  by  the  initiating  carrier  as  the  rate 
travels  through  various  steps :  prehearing  conference,  hearing,  briefs  to  the 
Administrative  Law  Judge,  possibly  briefs  to  the  full  Board,  oral  argument,  and 
possibly,  in  the  end,  even  court  challenges. 

Because  of  these  impediments,  one  observes  little  price  competition  in  the  air- 
lines. When  rates  are  lowered  they  are  usually  done  so  in  the  interest  of  the 
whole  industry,  as  for  example,  introducing  discount  fares  to  enlarge  total  rev- 
enues and  to  make  the  airlines  more  effective  in  competing  with  other  modes  of 
common-carrier  transportation,  such  as  intercity  buses.  Another  ramification 
of  this  constraint  system  is  that  from  the  standpoint  of  an  individual  airline 
it  makes  little  sense  to  change  the  rate  in  just  one  market.  In  an  attempt  to 
"spread  the  cost,"  airlines  which  propose  rate  reductions  usually  do  so  on  fairly 
large  chunks  of  traffic,  although  such  a  strategy  inevitably  reduces  the  likeli- 
hood of  ultimate  approval  by  the  Board  and  of  course  raises  litigation  costs. 

The  Board's  statutory  authority  to  control  price  and  its  procedures  for  imple- 
menting that  control  thus  have  rendered  price  competition  in  the  airlines  all  but 
non-existent.  On  the  other  hand,  there  are  other  means  that  carriers  have  for 
attracting  and  competing  for  passengers  over  which  the  Board  exercises  little 
or  no  direct  control.  Such  non-price  competition  takes  various  forms,  including 
costlier  meals,  "free"  drinks,  expensive  advertising,  flashy  interior  and  exterior 
color  schemes,  "VIP"  airport  lounges,  on-board  lounges,  pianos,  bars,  and  the 
like.  But  much  more  important,  in  terms  of  its  ultimate  cost  to  the  consumer, 
is  the  scheduling  form  of  non-price  competition.  As  will  be  discussed  below, 
scheduling  additional  flights  is  the  most  effective  means  that  individual  carriers 
have  of  attracting  additional  pas.sengers.  Notably,  except  for  its  power  to  grant 
antitrust  immunity  and  to  orchestrate  capacity  agreements  among  carriers,  the 
Board  is  prohibited  from  controlling  schedule  competition. '^ 

For  any  price  that  is  approved  or,  in  essence,  "set"  by  the  Board,  the  market 
has  a  "break-even"  load  factor,  which  we  define  so  as  to  include  a  normal  return 
on  investment.*  If  actual  load  factors  are  below  the  break-even  level,  the  carriers 
will  be  earning  less  than  a  normal  profit,  or  even  accounting  los.ses  and  will  cut 
back  on  capacity.  Since  market  demand  is  inelastic  with  respect  to  capacity,* 
load  factors  will  rise,  and  the  process  of  capacity  curtailment  will  continue 
until  actual  load  factors  have  risen  to  the  break-even  level,  at  which  point  the 
incentive  to  reduce  capacity  unilaterally  will  disappear."  On  the  other  hand,  if 
actual  load  factors  exceed  the  break-even  level,  individual  airlines  have  profit 
incentives  to  increase  capacity.  Actual  load  factors  will  fall  and  the  process  will 


s  Thus,  there  is  no  such  thing  as  a  conventional  "sale"  in  the  airline  business. 

''Section  401(e)(4)  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  states  that,  "No  term,  condition,  or 
limitation  of  a  certificate  shall  restrict  the  right  of  an  air  carrier  to  add  or  change 
schedules  ..." 

8  "Load  factor"  is  the  proportion  of  seats  filled,  usually  expressed  as  a  percentage. 

8  That  is,  the  percentage  change  in  total  traffic  in  the  market  is  less  than  the  percentage 
change  in  the  marl^et's  total  capacity. 

1°  Short  of  the  break-even  load  factor  an  individual  carrier  can  safety  assume  that  It 
reduces  capacity  its  competitors  will  also.  However,  once  equilibrium  has  been  renched, 
a  carrier  reducing  capacity  unilaterally  may  not  assume  that  its  competitors  will  do 
likewise. 


61 


continue  until  capacity  increases  have  reduced  actual  load  factors  to  break-even, 
at  which  point  there  is  no  more  incentive  to  add  to  capacity .^^ 

An  extremely  important  aspect  of  this  non-price  competition  is  that  there 
is  a  whole  range  of  prices  which  the  Board  may  choose  and  still  enable  com- 
petitive returns  to  the  individual  carriers,  or  at  least  to  the  carriers  as  a  group. 
If  the  Board  chooses  a  "high"  price,  the  break-even  load  factor  will  be  "low" 
and,  in  equilibrium,  so  will  be  the  actual  load  factor.  If  the  Board  chooses  a 
"low"  price,  the  break-even  load  factor  will  be  "high"  and,  in  equilibrium,  so 
will  the  actual  load  factor.  The  nature  of  this  trade-off  between  fare  and  average 
load  factor  is  displayed  in  figure  1." 


ATenge  Load  Tiaetor  (Psreent) 


(l)reak-«vea) 


100 


Figure  1 
(For  iUustratlon  purposes  ooly;  not  drava  to  sealv. ) 


"  When  market  load  factors  are  above  break-even,  an  individual  carrier  can  make 
more  profit  by  expanding  its  own  capacity  provided  other  carriers  do  not  also  expand  their 
capacity.  The  evidence  suggests  that  cnrriers  act  as  though  they  make  such  an  assumption. 
A  variant  explanation  of  observed  behavior  is  that  since  an  individual  carrier  may  not 
assume  that  its  competitors  will  not  increase  their  capacity  it  must  increase  its  capacity 
just  to  maintain  its  market  share.  In  any  event,  when  the  break-even  load  factor  is  reached, 
there  is  no  incentive  to  increase  capacity,  since  the  market  load  factor  will  fall  below 
break-even  and  each  carrier  may  assume  that  its  competitors  will  follow  a  policy  of 
restraint. 

For  a  more  thorough  description  of  this  nonprlce-competing  behavior  and  evidence  on 
same,  see  Douglas  and  Miller,  ibid.,  chapter  4  and  the  papers  cited  therein  by  De  Vany, 
Douglas,  Miller,  Straszheim,  Yance,  Barnekov,  Eads,  Milward,  and  White.  For  an  em- 
pirical analysis  of  the  relationship  between  market  shares  and  capacity  shares,  see  James  C. 
Miller  III,  "Airline  Market  Shares  vs.  Capacity  Shares  and  the  Possibility  of  Loss 
Kquilibria"  (processed,  1974)  and  CAB  Docket  22908  (Capacity  Reduction  Agreements 
Casel   DOT-T-1  through  ,5   (1974). 

^-  Notably,  the  Board  would  appear  to  have  accepted  this  model  of  regulated-carrier 
behnvior.  In  a  decision  in  its  recent  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation  (CAB  Docket 
21866),  the  Board  said  : 

"We  find  .  .  .  that  the  higlier  the  fare  level  in  relation  to  cost,  the  more  capacity  carriers 
will  offer  and  the  lower  load  factors  will  be  :  and,  conversely,  the  lower  the  fare  level,  the 
less  capacity  carriers  will  operate  and  the  higher  load  factors  will  be."  [CAB  Order  71- 
4-54  (April  9,  19710,  p.  23.] 


62 

Over  a  fairly  wide  range  of  prices,  carriers,  in  equilibrium,  will  earn  normal 
profits — and  thus,  arguably,  the  choice  of  price  is  not  material  to  them.  How- 
ever, the  passenger's  cost  of  service  is  greatly  dependent  upon  the  price  and  load 
factor  option  chosen  by  the  Board.  In  esssence,  the  passenger's  "full  cost" 
of  travel  is  the  ticket  price  plus  the  "cost"  of  delays  he,  or  she,  incurs  in  waiting 
for  a  flight.  We  see  in  figure  1  the  rather  obvious  proposition  that  as  the  average 
load  factor  rises  the  associated  break-even  fare  falls.  If  this  were  the  only 
element  in  the  passenger's  cost  of  service,  public  policy  would  dictate  a  fare 
consistent  with  load  factors  of  near  100  percent.  However,  as  load  factor  falls 
delay  cost  increases.  Passengers  find  it  more  diificult  to  secure  accommodations 
on  the  desired  departure  and  flights  are  fewer,  with  more  time  in  between 
departures.  When  translated  into  money  terms  this  delay  cost  is  as  characterized 
in  figure  1.  The  passenger's  full  cost  of  service  is  thus  the  sum  of  these  two 
types  of  cost,  i.e.,  ticket  price  plus  delay,  and,  given  these  two  curves,  for  some 
average  load  factor  level  the  "full  cost"  is  at  a  minimum,  i.e.,  ALF. 

A  recent  Brookings  publication  by  Professors  Douglas  and  Miller  came  to  the 
conclusion  that  the  Board  has  chosen  too  low  a  load  factor  standard,  i.e.,  55  per- 
cent as  opposed  to  60-65  percent,  and  consequently  is  promulgating  fares  which 
are  too  high."  This  means  that  the  typical  passenger  is  paying  an  "excess  fare" 
which  exceeds  the  value  of  the  reduction  in  delay.  This  in  turn  means  a  higher 
full  cost  of  service  with  no  offsetting  higher  profits  to  carrier.  Thus,  there  is  regu- 
lation-induced excess  capacity  which  represents  a  deadweight  loss  to  society." 
Douglas  and  Miller  estimate  that  during  1969  air  passengers  paid  excess  fares  to 
domestic  trunk  carriers  ranging  between  $366  million  and  $538  million,  for 
which  they  received  quality  improvements  valued  at  between  $118  million  and 
$182  million.  This  leaves  a  deadweight  welfare  loss  in  trunkline  service  for  1969 
of  between  $248  million  and  $356  million.'^ 

Since  1969  the  Board  has  established  target  load  factors  of  55  percent  as 
opposed  to  the  then-prevailing  levels  of  approximately  50  percent.  However,  the 
recent  increases  in  fuel  prices  have  raised  the  optimal  average  load  factor  to 
approximately  65-70  percent,  so  the  present  configuration  of  service  is  still 
characterized  by  efficiency  costs  on  the  same  order  of  magnitude.  Based  on  total 
domestic  trunk  revenues  of  $9,316  million  for  the  year  ending  September  1973, 
this  implies  a  current  annual  welfare  cost  for  trunk  service  ranging  between 
$355  million  and  $509  million. 

There  are  additional  costs  of  airline  regulation.  First,  there  is  evidence  that 
the  relationship  between  the  Board  and  the  industry  has  resulted  in  a  level,  and 
structure,  of  fares  which  maximizes  total  capacity  rather  than  one  which  maxi- 
mizes total  passenger  traffic."  This  is  illustrated  in  figure  2."  Since  some  costs  are 
"external"  to  the  airlines  and  their  passengers,  this  behavior  has  quite  likely 
resulted  in  excessive  investments  in  airport  and  airway  facilities  as  well  as 
excessive  consumption  of  fuel. 

Second,  the  Board's  policy  of  protecting  existing  carriers  from  competition  by 
preventing  the  entry  of  new  carriers  ^*  not  only  means  that  the  public  has  been  de- 
nied lower  price-quality  options,  but  that  potentially  more  efficient  carriers  have 
not  been  able  to  test  the  efficiency  of  existing  carriers.  Whether  new  carriers 
would  have  significantly  lower  costs  is  subject  to  considerable  debate,  but  evi- 
dence on  relative  carrier  costs  and  the  evidence  from  unregulated  markets  cer- 
tainly raises  this  possibility.^*  There  are  two  significant  problems  with  this  ap- 
proach, however.  First,  a  regulator  is  inherently  less  capable  of  administering 
resources  "correctly"  than  is  an  individual  competitive  entrepreneur.  The  regu- 


"  In  the  DPFI  the  Board  announced  its  intention  of  in  effect  setting  fares  at  levels 
which  would  cover  costs  (plus  a  reasonable  return  on  investment)  on  the  basis  of  an 
industry-wide  average  load  factor  of  55  percent. 

i*The  analysis  only  briefly  summarized  here  can  be  found  in  Douglas  and  Miller,  ibid., 
chapter  6. 

'5  Miller  and  Douglas,  ibid.,  p.  172. 

i«  See  Arthur  S.  De  Vanv,  "Effects  of  Price  and  Entry  Regulation  on  Airline  Output, 
Capacity  and  Efficiency,"  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management  Science,  (forth- 
coming Spring  1975;  and  Douglas  and  .Miller,  ibid.,  pp.  60  and  176-77. 

"Rather  than  choosing  fare  level  F*,  the  Board  has  chosen  fare  level  F**.  Figure  2  is 
adapted  from  De  Vany,  ibid. 

18  Since  regulation  w.ns  established  in  1938.  not  a  single  new  trunk  carrier  has  entered 
the  market,  and  not  a  single  trunk  has  exited  the  market  except  through  merger. 

19  See  Robert  J.  Gordon,  ".\irline  Costs  and  Managerial  Efficiency"  in  Transportation 
Economics  :  .\  Conference,  Columbia  Universitv  Press  for  the  National  Bureau  of  Economic 
Research,  1965,  pp.  61-94  ;  Theodore  E.  Keeler,  "Airline  Regulation  and  Market  I'erform- 
ance,"  Bell  Journal  of  Economics  and  Management  Science,  Autumn  1972,  pp.  ,'?99-424  ; 
William  A.  Jordan,  Airline  Regulation  in  America  :  Effects  and  Imperfections,  Bnltimore, 
The  Johns  Hopkins  Press,  1970,  chapter  11  ;  and  Douglas  and  Miller,  ibid.,  pp.  141-9. 


63 


Aure  Linrel 


Figure  2 
(Tar  illttstratioD  porpoaet  ooJor;  aot  drawn  to  scale. ) 

lator  neither  has  information  as  good  as  that  of  the  entrepreneur  nor  does  he, 
or  she,  have  the  appropriate  incentives.  Second,  in  terms  of  fact  versus  theory, 
the  performance  of  the  existing  regulatory  agencies  causes  one  to  be  extremely 
skeptical  of  achieving  good  industry  performance  by  relying  upon  regulation. 


ECONOMIC   EFFICIENCY   OF   DEREGULATED    MARKETS 

Costs  of  regulation  such  as  those  described  above  implicitly  assume  some 
alternative,  usually  and  ideally,  efficient  markets.  In  real  life,  critics  of  regula- 
tion must  be  careful  to  identify  realistic  alternatives.  Two  such  alternatives  im- 
mediately come  to  mind:  (a)  "enlightened"  regulation,  and  (b)  total  deregula- 
tion. On  the  one  hand,  it  is  entirely  possible  that  a  truly  enlightened  regulator 
could  eliminate  most  of  the  costs  described  above.  For  example,  in  an  ideal  set- 
ting the  CAB  could  adopt  target  load  factors  by  market  characteristic  and  ac- 
cordingly, by  regulating  fares,  eliminate  the  costs  of  "excess  capacity." 

At  the  other  extreme  is  the  hypothetical,  completely  deregulated,  competitive 
market.^  The  theoretical  argument  for  the  eflBciency  of  deregulated  airline  mar- 
kets is  extremely  powerful.  The  airline  industry  appears  to  conform  closely  to 
the  necessary  conditions  for  price  competition :  no  significant  scale  economies,^ 
fairly  elastic  or  firm  demand,  relative  difficulty  of  coordinating  pricing  and  output 
policies  i.e.,  collusion,  and,  in  the  absence  of  controls,  relative  ease  of  entry  and 
exit. 


=0  For  this  di-scussion,  by  the  term  "deregulation"  and  its  derivatives  we  mean  the  elimi- 
nation of  economic  regulation  only,   not  the  elimination  of  s-^fety  regulation. 

^  On  the  question  of  scale  economies  see  Douglas  and  Miller,  ibid.,  pp.  13-18  and  the 
sources  cited  therein. 


64 

Finally,  there  are  numerous  regulator-imposed  constraints  on  routings  and 
service  requirements  which  serve  to  raise  costs."'  To  our  knowledge  a  precise  esti- 
mate of  all  these  costs  has  not  been  made.  In  our  judgment  this  figure  would  be 
in  the  neighborhood  of  $1  billion  per  year,  or  around  10  percent  of  total  domestic 
trunkline  revenues.-^ 

Looking  at  the  question  of  optimal  price  and  load  factor,  with  fare  flexibility, 
a  carrier  would  have  an  alternative  means  of  attracting  additional  passengers : 
lowering  price.  The  carrier  could  then  judge  the  most  effective  way  of  attracting 
business :  lowering  price  or  providing  more  service.  The  result  would  be  the  ap- 
propriate market  combination  of  price  and  quality.  Moreover,  in  some  markets 
there  may  well  be  a  distribution  of  price  and  quality  combinations  that  is  de- 
sired by  the  public.-*  Free  markets  provide  incentives  for  this  configuration  to 
come  about. 

Under  conditions  of  free  entry  and  free  exit,  firms  would  have  to  stand  a  more 
substantive  "market  test"  of  their  efliciency.  More  efficient  firms  would  survive, 
and  inefficient  firms  would  be  forced  to  exit.  The  removal  of  restrictions  on  rout- 
ings w^ould  result  in  lower  costs  to  consumers,  and  uneconomical  markets  would 
be  abandoned.  There  might  well  be  some  "market  imperfections,"  -°  but  in  eco- 
nomic efficiency  terms  these  would  probably  be  fairly  minor. 

Of  course,  we  would  like  to  rely  upon  facts  concerning  deregulated  markets  as 
well  as  upon  theory.  Unfortunately,  we  do  not  have  ideal  tests  of  deregulation 
since  the  CAB  has  preempted  truly  comparable  experiments.  However,  we  do 
have  two  deregulated  markets  that  are  similar  in  many  respects  to  CAB-regulated 
markets,  except,  of  course,  for  differences  in  the  degree  of  regulation. 

First,  we  have  the  intrastate  markets,  which  are  outside  CAB  jurisdiction. 
Prior  to  1965,  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission  regulated  maximum 
prices  in  intrastate  air  service,  but  not  entry  and  exit.""  Professor  William  A. 
Jordan  has  made  an  extensive  study  of  the  history  and  economic  character  of 
this  market  and  has  concluded  that  in  virtually  all  respects  the  California  intra- 
state airline  market  is  much  more  efficient  than  comparable  interstate  CAB- 
regulated  markets."  Even  today,  with  tighter  regulation,  fares  in  California  intra- 
state markets  average  much  less  than  fares  in  comparable  interstate  markets. 

A  similar  result  was  obtained  in  the  Texas  intrastate  market,  where  Southwest 
Airlines,  a  carrier  licensed  by  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission,  is  in  compe- 
tition with  BranifE  Airways,  a  CAB-regulated  trunk  carrier,  and  Texas  Inter- 
national Airways,  a  CAB-regulated  local  service  carrier.  Despite  having  its 
service  introduction  postponed  nearly  four  years  because  of  judicial  challenges  by 
Braniff  and  Texas  International,  the  carrier  is  now  serving  the  "golden  triangle" 
(Dallas,  Austin,  and  Houston)  at  a  profit,  charging  fares  which  average  some 
20  to  50  percent  less  than  comparable  CAB-regulated  fares. 

The  other  major  unregulated  market  is  that  of  commuter  airlines,  previously 
known  as  air  taxis.  In  1952,  faced  with  doing  something  about  a  plethora  of 
illegal  interstate  air  taxi  operations,  the  Board  simply  exempted  from  regulation  ^ 
any  interstate  air  carrier  which  utilized  aircraft  having  no  more  than  12,500 
pounds  gross  take-off  weight.^  At  that  time  it  was  thought  that  no  operator  could 
provide  profitable  scheduled  operations  with  such  small  aircraft.  Subsequently, 
however,  technology  changed,  and  equipment  of  this  w^eight  is  now  capable  of 
carrying  up  to  19  passengers  at  reasonable  comfort  and  speed  and  at  relatively 
low  cost.  Today  there  are  literally  hundreds  of  such  operators  which  provide 
regularly-scheduled  service  to  low-density  markets — and  in  some  higher-density 


22  Some  of  these  have  been  instituted  to  assure  service  to  points  that  the  Incumbent 
carrier  might  not  ordinarily  serve.  To  some  extent,  then,  such  costs  are  revealing  of  the 
resource  costs  of  pursuing  certain  social  "non-economic"  objectives. 

23  Note  that  these  losses  are  not  simply  transfers  from  consumers  to  producers  or  from 
consumers  to  consumers.   They  represent  the  economic  cost  of  squandered  resources. 

2*  For  example,  a  low  load  factor,  low-density,  high-amenity,  high-priced  service  cater- 
ing to  business  travelers,  and  a  low-cost,  no-frills  service  catering  to  the  vacation  traveler. 
At  present  such  specialization  is  limited — another  cost  of  regulation. 

25  These  include:  (a)  collusion  over  prices  and/or  service,  (b)  quasi-monopoly  service  in 
marginal  niarlvcts.  and  (c)  inefficient  mixes  of  aircraft  and  frequencies.  On  the  latter 
point,  see  George  W.  Douglas,  "Equilibrium  in  a  Deregulated  Air  Transport  Market,"  paper 
delivered  at  a  seminar  on  Problems  of  Regulation  and  Public  Utilities,  Dartmouth  College, 
1972.  processed. 

2«  Since  then  control  over  entry  and  exit  has  been  instituted. 

2'  .Jordan,  ibid.  Also  see  Bureau  of  Accounts  and  Statistics.  "Traffic,  Fares,  and  Competi- 
tion :  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  Air  Travel  Corridor",  Washington,  U.S.  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board,  1965. 

28  Under  section  416(b)  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act. 

29  That  standard  was  recently  changed  to  a  30-passenger  capacity  and  a  net  payload  of 
no  more  than  7,500  pounds. 


65 

markets,  often  in  direct  competition  with  trunk  and  local  service  carriers  Since 
with  tew  exceptions  these  carriers  receive  no  government  subsidy,  and  since  they 
are  handieappeu  in  terms  of  tiie  size  of  the  aircraft  they  may  operate  they  tend 
to  serve  marginal,  or  uncertain  routes;  thus,  their  turnover  is  judged  by  some  as 
being  fairly  high.  However,  it  is  notable  that  such  unregulated  carriers  serve 
many  markets  that  CAB-reguiated  carriers  have  chosen  to  abandon  and  that 
tneir  service,  given  their  equipment  and  the  characteristics  of  their  markets,  is 
sate  and  reliable. 

By  no  means  has  the  brief  discussion  touched  on  all  the  characteristics  of 
deregulated  markets.  In  the  space  remaining,  however,  we  should  like  to  respond 
to  the  more  signiticant  criticisms  raised  by  those  who  oppose  less  regulation  of 
the  domestic  air  transport  system  : 

1.  Without  regulation,  flights  would  be  unsafe.  Critics  of  deregulation  argue 
that  regulation  is  needed  to  insulate  carriers  from  market  forces;  otherwise  the 
"dog-eat-dog '  atmosphere  of  free  comi^etition  would  lead  carriers  to  skimp  on 
safety,  to  the  public's  detriment.  There  are  several  answers  to  this;  First,  the 
governmental  instrumentality  charged  with  air  safety  is  the  FAA,  not  the  CAB. 
Deregulation,  as  we  have  defined  it,  would  leave  the  FAA's  role  unaffected. 
Second,  there  is  little  direct  evidence  that  economic  regulation  has  had  any 
effect  on  air  safety.  For  example,  the  Board  has  never  withdrawn  or  suspended 
the  certificate  of  a  trunk  operator  on  grounds  that  its  operations  were  unsafe, 
and  its  constraints  on  entry  have  seldom  if  ever  revolved  around  issues  of  safety. 
One  variant  of  the  safety  hypothesis  is  that  high  profits  mean  safe  operations. 
However,  when  we  tested  this  naive  proposition  over  the  period  1939  to  1953, 
for  which  there  appeared  to  be  adequate  variations  in  profit  rates  and  fatality 
rates  to  make  a  test  feasible,  we  found  the  result  contrary  to  what  critics  of 
deregulation  would  have  predicted.  While  the  net  effect  was  small  and  statisically 
not  meaningful,  the  result  actually  showed  a  positive  relationship  between  in- 
dustry profit  rates  and  industry  fatality  rates.^ 

2.  Under  deregulation  there  would  be  wholesale  abandonment  of  markets,  leav- 
ing only  the  "top-25"  (or  top-50  or  top-100)  markets  with  adequate  service.  This 
prediction  is  based,  in  essence,  upon  the  assumption  that  CAB  regulation  pres- 
ently constraints  the  abandonment  of  hundred  of  markets.  In  particular,  it  is 
argued  that  the  present  pricing  structure  enables  a  considerable  amount  of  cross- 
subsidy  whereby  a  carrier  uses  the  excess  profits  from  some  markets  to  offset 
losses  in  others  that  presumably  would  not  receive  service  under  deregulated 
conditions.  Miller  and  Douglas  have  found  that  the  extent  of  this  cross-subsidy 
is  greatly  overstated,^  and  apparently  the  Board  agrees.^^  If  this  is  true  then 
presumably  most  alleged  "losing"  markets  are  in  fact  self-supporting  and  would 
not  be  abandoned  if  regulation  were  terminated.  Second,  even  if  one  carrier  aban- 
dons a  market,  this  is  not  to  say  that  some  other  carrier  could  not  serve  it  at  a 
profit.^  Third,  there  may  be  points  which  would  be  abandoned  if  carriers  were 
restrained  to  the  CAB-regulated  fare,  but  free  to  charge  a  higher  fare  if  need  be, 
carriers  could  serve  many  such  markets  at  a  profit.  There  are  numerous  cases 
where  trunks  or  local  service  carriers  have  abandoned  markets  that  were  later 
served  by  commuter  carriers  at  a  profit,  often  a  slightly  higher  price  and  a  more 
frequent  service  configuration. 

3.  Under  deregulation,  only  a  handful  of  carriers  would  survive.  This  could 
happen,  but  if  it  did  such  industry  concentration  would  not  be  a  problem.  Since 
there  are  no  pervasive  .scale  economies,  there  is  little  reason  to  anticipate  this 
outcome  any  more  than  one  might  anticipate  the  emergence  of  several  hundred 
operators.  However,  even  if  only  a  handful  of  carriers  did  survive,  the  ease  of 
entry  into  deregulated  markets  would  act  to  "police"  the  market  and  thus  pre- 
vent any  abuses  of  monopoly  power. 

4.  Under  deregulation,  prices  and  schedules  would  be  unstable.  Without  doubt 
deregulation  fares  would  be  less  stable  than  at  present.  After  all,  regulation  has 
virtually  precluded  price  competition.  However,  rates  would  not  fluctuate  broadly. 
The  reason  is  that  information  is  a  scarce  resource  and  carriers  can  reduce  this 
expense  and  thus  attract  passengers  by  keeping  such  rates  relatively  stable.  The 


^'The  result  was  as  follows:  Domestic  fatality  rate  (pa.ssenper  fatalities  per  100 
million  miles  flown)  =1.76+ (.009X<lomestic  industry  profit  rate).  (T-statistic  on  variable 
coeffloient  =  .2.5  :  equation  R==.OS.)  Data  sources:  T^.S.  Tivil  Aeronautics  Board.  Handhook 
of  Airline  f^tafirticfi:  1971  Edition.  Washington.  GPO,  1972.  p.  554  ;  and  Caves,  ibid.,  p.  S9^. 

31  Miller  and  Dousrlas.  ibid.,  chapter  fi.  „        ,, 

32  See  C\B  Order  74-3-S2.  March  18.  1974.  pp.  66-72.  Moreover,  the  Board  has  recently 
enunciated  a  nolicv  of  eliminating  anv  cross-subsidy.  (Ibid.,  p.  68.) 

33  Perhaps  the  replacement  carrier  is  more  efficient,  or  the  point  is  more  complementary 
to  Its  route  system. 


51-146   O  -  76 


same  is  true  of  schedules.  An  unregulated  carrier  stands  to  gain  considerable  ill 
will  by  not  keeping  schedules,  or,  put  another  way,  an  unregulated  carrier  may 
gain  a  good  reputation  by  maintaining  published  schedules.  Certainly  the  ex- 
perience of  the  intrastate  airlines  and  the  commuter  airlines  is  inconsistent 
with  the  prediction  of  unstable  rates  and  schedules  under  deregulated  condi- 
tions.^ 

APPROACHES   TO   REGULATORY   REFORM 

From  the  prior  discussion,  it  should  be  apparent  that  the  economic  perform- 
ance of  the  domestic  airline  industry  would  be  significantly  enhanced  if  economic 
regulation  were  liberalized  or  perhaps  eliminated.  ISince  one  cannot  predict  with 
absolute  certainty  what  would  happen  with  complete  deregulation,  it  may  not  be 
feasible  to  make  a  total  commitment  to  such  a  course  of  action  at  this  time.  For- 
tunately, there  is  an  approach  which  appears  feasible,  which  leaves  open  the 
question  of  ultimate  total  deregulation,  and  which  we  would  highly  recommend. 
That  is,  we  should  move  smartly  in  the  direction  of  more  liberal  regulation  ;  at  the 
same  time  we  will  gain  additional  information  about  the  efficiency  of  total  de- 
regulation and  can  make  incremental  decisions  as  needed.  Such  a  regulatory  re- 
form proposal  would  be  consonant  with  the  following  principles  : 

1.  Entry.  It  should  be  easier  for  existing  carriers  to  enter  new  markets  and  for 
new  carriers  to  enter  the  business.  At  a  minimum,  the  Board  should  consider  the 
effects  on  economic  efficiency  of  prospective  new  service  when  deciding  entry 
cases.  Also,  it  would  be  desirable  to  prohibit  the  Board  from  constraining  entry 
on  the  grounds  that  it  might  adversely  affect  other  carriers. 

2.  Exit.  Cairriers  should  be  allowed  to  abandon  markets  where  they  cannot 
cover  costs.  Otherwise,  implicit  taxes  on  other  travellers  have  to  support  such 
services  and  this  is  not  only  questionable  as  a  matter  of  equity,  but  it  tends  to 
hide  the  real  cost  of  serving  these  markets. 

3.  Rates.  Fares  should  be  flexible  so  as  to  allow  price  competition.  One  ap- 
proach would  be  to  institute  a  "zone  of  reasonableness,"  such  as  plus  or  minus 
15  percent  of  existing  fares,  within  which  fares  would  be  totally  exempt  from 
regulation.^  Retaining  control  over  maximum  and  minimum  fares  thus  guards 
against  the  possibility  of  monopolistic  exploitation  on  the  high  side  and  alleged 
"cut-throat"  competition  on  the  low  side.  Over  time  the  zone  could  be  widened 
to  allow  for  even  more  price  competition,  lower  fares,  and  further  differentiation 
in  price-quality  offerings. 

4.  Antitrust  immunity.  In  order  to  assure  that  the  basic  thrust  toward  less 
regulation  were  not  perverted,  it  would  be  necessary  to  limit  the  Board's  power 
to  grant  antitrust  immunity.  Such  a  change  would  affect  such  things  as  agree- 
ments over  fares,  pooling  of  revenues,  agreements  to  control  capacity,  et  cetera. 
Not  affected  would  be  innocuous  relationships  such  as  baggage  interchange,  joint 
reservation  facilities,  and  the  like. 

5.  Subsidy.  During  an  interim  period,  it  might  well  be  desirable  to  retain  the 
Board's  subsidy  program.  However,  we  would  suggest  that  the  whole  subsidy 
mechanism  be  reexamined  in  order  to  determine  ways  of  obtaining  more  results 
from  each  subsidy  dollar,  or,  alternatively,  of  reducing  the  subsidy  bill  for  any 
given  results. 

Legislative  proposals  for  regulatory  reform  reflecting  these  principles  are  now 
being  considered  by  the  Administration.  It  is  anticipated  that  the  Administration 
will  recommend  to  this  session  of  Congress  a  comprehensive  program  which,  if 
enacted,  would  significantly  increase  the  efficiency  of  our  air  transportation  sys- 
tem and  provide  consumers  with  improved  transportation  services  at  lower  costs. 


^  See.  for  example,  Jordan,  ibid.,  chapters  5-10. 

35  It  is  important  that  this  zone  be  wide  enough  to  allow  for  meaningful  price  com- 
petition. Also,  too  narrow  a  zone  would  facilitate  price  collusion.  Fifteen  percent,  plus 
and  minus,  would  appear  to  be  a  minimal  standard. 


AIR  TRAVEL 
(From  Economic  Report  of  the  President,  1975,  G.P.O.,  pp.  154-5) 

In  the  domestic  airline  industry,  regulation  has  reserved  primarily  to  bring 
about  a  nonoptimal  choice  of  price  and  quality.  Because  the  CAB  had  a 
fairly  liberal  policy  during  the  1950's  and  1960's  toward  the  entry  of  existing 
carriers  into  city -pair  markets,  the  principal  markets  are  now  served  by  two 
or  more  airlines.  However,  since  their  fares  are  regulated  by  the  CAB,  the 
airlines  tend  to  complete  on  the  basis  of  scheduling,  over  which  the  Board 
does  not  exercise  direct  control.  The  result  is  "excess  capacity,"  and  efforts 
to  raise  the  regulated  fares  in  order  to  assure  a  return  on  investment  greater 
than  the  industry's  perceived  cost  of  capital  serve  only  to  set  the  stage  for 
further  capacity  augmentation. 

Carriers  as  a  group  have  consequently  tended  to  earn  neither  excess  profits 
nor  losses,  but  the  traveling  public  has  paid  higher  fares  because  of  the 
regulation-induced  excess  capacity.  While  excess  capacity  does  yield  some 
benefit  in  the  form  of  more  frequent  departures,  less  crowding,  and  a  better 
chance  of  obtaining  a  seat  on  the  preferred  departure,  the  value  of  this  excess 
capacity  is  almost  surely  less  than  its  cost.  As  evidence,  in  the  relatively  un- 
regulated California  and  Texas  intrastate  markets  the  competitively  deter- 
mined higher-load  factor  service  has  historically  been  sold  at  prices  some  40 
percent  below  the  prices  of  comparable  interstate,  CAB-regulated  services.  More- 
over, a  recent  study  reports  that  in  1969  domestic  air  passengers  paid  "excess 
fares"  ranging  between  $366  million  and  $538  million,  for  which  they  received 
service  quality  improvements  valued  at  between  $118  and  $182  million.  The 
difference,  between  $248  million  and  $356  million,  represents  a  deadweight  loss 
to  society. 

In  its  recent  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation,  the  CAB  established 
target  load  factors  of  55  percent.  Since  the  prevailing  load  factors  were 
around  50  percent,  this  policy  had  the  effect  of  reducing  excess  capacity  and 
lowering  fares.  However,  it  would  appear  that  a  much  higher  load  factor 
standard  is  justified  especially  in  view  of  the  recent  increa.ses  in  fuel  prices. 
The  Board's  new  policy  of  encouraging  agreements  among  carriers  to  limit 
capacity  is  not  an  appropriate  way  of  dealing  with  this  problem.  In  markets 
covered  by  agreements,  the  passenger's  total  cost  of  service  is  increased  because 
of  increased  delays,  but  the  fare  is  not  reduced. 

Airline  regulation  imposes  other  costs,  which  are  not  generally  well  per- 
ceived. For  instance,  through  the  regulatory  process,  fares  have  tended  to  be 
set  at  levels  and  with  a  structure  that  maximizes  total  seat  capacity,  as  opposed 
to  maximizing  total  passenger  traffic,  the  result  being  added  congestion  and 
environmental  costs,  as  well  as  increased  costs  of  airports  and  airways.  By  re- 
stricting the  entry  of  new  firms  into  trunk  carrier  service  in  order  to  protect 
less  eflScient  incumbent  firms,  regulation  has  also  penalized  potentially  more 
eflScient  firms  and  has  resulted  in  higher  fares  for  a  given  quality  of  service. 

These  costs  of  airline  regulation  could  be  reduced  substantially  or  even 
eliminated  if  entry  into  and  exit  from  markets  were  made  easier  and  if 
control  over  fares  were  liberalized  so  as  to  encourage  price  competition.  Under 
such  circumstances  an  individual  airline  could  attract  more  passengers  by 
lowering  its  price  rather  than  increasing  its  total  capacity. 

(67) 


68 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  Peck  is  our  next  witness,  a  former  member 
of  the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers. 

Then  Professor  Noll,  if  you  would  be  kind  enough— Professor  Noll 
received  his  Ph.  D.  in  1957,  was  on  the  senior  staff,  Council  of  Eco- 
nomic Advisers,  through  1973,  and  senior  fellow,  and  currently  pro- 
fessor of  economics  at  the  California  Institute  of  Technology. 

Thomas  Moore,  would  you  come  up  ?  Mr.  Moore  is  professor  of  eco- 
nomics, at  Stanford  University. 

Mr.  Peck,  do  you  want  to  start  ? 

STATEMENTS  OF  MERTON  J.  PECK,  PROFESSOR  OF  ECONOMICS, 
YALE  UNIVERSITY;  ROGER  G.  NOLL,  PROFESSOR  OF  ECONOMICS, 
CALIFORNIA  INSTITUTE  OF  TECHNOLOGY;  AND  THOMAS  G. 
MOORE,  SENIOR  FELLOW,  THE  HOOVER  INSTITUTION  ON  WAR, 
REVOLUTION,  AND  PEACE,  STANFORD  UNIVERSITY 

Mr.  Peck.  Yes,  thank  you.  Senator. 

I  have  a  short  statement  I  would  like  entered  into  the  record,  but  I 
will  not  read  it.  The  reason  is  that  the  testimony  of  the  previous  wit- 
nesses from  the  Department  of  Transportation,  Council  of  Economic 
Advisers,  the  Federal  Trade  Commission  and  the  Department  of 
Justice  have  made  many  of  my  points.  To  read  my  statement  now 
might  seem  to  be  preaching  to  the  converted.  Much  of  my  statement 
would  be  cumulative. 

I  would  like  to  indicate,  however,  that  the  economic  literature  in 
recent  years  has  made  two  points:  First,  regulation  is  economically 
inefficient ;  it  costs  the  consumer  too  much.  Second,  the  solution  to  this 
inefficiency  lies,  in  general,  in  more  competition  and  less  regulation 
to  provide  the  consumer  additional  price  and  service  options. 

Those  two  points  were  made  well,  I  think,  by  the  preceding  wit- 
nesses. Looking  at  their  footnotes,  I  discovered  an  amazing  fact.  Peo- 
ple do  read  economists'  waitings,  and  those  writings  are  reflected  in 
the  testimony  of  the  previous  witnesses. 

I  would  add  three  other  points.  First,  we  have  all  observed  that 
airplanes  fly  half  empty,  and  the  numerous  flights  reduces  waiting 
time  but  raises  costs.  A  Yale  student  of  mine,  Michael  Pustay,  has 
calculated  the  value  in  reduced  waiting  time  relative  to  the  cost  of 
more  flights.  He  found  that  in  1969  the  excess  capacity  flown,  if  waiting 
time  is  valued  at  $10  an  hour,  added  about  10  percent  to  airline  fares. 


In  transcontinental  markets,  it  added  even  more  to  the  costs.  His  results 
suggest  the  following  conclusion :  In  1969,  the  American  airlines  were 
flying  the  right  number  of  flights  for  the  $60,000-a-year  man,  to  whom 
convenience  matters  more  than  cost.  Everyone  also  was  offered  too 
many  flights  and  too  high  fares. 

Now  I  would  like  to  turn  to  another  point.  I  think  congressional 
hearings  are  a  highly  desirable  forum  in  which  to  raise  the  critical 
issue  of  regulatory  reform.  You  mentioned  earlier.  Senator,  the  regu- 
latory proceedings  themselves  as  a  way  to  change  policy.  I  have  ap- 
peared as  an  expert  witness  in  regulatory  proceedings.  I  have  been 
impressed  with  the  care  and  diligence  of  regulatory  officials  as  well 
as  their  concern  with  the  public  interest.  But  I  find  the  issues  are  too 
narrowly  drawn  to  make  regulatory  proceedings  a  good  place  in  which 
to  examine  broad  issues. 

I  would  add  one  final  point  made  in  my  statement.  I  recall  President 
Kennedy's  transportation  message  of  1962,  which  was  a  forceful  plea 
for  deregulation.  If  one  heard  only  the  firet  day  of  the  hearings  on 
that  message,  with  witnesses  all  in  favor  of  it,  one  would  conclude  de- 
regulation was  going  to  come  within  a  week  or  two.  It  turned  out  that 
the  first  day  was  not  representative,  and  the  legislation  that  accom- 
panied that  message  did  not  do  well  in  Congress. 

It  seemed  to  me  then  that  President  Kennedy's  plea  for  deregula- 
tion was  good  economics.  It  may  even  be  better  economics  today. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Professor  Noll. 

Mr.  Noll.  Senator,  we  have  engaged  in  a  little  bit  of  collusive  be- 
havior of  our  own,  and  I  think  it  would  be  more  appropriate  if  Mr. 
Moore  came  before  I  did. 

Mr.  MooRE.  Thank  you.  Senator.  I  would  like  to  summarize  my 
statement. 

My  research  and  other  research  all  on  the  question  of  regulation 
is  going  to  point  to  the  same  thing :  regulation  produces  waste,  higher 
prices,  and  often  poor  service.  My  research  has  been  in  the  area  of  ICC 
regulation,  regulation  of  trucking  in  Europe,  regulation  of  electricity 
utility  rates  by  State  Commissioners,  occupationally  sensin^i-,  and  the 
regulation  of  stock  market  margin  requirements.  I  might  indicate  my 
study  of  ICC  regulations  has  indicated  in  1968  ICC  regulations  in- 
flicted costs  on  the  American  economy  in  the  order  of  $3.8  to  $8.8 
billion.  Today  the  figure  would  be  considerably  higher 

I  would  like  to  turn  to  my  experience  in  v  estern  Europe,  which  I 
have  just  come  back  from,  studying  the  regulations  there. 


70 

I  found  that  regulation  has  the  same  pattern  there  as  it  does  here. 
In  those  countries  like  West  Germany,  they  have  very  strict  regula- 
tions, and  prices  are  much  higher,  almost  40  percent  higher,  than  in 
free  market  countries. 

England,  for  example,  has  deregulated  trucking  entirely,  and  it  il- 
lustrated an  appropriate  one  for  this  hearing  because  many  of  the 
same  points  that  you  were  raising  this  morning  and  others  raised  about 
deregulation  were  raised  about  deregulating  trucking.  Professor  Noll, 
who  has  argued  that  he  would  get  predatory  pricing  cutthroat  com- 
petition, monopolizing,  services  would  disappear  to  small  countries, 
safety  would  decline,  but  when  they  deregulated  trucking,  none  of 
these  things  happened,  prices  did  come  down,  but  profits  surprisingly 
enough  were  not  appreciably  affected.  Service  appeared  to  improve, 
their  service  to  small  communities,  even  in  northern  parts  of  Scotland, 
were  maintained,  and  in  fact  improved  under  deregulation,  and  the 
safet}^  record  also  improved.  That  was  due  partly  to  some  additional 
statutes  dealing  with  safety  and  trucking. 

So  that  none  of  these  things  that  are  alleged  to  happen  happened 
there.  There  is  no  reason  to  believe  they  would  happen  in  the  airline 
industry. 

The  second  point  that  I  want  to  make  is  that  regulation  as  a  process 
is  inherently  faulty.  There  is  nothing  that  you  could  do,  no  rewriting 
of  the  statute,  no  appointment  of  better  commissioners  is  going  to  do 
more  than  make  marginal  improvements.  The  regulatory  process  as  it 
is  developed  must  in  fact  emphasize  the  economic  liealth  of  the  in- 
dustry. The  regulators  cannot  tolerate  major  firms  failing.  Your  hear- 
ings last  fall  indicated  that  the  CAB  was  attempting  to  put  a  floor 
under  charters. 

Too,  as  your  own  report  said,  to  maintain  or  increase  the  profit- 
ability that  Pan  Am — let  me  see — had  in  order  to  help  Pan  Am  with 
its  financial  problems. 

This  is  inherent  in  regulation.  Regulation  also  by  its  very  nature  in 
a  competitive  industry  often  results  in  the  regulated  not  even  getting 
the  benefits,  because  price  competition  which  others  have  talked  about 
this  morning  has  been  eroding. 

Roger  Xoll  is  going  to  elalaorate  a  little  more  on  this  and  the  prob- 
lems with  the  regulatory  policy. 

Mr.  Noll.  Thank  you.  I,  too,  as  Professor  Peck,  have  a  written  state- 
ment that  I  do  not  intend  to  bore  you  with  in  completeness.  I  have 
given  a  corrected  version  to  professor  Breyer  which  I  hope  you  will 
put  into  tlie  record. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes.  It  will  be  included  in  the  record. 


71 

Mr.  Noll.  Since  this  is  in  fact  a  committee  on  administrative  prac- 
tices, I  would  like  to  focus  on  the  way  the  administrative  practices 
operate  and  what  kind  of  efficiency  effects  they  have. 

I  think,  as  judged  from  the  testimony  so  far  here  today,  economists 
and  even  lawyers  and  political  scientists  who  have  studied  regula- 
tion have  focused  too  much  of  their  attention  on  performance  of  the 
industry  and  too  little  of  their  attention  on  the  nature  of  the  process 
itself.  One  is  normally  faced  with  a  conclusion  which  says  regulation 
of  the  industry  is  costing  us  x  billion  dollars,  therefore,  let's  stop 
having  fools,  and  incompetents,  and  politicians  appointed  and  fix  the 
whole  thing  up  or  they  will  say  let's  tinker  with  the  administrative 
procedure  so  the  procedure  can  be  made  better. 

CERTAIN    COSTS    ARE    INTRINSIC    TO    REGULATION 

What  I  Avould  like  to  give  today  is  a  view  on  why  I  think  this  is 
a  mistaken  view.  I  have  known  fine  men  on  regulation  commissions 
who  came  out  after  their  term  simply  shaking  their  heads,  not  under- 
standing why  they  weren't  able  to  accomplish  all  the  things  they 
were  hoping  to  accomplish  when  they  went  in. 

The  problem  lies  in  the  institution  itself.  There  are  a  number  of 
dilemmas  in  setting  up  an  industry  to  control  market  behavior  that 
are  simply  unresolvable. 

COSTS   DUE   TO   REGULATORY   DELAYS 

It  first  arises  from  incompatability  of  decisions,  that  make  de- 
cisions with  staff,  that  individuals  are  accorded  due  process,  that 
decisions  are  based  upon  evidence,  and  that  when  someone  raises 
an  issue  in  a  proceeding  that  is  to  be  accounted  for  by  the  person 
making  the  decision. 

It  is  inconceivable  the  kinds  of  power  to  redistribute  wealth  that 
inheres  in  regulatory  institutions  would  be  delegated  to  any  bureau- 
cracy without  subjecting  the  decisions  to  judicial  review  and  without 
giving  affected  individuals  the  right  to  plead  their  cases  before 
decisionmakers. 

To  safeguard  the  rights  of  individuals  against  capricious  and  ar- 
bitrary decisions  of  an  agency  requires  establishing  decisionmaking 
procedures  that  normally  cause  decisions  on  important  issues  to  be 
protracted.  This  can  create  serious  problems  in  three  types  of  circum- 
stances, when  rapid  inflation  pushed  costs  up  and  firms  cannot  respond 
to  cost  increases  by  raising  prices  until  a  protracted  regulatory  review 
has  been  completed;  when  a  technological  development  that  would 


72 

lower  costs  and  improve  service  quality  cannot  be  fully  exploited  with- 
out regulatory  review;  and  when  an  innovative  new  firm  seeks  to 
enter  a  regulated  market  but  must  first  win  the  approval  of  the  regu- 
lators. The  last  two  effects  significantly  reduce  the  incentive  to  the 
firm  to  be  innovative,  since  to  all  the  risks  and  costs  of  innovation 
are  added  the  expense  in  time  and  resources  of  a  regulatory  proceed- 
ing, while  the  risk  of  a  more  innovative  competitor  capturing  a 
superior  market  position  is  reduced. 

COSTS  DUE  TO  NECESSARY  BIAS  TOWARD  THE  FEW  COMPANIES  MOST  AFFECTED 

The  second  major  dilemma  of  regulatory  institutions  reflects  the 
trade-off  between  an  expensive  regulatory  process  and  a  process  that 
is  insulated  from  the  individuals  affected  by  its  outcomes.  In  part  be- 
cause the  preservation  of  accountability  and  due  process  through  ju- 
dicial review  makes  participation  in  the  regulatory  process  expensive, 
and  in  part  because  the  vast  majority  of  persons  who  are  affected  by 
regulatory  decisions  are  not  effectively  organized  to  represent  them- 
selves in  regulatory  proceedings,  the  flow  of  information  and  proposed 
rules  to  the  agency  is  one-sided.  A  passive  agency  that  relies  upon  the 
evidence  supplied  by  participants  in  the  process  will  inevitably  make 
decisions  based  upon  incomplete  assessments  of  the  issues  at  hand ;  an 
agency  that  can  generate  its  own  independent  flow  of  information  on 
every  important  case  will  be  much  more  expensive  to  operate.  In  fact, 
none  of  the  Federal  regulatory  authorities  engaged  in  price  and  profit 
regulation  devotes  anywhere  near  the  resources  to  generating  informa- 
tion for  use  in  regulatory  proceedings  that  is  committed  by  the  indus- 
tries they  regulate. 

An  example  of  what  basically  happens  is  that  a  few  well  represented 
groups,  by  virtue  of  the  procedure  of  the  agency,  get  to  structure  what 
the  issue  will  be  in  the  proceeding  and  they  get  to  provide  most  of  the 
information  upon  which  the  decisions  will  be  based. 

The  outcome  is  best  illustrated  by  the  recent  debate  over  the  regula- 
tion of  cable  television. 

The  recent  debate  over  the  regulation  of  cable  television  is  an  illus- 
trative case  in  point :  The  final  regulatory  rules  were  worked  out  by  a 
coalition  of  broadcasters,  cable  system  owners  and  program  producers. 
While  each  of  these  groups  cast  their  arguments  defending  their  own 
positions  in  terms  of  the  beneficial  effects  a  system  satisfying  them 
would  have  on  society  at  large,  and  while  the  FCC  devoted  some  staff 
resources  to  investigating  the  stake  of  viewers  in  the  issue,  neverthe- 
less the  final  compromise  was  hammered  out  exclusively  by  the  well- 
represented  special  interests,  and  was  adopted  by  the  FCC  explicitly 
because  none  of  the  three  groups  would  appeal  the  compromise,  legally 
or  politically. 


73 

Senator  Kexnedy.  Professor  Breyer  is  goin^?  to  chair  this  part  of 
the  hearing.  I  hope  vou  will  continue  if  that  is  all  right. 

Mr.  Noll.  OK. 

These  endemic  problems  of  regulation  do  not  necessarily  lead  to  the 
conclusion  that  under  no  conditions  should  industry  be  regulated.  All 
they  imply  is  that  certain  inevitable  costs  are  to  be  expected.  Gener- 
ally, these  costs  will  be  higher  because  :  (1)  the  sophistication  required 
to  determine  the  true  technical  and  economic  conditions  of  the  industry 
is  greater,  (2)  the  greater  the  portion  of  the  effects  of  regulation  that 
is  diffused  over  a  large,  heterogeneous  group  that  is  unlikely  to  be  ef- 
fectively organized,  and  (3)  the  more  uncertain  and  rapidly  changing 
the  economic  environment  in  which  the  regulated  firms  operate,  such 
as  is  the  case  during  a  period  of  rapid  inflation  or  deepening  recession. 

The  cost  of  regulation  is  also  likely  to  be  greater  the  more  competi- 
tive the  regulated  industry.  This  is  because  entrenched  firms  are  to 
some  extent  protected  from  competition  by  the  slowness  and  costs  of 
procedures  that  must  be  followed  by  new  entrants  into  a  market.  In 
addition,  the  regulatory  forum  allows  competitive  firms  to  engage  in 
a  far  greater  degree  of  collusive  behavior  than  would  be  permitted  in  a 
normal  competitive  circumstance.  And  by  exercising  some  control  over 
the  information  flowing  to  the  agencies,  while  constituting  the  pri- 
mary threat  of  appeal  to  the  agency's  decision,  the  industry  can  push 
the  agency  to  make  policies  and  adopt  rules  that  enforce  cartel-like 
behavior  upon  the  firms  in  the  industry.  These  types  of  actions — the 
mutual  service  reduction  agreements  among  the  airlines  that  were 
promoted  by  the  CAB  are  good  examples — would  surely  be  antitrust 
violations  in  the  absence  of  the  protective  umbrella  of  the  regulatory 
statutes. 

The  principal  conclusion  of  the  preceding  remarks  is  rather  straight- 
forward :  one  should  keep  in  mind  the  costs  of  regulation  when  de- 
ciding whether  to  regulate  any  particular  industry,  and  whether  to 
continue  to  regulate  an  industry  that  was  subjected  to  regulation  when 
circumstances  were  far  different  from  the  present.  For  example,  if  an 
industry  becomes  increasingly  able  to  support  a  competitive  market 
structure  as  time  progresses,  the  expected  costs  of  regulation  will  in- 
crease while  the  expected  benefits  of  regulation  will  decline. 

COSTS    INCREASED    WHERE    REGULATOR — LIKE    CAB — MUST   PROMOTE 
INDUSTRY 

Presumably  the  argument  for  regulation  of  most  industries  is  more 
complex  than  simply  the  avoidance  of  monopolistic  practices.  In  the 
case  of  domestic  airlines,  regulation  has  a  certain  promotional  feature, 
owing  to  the  effects  attributed  to  an  extensive  air  route  structure  on 
economic  development,  the  distribution  of  economic  activity,  and  na- 


74 

tional  defense.  Without  debating  the  merits  of  these  contentions — 
which  are,  of  course,  eminently  debatable — the  issue  remains  which 
policy  instrument  can  most  effectively  generate  the  desired  route  struc- 
ture. The  difficulty  with  the  regulatory  approach  is  that  this  explicit 
promotional  aim  gives  the  regulatory  authority  an  even  greater  indus- 
try orientation  than  the  institutional  dilemmas  would  normally  pro- 
duce. On  the  industry's  part,  promotional,  cost-plus  regulatory  policies 
generate  overly  optimistic  investment  plans  since  the  incentive  for 
investment  is  heightened  by  the  belief  by  firms  that  regulators  will 
act  to  ameliorate  at  least  some  of  the  financial  losses  that  will  be  suf- 
fered if  an  investment  plan  proves  too  optimistic.  On  the  agency's 
part,  financial  failure  of  a  regulated  firm  is  at  best  an  embarrassment 
and  at  worst  a  serious  problem ;  the  failure  may  be  attributed  to  the 
decisions  of  the  agency,  and,  in  any  event  will,  at  least  temporarily, 
cause  the  pattern  of  service  to  fall  short  of  the  promotional  objective 
that  led  the  agency  to  acquiesce  to  overinvestment  in  the  first  place. 
The  result  is  a  continuing  spiral  of  overly  optimistic  expansions — too 
many  new  planes  flown  too  frequently  over  too  many  routes — followed 
by  policies  propounded  by  regulators  to  bail  out  their  charges. 

Deregulating  a  competitive  industry  will  undoubtedly  have  some 
significant  adjustment  effects.  Prices  and  pi'ofi^^s  Avill  probably  fall, 
dramatically  so  in  the  short  run,  some  routes  will  be  abandoned  or  be 
subjected  to  sharp  service  curtailment,  and  some  firms  may  face  bank- 
ruptcy and  reorganization.  But  in  the  long  run,  more  and  better  service 
and  normal  profits  can  be  expected,  and  at  reduced  prices,  as  firms 
learn  to  operate  more  efficiently  and  as  the  price  system  is  used  as  a 
signalling  device  for  tailoring  service  to  user  tastes. 

ALTERNATIVE  TO  REGULATION  OF  AIRLINES  :  DIRECT  8XTBSIDY  ALLOCATED  BY 
COMPETITIVE   BIDDING 

If  the  resulting  route  structure  is  judged  to  be  somehow  unsatisfac- 
tory by  the  political  process,  competitive  bidding  for  contracts  to  serve 
unprofitable  routes  or  to  fly  unprofitably  large  and  fast  aircraft  into 
some  cities  will  prove  a  far  more  efficient  mechanism  for  promoting 
the  industry  than  regulation.  The  key  to  the  contract  alternative  is 
its  reliance  on  the  natural  forces  of  competition  in  all  markets,  includ- 
ing the  subsidized  ones.  Even  if  Congress  desires  to  promote  a  more 
developed  route  structure  than  the  competitive  market  would  yield 
but  without  paying  subsidies  from  general  revenues — a  circumstance 
which  plausibly  suggests  that  a  subsidy  should  not  be  paid  in  any 


75 

event — an  explicit  intraindustry  transfer,  retaininj^  the  competitive 
market  structure,  is  still  feasible.  Subsidized  routes  could  be  jfinanced 
by  a  tax  on  airline  tickets,  for  example. 

Economists,  myself  included,  blanch  at  most  any  proposal  to 
engage  in  Government  promotion  of  an  industry,  especially  when 
financed  by  the  profitable  activities  of  the  industry.  Such  cross-sub- 
sidization extracts  its  own  costs  in  terms  of  efficiency  of  the  economic 
system,  and  these  are  not  trivial.  But  the  point  remains  that  the  econ- 
omists' arguments  for  unregulated  competitive  industry  inevitably 
penetrates  costs  but  provides  no  benefits,  except  that  in  the  short  run 
existing  firms  in  the  industry  that  have  overinvested  in  response  to 
perverse  regulatory  incentives  experience  losses  when  the  protective 
shield  of  regulation  is  removed.  The  efficient  way  to  promote  an  in- 
dustry, or  to  force  it  is  to  respond  to  considerations  not  normally  re- 
flected in  the  marketplace,  to  do  so  directly  through  taxes,  subsidies, 
and  performance  standards  tied  specifically  to  the  policy  concern  of 
the  Government. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Thank  you  very  much. 

What  we  are  trying  to  do  is  in  part  generate  a  debate,  and  I  would 
like  to  know  your  views,  and  that  will  be  helpful  to  develop  questions 
with  other  people  to  testify. 

First  of  all.  I  know  you  teach  in  this  field,  and  I  take  it  you  are  not 
experts  in  airline  regulation,  but  you  do  read  the  things  written  both 
from  the  industry  point  of  view  and  from  other  points  of  view ;  and 
you  feel  that  you  have  an  ability  to  compare  the  trucking  regulation 
with  a  whole  host  of  other  regulations. 

CONSENSUS   AMONG   ECONOMISTS 

Is  there  any  sort  of  consensus  among  economists  on  the  question  of 
air  regulations  ?  I  have  noticed  a  lot  of  economic  issues.  There  are  as 
many  views  as  political  points  of  view.  Democratic  economists  say  one 
tiling,  and  Republican  economists  say  another.  Are  people  pretty  much 
in  agreement,  or  is  it  a  political  thing  even  among  economists? 

Mr.  Peck.  I  would  think  there  is  a  general  consensus  among  econo- 
mists that  airline  regulation  is  not  economically  efficient.  I  tried  to  look 
for  defenses  by  industry  scholars  of  the  present  regulatory  processes 
by  independent  scholars  for  my  courses,  and  the  search  has  been  in 
vain. 

It  seems  to  me  there  is  an  emerging  consensus  in  economic  writings 
that  regulation  no  longer  serves  the  public  interest.  Since  there  are 


76 

25,000  economists  in  the  country,  and  we  speak  for  three,  there  is  ob- 
viously going  to  be  a  diversity  of  views,  but  less  than  other  economic 
views. 

Mr.  MooRE.  I  would  like  to  add  that  I  was  at  the  President's  eco- 
nomic summit,  and  I  put  forward  at  that  summit  a  package  of  22  steps, 
mainly  which  dealt  with  regulation,  several  of  which  dealt  with  CAB 
regulation  in  particular.  At  that  meeting  there  were  23  economists, 
many  liberal  Democrats,  many  conservative  Kepublicans,  some  of  the 
best  known  names  in  the  profession. 

Of  the  23  people  there,  21  endorsed  the  package  or  at  least  the  gen- 
eral gist  of  the  package,  which  was  antiregulation.  One  of  the  persons 
did  not  just  think  it  was  irrelevant  in  connection  with  inflation,  so  that 
gives  me  some  idea. 

Mr.  Noll.  When  I  spent  3  years  at  Brookings  I  was  codirector  of  a 
service  of  research  projects  on  regulation.  Approximately  25  projects 
were  undertaken,  the  political  complexion  of  the  researchers  varied 
from  the  extreme  right  to  the  extreme  left.  All  of  the  Federal  regula- 
tions were  studied  in  some  detail  and  particularly  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board  were  studied  separately,  some  in  the  Republican  coun- 
cil of  economic  advisers  and  some  on  the  Democratic  council  of 
economic  advisers. 

They  found  out  it  was  costing  to  the  tune  of  several  billion  dollars 
a  year.  Economists  are  justifiably  often  criticized  for  failure  to  reach 
consensus  on  major  policy,  and  in  most  instances  that  is  right,  that  thoy 
are  not  people  who  do  in  fact  reach  consensus  easily. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  nice  thing  about  being  a  student  of  industrial 
organization  and  regulation  is  that  you  can  get  along  with  your  col- 
leagues, because  you  never  have  to  run  the  risk  of  being  dead  wrong 
and  saying  regiilation  has  been  foolish  in  a  particular  sector.  I  know 
of  no  major  industrial  scholarly  work  by  an  economist  or  political 
scientist  or  lawyer  in  the  last  10  years  that  reaches  the  conclusion  that 
a  particular  industry  would  operate  less  efficiently  and  less  equitably 
than  with  regulation.  The  conclusion  is  unanimous.  None  outside  of 
the  industry  organizations  themselves  seriously  contend  that  regula- 
tion is  serving  the  consumers,  or  has  a  serious,  positive  benefit. 

TRANSITION    TO    DEREGULATION 

Mr.  Breyer.  Are  the  economists,  even  with  this  consensus,  suffi- 
ciently sensitive  to  what  undoubtedly  are  very  real  problems  the  in- 
dustry has?  If  in  fact  you  had  deregulation,  isn't  there  a  risk  you 
would  end  up  putting  a  lot  of  companies  out  of  business  ?  If  they  don't 


77 

make  profits,  they  won't  be  in  business.  Is  not  there  some  kind  of  real 
risk  that  despite  consensus  in  the  classroom,  out  in  the  real  world 
deregulation  means  you  will  force  airlines  out  of  business  and  end  up 
with  significantly  worse  services  ? 

Mr.  Noll.  I  think  as  a  characterization  of  the  transition  phenome- 
non, there  is  a  lot  to  be  said  for  it.  Why  does  it  like  to  be  regulated  ? 
The  answer  is  quite  simple.  Ever  since  1938,  36  years,  almost  37  years, 
the  industry  has  made  investment  decisions,  routing  decisions,  on  the 
basis  of  the  assumptions  the  industry  will  be  regulated. 

The  excess  capacity  of  seats  is  not  magically  construed  out  of  the 
air.  So  investment  plans  are  put  forth  on  the  basis  of  the  assumption 
that  planes  will  be  flown  half  empty. 

In  the  transition  scenario  from  the  regulated  industry  to  the  un- 
regulated industry,  there  are  going  to  be  financial  difficulties  by  some 
of  the  firms,  not  by  all  of  the  firms,  in  the  industry.  Some  of  the  firms 
will  prove  better  able  to  survive  than  others.  I  would  expect  there 
would  be  bankruptcies,  or  not  bankruptcy,  but  operating  in  a  deficit. 
That  is  testimony  of  inefficiency  of  regulation.  The  reason  there  would 
be  losses  is  because  a  whole  inefficient  industry  structure  has  been 
built  upon  the  regulation  institution,  a  lot  of  decisions  have  been 
made  because  they  are  protected  by  regulation. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Are  you  saying  we  will  end  up  with  the  possibility  of 
not  having  an  airline  industry  ? 

Mr.  Noll.  I  am  not  finished  yet.  The  first  point  to  remember  is  what 
financial  failure  means.  It  means  a  lot  of  managers  will  be  put  out  of 
jobs.  The  people  who  are  now  directing  airline  companies  are  directing 
because  of  their  sophistication  in  dealing  with  regulations.  That  will 
no  longer  be  a  talent  for  which  airlines  will  pay  a  high  salary. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Are  you  saying  that  at  the  end  of  the  line  we  will  have 
an  airline  industry,  or  that  we  won't  ?  Is  there  a  big  risk  or  a  little  risk  ? 

Mr.  Noll.  Airplanes  will  be  there,  dift'erent  people  will  own  them, 
different  firms  perhaps,  different  managers  of  those  firms  will  be  in 
existence.  But  the  point  is  as  long  as  you  can  make  money  flying  peo- 
ple from  New  York  to  Los  Angeles,  there  will  be  people  and  airlines 
ready  to  do  that.  There  will  be  a  transition  when  the  ownership  and 
the  management  changes,  and  the  more  gradual  you  make  the  transi- 
tion and  the  more  you  compensate  the  people  for  the  transition,  the  less 
shaken])  there  will  be. 

Mr.  Breyer  Professor  Peck. 

Mv.  Peck.  You  have  to  distinguish  between  the  long  run  and  the 
short  run. 


78 

The  longrun  prospects  of  an  airline  industry  operating  without 
regulations  is  very  good.  It  will  be  a  good  industry. 

There  is  the  transitional  problem  which  economists  have  not  really 
addressed  as  seriously  perhaps  as  it  deserves.  It  is  partly  a  question 
of  equity,  partly  a  question  of  efficiency  of  a  special  kind  moving  to 
a  new  and  better  competitive  situation. 

The  proposals  for  tleregulation  usually  are  stated  so  that  they  allow 
for  a  transition.  One  of  the  witnesses  this  morning  said  we  would  not 
deregulate  overnight. 

But  I  think  the  transitional  problems  are  solvable  if 

Mr.  Breyer.  Down  the  road  the  airline  industry  would  be  profitable, 
eventually  ? 

Mr.  Peck.  That  is  right. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Why  are  they  so  against  this  then? 

Mr.  Peck.  I  am  reminded  of  the  remark  the  best  of  all  monopoly 
profits  is  a  quiet  life.  It  may  be  true  of  our  regulations;  people  are 
used  to  doing  business  in  a  certain  way.  They  are  also  concerned  about 
transitional  problems.  I  would  be,  too,  if  I  were  a  president  of  an 
airline. 

EVIDENCE    OF    OTHER    UNREGULATED    INDUSTRIES 

Mr.  Breyer.  You  would  ask  the  industry  what  would  happen  in 
the  long  run  ?  You  think  the  problems  could  be  overcome  ?  Is  there  any 
reason  to  believe  if  you  have  fears  of  competition,  people  won't  start 
cutting  back  in  safety  and  we  won't  have  a  lot  of  unsafe  planes  flying 
around?  Don't  you  have  to  worry  about  people  cutting  back  on  seat- 
belts  or  oxygen  masks  ? 

Mr.  Noll.  If  it  would  be  profitable  for  them  to  do  it  in  an  unregu- 
lated environment,  if  there  were  evidence  there  would  be  planes  falling 
out  of  the  skies  like  California  and  Texas. 

Mr.  Breyer.  You  mean  historically  they  are  not  regulated  to  the 
same  extent  in  California  and  Texas,  is  that  your  point  ? 

Mr.  Noll.  That  is  my  point. 

Mr.  Breyer.  They  are  regulated  from  the  point  of  view  of  safety. 

Mr.  Noll.  That  is  right. 

Mr.  Breyer.  But  they  don't  have  fare  regulations  to  the  same  extent. 

Mr.  Noll.  Yes. 

Mr.  INIoore.  British  deregulation  of  trucking,  the  same  problem  of 
transition  came  up,  and  if  you  face  the  transition  over  enough  period 
of  time  and  do  it  appropriately  you  can  minimize  it.  There  will  still 
be  these  transitional  costs,  and  that  is  Avhy  the  airline  fears  it,  but  in 
the  \on<r  run  the  industry  will  perform — — 

Mr.  Breyer.  Trucking  was  deregulated  in  England,  and  the  net  re- 
sult was  the  firms  were  just  as  profitable  ? 

Mr.  Moore.  Just  as  profitable  as  they  were  before,  and  they  were 
not  in  fact  highway  safety  improved,  and  prices  came  down. 


79 


DESTRUCTIVE    COMPETITION" 


Mr.  Breyer.  There  are  a  couple — I  am  just  g:etting  rather  quick 
answers,  I  know — but  there  are  a  couple  of  things  that  concern  me. 

People  are  generally  concerned  whether  in  an  unregulated  environ- 
ment you  would  discover  destructive  competition.  Again  and  again 
that  argument  is  made.  Is  there  any  reason  to  think  you  would  not  have 
destructive  competition,  such  tremendous  fare  competition  that  in  fact 
one  airline  ch'ives  everybody  out  of  business  or  they  all  go  under  and 
you  end  up  without  service.  What  is  the  risk  of  that  happening? 

Mr.  Noll.  That  is  an  extremely  difficult  question  to  answer  briefly. 
Here  are  a  few  kinds  of  responses  to  it.  No.  1,  it  is  not  obvious  that 
will  ever  hap])en,  historically,  in  any  industry  that  did  not  have  a  scale 
economies,  which  is  to  say  if  there  exists  an  industry  where  there  are 
no  true  economies  gained  to  being  a  monopoly,  it  is  much  cheaper  to 
merge  than  to  try  to  force  the  other  guy  to  go  bankrupt.  Historically, 
in  industries  where  unregulated  competition  has  prevailed  I  do  not 
know  of  a  single  instance  where  that  has  happened. 

Second,  in  the  unregulated  markets — or  the  markets  that  at  least 
for  a  time  were  unregulated — this  has  not  happened.  PSA  is  not  an 
airline  running  business  losses  to  the  point  of  doing  in  big  companies 
like  United. 

Another  point  is  that  antitrust  laws  do  exist,  and  one  of  the  clearest 
prohibitions  in  the  antitrust  laws  is  predatory  price  cutting,  that  is 
cutting  prices,  low  costs  to  drive  somebody  else  out  of  business  and 
then  raise  costs.  There  will  always  be  that  route. 

Finally,  in  the  case  of  the  airline  industry,  even  if  in  the  short  run 
someone  could,  if  airline  A  could  drive  airline  B  out  of  a  given  market, 
as  soon  as  the  price  went  back  up  the  airline  would  be  able  to  jump 
right  in.  Airlines  will  not  disappear  from  the  face  of  the  Earth.  There 
will  always  be  airplanes  you  can  use  to  enter  the  market  again. 

So  unless  a  price  cutter  is  to  have  his  price  be  below  cost  forever  he 
will  not  find  it  in  his  interest  to  engage  in  such  behavior. 

Mr.  MooRE.  Pan  Am  and  TWA  offer  charter  service  to  Europe  and 
have  not  driven  other  charters  out  of  business.  They  have  complained 
about  the  competition  in  these  smaller  firms. 

The  same  point  was  made  by  trucking.  There  is  no  expense  in 
England  with  predatory  pricing  and  monopoly.  It  just  does  not  occur. 

Mr.  Breyer.  I  think  that  is  fine. 

[The  prepared  statements  of  Messrs.  Peck,  Moore,  and  Noll  follow :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Merton  J;  Peck,  Professor  of  Economics, 
Yale  University 

regulatory  reform   of  the  civil  aeronautics  board 

I  am  pleased  to  have  the  opportunity  to  appear  before  you.  My  specialty  is  the 
economics  of  regulation,  and  for  the  past  two  decades  I  have  taught  courses 


80 

and  published  on  this  subject.  In  1968  I  served  as  a  member  of  the  Council  of 
Economic  Advisers,  with  responsibility  for  regulatory  policy.  I  have  not,  how- 
ever, written  on  the  airline  industry.  My  comments  will  be  based  on  my  general 
knowledge  of  regulatory  policy. 

In  1970,  an  MIT  economist,  Paul  Maaivoy,  edited  a  book  which  he  called 
The  Crisis  of  Regulatory  Commissions.^  At  the  time  I  thought  the  title  an  un- 
seemly one,  since  the  custom  in  academia  is  for  colorless  and  somewhat  pedantic 
titles.  But  I  now  think  that  Professor  MacAvoy  was  right;  there  is  a  crisis  in 
the  regulatory  commissions. 

In  recent  years,  economists  have  been  almost  uniformly  critical  of  Federal 
regulatory  commissions.  Indeed,  I  have  sought  for  my  courses  recent  scholarly 
publications  that  find  some  good  in  present  policies.  The  search  has  been  in 
vain.  The  uncharitable  might  say  I  have  not  looked  diligently  enough,  but  it 
seems  to  me  that  there  is  an  emerging  consensus  in  economic  writings  that 
regulation  no  longer  serves  the  public  interest.  A  review  of  these  writings  leads 
me  to  make  three  points  : 

1.  Regulation  is  frequently  very  costly  to  the  American  public. 

2.  Regulation  ought,  in  general,  to  be  reduced.  We  would  be  better  off  with 
less  regulation  and  more  competition. 

3.  Congressional  hearings  on  Federal  regulatory  policies  such  as  those  initiated 
here  are  needed. 

1.  Regulation  is  generally  very  costly  to  the  American  public 

Several  recent  studies  have  shown  that  the  costs  of  regulation  in  terms  of 
economic  efficiency  are  substantial."  And  for  airlines,  we  have  all  taken  trips 
with  practically  empty  airplanes,  and  yet  airline  fares  keep  climbing. 

A  Yale  doctoral  student  of  mine,  Michael  Pustay,  has  attempted  to  quantify 
such  casual  observations.^  There  are  two  factors  which  he  recognized  in  his 
calculations.  More  flights  mean  shorter  waiting  times.  That  is  worth  something, 
and  so  Dr.  Pustay  put  a  valuation  on  reductions  in  waiting  time.  More  flights 
also  mean  higher  costs,  and  Pustay  used  the  CAB  costing  formula  to  estimate 
those  added  costs.  Pustay  applied  his  technique  to  289  city-pairs  for  1969.  For 
each  city-pair  he  used  a  model  developed  by  another  economist,  George  Douglas, 
to  establish  the  optimal  number  of  flights,  recognizing  both  the  costs  of  added 
flights  and  the  savings  in  waiting  time.  He  then  estimated  the  net  cost  of  having 
more  daily  flights  from  the  optimal  number. 

Pustay's  results  are  striking.  If  waiting  time  is  valued  at  $10.00  an  hour,  the 
added  costs  in  1969  were  $4.56  million  annually,  about  9  percent  of  airline  fares 
at  that  time.*  Of  course,  if  waiting  time  is  valued  at  more  per  hour,  then  more 
flights  become  economically  justified.  Even  at  $20.00  an  hour  the  excess  costs 
were  $273  million  annually.  Pustay's  results  suggest  that  American  airlines  in 
1969  were  flying  the  right  amount  of  flights  for  the  $60,000  a  year  man.  Everyone 
else  was  being  offered  too  many  flights  and  too  high  fares." 


1  Paul  W.  MacAvoy  (ed),  The  Crisis  of  Regulatory  Commissions.  W.  W.  Norton  Company, 
1970. 

2  Studies  for  surface  transportation  are  reviewed  in  Lee  I.  Sparling.  "Rate  Regulation 
and  Freiglit  Traffic  Allocation,  A  Review  and  Revision,"  Social  Science  Working  Paper, 
#68,  California  Institute  of  Technology,  1974.  For  a  study  of  the  costs  of  regulation  in 
television,  see  Roper  Noll.  ^Terton  J.  Peck,  and  John  J.  McGowan,  Economic  Aspects  of 
Television  Regulation  (Brookings  Institution  1973). 

^  Michael  W.  Pustay,  The  Effects  of  Regulation  on  Resource  Allocation  in  the  Domestic 
Trunk  Airline  Industry,  Yale  Doctoral  Dissertation,  1973. 

*  Ibid.,  p.  117. 

^  Note  that  Pustay's  results  are  for  over-supplied  city-pairs  ;  there  were  other  smaller 
markets  that  had  too  few  flights.  George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C.  Miller  used  a  some- 
what different  approach  and  estimated  the  costs  of  excess  capacity  in  1969  as  ^R66  million 
at  a  $10  per  hour  valuation  of  waiting  time.  See  Economics  of  Regulation  Domestic  Air 
Transport  (Brookings  Institution,  1974)  p.  172. 


81 

For  particular  city-pairs,  the  added  costs  are  more  striking.  Chicago  to  Los 
Angeles  is  an  example.  Pustay  calculated  that  if  waiting  time  were  valued  at 
$10.00  per  hour,  the  optimal  number  of  daily  flights  would  have  been  20  with 
a  73  percent  load  factor.  In  fact,  in  1969  there  were  30  flights  and  a  49  percent 
load  factor.  The  actual  fare  was  $106.  If  there  had  been  an  optimal  load  factor, 
the  cost  per  passenger  would  have  been  $50." 

Pustay's  results  have  several  limitations.  The  approach  may  over-value  wait- 
ing time.  It  is  a  market-by-market  analysis  and  some  excess  capacity  may  be 
justified  because  an  aircraft  serves  several  city-pairs.  The  calculations  are  for 
1969 ;  since  then  load  factors  have  improved  somewhat. 

Still,  the  magnitudes  of  Pustay's  results  are  so  large  that  they  clearly  support 
what  common  sense  suggests.  Flying  planes  half  empty  is  not  good  economics. 

2.  Regulation  ought  to  be  lessened  and  more  relianee  plaeed  on  competition. 
These  added  costs  are  likely  the  result  of  regulatory  policies.  Regulatory  com- 
missions have  been  loathe  to  see  price  competition  emerge.  At  the  same  time 
regulated  firms,  like  other  American  businesses,  have  been  eager  to  expand  their 
market  shares.  With  price  comi)etition  tabu,  the  competitive  rivalry  is  chan- 
nelled into  service  competition.  That  often  takes  the  form  of  adding  capacity 
to  provide  more  frequent  service  which  in  turn  raises  costs.  The  higher  costs 
as  they  spread  to  the  industry  generally  can  then  become  the  basis  for  a  request 
for  a  rate  increase. 

One  solution  is  regulation  of  capacity,  but  the  better  solution  may  be  in  the 
opposite  direction — to  allow  more  price  competition.  Consumers  should  have  the 
choice  between  service  and  price  that  unregulated  markets  generally  provide. 
And  there  seems  no  better  way  to  ensure  such  choice  than  through  allowing 
price  competition. 

3.  Congressional  hearing  on  the  Federal  regulatory  policies  are  very  much  needed. 
Congressional  hearings  are  a  highly  desirable  forum  in  which  to  raise  the 

critical  issues  of  regulatory  reform.  I  have  appeared  as  an  expert  witness  in 
regulatory  proceedings.  I  have  been  impressed  with  the  care  and  diligence  of 
regulatory  oflicials  as  well  as  their  concern  with  the  public  interest.  But  usually 
the  issues  are  narrowly  drawn  and  there  is  no  occasion  to  raise  broader  issues 
as,  for  example,  the  desirability  of  more  price  competition. 

Congress  now  has  a  full  agenda  of  pressing  problems.  One  should  not  urge 
adding  another  one  lightly.  But  regulation  seems  badly  askew ;  there  is  a  regu- 
latory crisis.  Inflation  and  rising  energy  prices  appear  to  have  made  existing 
regulatory  policies  even  more  expensive  to  the  public.  And  many  regulated  firms 
themselves  are  often  in  trouble,  from  Pan  Am  to  the  Penn  Central. 

I  would  add,  however,  Mr.  Chairman,  that  tlie  issue  of  regulatory  reform  is 
not  a  new  one.  President  Kennedy's  Transportation  Message  of  1962  was  a  force- 
ful plea  for  deregulation.  The  Kennedy  message  called  for  "greater  reliance  on 
the  forces  of  competition  and  less  reliance  on  the  restraints  of  regulation." ' 
The  legislation  that  accompanied  that  message  did  not  fare  well  in  Congress. 
And  yet  it  seems  to  me  that  President  Kennedy's  plea  for  deregulation  was  good 
economics  then ;  it  may  be  even  better  economics  today. 


°  Pustay,  op.  cit.  p.  123. 

■^  Quoted   in    Ann   F.    Priedlander.    The  Dilemma  of  Freight   Transportation,  Brookings 
Institution,   1970,  p.   vii. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


82 

Prepared  Statement  of  Thomas  G.  Moore,  Senior  Fbxlow,  The  Hoover  Institu- 
tion ON  War,  Revolution,  and  Peace,   Stanford  University 

THE    REGULATORY    REFORM    OF    THE    CIVIL   AERONAUTICS    BOARD 

It  is  a  great  honor  and  privilege  to  be  here  today  to  give  my  views  on  this 
important  topic.  This  subcommittee  must  be  commended  for  leading  the  way  in 
exploring  a  vital  topic — regulatory  reform. 

As  you  know,  next  year  marks  the  200th  anniversary  for  the  founding  of  this 
great  Nation.  It  also  marks  the  200th  anniversary  of  the  publication  of  one  of 
the  world's  greatest  books,  The  Wealth  of  Nations.  I  would  like  to  take  the 
text  for  my  statement  today  from  Adam  Smith's  opus.  While  he  wrote  in  1776, 
it  is  still  true  today  that : 

No  regulation  of  commerce  can  increase  the  quaiftity  of  industry  in  any 
society  beyond  what  its  capital  can  maintain.  It  can  only  divert  a  part  of  it 
into  a  direction  into  which  it  might  not  otherwise  have  gone;  and  it  is  by 
no   means   certain   that   this  artificial   direction  is  likely   to   be  more  ad- 
vantageous to  the  society  than  that  into  which  it  would  have  gone  of  its 
own  accord. 
Adam  Smith  understated  the  case.  My  research  and  that  of  others  show  that 
regulation  produces  wastes,  higher  prices,  and  often  poorer  service.  My  work 
has  covered  ICC  regulation  of  surface  freight  transportation,  the  regulation  of 
trucking  in   Europe,   the   regulation  of  electric  utilities  by   state  commissions, 
occupational  licensing,  and  the  regulation  of  stock  market  margin  requirements. 
As  a  result  of  these  studies  and  the  studies  of  others  it  is  possible  to  draw 
some  conclusions  about  regulation  as  a  whole.  Regulation's  main  effect  is  to  in- 
crease the  cost  of  the  product  or  service  offered ;  normally  consumers  will  have 
to  pay  higher  prices  ;  even  the  regulated  gain  little. 

Transportation  regulation,  which  I  have  been  studying  in  recent  years,  is 
particularly  relevant  to  the  topic  of  these  hearings.  I  found  in  studying  the 
regulation  of  surface  freight  transportation  by  the  Interstate  Commerce  Com- 
mission that  it  had  increased  the  cost  to  our  country  of  moving  our  goods  between 
$3.8  and  $8.8  billion  in  1968.  The  cost  today  with  inflation  is  obviously 
much  higher.  This  cost  stems  from  ICC  efforts  to  insure  that  each  of  the  firms 
under  its  control  is  profitable.  In  order  to  insure  profitability  of  even  ineflacient 
firms,  the  ICC  restricts  competition  by  attempting  to  give  each  firm  a  limited 
market  that  few  if  any  other  firms  my  serve.  In  order  to  restrict  competition 
firms  are  often  granted  authority  to  carry  goods  from  one  part  of  the  country  to 
another  but  without  authority  to  carry  goods  on  the  back  haul.  Route  restrictions 
have  forced  trucking  firms  to  drive  hundreds  of  miles  out  of  their  way  or  not 
offer  a  through  service  between  points  they  are  authorized  to  serve. 

I  have  just  returned  from  studying  regulation  of  trucking  in  Europe.  West 
Germany  has  the  most  strict  regulation  in  Europe,  controlling  both  rates  and 
trucking  capacity.  Trucking  rates  in  West  Germany  in  1973  were  over  50  percent 
higher  than  in  Great  Britain  which  has  no  economic  regulation  whatsoever. 
But  interestingly  enough  profits  appear  to  be  as  high  or  higher  in  the  uncontrolled 
British  situation  than  in  West  Germany. 

Economic  theory  and  some  evidence  have  shown  that  regulation  of  utilities 
tends  to  inflate  costs.  Becau.se  regulators  permit  firms  to  earn  a  certain  rate  of 
profit  on  their  investment,  regulated  utilities  have  a  tendency  to  substitute  capi- 
tal, which  goes  into  their  rate  ba.se,  for  labor.  This  means  that  they  can  earn 
larger  profits  although  costs  of  production  as  well  as  utility  rates  will  be  higher. 
My  own  research  indicates  that  utility  rate  regulation  has  not  appreciably  re- 


83 

duced  rates  below  what  the  firms  would  charge  in  the  absence  of  such  regulation. 
Under  some  plausible  assumptions  rates  are  actually  higher  for  electric  utilities 
than  they  would  be  if  there  were  no  controls. 

The  problem  is  that  regulation  as  a  process  is  inherently  faulty.  No  rewriting 
of  the  regulatory  statutes  or  appointment  of  better  regulators  can  do  more  than 
make  some  minor  improvements  in  a  bad  situation.  There  are  a  number  of  reasons 
why  regulation  is  inherently  faulty,  some  of  which  I  will  touch  on,  others  will  be 
discussed  in  more  depth  by  my  colleague  this  morning,  Roger  Noll. 

I  would  like  to  emphasize  the  compulsion  of  each  regulator  to  protect  his  par- 
ticular industry.  In  some  cases  the  act  establishing  the  regulation  makes  specific 
the  need  to  promote  the  health  of  the  industry.  For  example  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Act  specifies  in  Title  I  that : 

In  the  exercise  and  performance  of  its  powers  and  duties  under  this  Act, 
the  Board  shall  consider  the  following  *  *  *  as  being  in  the  public  inter- 
est *  *  *  (a)  The  encouragement  and  development  of  an  air-transportation 
system  *  *  *  (b)  The  regulation  of  air-transportation  in  such  manner  as 
to  *  *  *  foster  sound  economic  conditions  in,  such  transportation  *  *  *. 

Given  that  mandate  how  can  the  CAB  idly  stand  by  while  Pan  American  fails? 
It  can't.  In  1974  the  CAB  approved  four  rate  increases  for  international  opera- 
tions to  bail  out  Pan  Am  and  TWA. 

i^ailure  of  a  major  company  regulated  by  an  agency  is  considered  to  be  a 
failure  of  that  regulatory  agency.  But  under  a  few  market  system,  both  the 
carrot  and  the  stick  are  needed.  Failure  is  necessary  to  force  firms  to  meet  the 
needs  of  the  public.  Even  where  an  act  establi>hing  a  regulatory  commission 
does  not  specify  that  a  prosperous  industry  is  important,  regulators  will  believe 
that  unless  the  regulated  firms  earn  profits  they  will  be  unable  to  serve  their 
customers.  Thus  the  regulators  will  consider  it  their  duty  to  the  public  and  to 
consumers  to  make  the  industry  profitable  and  one  of  the  most  efficient  ways  to 
accomplish  that  is  to  reduce  competition. 

Your  committee  in  hearings  last  fall  investigated  a  clear  example  of  the  tend- 
ency of  regulation  to  restrict  competition.  As  your  excellent  staff  report  brought 
out,  the  CAB  was  attempting  to  set  minimum  charter  fares  to  I'educe  competi- 
tion. To  quote  from  your  report,  such  minimum  rates  were  sought  "in  order  to 
help  Pan  American  with  its  financial  problems." 

Prohibiting  regulators  from  restricting  competition  in  order  to  protect  com- 
petitors won't  work.  The  Congress  in  the  Transportation  Act  of  1958,  wrote  a 
clear  prohibition  on  protecting  one  mode  from  competition  of  another,  yet  the 
ICC  has  continued  to  do  just  that.  Protecting  competitors  and  reducing  competi- 
tion is  inherent  in  all  economic  regulation. 

In  inherently  competitive  industries  such  as  airlines  and  trucking  it  is  vir- 
tually impossible  for  the  regulators  to  eliminate  competition.  The  best  the  regu- 
lators can  do  is  to  eliminate  price  comi>etition  and  thus  to  hold  prices  up.  But 
this  simply  stimulates  firms  to  compete  in  non-price  areas.  A  few  years  ago  the 
international  airlines  engaged  in  a  sandwich  war  to  attract  passengers.  More 
recently  in  the  U.S.  we  have  witnessed  a  seating  war,  with  airlines  competing  to 
offer  the  most  comfortable  .seats  in  coach  class.  Last  fall  there  was  a  free  drink 
war.  Since  rates  are  identical  due  to  CAB  regulation,  airlines  compete  by  pur- 
chasing the  most  up-to-date  equipment  and  phasing  out  older  and  slower  equip- 
ment long  before  it  would  be  obsolete  under  a  more  rational  system.  No  scheme 
of  regulation  that  permits  management  to  manage  the  firms  can  eliminate  non- 
price  competition.  There  are  an  infinite  number  of  ways  firms  can  compete.  As  a 


84 

result  of  the  non-price  competition,  most  of  the  profits  originally  generated  by 
high  rates  are  dissipated. 

In  adtiition  to  the  inevitability  of  non-price  competition,  which  tends  to  erode 
the  profits  that  the  regulators  are  attempting  to  guarantee  he  industry,  the  firms 
compete  for  regulatory  favors.  If  a  route  to  Hawaii  or  Florida  is  profitable,  firms 
can  and  will  spend  millions  in  legal  fees  and  legal  maneuvers  attempting  to  win 
the  franchise  or  to  block  others  from  securing  the  franchise.  For  example,  sup- 
pose that  a  firm  is  earning  one  million  in  clear  profits  a  year  from  a  route.  It  is 
then  worth  spending  up  to  a  million  a  year  to  block  the  introduction  of  competi- 
tors. To  the  would-be  comi>etitor  it  may  be  worth  half  a  million  if  he  enters.  As 
a  result  the  potential  entrant  will  be  willing  to  spend  large  sums  to  secure  a 
license,  perhaps  as  much  as  two  and  a  half  million  dollars.  The  entire  profit  on 
such  a  route  can  be  dissipated  in  this  competition  for  licenses. 

In  many  ways  regulation  is  the  worst  of  all  worlds  for  everyone.  While  the 
regulators  try  to  guarantee  profits,  non-price  competition  and  legal  competition 
work  to  eliminate  the  profits.  Consumers  pay  high  prices  but  the  regulated  firms 
don't  reap  the  benefits.  Costs  are  inflated ;  profits  are  no  greater  than  they  would 
be  without  regulation  ;  and  prices  are  higher. 


Prepared  Statement  of  Roger  G.  Noll,  Professor  of  Economics,  California 
Institute  of  Technology 

the  causes  of  regulatory  failures 

During  the  past  15  years  an  impressive  literature  has  developed  in  economics, 
law  and  political  science  evaluating  the  performance  of  regulatory  agencies. 
To  an  extent  uncharacteristic  of  academic  research,  this  literature  is  remark- 
ably consistent  in  its  principal  finding.  Most  scholars  of  public  policies  toward 
business  have  come  to  believe  that  public  utility  regulation — the  control  of 
prices,  profits,  service  quality  and  the  entry  and  exit  of  firms  from  the  industry — 
is  an  exceptionally  costly,  ineffective  instrument  of  government  policy.  Numerous 
studies  published  in  the  last  few  years  have  identified  gross  inefficiencies  and 
inequities  in  the  key  sectors  subject  to  regulation — transportation,  communica- 
tions, energy — that  can  be  traced  to  seemingly  nonsensical  rules  and  policies  of 
regulatory  agencies. 

The  purpose  of  my  statement  is  not  to  discuss  in  detail  the  findings  of  these 
research  studies,  since  many  of  the  authors  of  such  studies  will  be  heard  at 
these  hearings.  Instead,  this  statement  deals  with  the  causes  of  regulatory  fail- 
ures, with  the  purpose  being  to  contribute  to  the  dialog  about  the  possible  mecha- 
nisms for  reforming  or  replacing  regulatory  institutions. 

In  establishing  institutions  to  control  the  market  activities  of  private  firms, 
government  is  faced  with  two  dilemmas.  These  dilemmas  are  probably  unresolv- 
able,  and  thereby  guarantee  that  the  agency  will  impose  serious  social  costs  if  it 
tries  to  do  the  job  for  which  it  was  created. 

The  first  dilemma  arises  from  the  incompatibility  of  structuring  a  decision 
process  that  is  "fair",  e.g.,  decisionmakers  are  accountable  for  their  actions, 
individuals  are  accorded  due  process,  etc.,  and  that  makes  decisions  with  dis- 
patch. It  is  inconceivable  that  the  kinds  of  power  to  redistribute  wealth  that 


85 

inheres  in  regulatory  institutions  would  be  delegated  to  any  bureaucracy  with- 
out subjecting  the  decisions  to  judicial  review  and  without  giving  affected  in- 
dividuals the  right  to  plead  their  cases  before  decisionmakers. 

To  safeguard  the  rights  of  individuals  against  capricious  and  arbitrary  de- 
cisions of  an  agency  requires  establishing  decisionmaking  procedures  that 
normally  cause  decisions  on  important  issues  to  be  protracted.  This  can  create 
serious  problems  in  three  types  of  circumstances :  when  rapid  inflation  pushes 
costs  up  and  firms  can  not  respond  to  cost  increases  by  raising  prices  until  a 
protracted  regulatory  review  has  been  completed,  when  a  technological  develop- 
ment that  would  lower  costs  and  improve  service  quality  can  not  be  fully  ex- 
ploited without  regulatory  review,  and  when  an  innovative  new  firm  seeks  to 
enter  a  regulated  market  but  must  first  win  the  approval  of  the  regulators. 
The  last  two  effects  significantly  reduce  the  incentive  to  the  firm  to  be  innovative, 
since  to  all  the  risk  and  costs  of  innovation  are  added  the  expense  in  time  and 
resources  of  a  regulatory  proceeding,  while  the  risk  of  a  more  innovative  com- 
petitor capturing  a  superior  market  position  is  reduced. 

The  second  major  dilemma  of  regulatory  institutions  reflects  the  trade-off  be- 
tween an  expensive  regulatory  process  and  a  process  that  is  insulated  from  the 
individuals  affected  by  its  outcomes.  In  part  because  the  preservation  of  account- 
ability and  due  process  through  judicial  review  makes  participation  in  the  regu- 
latory process  expensive,  and  in  part  because  the  vast  majority  of  persons  who 
are  affected  by  regulatory  decisions  are  not  eft'ectively  organized  to  represent 
themselves  in  regulatory  proceedings,  the  flow  of  information  and  proposed  rules 
to  the  agency  is  one-sided.  A  passive  agency  that  relies  upon  the  evidence  supplied 
by  participants  in  the  process  will  inevitably  make  decisions  based  upon  incom- 
plete as^sessments  of  the  issues  at  hand ;  an  agency  that  can  generate  its  own, 
independent  flow  of  information  on  every  important  case  will  be  much  more  ex- 
pensive to  operate.  In  fact,  none  of  the  federal  regulatory  authorities  engaged  in 
price  and  profit  regulation  devotes  anywhere  near  the  resources  to  generating 
information  for  use  in  regulatory  proceedings  that  is  committed  by  the  industries 
they  regulate. 

The  recent  debate  over  the  regulation  of  cable  television  is  an  illustrative  case 
in  point :  the  final  regulatory  rules  were  worked  out  by  a  coalition  of  broadcasters, 
cable  system  owners  and  program  producers.  While  each  of  these  groups  cast 
their  arguments  defending  their  own  positions  in  terms  of  the  beneficial  effects  a 
system  sati.«fying  them  would  have  on  society  at  large,  and  while  the  FCC  devoted 
some  staff  resources  to  investigating  the  stake  of  viewers  in  the  issue,  nevertheless 
the  final  comi)romise  was  hammered  out  exclusively  by  the  well-represented 
special  interests,  and  was  adopted  by  the  FCC  explicitly  because  none  of  the 
three  groups  would  appeal  the  compromise,  legally  or  politically. 

These  endemic  problems  of  regulation  do  not  necessarily  lead  to  the  conclusion 
that  under  no  conditions  should  industry  be  regulated.  All  that  they  imply  is  that 
certain  inevitable  costs  are  to  be  expected.  Generally,  these  costs  will  be  higher  if : 
1)  the  sophistication  required  to  determine  the  true  technical  and  economic  condi- 
tions of  the  industry  is  greater,  2)  the  greater  the  iX)rtion  of  the  effects  of  regula- 
tion that  is  diffused  over  a  large,  heterogeneous  group  that  is  unlikely  to  be  effec- 
tively organized,  and  3)  the  more  uncertain  and  rapidly  changing  the  economic 
environment  in  which  the  regulated  firms  operate,  such  as  is  the  case  during 
a  period  of  rapid  inflation  or  deepening  recession. 


The  cost  of  regulation  is  also  likely  to  be  greater  the  more  competitive  the  regu- 
lated industry.  This  is  because  entrenched  firms  are  to  some  extent  protected  from 
competition  by  the  slowness  and  costs  of  procedures  that  must  be  followed  by 
new  entrants  into  a  market.  In  addition,  the  regulatory  forum  allows  competitive 
firms  to  engage  in  a  far  greater  degree  of  collusive  behavior  than  would  be 
permitted  in  a  normal  competitive  circumstance.  And  by  exercising  some  control 
over  the  information  flowing  to  the  agencies,  while  constituting  the  primary 
threat  of  appeal  to  the  agency's  decision,  the  industry  can  push  the  agency  to  make 
policies  and  adopt  rules  that  enforce  cartel-like  behavior  upon  the  firms  in  the 
industry.  These  type  of  actions — the  mutual  service  reduction  agreements  among 
the  airlines  that  were  promoted  by  the  CAB  are  good  examples — would  surely  be 
antitrust  violations  in  the  absence  of  the  protective  umbrella  of  the  regulatory 
statutes. 

The  principal  conclusion  of  the  preceding  remarks  is  rather  straightforward : 
one  should  keep  in  mind  the  costs  of  regulation  when  deciding  whether  to  regulate 
any  particular  industry,  and  whether  to  continue  to  regulate  an  industry  that  was 
subjected  to  regulation  when  circumstances  were  far  different  from  the  present. 
For  example,  if  an  industry  becomes  increasingly  able  to  support  a  competitive 
market  structure  as  time  progresses,  the  expected  costs  of  regulation  will  increase 
while  the  expected  benefits  of  regulation  will  decline. 

Presumably  the  argument  for  regulation  of  most  industries  is  more  complex 
than  simply  the  avoidance  of  monopolistic  practices.  In  the  case  of  domestic  air- 
lines, regulation  has  a  certain  promotional  feature,  owing  to  the  affects  at- 
tributed to  an  extensive  air  route  structure  on  economic  development,  the  dis- 
tribution of  economic  activity,  and  national  defense.  "Without  debating  the  merits 
of  these  contentions — which  are,  of  course,  eminently  debatable — the  issue  re- 
mains which  policy  instrument  can  most  effectively  generate  the  desired  route 
structure.  The  diflBculty  with  the  regulatory  approach  is  that  this  explicit  pro- 
motional aim  gives  the  regulatory  authority  an  even  greater  industry-orientation 
than  the  institutional  dilemmas  would  normally  produce.  On  the  industry's  part, 
promotional,  cost-plus  regulatory  policies  generate  overly  optimistic  investment 
plans  since  the  incentive  for  investment  is  heightened  by  the  belief  by  firms  that 
regulators  will  act  to  ameliorate  at  least  some  of  the  financial  losses  that  will 
be  suffered  if  an  investment  plan  proves  too  optimistic.  On  the  agency's  part,  fi- 
nancial failure  of  a  regulated  firm  is  at  best  an  embarrassment  and  at  worst  a 
serious  problem :  the  failure  may  be  attributed  to  the  decisions  of  the  agency, 
and.  in  any  event,  will,  at  least  temporarily,  cause  the  pattern  of  service  to  fall 
short  of  the  promotional  objective  that  led  the  agency  to  acquiesce  to  overinvest- 
ment in  the  first  place.  The  result  is  a  continuing  spiral  of  overly  optimistic 
expansions — too  many  new  planes  flown  too  frequently  over  too  many  routes — 
followed  by  policies  propounded  by  regulators  to  bail  out  their  charges. 

Deregulating  a  competitive  industry  will  undoubtedly  have  some  significant  ad- 
justment effects.  Prices  and  profits  will  probably  fall,  dramatically  so  in  the  short 
run,  some  routes  will  be  abandoned  or  be  subjected  to  sharp  service  curtailments, 
and  some  firms  may  face  bankruptcy  and  reorganization.  But  in  the  long  run, 
more  and  better  service  and  normal  profits  can  be  expected  and  at  reduced  prices, 
as  firms  learn  to  operate  more  efficiently  and  as  the  price  system  is  used  as  a 
signaling  device  for  tailoring  service  to  user  tastes. 

If  the  resulting  route  structure  is  judged  to  be  somehow  unsatisfactory  by  the 
political  process,  competitive  bidding  for  contracts  to  serve  unprofitable  routes 


87 

or  to  fly  unprofitably  large  and  fast  aircraft  into  some  cities  will  prove  a  far 
more  efficient  mechanism  for  promoting  the  industry  than  regulation.  The  key 
to  the  contract  alternative  is  its  reliance  on  the  natural  forces  of  competition  in 
all  markets,  including  the  subsidized  ones.  Even  if  Congress  desires  to  promote  a 
more  developed  route  structure  than  the  competitive  market  would  yield  but 
without  paying  subsidies  from  general  revenues — a  circumstance  which  plausibly 
suggests  that  a  subsidy  should  not  be  paid  in  any  event — an  explicit  intraindustry 
transfer,  retaining  the  competitive  market  structure,  is  still  feasible  and  subsi- 
dized routes  could  be  financed  by  a  tax  on  airline  tickets,  for  example. 

Economists  (myself  included)  blanch  at  most  any  proposal  to  engage  in  gov- 
ernment promotion  of  an  industry,  especially  when  financed  by  the  profitable 
activities  of  the  industry.  Such  "cross-subsidization"  extracts  its  own  costs  in 
terms  of  efl!iciency  of  the  economic  system,  and  these  are  not  trivial.  But  the 
point  remains  that  the  economists'  arguments  for  unregulated  competition  are  not 
dependent  upon  their  position  on  cross-subsidization,  and  the  two  issues  should 
not  be  confused.  Regulating  a  competitive  industry  inevitably  generates  costs  but 
provides  no  benefits,  except  that  in  the  short  run  existing  firms  in  the  industry 
that  have  overinvested  in  response  to  perverse  regulatory  incentives  experience 
losses  when  the  protective  shield  of  regulation  is  removed.  The  efl^cient  way  to 
promote  an  industry,  or  to  force  it  to  respond  to  considerations  not  normally  re- 
flected in  the  marketplace,  is  to  do  so  directly  through  taxes,  subsidies  and  per- 
formance standards  tied  specifically  to  the  policy  concern  of  the  government. 


Mr.  Breyer.  I  think  it  will  be  2:30  when  we  reconvene  this 
afternoon. 

[Whereupon  the  subcommittee  adjourned  at  1 :25  p.m.,  to  recon- 
vene at  2:30  p.m.  that  same  day.] 

AFTERNOON    SESSION 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  subcommittee  will  come  to  order. 

Our  next  witness  is  Mr.  Alfred  Kahn,  chairman  of  the  Public 
Service  Commission,  State  of  New  York,  who  taught  economics  at 
Yale  University  and  served  as  a  senior  staff  member  of  the  economic 
advisers,  and  is  presently  on  leave  from  Cornell  University.  He  has 
written  extensively  in  the  area  of  economic  regulation. 

Mr.  Kahn. 

STATEMENT  OF  ALFRED  E.  KAHN,  CHAIRMAN,  NEW  YORK  STATE 
PUBLIC   SERVICE   COMMISSION 

Mr.  Kahn.  I  am  very  honored  by  your  invitation  to  testify  here. 

I  have  been  asked  to  hold  my  testimony  to  10  minutes,  which  means 
I  will  have  to  talk  terribly  fast.  I  will  make  no  effort  to  read  my 
statement. 


88 

I  hope  I  am  not  here  under  false  pretenses.  I  have  been  a  student  of 
economic  reguLition  for  some  time  and  now  a  practitioner,  but  I  am 
not  an  expert  on  the  airline  industry  and  do  not  presume  to  come  to 
you  with  explicit  reconunendations. 

There  are  certain  common  tendencies  and  patterns  in  regulation, 
however,  which  I  would  like  to  bring  to  your  attention.  In  fact.  I  will 
make  four  points  which  may  be  illuminating  to  you.  at  least  10  minutes 
worth.  If  you  try  to  follow  my  statement  you  would  not  succeed. 

KEGULATIOX    IS  AX  IMPERFECT    IXSTITUTIOX 

First,  it  is  a  commonplace  observation  that  regulation  is  a  very  im- 
perfect institution.  I  think  it  is  essential  where  competition  is  not  feasi- 
ble, and  of  course  that  is  where  I  happen  to  operate,  in  Xew  York  State, 
that  is  to  say  where  competition  is  inconsistent  with  economies  of  scale. 
But  it  cannot  do  what  competition  does.  It  cannot  innovate.  It  cannot 
force  companies  to  be  efficient.  It  cannot  force  management  to  be  enter- 
prising. It  cannot  make  companies  risk  their  own  capital.  So  regulation 
has  an  inevitable  large  element  of  cost-plus  in  it  with  all  the  familiar 
deficiencies  of  such  arrangements. 

REGrLATIOX   IS   AXTITHETICAL   TO    COMPETITIOX 

Point  Xo.  "2 :  Although  there  are  many  ways  in  which  it  makes  sense 
to  try  to  introduce  competition  into  a  regulated  system,  still  funda- 
mental competition  and  regulation  are  antithetical. 

I  think,  possibly  the  airline  industry  performs  better  than  it  would 
by  virtue  of  the  presence  of  some  competition  in  it.  But  fundamentally, 
there  is  something  inherent  in  regulation  that  makes  it  hostile  to 
competition. 

By  the  way.  this  has  nothing  to  do  with  honesty  or  corruption  or 
irresponsibility  of  regulatoi-s.  It  has  to  do  with  the  fact  that  under 
competition  nobody  is  responsible  for  supply,  no  single  firm  has  an 
obligation  to  serve.  The  protection  of  consumers,  the  assurance  of  sup- 
ply comes  from  the  impersonal  functioning  of  the  competitive  market. 

In  a  regulatory  situation,  in  contrast,  we  rely  on  chosen  instruments, 
identifiable  firms  and  the  i-egulator  himself. 

As  a  result,  I.  as  chairman  of  the  Public  Service  Commission  of 
New  York,  feel  a  kind  of  direct  pei-sonal  responsibility  for  seeing 
to  it  that  lights  will  go  on  in  19S5  when  people  flick  on  the  switches. 
That  means"  that  I  have  to  be  very  solicitious  of  the  financial  health 
of  those  chosen  instrument  companies.  Similarly,  every  i-esponsible 
airline  regulator  will  undoubtedly  tell  you  that  he  has  an  enonnous 
responsibility  for  the  continuation  of  ample,  safe,  and  economical  air 


89 

service.  That  inevitably  produces  a  distrust  of  price  competition.  It 
is  a  nuisance,  a  threat  to  the  financial  health  of  the  chosen  instruments. 
Competitive  innovations  may  suddenly  render  obsolete  a  whole  bunch 
of  equipment.  Competitors  have  an  inherent  tendency,  in  the  words  of 
regulators  and  regulatees,  to  skim  the  cream  off  the  market,  which  is 
only  to  say  they  tend  to  go  in  naturally  where  prices  are  high,  and 
they  stay  out  where  costs  are  high  relative  to  price.  So  the  regulator 
will  ask  you  how  they  are  supposed  to  supply  continued  service  in 
bad  weather  as  well  as  good,  in  the  winter  as  well  as  the  sununer,  over 
lightly-traveled  as  well  as  heavily-traveled  routes,  if  competitors  are 
allowed  to  come  in  and  skim  off  the  cream  off  the  profitable  operations 
that  support  the  unprofitable.  So,  to  a  regulator,  competition  is  a 
nuisance. 

This  means  that  where  you  are  dealing  with  an  industry  that  is 
structurally  competitive — the  brokerage  business  on  security  ex- 
changes, trucking — regulation  typically  involves  cartelization.  It 
means  holding  prices  up,  not  down,  it  means  preserving  market  shares 
of  existing  firms.  Now,  that  is  a  distinction  not  often  made.  Ask  your- 
self when  you  look  at  a  particular  instance  of  regulation :  Is  it  f imc- 
tioning  to  keep  price  down,  which  I  think  is  my  job  in  Xew  York 
State,  or  to  keep  prices  from  falling,  which  often  happens  in  trans- 
portation ?  Or  again,  is  it  trying  to  hold  the  quality  of  service  up,  or 
is  it  trying  to  hold  service  competition  down,  as  I  think  you  will  find 
in  the  airline  industry.  That  is  my  second  point.  There  is  a  basic 
antithesis  here.  You  have  to  choose. 

REGULATION   PRODUCES   CARTELIZATION   AND   INEFFICIENCY 

No.  3,  in  these  structurally  competitive  situations,  regulation  and  the 
cartelization  that  goes  with  it,  it  is  terribly  inefficient  in  terms  of 
producing  at  the  lowest  possible  cost.  In  some  ways,  it  is  the  worst  of 
all  possible  worlds.  It  is  worse  than  single-firm  monopoly ;  it  is  worse 
than  competition,  no  matter  how  imperfect  competition  is. 

It  is  hostile  to  letting  business  go  into  the  most  efficient  firms. 
Instead,  it  tries  to  preserve  the  market  shares  of  all  firms,  high-cost 
and  low-cost.  Think  of  the  ICC  and  its  limitations  on  competition  by 
the  railroads,  often  when  they  can  reach  out  and  take  business  at  a 
lower  incremental  cost,  not  letting  them  do  so.  Think  of  the  proration- 
ing  of  crude  oil.  To  the  extent  they  cut  back  output,  they  did  not  cut 
back  equally,  but  instead  they  imposed  stringent  controls  on  the  low- 
cost  wells,  at  the  extreme  of  holding  them  down  to  8  days  of  produc- 
tion a  month,  and  exempted  the  high-cost  marginal  producers.  They 
had  higher  quotas  for  deep  wells,  because  they  were  more  costly. 


90 

Cartels  encourage  inefficiency  in  another  way.  If  you  hold  price  up, 
it  induces  people  to  try  to  expand  capacity.  Inside  tne  cartel,  by  drill- 
ing additional  oil  weils  or  scheduling  more  flights,  or  outside  the 
cartel,  look  what  is  happening  in  the  oil  industry  today.  The  result 
is,  if  the  cartel  is  going  to  lunction,  it  has  to  cut  back  output  more  and 
more,  so  that  everybody  operates  at  an  inefficient  level  of  capacity. 

That  is  my  third  point :  Cartelization  tends  to  be  terribly  inefficient. 

Before  getting  to  my  fourth  point,  I  would  like  to  explain  the 
simple  economics  of  why  cartels  produce  inefficiency.  I  will  do  so 
in  the  form  of  a  series  of  propositions,  but  with  enough  illustra- 
tions to  demonstrate  that  I  am  talking  about  the  real  world.  If  regula- 
tion limits  competition,  it  must  be  because  some  competition  would 
otherwise  be  feasible:  Ability  and  will  to  compete  are  therefore 
present.  And  if  the  regulation  is  effective,  it  will  hold  price  above 
the  costs  of  at  least  some  producers  or  potential  producers.  I  have 
already  described  how  this  sets  up  persistent  temptations  for  firms 
already  inside  the  cartel  to  expand  their  capacity  and  output,  and 
for  firms  outside  the  market,  and  possibly  outside  the  boundaries  of 
the  cartel,  to  enter,  increasing  the  aggregate  capacity  hanging  over 
the  market  and  creating  the  necessity  for  progressive  cutbacks  of  out- 
put quotas,  if  the  price  is  to  be  sustained.  These  temptations  cease 
only  when  output  is  so  curtailed,  and  unit  costs  of  production  so 
increased,  by  the  production  cutbacks  that  entry  and  investment  in 
new  capacity  are  no  longer  attractive. 

REGULATION  INDUCES  EXCESS  PRICE  AND  SERVICE  TO  THE  EXTENT  THAT  THE 
INDUSTRY   IS    NATURALLY    COMPETITIVE 

For  exactly  the  same  reasons,  and  this  is  my  fourth  point :  Controls 
over  price  competition  are  subject  to  evasion  because  of  the  incentive 
they  provide  for  accentuated  quality  and  service  rivalry,  limited  only 
by  the  ingenuity  of  businessmen  in  seeking  new  methods  of  enticing 
customers  to  them.  I  do  not  have  to  cite  you  the  airline  examples  of 
that,  the  strenuous  competition,  instead  of  via  price,  in  adopting  the 
most  modern  equipment,  in  the  frequency  in  which  they  schedule 
their  flights,  in  attractive  hostesses,  in-flight  entertainment,  food  and 
drink. 

Let  me  state  the  general  underlying  principle:  If  regulation  or 
cartelization  prevent  price  from  falling  to  costs,  then,  to  the  extent 
that  competition  continues  to  prevail,  it  will  tend  to  raise  cost  to  the 
level  of  price. 


91 

One  of  the  most  flagrant  examples  of  this — and  it  is  a  liistorical 
one — I  do  not  know  wlietlier  it  represents  CAB  policy  today — was 
the  refusal  of  the  CAB  to  let  carriers  with  older  piston  equipment 
reduce  their  rates  sufficiently  below  the  level  for  jet  fares  to  keep  that 
piston  equipment  in  service  as  long  as  economically  justified.  Carriers 
asked  the  CAB  to  let  them  reduce  those  rates,  the  CAB  said  no  it 
would  not  permit  them.  Now,  if  the  prices  are  kept  equal,  then  of 
course  nobody  is  going  to  go  on  a  piston  craft. 

What  is  wrong  with  service  competition  of  this  sort?  Surely  in 
some  degree  it  is  obviously  desirable.  The  more  flights  you  have  sched- 
uled the  more  convenient  it  is.  What  is  wrong  with  it,  is  that  cus- 
tomers, if  you  do  not  have  price  competition,  are  not  given  a  choice, 
and  so  you  have  no  way  of  knowing  whether  your  quality  competition 
is  excessive.  The  only  way  of  testing  whether  the  increment  of  in- 
service  quality  involved,  for  example,  in  more  intensive  scheduling  is 
worth  the  higher  cost,  is  to  offer  shippers  or  travelers  the  choice  be- 
tween lower  rates  and  less  frequent  operations,  on  the  one  hand,  and 
higher  rates  to  cover  the  costs  of  more  frequent  scheduling,  on  the 
other.  The  same  flights  that  provide  no  food,  drink,  or  entertainment, 
on  the  one  hand,  and  sumptuous  flights,  on  the  other,  and  as  many 
other  combinations  as  feasible  in  between. 

In  my  paper  I  refer  to  the  same  tendency  in  the  security  brokerage 
business.  They  compete  in  salesmanship,  and  free  advice.  Wliat  about 
the  fellow  who  says  I  do  not  want  salesmanship,  I  just  want  to  con- 
summate a  transaction  ? 

That,  of  course,  is  what  competition  does,  it  off'ers  you  such  choices. 
Now,  in  these  circumstances,  it  is  understandable  that  regulators  have 
constantly  to  spread  the  net  of  their  regulation.  If  they  can  raise 
prices,  then  people  want  to  expand  output,  so  they  have  to  control  out- 
put. If  they  do  that,  they  find  it  attracts  new  firms  into  the  market,  and 
then  they  have  to  keep  firms  out  of  the  market.  If  they  do  that  and 
still  hold  the  price  up,  and  find  this  attracts  imports,  then  they  have 
to  put  quotas  on  inputs.  If  they  prevent  price  competition,  and  firms 
escape  it  by  engaging  in  destructive  quality  competition,  then  they 
find  themselves  forced  to  put  a  lid  on  quality  competition,  too. 

All  these  tendencies  of  regulation  in  a  structurally  competitive  in- 
dustry inescapably  raise  the  question  of  whether  it  would  not  be  pref- 
erable simply  to  abandon  economic  regulation,  and  open  the  field  to 
competition. 

Did  I  make  it  in  10  minutes  ? 


92 

THE  GENERAL  CONDITIONS  OF  DESTRrCTI^^R   COMPETITION 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  about  the  other  side  of  the  coin,  though, 
what  about  the  destructive  competition?  Don't  we  have  the  most  elab- 
orate service  of  air  transportation  in  the  world,  and  probably  the 
safest?  That  is  certainly  woiih  something  to  the  traveling  consumer. 
How  can  we  be  so  sure  that  if  you  allow  competition  you  will  not  get 
destructive  competition  and  uncertainty  and  unrealiability  ? 

Mr.  Kahn.  Those  are  real  questions  which  explain  my  qualification 
at  the  beginning,  I  am  not  going  to  be  able  to  give  you  decisive 
answers.  But  I  do  have  a  few  suggestions  of  places  to  look. 

First,  no  businessman  protected  from  competition  ever  believes  com- 
petition is  anything  but  destructive.  In  the  same  way,  he  does  not 
use  the  word  "competitor"  he  uses  "chiseler." 

Second,  there  are  conditions  which  are  conducive  to  destructive  com- 
petition, and  you  have  to  see  if  they  apply  in  this  case.  Where  you 
have  very  heavy  capital  costs,  or  enormous  economies  of  scale  such 
that  marginal  costs  are  typically  Avay  below  average  costs  you  will 
have  a  tendency  for  competition  to  drive  rates  down  to  that  level. 
You  will  want  to  look  and  see  whether  that  is  really  true  in  this  in- 
dustry. Third,  is  capital  immobile?  Once  it  is  there,  does  it  tend  to 
get  stuck  and  not  be  able  to  get  out  ? 

Well,  in  trucking,  of  which  I  have  a  greater  knowledge,  I  emphasize 
that  trucks  are  very  mobile,  they  can  move  from  one  market  to  the 
next.  Moreover,  a  large  part  of  your  costs  are  variable;  so  prices  can- 
not go  down  very  far.  If  you  can  move,  especially  with  transporta- 
tion equipment,  you  can  move  to  another  market,  competition  in  any 
market  cannot  be  destructive. 

Fourth,  is  entry  likely  to  be  excessive?  Well,  I  am  very  skeptical 
that  you  will  have  rapid  entry  into  airline  mai'kets.  It  is  not  an  easy 
thing,  where  you  have  product  ditferentiation  in  these  markets  and 
the  attractiveness  of  known  brands,  I  am  skeptical  of  that. 

Look  at  some  areas  where  you  have  unregulated  com])etition.  You 
have  probably  heard  the  story  of  California  and  Texas.  I  would  look 
very  carefully  at  those  instances.  It  appears  they  have  effective  com- 
petition, and  it  is  not  destructive. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  it  would  be  useful  to  have  some- 
body on  the  regulatory  commission  who  is  an  economist? 

Mr.  Kahn.  Why  I  think  it  would  be  marvelous.  No,  I  really  be- 
lieve that.  Senator  Kennedy.  It  is  amazing  to  me  how  few  econo- 
mists there  are.  I  think  it  mijrht  be  fatal  if  thev  are  all  economists. 


There  is  a  perspective  that  an  economist  brings  that  is  very  important. 
An  economist  tends  to  think  in  terms  of  benefits  versus  costs,  and  every 
decision  we  make  in  our  society  today  is  a  benefit-cost  measurement, 
whether  we  like  it  or  not. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thanks  very  much.  I  hope  you  make  your  plane. 

It  was  very  interesting  and  very  helpful. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Kahn  follows :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Alfred  C.  Kahn,  Chairman,  New  York  State  Public 
Service  Commission 

I  am  honored  by  your  invitation  to  testify  before  your  subcommittee  on  the 
reguhition  of  tlie  airline  industry.  I  trust  I  do  not  appear  here  under  false  pre- 
tenses. I  have  for  many  years  been  a  student  of  the  economics  of  regulation,  and 
now  find  myself  a  practitioner,  but  I  do  not  consider  myself  sufficiently  expert 
on  the  airline  industry  to  presume  to  give  you  specific  recommendations  about 
how  it  should  be  regulated,  or  whether  it  should  be  regulated  at  all. 

And  yet,  whi.e  it  is  true  that  each  regulated  industry  is  in  some  degree  unique 
and  the  policy  with  respect  to  it  must  be  designed  in  the  light  of  its  own  peculiar 
characteristics,  it  is  also  true  that  regulation  manifests  certain  tendencies  and 
raises  certain  problems  common  to  all  industries.  I  hope  therefore  that,  by  de- 
scribing to  you  those  general  tendencies  and  problems  that  seem  to  me  particularly 
pertinent  to  airlines,  I  may  be  of  help  to  you  in  your  effort  to  assess  the  system 
of  regulation  that  we  apply  to  that  industry  today  in  the  United  States. 

The  first  observation  I  would  like  to  make  is  that  competition  and  the  kind  of 
regulation  we  practice  in  the  public  utility  industries — and  that  is  the  only  kind 
of  regulation  I  am  concerned  with  in  this  testimony  ^ — are  inherently  antithetical. 
While  the  choice  between  these  two  control  mechanisms  is  rarely  absolute,  as  I 
will  point  out  presently,  society  typically  must  in  each  individual  instance  choose 
whether  to  rely  on  regulation  or  on  competition  to  protect  the  public  interest ;  it 
cannot  typically  have  both.  It  is  commonplace  that  direct  regulation  becomes 
necessary  where  competition  is  not  feasible;  regulation  is  imposed  because 
competition  is  throuiiht  to  be  ineffective.  And  it  is  now  also  commonplace  that 
regulation  has  a  strong  inherent  tendency,  in  turn,  to  control  and  eliminate  com- 
petition that  would  otlierwise  prevail. 

This  is  so  not  only  for  the  superficial  reason  that  regulation,  by  definition, 
typically  involves  the  imposition  of  limitations  on  competitive  entry  and  inde- 
pendent competitive  action  in  the  determination  of  price.  It  is  also  because  regu- 


1  Government  influences  the  functioning  of  the  economy  generally  in  a  wide  variety  of 
ways,  for  example,  by  repulating  the  supply  and  availability  of  money,  enforcinp:  contracts, 
providing  subsidies  or  tariff  jirotection,  prohibiting  unfair  competition,  imposing  standards 
for  packaging  and  product  contents,  licensing  entrants  into  various  trades  and  professions 
on  the  basis  of  qualifications,  .-ind  in  the  case  of  airlines,  licensing  pilots  and  imposing 
various  other  rules  in  the  interest  of  safety.  But  all  of  these  instances  of  regulation,  at 
least  in  principle,  are  intended  not  to  supplant  the  competitive  market  as  the  principal 
instrument  of  social  control,  but  to  supplement  it  to  remove  its  imperfections,  in  theory 
to  make  it  work  better.  The  regulation  thnt  I  am  concerned  with  in  this  testimony  is  the 
kind  that  is  practiced  in  the  public  utility  sectors  of  the  economy,  and  in  considerable 
measure  in  civil  aviation,  and  lias  as  its  central  purpose  the  direct  prescription  of  ind'istrial 
structure  and  performance,  by  such  devices  as  restricting  entry  into  the  market  to  the 
number  that  some  government  commission  determines  is  desirable  and  imposing  on  the 
certificated  firms  an  obligation  to  serve  all  customers  under  reasonable  conditions,  directly 
fi.xing  price,  and  prescribing  the  quality  and  conditions  of  service. 


94 

lation  tends  iuherently  to  place  a  heavy  emphasis  on  protecting  the  companies  it 
is  also  supposed  to  be  controlling.  I  do  not  mean  here  to  repeat  the  vulgar  popular 
notion  that  regulators  are  typically  "in  the  pockets  of  the  utility  companies,"  and 
somehow  untrue  to  the  public  interest  that  has  been  entrusted  to  them,  though 
there  are  undoubtedly  many  examples  of  this.  The  tendency  is  one  that  will 
inevitably  affect  also  honorable  and  dedicated  public  servants. 

The  reason  is  this :  Under  competition,  in  principle,  no  government  oflScial  and 
no  single  company  is  responsible  for  the  continuity  of  supply ;  no  company  has 
an  obligation  to  serve.  The  consumer's  protection  comes  from  the  impersonal 
functioning  of  the  competitive  market  itself,  from  the  rivalry  among  companies, 
from  the  fact  or  threat  of  competitive  entry.  Regulation,  instead,  relies  on  chosen 
instruments.  A  specific  company  is  given  a  franchise ;  and  that  company  and  the 
regulating  agency,  instead  of  the  market  itself,  bear  the  direct  responsibility  for 
serving  and  protecting  the  public.  That  responsibility  weighs  heavily  on  the  reg- 
ulator. I  feel  some  direct,  personal  responsibility  for  seeing  to  it  that  the  lights 
will  still  go  on  when  people  in  New  York  flick  their  switches  in  1985.  Since  it 
takes  six  to  twelve  years  to  install  new  base-load  generating  capacity.  I  have  to 
be  concerned  about  the  ability  of  the  franchised  electric  companies  in  my  State 
to  begin  taking  the  steps  today  that  will  assure  that  result  a  decade  from  now. 
And  that  means,  to  complete  the  explanation,  that  I  have  to  be  solicitous  of  the 
financial  health  of  those  chosen  instruments.  So  every  responsible  airline  regula- 
tor, similarly,  will  emphasize  his  heavy  responsibility  for  the  continued  provision 
of  ample,  safe,  and  economical  air  service  in  every  part  of  the  country. 

And  that  responsibility,  in  turn,  inevitably  breeds  a  distrust  of  competition. 
Price  competition,  particularly  in  times  of  excess  capacity,  is  a  threat  to  the 
financial  health  of  the  chosen  instrument  company.  Competitive  innovations,  intro- 
duced without  restraint,  may  suddenly  render  obsolete  the  utility  company's 
investment  in  as  yet  in  completely  depreciated  equipment,  leaving  the  residual 
of  depreciation  somehow  to  be  recovered  from  its  other  customers,  if  it  is  to  retain 
the  financial  health  and  ability  to  attract  the  capital  necessary  to  provide  con- 
tinued service.  Competitors  have  an  inherent  tendency,  in  the  words  of  regulators 
and  regulatees,  to  skim  the  cream  off  the  market — which  is  only  to  say,  very 
roughly,  to  compete  for  business  where  prices  are  far  above  costs,  and  to  leave  to 
the  chosen  instruments  the  markets  where  costs  are  far  above  price.  How,  the 
regulated  company  and  regulator  will  protest,  are  they  supposed  to  provide  con- 
tinued service  in  bad  weather  as  well  as  good,  in  the  winter  as  well  as  in  the 
summer,  over  lightly-traveled  as  well  as  heavily-traveled  routes,  if  competitors 
are  to  be  free  to  come  in  and  skim  off  the  profits  from  the  latter  that  have  been 
financing  service  on  the  former?  To  the  regulator,  then,  competition  is  disruptive 
and  threatening,  it  interferes  with  orderly  planning,  it  upsets  stable  markets ;  it 
is  something  to  be  restricted,  confined,  prohibited. 

You  will  not  need  my  help  in  seeing  manifestations  of  this  tendency  in  the  air- 
line industry. 

This  does  not  mean  that  competition  has  no  useful  role  to  play  in  regulated 
industries.  On  the  contrary.  Regulated  monopoly  is  a  very  imperfect  institution. 
The  authority  of  the  regulatory  commission  is  essentially  negative ;  at  best,  it 
serves  only  as  a  check  on  the  exercise  of  private  monopoly  power  ;  prevents  exces- 
sive profits  and  excessive  discrimination.  It  is  extremely  diflScult  for  it  to  take 
major  initiatives.  A  regulator  cannot  risk  his  own  capital,  and  the  14th  amend- 
ment puts  severe  limits  on  his  ability  to  force  the  companies  under  his  supervision 
to  risk  theirs.  He  cannot  force  a  company  to  be  progressive,  to  innovate,  indeed, 
even  to  be  efiicient.  He  cannot  do  what  a  good  management  can  do,  and  there 
is  very  little  he  can  do  about  what  poor  management  does.  In  short,  he  cannot 
supply  the  dynamic  stimulus  that  in  other  industries  is  supplied  by  competition. 


95 

There  is,  therefore,  a  very  respectable  body  of  opinion  that  regulation  really 
has  very  little  eftect.  This  view  merges  with  the  other,  which  I  have  already 
characterized,  that  regulators  tend,  almost  inevitably,  to  associate  their  concep- 
tion of  the  public  interest  with  that  of  the  companies  they  are  supposed  to  be 
regulating,  typically  protecting  them  against  competition  and  supplying  no  alter- 
native effective  stimulus.  Paradoxically,  according  to  this  view,  regulation  has  the 
greatest  eftect  in  areas,  like  transportation,  where  competition  could  otherwise 
prevail,  and  there,  because  of  its  tenuencies  to  protectionism  and  cartelization, 
it  tends  to  do  a  great  deal  of  harm ;  and  elsewhere,  in  the  presence  of  monopoly, 
its  effects  are  not  discernible. 

For  these  reasons,  where  it  can  be  permitted  without  intolerable  loss  of  efficiency 
competition  can  play  a  very  useful  supplementary  role  even  in  the  most  tightly 
regulated  industries.  In  my  judgment,  for  example,  while  the  basic  intercon- 
nected, national  communications  network  is  probably  something  like  a  natural 
monopoly,  competition  can  and  should  play  an  important  role  in  the  manufactur- 
ing industry  that  supplies  equipment  for  attachment  to  that  network  at  the  sub- 
scriber's end.  Similarly,  I  believe  that  such  competition  as  we  have  permitted 
in  the  passenger  airline  business  has,  on  balance,  improved  its  performance. 

Still,  to  return  to  my  first  major  point :  because  of  the  inherent  conflicts  and 
contradictions  between  competition  on  the  one  hand  and  regulation  on  the  other, 
and  because  of  the  inherent  tendencies  of  regulation  toward  conservatism,  pro- 
tectionism, and  cartelization.  society  must  periodically  reexamine  the  premises 
on  the  basis  of  which  it  decided  to  impose  on  the  public  utility  status  of  an 
industry,  and  consider  whether  a  return  to  essentially  unregulated  competition 
might  not  be  preferable,  as  this  Committee  is  doing  today.  This  is  especially 
important  in  those  industries,  like  transportation,  where  a  competitive  struc- 
ture may  well  be  feasible — that  is,  consistent  with  the  individual  suppliers 
achieving  most  or  all  of  the  available  economies  of  scale.  Transportation  is 
not  a  natural  monopoly.  It  is  precisely  in  such  situation  that  it  becomes  essen- 
tial for  us  periodically  to  ask  whether  regulations  may  not  be  doing  more  harm 
than  good.  In  my  own  judgment,  transportation  is  the  leading  example  of  an 
area  in  which  a  substantial  dose  of  dereguation,  and  perhaps  something  close 
to  complete  deregulation,  is  long  overdue. 

In  the  rest  of  these  comments,  I  will  suggest  to  you  why  I  think  this  kind  of 
reevaluation  is  particularly  necessary  in  an  industry  like  airline  transportation. 

Before  doing  so,  I  should  like  to  emphasize  that  competition  in  the  real  world 
is  also  a  very  imperfect  institution.  Consumers  are  rarely  adequately  informed 
about  the  choices  available  to  them,  and  as  a  result  the  competitive  advantage 
often  goes  to  the  more  effective  saleman,  or  the  less  scrupulous  advertiser,  rather 
than  the  most  efficient  producer  or  the  seller  who  gives  the  best  value  for  the 
dollar.  The  greater  the  number  of  independent  suppliers,  the  more  likely  mistakes 
are  to  be  made,  and  capital  committed  to  ventures  that  should  never  have  been 
undertaken.  Competition  is  often  wasteful,  and  produces  instability  and  uncer- 
tainty. But  most  of  us  regard  the  competitive  market  in  much  the  same  way  as 
we  regard  democracy — it  is  a  manifestly  inefficient  system  that  is  better  than  any 
available  alternative.  To  the  extent  competition  is  imperfect,  our  preferred  remedy 
is  to  try  to  diminish  its  imperfections,  rather  than  to  supplant  it  with  monopoly 
or  socialized  enterprise. 

But  public  utility-type  regulation  in  industries  that  are  potentially  and  struc- 
turally competitive  tends  to  produce  the  worst  economic  results  of  all — worse 
than  regulated,  franchised  single-form  monopoly,  on  the  one  hand,  and  worse 
than  unregulated  competition,  with  all  its  possible  wastes  and  imperfections,  on 
the  other.  There  are  so  far  two  major  reasons,  and  both  spring  from  the  fact  that 
in  industries  of  this  kind,  of  which  transportation  is  the  leading  example,  regu- 


96 

lation  specifically  involves  preventing,  controlling  and  limiting  competition — 
restricting  competitive  entry,  and  prohibiting  rivalry  in  price  and  service — in 
brief,  to  use  the  proper  term,  it  involves  cartelization. 

In  principle,  a  cartel  need  be  no  less  efficient  than  a  pure  monopoly.  Single- 
firm  monopoly  has  both  the  incentive  and  the  opportunity  to  produce  at  minimum 
cost,  to  take  fullest  possible  advantage  of  economies  of  scale,  to  adopt  the  most 
efficient  technology,  to  limit  capacity  to  the  amount  required  to  supply  the  market 
at  minimum  cost,  to  concentrate  production  in  the  lowest-cost  plants,  and  to 
operate  them  at  the  most  efficient  rates.  In  theory  a  cartel  could  do  all  these 
things,  too,  producing  the  cartel-determined  output  at  minimum  cost,  pooling, 
the  industry's  profits,  maximized  in  this  fashion,  and  distributing  them  according 
to  some  formula  among  the  cartel  partners. 

But  no  cartel  in  history,  regulated  or  unregulated,  has  to  my  knowledge  ever 
done  these  things.  The  typical  practice,  instead,  is  to  maintain  price  by  imposing 
output  quotas  on  the  several  members,  efficient  and  inefficient  alike.  Indeed, 
where  cartels  have  been  in  a  position  to  make  distim  tions,  they  have  regulated 
production  more  often  by  cutting  back  the  output  of  the  lowest-cost  producers 
than  the  other  way  around,  in  order  to  leave  room  in  the  market  for  the  higher- 
cost  firms,  whom  competition  would  otherwise  have  driven  out  of  business.  The 
result  has  been  gross  inefficiency  in  production.  We  have  had  the  abundant  ex- 
amples of  this  phenomenon  among  regulated  cartels.  Parity  price  supports  in 
agriculture  were  accompanied  by  the  imposition  of  acreage  limitations  across  the 
board.  In  petroleum  prorationing,  production  allowables  were  cut  back,  at  their 
lowest  point,  to  eight  days  a  month  for  the  typically  highest-volume  and  lowest- 
cost  wells,  while  exempted  from  all  such  restraints  were  the  highest-cost,  low- 
volume  marginal  or  stripper  wells,  and  deeper  wells  were  typically  granted  larger 
production  quotas  than  shallow  wells,  precisely  because  they  were  higher-cost ! 
And  in  transportation,  the  Interstate  Commerce  Commission  has  placed  limita- 
tions on  the  ability  of  railroads,  by  cutting  rates,  to  reach  out  for  traffic  that 
they  were  in  a  position  to  serve  at  lower  incremental  costs  than  competing 
trucks  or  barges. 

Moreover,  cartels  have  been  typically  incapable  of  imposing  full  controls  on 
investment  and  entry.  By  holding  prices  at  non-competitive  levels,  instead,  they 
have  tended  to  encourage  new  competitive  entry,  particularly,  in  areas  outside 
their  control ;  and  where  they  have  succeeded  in  restricting  entry,  they  have 
typically  been  incompletely  successful  in  restricting  the  making  of  additional  in- 
vestments by  firms  already  in  the  market — for  example,  the  drilling  of  grossly 
excessive  numbers  of  developmental  wells  in  the  oil  industry,  in  quest  of  addi- 
tional production  quotas.  Maintaining  prices  in  the  face  of  these  artifically 
stimulated  increases  in  production  capacity  has  in  turn  necessitated  further  cut- 
backs in  output  quotas,  foi'cing  producers  in  turn  to  operate  at  even  more  grossly 
suboptimal  levels,  with  correspondingly  higher  co.sts,  and  further  preventing  the 
distribution  of  the  business  to  the  lowest-co.st  suppliers.  In  these  important  ways, 
cartels  foster  inefficiencies  far  more  gross  than  either  single-firm  monopoly  or 
unregulated  competition. 

The  resulting  inefficiencies  are  in  no  sense  purely  theoretical.  The  wastes  in 
tran.sportation,  for  example,  have  been  estimated  as  running  to  billions  of  dollars 
annually  ;  and  the  wastes  of  excessive  developmental  oil  well  drilling  in  the 
late  1950's  and  early  1960's  in  this  country  were  estimated  by  knowledgeable 
industry  sources  as  running  on  the  order  of  $V2  billion  a  year. 

Second,  and  for  exactly  the  same  reason,  cartels  promote  waste  in  another 
way  that  is  particularly  pertinent  to  the  airline  industry,  by  encouraging  ex- 
cessive non-price  competition  or  service  rivalry. 

Perhaps  the  simplest  way  of  explaining  this  is  to  set  forth  the  economics  that 
underlie  both  of  these  two  tendencies  toward  inefficiency.  I  will  do  so  in  the  form 
of  a  series  of  propositions,  but  then  I  will  give  you  enough  illustrations  to  demon- 
strate that  I  am  talking  about  the  real  world.  If  regulation  limits  competition, 
it  must  be  because  some  competition  would  otherwise  be  feasible :  the  ability  and 
will  to  compete  are  therefore  present.  And  if  the  regulation  is  effective,  it  will 
hold  price  above  the  costs  of  at  least  some  producers  or  potential  producers.  I 
have  already  described  how  this  sets  up  persistent  temptations  for  firms  already 
inside  the  cartel  to  expand  their  capacity  and  output,  and  for  firms  outside  the 
market,  and  possibly  outside  tlie  boundaries  of  the  cartel,  to  enter,  increasing 
the  aggregate  capacity  hanging  over  the  market  and  creating  the  necessity  for 


97 

progressive  cutbacks  of  output  quotas  if  the  price  is  to  be  sustained.  These 
temptations  cease  only  when  output  is  so  curtailed,  and  unit  costs  of  production 
so  increased,  by  the  production  cutbacks  that  entry  and  investment  in  new 
capacity  are  no  longer  attractive. 

For  exactly  the  same  reasons,  controls  over  price  competition  are  subject  to 
evasion  because  of  the  incentive  they  provide  for  accentuated  quality  and  service 
rivalry,  limited  only  by  the  ingenuity  of  businessmen  in  seeking  new  methods  of 
enticing  customers  to  them  at  the  attractive,  cartel-sustained  price  levels.  Denied 
the  opportunity  to  compete  by  reducing  price,  they  are  induced  instead  to  compete 
for  business  in  other  ways  that  increase  costs. 

The  point  is  that  if  competition  is  sufficiently  strong  potentially  to  drive  price 
down  to  cost — and  that  is  the  reason  for  the  regulatory  restraints  being  imposed 
on  competition  in  tlie  first  place — it  will  also  ordinarily  be  sufficiently  strong  to 
induce  supplers,  confronting  a  price  above  costs,  to  seek  other,  non-price  methods 
of  producing  additional  sales. 

Please  observe  carefully  the  general  principle ;  it  is  an  important  one :  If  regu- 
lation or  cartelization  prevent  price  from  falling  to  costs,  then,  to  the  extent  that 
competition  continues  to  prevail,  it  will  tend  to  raise  cost  to  the  level  of  price. 

This  tendency  toward  accentuated  non-price  competition  is  of  course  not  con- 
fined to  the  regulated  or  cartelized  industries.  On  the  contrary,  and  for  similar 
reasons,  it  tends  to  take  place  also  in  non-regulated  industries  tliat  are  sufficiently 
concentrated  to  avoid  price  competition — witness,  for  example,  the  practice  of 
frequent  and  often  functionally  meaningless  but  nevertheless  cost-inflating  model 
changes  in  automobiles  and  appliances,  and  the  heavy  expenditures  on  adver- 
tising and  other  forms  of  product  differentiation  across  a  wide  spectrum  of 
oligopolistic  industries. 

But  there  are  striking  examples  in  the  regulated  sector.  The  Interstate  Com- 
merce Commission  is  not  permitted,  under  the  Motor  Carriers  Act,  to  place  limi- 
tations on  the  amount  of  equipment  and  facilities  or  the  schedules  put  into  effect 
by  certificated  tru.kers;  but  it  does  restrict  the  entry  of  common  carriers,  and 
it  does  control  prices.  The  consequence  is  a  tendency,  well-documented  in  the 
literature,  for  regulated  trucking  companies  to  compete  by  offering  greater 
frequency  of  service,  at  the  cost  of  lower  average  utilization  of  capacity. 

Similarly,  the  maintenance  of  non-competitive  brokerage  commission  rates  by 
the  New  York  Stock  Exchange  has  encouraged  brokers  to  engage  in  cost-inflating 
methods  of  service  competition — the  payment  of  large  commissions  to  salesmen, 
and  the  offering  of  costly  customer  services  in  the  form  of  free  advice  and  re- 
search, in  addition  to  the  basic  service,  which  is  the  consummation  of  trans- 
actions in  securities. 

In  the  airline  industry,  the  requisite  cartelization  is  achieved  by  the  CAB 
restrictions  on  competitive  entry,  the  resultant  fewness  of  competing  firms  along 
particular  routes,  and  the  rather  consistent  discouragement  of  competitive  rate 
reductions  and  special,  promotional  rates  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board, 
domestically,  and  by  the  International  Air  Transport  Association.  As  a  result, 
as  anyone  can  observe,  the  airline  companies  compete  very  strenuously,  instead, 
in  adopting  the  most  modern  and  attractive  eq,uipment,  in  the  frequency  with 
which  they  schedule  fiights,  in  advertising,  and  in  providing  comfort,  attractive 
hostesses,  in-flight  entertainment,  food  and  drink. 

In  turn — reflecting  an  almost  inevitable  tendency  for  regulation  to  become 
ever  more  thorough  and  pervasive  in  structurally  competitive  situations,  because 
of  tlie  necessity  for  controlling  whatever  new  forms  of  rivalry  ingenious  com- 
petitors and  potentail  competitors  devise — the  CAB  and  the  lATA  have  been 
forced  to  try  to  control  this  service  rivalry  as  well.  Price  regulation  alone  is 
obviou.sly  meaningless,  if  quality  of  service  goes  unregulated.  In  the  more  mono- 
polistic, traditional  public  utility  industries,  where  regulation  has  had  the  prin- 
cipal purpose  of  holding  prices  and  profits  down,  commissions  have  found  it 
essential  to  regulate  quality  of  service  as  well  as  price :  the  consumer  can  be 
just  as  effectively  exploited  by  deteriorations  in  the  former  as  by  increases  in 
the  latter.  So,  in  these  more  structurally  comi^titive  markets,  where  regulation 
has  been  introduced  principally  to  prevent  competition  from  driving  price  down, 
commissions  have  had  to  recognize  that  the  service  competition  that  pushes 
costs  up  can  be  almost  as  "destructive"  as  unrestricted  price  rivalry — witness, 
for  example,  the  disastrous  impact  of  competitive  scheduling  of  flights  on  air- 
line load  factors,  costs  and  profits. 


51-146    O  -  76  -  pt. 


And  so  we  have  had  the  unedifying  experience  of  the  CAB  and  lATA  imjwsing 
restrictions  on  the  provision  of  free  drinks,  the  size  ana  sumptuousuess  of  meals, 
the  amount  of  space  between  seats,  authorizing  concerted  reductions  in  the 
scheduling  of  flights,  and  requiring  a  uniform  supplementary  charge  for  in-flight 
motion  pictures. 

One  particularly  troublesome  way  in  which  the  government-imi)osed  restric- 
tions on  price  competition  have  encouraged  cost-inflation  in  this  industry  has 
been  the  general  refusal  of  the  CAB  to  permit  carriers  with  older,  inferior 
equipment  to  set  substantially  lower  rates  in  order  to  preserve  their  market 
shares  in  the  face  of  the  introduction  of  newer  equipment.  Since,  when  the 
prices  are  equal,  the  customer  will  obviously  prefer  the  faster  and  more  com- 
modious jet  to  the  slower  piston  aircraft,  the  refusal  of  the  Board  to  permit  a 
substantially  lower  fare  for  the  latter  created  an  irresistible  temptation  on  the 
part  of  carriers  to  scrap  the  older  equipment  and  introduce  the  newer  as  rapidly 
as  possible,  as  Professor  Richard  Caves  has  pointed  out.  And  this  has  indeed 
been  a  conscious  policy  of  the  Board,  in  keeping  with  its  statutory  mandate  to 
promote  the  utilization  of  airline  transportation. 

This  last  example  clearly  invites  the  obvious  question :  what  is  wrong  with 
service  rivalry  of  this  kind?  Isn't  it  desirable  to  encourage  airlines  to  shift 
rapidly  to  newer,  faster  and  more  attractive  equipment?  Doesn't  more  frequent 
scheduling  mean  better  service,  because  it  means  a  traveler  has  a  correspondingly 
greater  certainty  of  being  able  to  get  a  flight  at  any  time  that  he  wants  it? 
What  is  wrong  with  having  a  financially  healthy  security  brokerage  business, 
enabled  by  the  restrictions  on  price  competition  to  provide  investors  with  the 
benefits  of  research  and  advice,  at  no  extra  charge,  and  providing  brokerage 
service  in  small  and  remote  localities  where  it  might  otherwise  be  unprofitable? 
Effective  competition  surely  does  require  constant  efforts  at  product  and  service 
quality  improvement. 

The  only  answer  an  economist  can  give  is  that  the  proper  balance  between 
service  and  price  rivalry  can  only  be  determined,  in  a  market  economy,  by  sub- 
jecting the  alternatives  to  a  market  test.  The  proper  prescription  is  to  give 
consumers  the  opportunity  to  choose  between  the  two  alternatives,  the  faster  jet 
aircraft  at  a  price  reflecting  the  higher  cost  of  its  introduction,  and  the  slower 
but  still  serviceable  piston  aircraft,  at  whatever  rates  down  to  operating  costs 
are  necessary  to  keep  them  utilized  as  well.  This  does  not  mean  that  old  equip- 
ment should  not  at  some  point  be  scrapped.  But  so  long  as  customers  will 
patronize  it  at  rates  that  exceed  the  variable  costs  of  operating  it,  it  continues 
to  have  economic  value  as  well  as  physical  serviceability ;  and  any  policy  that 
prevents  dropping  that  price  down  toward  variable  costs,  and  thereby  provides 
customers  no  incentive  to  keep  using  the  old,  promotes  premature  and  wasteful 
scrapping,  and  correspondingly  wastefuUy  rapid  introduction  of  the  new. 

The  only  way  of  testing  whether  the  increment  in  service  quality  consequent 
on  more  intensive  scheduling  is  worth  the  higher  cost  it  entails  is  to  offer  shippers 
or  travelers  the  choice  between  lower  rates  and  less  frequent  operations,  on  the 
one  hand,  and  the  high  rates  required  to  cover  the  costs  of  more  frequent  sched- 
uling, on  the  other.  The  same  is  true  of  flights  that  on  the  one  hand  provide 
minimum  leg  room,  and  no  food,  drink,  or  entertainment,  and  sumptuous  flights, 
on  the  other,  and  as  many  quality  combinations  as  feasible  between  these  two 
extremes,  all  at  prices  reflecting  the  respective  costs  of  providing  them. 

Similarly  for  the  security  brokers :  only  if  investors  are  offered  the  choice 
between  the  barebones  service  of  consummating  security  purchases  and  sales,  at 
a  price  corresponding  to  the  cost  of  doing  just  that,  on  the  one  hand,  and,  on  the 
other,  the  execution  of  orders  plus  salesmanship,  plus  advice,  plus  research  will  the 
market  provide  the  economically  optimum  quantity  of  both.  So  long  as  the 
customer  pays  the  same  price  for  both  of  these  packages,  there  will  be  an  in- 
herent tendency  to  wasteful  and  cost-inflating  service  rivalry.  And  that,  it  clearly 
appears,  is  what  has  happened  in  the  airline  industry. 

The  objection  is  not  necessarily  that  airlines  have  been  forced  by  their  com- 
petition fo  inrnr  creater  costs  for  denser  schedules,  more  advertising,  meals,  and 
in-flight  entertainment  than  they  would  if  they  were  able  to  get  together  and 
restrict  such  expenditures.  Tlie  ob.iection  i«,  rather,  that  these  cost-inflating 
service  improvements  have  not  been  subjected  to  the  test  of  having  to  compete 
with  lower-cost  lower-price  alternatives.  The  defect,  in  short,  has  not  been  the 
.service  competition,  as  such,  but  the  inadequate  play  of  price  competition  along 
with  it.  In  point  of  historical  fact,  the  airline  industr.v — as  well  as  trucking,  and 
the  security  brokerage  business — offers  numerous  evidences  that  price  competi- 


tion  will,  if  given  a  chance,  hold  service  inflation  in  check.  Witness  the  popular- 
ity of  the  more  Spartan  non-scheduled  passenger  service,  the  desertion  of  regular 
security  brokers  by  large  investors,  and  the  wholesale  desertion  by  shippers 
from  common  carrier  to  private  trucking  wherever  they  had  the  opportunity 
to  do  so. 

In  these  circumstances,  the  attempts  of  the  regulators  to  limit  service  rivalry 
are  entirely  logical.  But  that  still  has  the  effect  of  limiting  the  range  of  cus- 
tomer choices.  And  it  inescapably  rai.«es  the  question  of  whether  it  would  not  be 
preferable  simply  to  abandon  economic  regulation  plus  cartelization  in  favor  of 
the  freer  play  of  price  competition. 


Senator  Kexnkdy.  Our  final  witness  is  Dr.  George  James,  senior 
vice  president  of  economics  and  finance,  Air  Transport  Association. 
He  has  spent  much  time  analyzing  economic  trends  and  problems  of 
the  association,  problems  on  behavior  of  the  member  airlines,  and  di- 
recting the  operations  of  the  Economic  Finance  Council.  Dr.  James  is 
a  member  of  f  he  Conference  of  Business  and  American  Economic  Asso- 
ciation, university  guest  lecturer  and  currently  serves  on  the  Doctorial 
Dissertation  Association  of  American  University. 

We  are  glad  to  have  you. 

STATEMENT  OF  DR.  GEORGE  W.  JAMES,  SENIOR  VICE  PRESIDENT 
OF  ECONOMICS  AND  FINANCE,  AIR  TRANSPORT  ASSOCIATION  OF 
AMERICA,  ACCOMPANIED  BY  JAMES  LANDRY  AND  GABRIEL 
PHILLIPS 

Dr.  James.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  am  accompanied  by  Mr.  James  Landry  and  Mr.  Gabriel  Phillips. 

I  have  submitted  a  lengthy  statement  which  I  will  not  read,  but  I 
do  have  a  summary  which  I  will  read  but  I  request  the  more  lengthy 
testimony  be  included  in  the  record. 

Senator  Kennedy.  It  will  be  included  in  the  record. 

Dr.  James.  I  find  it  enlightening  to  hear  the  testimony  we  have  just 
heard  from  Professor  Kahn.  I  have  many  smart  friends  who  have 
been  educated  under  Professor  Kahn. 

I  must  say,  however,  that  after  listening  to  what  I  heard  this  morn- 
ing from  all  of  the  other  witnesses  that  I  have  never  been  exposed  to 
such  incorrect  economics  in  the  airline  industry  except  9  years  ago 
when  I  first  came  into  the  business  myself.  I  think  it  is  terribly  impor- 
tant to  have  the  exposure  to  the  industry  and  understanding  of  it 
before  you  can  really  understand  the  practical  implications  of  some  of 
the  proposals  that  have  been  made  and  to  have  a  more  full  understand- 
ing of  why  so  many  of  our  witnesses  are  stumbling  on  questions  that 
you  are  asking  on  what  the  effects  of  deregulation  would  be. 

Well,  as  you  stated  on  December  16,  Senator  Kennedy,  the  basic 
objective  of  airline  regulation  is  adequate  service  at  reasonable  prices. 
We  believe  airline  regulation  has  met  that  test.  Nevertheless,  we  be- 
lieve that  consideration  by  this  subcommittee  and  others  of  the  issue  of 
regulatory  reform  presents  opportunities  not  only  for  thorough  review 
of  the  existing  structure  and  procedures,  but  more  important,  for 
seekmg  improvements  in  regulation.  These  improvements  can  lead  to 
an  even  more  effective  and  responsive  public  air  transportation  system. 


100 

The  more  extensive  statement  we  have  submitted  to  this  subcom- 
mittee, under  separate  cover,  deals  with  the  concept  of  re^ilated  com- 
petition in  air  transportation,  with  the  objectives  we  understand  are 
sought  through  regulatory  reform  investigations,  with  the  achieve- 
ments of  regTilated  competition  in  the  air  transportation  industry  since 
1938,  and  with  the  likely  adverse  impacts  of  many  of  the  concepts  of 
regulatory  reform  that  are  being  proposed.  Our  statement  also  makes 
recommendations  for  some  improvements  in  present  air  transport 
regulation. 

I  would  noAv  like  to  summarize  the  principal  points  made  in  our 
statement. 

ADVANTAGES    OF    REGULATED    COMPETITION 

The  system  of  air  transportation,  since  its  inception  as  an  effective 
force  in  the  American  economy  in  1938,  has  been  founded  on  the  prin- 
ciple of  regulated  competition.  This  has  been  necessary  because  of  the 
special  position  of  public  transportation  in  the  economy.  In  the  spec- 
trum of  economic  activity,  from  a  natural  monopoly  to  perfect  compe- 
tition, transportation  falls  in  between. 

It  is  unlike  specific  public  utilities  in  which  embedded  costs  are  im- 
mense and  therefore  economies  of  scale  are  apparent.  But  because  of 
the  need  and  value  of  providing  a  public  service  to  a  vast  interlinking 
network  of  cities  and  communities,  air  transportation  cannot  be  placed 
in  the  so-called  perfect  or  workable  competitive  environment  either. 
Further,  it  has  characteristics  that  under  deregulation  would  quickly 
lead  to  a  high  degree  of  concentration.  These  characteristics  include 
the  complexity  of  aircraft  operations,  the  increasing  expense  of  indi- 
vidual aircraft,  the  need  for  extensive  maintenance  facilities,  and  the 
fact  that  an  inordinately  high  percentage  of  the  passenger  markets  are 
between  points  of  low  traffic  density. 

The  present  national  air  transportation  system  is  characterized  by 
stability,  speed,  reliability,  and  above  all  a  vast  network  of  the  inter- 
locking air  routes  involving  58,000  city-pairs.  Its  value  to  the  Nation 
and  to  the  public  is  derived  from  all  of  these  essential  features  which 
would  be  seriously  <!ompromised,  if  not  lost,  through  deregulation. 

We  believe  it  is  essential  that  in  the  deliberations  today,  and  in 
those  which  will  follow,  special  care  should  be  taken  to  ensure  that 
it  is  the  real  world  of  air  transportation  which  is  the  subject  of 
scrutiny.  Hypothetical  models  alone — based  as  they  are,  not  on  the 
actual  demonstrated  needs  of  the  traveling  and  shipping  public,  but 
rather  on  theories  applicable  only  in  an  insulated  theoretical  environ- 
ment— may  be  helpful  as  a  guide  to  thinking.  But  their  application 
beyond  the  classroom  or  the  textbook  must  be  carefully  considered  in 
the  light  of  existing,  real  circumstances. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  do  you  say  that ;  what  is  the  basis  of  that 
statement  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  do  not  be-ieve  anybody  was  recognizing  that  we  have 
58,000  city-pairs,  a  stable  environment  in  which  that  system  is  now 
operating,  that  we  have  met  the  test  of  keeping  prices  down,  that  we 
have  a  system  built  in  through  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  now  in 
which  the  consumer  interests  are  being  represented  and  the  prices 
that  we  might  seek  are  being  penalized  by  the  fact  that  we  may  not 
be  meeting  certain  of  those  standards,  and  many  other  points  that  I 


101 

will  bring  out  in  my  testimony  in  answer  to  your  question  in  a 
moment. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  would  not  the  Department  of  Transporta- 
tion understand  that  ? 

POTENTIAL     ABANDONMENT    OF   SMALL     TOWN     SERVICE      (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Dr.  James,  The  Department  of  Transportation,  through  the  sub- 
missions they  made  and  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation, 
was  not  taking  as  what  I  would  consider  a  practical  position  regarding 
load  factors,  load  factor  standards,  and  the  realities  of  service  to  this 
58,000  network  that  we  now  serve.  The  implications  contained  in 
many  of  the  submissions  they  made  would  have  the  load  factors  and 
load  factor  standards  beginning  abnormally  high,  and  the  only  way 
to  accomplish  this  would  be  to  cut  out  service  to  many. of  the  com- 
munities now  serviced,  thousands  of  them,  as  a  matter  of  fact. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  you  submit  a  list  of  which  ones  that  would 
be? 

Dr.  James.  Of  the  communities  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes. 

Dr.  James.  We  can  attempt  to  do  that,  Senator,  That  is  a  com- 
puterized answer  that  we  would  have  to  develop,  and  would  involve 
millions  of  calculations.  It  is  a  difficult  thing  to  obtain,  and  we  would 
have  to  obtain  it. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  can  you  be  sure  that  you  know  and  the 
Department  of  Transportation  does  not  know  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  know  the  size  of  the  problem  and  that  is  what  we  are 
attempting  to  define. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  have  asked  you  for  specific  testimony  since  you 
have  discredited  the  witnesses,  saying  they  were  speaking  through  their 
hat.  That  is  a  gracious  way  of  putting  it.  Then,  I  asked  you  the  basis 
of  it  and  you  say  they  do  not  understand  this  particular  problem.  I  ask 
you  the  basis  for  your  information  and  you  say  you  have  not  got  it. 
"You  supply  it  and  I  will  ask  the  Department  of  Transportation  to  do 
the  same  thing.  Let  the  record  speak  for  itself, 

Dr,  James.  Let  me  put  it  this  way.  Senator.  What  we  have  is  aggre- 
gate information,  and  what  you  are  asking  for  is  detailed  information. 
The  aggregate  information  (s  that  if  we  Avere  to  attempt  to  get  to  a  65- 
percent  load  factor  today  we  would  have  to  cut  25  percent  off  of  these 
58,000  city-pairs.  I  understand  your  question  to  be  which  of  the  58,000 
would  be  cut. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  right. 

Dr.  James.  We  have  nothing  that  far.  We  have  gone  as  far  as  to  say 
one-fourth  of  them  would  be  cut.  I  do  not  believe  the  Department  of 
Transportation  has  thought  of  it  in  those  terms,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  I  will  ask  them  the  same  question,  to  submit 
information,  as  I  am  asking  you,  so  if  you  can  supply  information  on 
that  and  be  as  specific  as  possible  I  wiU  ask  them  the  same  question. 

[In  a  letter  dated  February  7, 1975,  the  chairman  of  the  subcommittee 
made  more  explicit  his  request  of  Dr.  James  for  a  list  of  routes  t:hat 
would  be  eliminated  under  the  conditions  discussed  above.  On  April  3, 
1975,  the  Air  Transport  Association  submitted  its  reply  which  totaled 
more  than  200  pages.  The  chairman  then  requested  independent  eval- 


102 

uations  of  this  ATA  study  from  five  leading  economists  and  several 
Government  agencies.  The  ATA  study  and  the  evaluations,  together 
with  relevant  correspondence,  are  printed  at  the  end  of  Dr.  James'  pre- 
pared statement  following  his  testimony  of  this  day,  p.  189  ff.,  below.] 
Senator  Kennedy.  Let  us  continue. 

RELATIVE  DECREASE  IN  AIR  FARES  SINCE  19  38 

Dr.  James.  The  objectives  sought  by  the  theorists  or  the  critics  of 
the  present  system  have  been  accomplished  in  a  regulated  competitive 
environment.  Those  who  have  found  fault  with  the  regulatory  environ- 
ment in  which  air  transportation  now  operates  seek  to  achieve  a  lauda- 
tory goal :  air  transportation  service  at  minimum  and  cost-based  prices, 
providing  a  maximum  efficient  quality  of  service.  We  believe  we  have 
accomplished  that  goal. 

Today  average  scheduled  airline  passenger  fares,  in  1938  dollars,  are 
64  percent  less  than  37  years  ago,  when  Congress  passed  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Act.  Moreover,  if  one  wishes  to  switch  to  current  dollar 
comparisons,  from  1948  to  1974  the  air  fare  between  New  York  and 
San  Francisco  rose  21  percent.  At  the  same  time  the  price  of  a  pound 
of  roundsteak  increased  100  percent,  a  pair  of  men's  shoes  120  percent, 
a  Chevrolet  automobile  220  percent,  and,  though  perhaps  not  com- 
monly purchased,  a  year's  tuition  at  Harvard  over  640  percent. 

Air  freight  rates  have  similarly  experienced  a  decline  relative  to 
costs  of  all  U.S.  goods  and  services  in  the  period  1946-1974. 

Senator  Kennedy.  With  all  due  respect,  what  has  that  possibly  got 
to  do  with  it?  Television  has  gone  down,  the  cost  of  radio  has  gone 
down,  wristwatches  have  gone  down.  So  what  sense  does  that  particular 
comment  make — how  does  that  prove  your  thesis  ?  I  can  give  as  many 
examples  as  you  have  given  that  have  gone  the  other  way.  I  am  not  an 
expert  in  this,  but 

Dr.  James.  The  only  point  I  am  making,  Senator,  for  every  one  you 
can  give  I  can  give  one  above  the  average.  We  are  standing  with  a 
small  group  of  services  and  products  which  have  actually  declined 
in  this  time  period.  We  are  64  percent  below  the  average,  so  obviously 
there  are  larger  numbers  that  have  gone  up  than  have  gone  down  rela- 
tive to  our  performance. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Maybe  that  is  convincing  to  some  people,  but 
what  we  do  not  know  without  competition  is  how  much  further  it 
would  have  gone  down.  I  would  think  that  would  have  been  the  im- 
portant question.  If  this  is  satisfactory  to  you  as  an  explanation  we 
will  be  glad  to  receive  it. 

Dr.  James.  We  also  can  compare  ourselves  with  consumer  price 
index  and  the  wholesale  price  index,  and  we  will  have  outperformed 
those. 

REGULATED    AND    UNREGULATED    FARES    COMPARED 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  do  not  suppose  you  could  mention  that  the  PSA 
has  gone  down  further  than  you  have,  or  Texas,  so  therefore  they 
demonstrate 

Dr.  James.  Senator,  I  think  PSA  would  be  delighted  to  say  that, 
but  they  cannot.  From  1967-1973  their  i^rices  went  up  23  percent. 
Ours  went  up  17  percent.  Since  1973,  PSA  has  increased  their  prices 
25  percent  and  is  applying  for  10.5  percent  more.  Since  1973,  our  gen- 


eral  fares  are  up  15  percent.  Our  price  record  against  PSA  is  very 
competitive  and  we  beat  them. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Which  makes  the  point  that  competition  does 
not  make  much 

Dr.  James.  They  are  probably  within  a  i^-cent  yield  away 
i'rom  our  average,  and  we  have  three  or  four  fares  that  we  offer  today 
that  are  less  than  what  PSA  offers  on  a  yield  basis. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  the  fares,  as  I  understand,  are  close  to  half 
the  price. 

Dr.  James.  They  are  not,  sir.  Their  yields  are  close  to  6  cents  a  mile 
and  ours  are  running  close  to  7  cents  a  mile,  including  the  charges 
that  have  just  been  made. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  give  me,  just  to  clarify  for  a  layman,  what 
the  fare  is  from  San  Francisco  to  Los  Angeles  for  CAB  regulated 
and  then  the  PSA. 

Dr.  James.  Well,  I  see  the  frame  of  reference  in  which  you  are 
speaking. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  you  answer  that  question  for  me  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  have  the  airline  guide  here  and  I  can  probably  pull  out 
that  fare  for  you,  if  you  wish. 

Senator  Kennedy.  OK. 

Dr.  James.  The  yields  I  am  quoting  to  you  are  the  average  of  all  of 
our  fares  against  PSA.  If  you  would  like  I  would  also  like  to  elaborate 
on  that  in  a  moment  as  to  the  differences  of  the  kind  of  service  that 
PSA  is  offering  and  the  different  cost  against  our  own  carriers.  I  can 
do  that  if  you  wish  while  we  are  attempting  to  find 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  point  that  I  was  making  is,  I  did  not  under- 
stand the  relevancy  of  the  increase  in  Harvard's  tuition,  and  then  we 
got  diverted  on  this  other  situation,  so  whatever  you  like,  we  will  just 
put  those  in  the  record  and  you  can  continue. 

Dr.  James.  Senator,  there  is  a  specti-um  of  fares  on  that  route  be- 
tween Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  PSA,  for  example,  has  a  fare 
$20.25.  TWA  has  a  fare  for  $19.50.  Air  West  has  a  fare  for  $18.37, 
Continental  $17. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  those  the  intrastate  passengers  ? 

Dr.  James.  Between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco,  yes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Those  are  traveling  intrastate,  right  ? 

Dr.  James.  Yes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Say  someone  took  a  plane  from  Boston,  San 
Francisco,  Los  Angeles,  what  would  be  the  cost  of  the  San  Francisco- 
Los  Angeles  rates  ? 

Dr.  James.  Those  would  be  larger. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Give  me  those. 

Dr.  James.  I  will  submit  that  for  the  record  later.  I  do  not  have  it 
with  me  at  this  time. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  it  must  be  in  the  airline  guide.  You  are  the 
experts  on  it. 

You  can  continue  in  your  testimony. 

Dr.  James.  All  right,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Counsel  informs  me  that  it  is  $38.89. 

Dr.  James.  The  airline  offers  the  public  a  wide  range  of  available 
fares,  and  extensive  use  has  been  made  of  these.  For  the  year  ending 
Sej^tember  1974,  for  example,  use  of  lower  than  full  fares  accounted 


104 

for  almost  one-third  of  all  coach  revenue  passenger  miles  flown.  Be- 
ginning this  month  another  broad  based  discount  fare  has  been  intro- 
duced which  will  provide  an  attractive  bridge  between  charter  and 
regular  fares. 

The  spectrum  of  fares  that  we  offer  has  been  used  extensively  by  low 
income  groups  in  the  United  States.  Last  year  one  of  every  seven 
adults  making  less  than  $7,000  annually  flew  on  a  scheduled  airline. 
Overall,  18  percent  of  all  adults  taking  one  or  more  trips  by  air  made 
less  than  $7,000.  This  pricing  performance,  at  an  adequate  level  of 
service,  either  in  the  long  run  or  in  the  short  run,  could  not  have  been 
matched  by  pricing  in  a  deregulated  environment.  In  fact,  in  the  long 
run,  as  evidenced  by  the  pricng  performance  of  the  U.S.  economy  as  a 
whole,  deregulation  of  the  air  transport  industry  would  have  placed 
prices  and  fares  at  a  much  higher  level  than  now  exists. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  is  that  ? 

Dr.  James.  Basing  that  on  the  pricing  performance  of  the  U.S. 
economy  as  a  whole,  which  was  much  higher  in  constant  dollars  in 
1938  than  our  own  performance,  which  was  64  percent  less. 

THE   domestic    PASSENGER   FARE  INVESTIGATION 

More  recently,  we  believe  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  has 
taken  precedent-setting  steps,  througli  the  results  of  its  Domestic  Pas- 
senger Fare  Investigation,  to  assure  that  the  airline  industry  operates 
at  standards  of  efficiency  responsive  to  consumer  interests.  The  initia- 
tion of  this  investigation  came  from  Members  of  Congress  in  late  1969. 
The  investigation  began  in  January  1970,  and  that  portion  of  it  cover- 
ing fare  level  rate  of  return  procedures  produced  its  first  results  in 
May  1973. 

The  resulting  CAB  standards  of  efficiency  assure  that  no  automatic 
fare  increase  is  charged  to  consumers  for  so-called  industry  cost  mis- 
takes of  purchasing  excess  equipment,  of  misestimating  a  market  and 
hauling  too  few  people,  or  for  giving  away  business  through  discount- 
ing. The  CAB  standards  of  efficiency  adjust  for  all  of  these,  and  no 
fare  change  is  made  until  these  adjustments  have  been  made.  Each 
fare  increase  granted  to  the  industry  since  1973,  including  the  4  per- 
cent increase  granted  last  November,  has  been  based  on  meeting  these 
standards. 

These  CAB  fare  level  procedures,  resulting  from  open  public  hear- 
ings, are  not  arbitrary,  were  not  developed  from  clandestine  meetings, 
and  have  a  clear  and  comprehensive  public  interest  platform  built  in. 
Yet  the  opposite  and  misleading  impression  is  often  given  by  critics  as 
an  emotional  appeal  to  consumers.  As  we  have  shown,  in  fact,  it  is  the 
consumer  who  is  the  primary  beneficiary  of  these  procedures. 

Let  us  turn  our  attention  to  the  question  of  load  factors,  a  concept 
grossly  misunderstood  and  misused.  Continually  our  industry  is  told 
two  things :  ( 1 )  we  are  not  providing  adequate  levels  of  service,  and  (2) 
our  load  factors  should  be  higher.  For  our  industry  these  objectives 
are  contradictory. 

I  believe  I  can  make  my  point  by  referring  to  the  statement  that 
Senator  Kennedy  made  on  the  Senate  floor  on  December  16,  where  he 
referred  to  the  difficulty  a  student  in  Boston  might  experience  in  re- 
turning to  his  home  in  Detroit  because  of  a  lack  of  available  seats  on 
that  route.  Keeping  in  mind  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's 


105 

domestic  passenger  fare  investigation  established  the  load  factor 
standard  at  55  percent  in  1974,  the  average  load  factor  in  the  Boston- 
Detroit  market  was  59  percent.  Senator  Kennedy  has  cited  an  ex- 
ample of  possible  inadequate  service  at  a  load  factor  of  59  percent.  To 
aA'erage  59  percent,  the  Boston-Detroit  market  shows  a  monthly  load 
factor  range  of  52-67  percent  thus  further  demonstrating  the  season- 
ality of  our  markets. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  missed  the  point  completely,  because  I  was 
not  really  talking  about  the  load  factor  there,  I  was  talking  about  the 
competition  that  existed  in  that  particular  route  and  pointing  out  that 
there  was  only  one  carrier  traveling  that  route.  There  was  another 
one  that  offered  to  provide  better  service  and,  because  the  Board  had 
refused  to  have  a  hearing,  was  unable  to  do  so.  That  is  the  point  that 
was  made.  I  think  it  is  still  a  valid  one.  If  you  want  to  draw  some  kind 
of  reference  to  the  load  factor  as  being  the  purpose  of  that  comment, 
then  I  am  glad  to  clarify  that  for  you  at  the  present  time,  but  that 
certainly  was  not  the  point  being  made.  There  is  another  carrier  who 
wanted  to  get  in,  offered  more  frequent  and  better  service,  was  never 
granted  a  hearing  and  that  opportunity  is  not  available  to  that  young 
person.  If  you  want  to  argue  with  that  point  I  will  be  glad  to  hear  you. 

Dr.  James.  You  Avere  citing  in  your  statement.  Senator,  that  the 
students,  for  example,  between  Boston  and  Detroit  would  be  unable 
to  get  on  flights  between  certain  periods  of  time  because  of  lack  of 
service  and  the  refusal  of  the  Board  to  add  additional  capacity. 

My  point  is  that  here  is  a  situation  where  apparently  there  was 
insufficient  capacity  and  yet  there  was  a  59  percent  load  factor. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  many  carriers  are  there  in  that  group? 

Dr.  James.  I  am  not  aware. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Oh,  now,  you  know  how  many  carriers  there 
are.  Ask  your  associates.  There  is  one  carrier,  one  non-stop  carrier. 

Dr.  James.  There  are  lots  of  ways  of  getting  between  Boston  and 
Detroit,  if  you  are  talking  nonstop,  then  there  is  one  carrier. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  right.  OK. 

SMALL   TOWN    SERVICE    (CROSS -SUBSIDY) 

Dr.  James.  What  is  commonly  overlooked  by  observers  of  the  sched- 
uled air  transport  system  system  is  that  30  percent  of  our  domestic 
traffic  is  produced  by  only  70  larger  city-pair  markets;  another  40 
percent  is  derived  from  an  additional  840  markets;  and  the  final  30 
percent  is  produced  in  some  57,000^maller  markets.  Yet,  these  smaller 
markets  are  an  integral  part  of  the  system  and  their  loss  would  seri- 
ouslv  damage  the  adequacy  of  public  air  transport  service,  as  well  as 
invoking  a  severe  cost  to  the  national  economy. 

For  example,  out  of  a  passenger  load  of  85  on  a  typical  flight  from 
Denver  to  Chicago,  over  three-fourths  do  not  originate  in  Denver.  They 
are  coming  from  Pueblo,  Colo. ;  Cheyenne,  Wyo. ;  Great  Falls,  Mont. ; 
Sacramento,  Fresno,  and  San  Jose,  Calif. ;  and  other  cities  in  the  West. 
If  this  feeder  system  were  tampered  with,  the  primary  market  would 
also  became  less  profitable.  As  a  result,  it  would  receive  less  service, 
and  the  remaining  smaller  feeder  markets  woidd  also  receive  less  in- 
direct service. 

Senntor  Kennedy.  Well,  how  can  you  say  that?  I  would  be  inter- 
ested in  your  printouts  on  that  particular  fact.  I  just  know  that  with 


106 

regard  to  my  part  of  the  country,  Air  New  England  provides  many 
more  opportunities  for  the  trunk  carriers  and  the  scheduled  line  car- 
riers to  move  people  than  when  the  major  scheduled  carriers  were 
traveling  down  into  southern  Massachusetts  and  to  other  parts  of  the 
State. 

Dr.  James.  My  example  would  be  that  the  analogy  that  Air  New 
England,  for  example,  is  feeding  into  Boston,  Boston  is  a  major  hub 
serving  to  Los  Angeles  or  San  Francisco.  Flights  out  of  Boston  are 
fed  by  many  of  the  feeders  in  the  New  England  area.  The  profitability 
of  those  hub  routes  depends  to  a  large  extent  on  the  feeder  routes 
coming  into  Boston. 

I  cite  an  example  later  in  the  testimony  concerning  a  flight  coming 
from  the  West,  Fresno  on  through  Denver  and  Chicago  on  which  1 
have  specific  figures  which  I  believe  may  illustrate  the  point  you  are 
looking  for. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  the  point  here  ? 

Dr.  James.  If  you  tamper  with  this  system  that  you  will  begin  to 
close  it  in  on  the  periphery,  that  is  the  feeder  points  would  be  the  ones 
that  would  begin  to  shut  down.  As  they  were  shut  down  it  would 
also  have  an  effect  on  the  hub.  Hub  service  would  be  less,  and  what 
you  are  doing,  because  it  is  a  concentrated  industry,  is  that  you  are 
going  to  end  up  with  only  a  few  markets  served  by  fewer  carriers  and 
the  air  transport  service  will  be  seriously  compromised. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  that  has  not  been  the  experience  in  my 
State.  You  may  be  able  to  document  it  in  other  parts.  I  dare  say  that 
would  not  hold  up  in  New  England.  I  dare  say  it  would  not  in  Cali- 
fornia. There  may  be  other  parts  of  the  country  that  it  would. 

I  would  be  interested  in  what  information  you  have  to  show  that  this 
has  been  the  situation  in  any  of  the  places  where  there  has  been  a  reduc- 
tion of  scheduled  flights,  because  it  certainly  has  not  been  the  case  in 
Boston  or  Massachusetts. 

Dr.  James.  Well,  I  do  not  know  that  we  can  demonstrate  what  the 
impact  would  be  fully  from  our  standpoint  or  the  standpoint  of  those, 
for  example,  that  testified  this  morning. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  then,  how  can  you  make  your  statements 
with  such  assurance  ? 

Dr.  James.  Let  me  make  this  point  first,  if  I  may. 

The  point  I  was  leading  up  to  is  that  we  do  not  have  the  experience  in 
this  country  of  shutting  down  the  air  transport,  systems  to  fully  under- 
stand what  the  impact  would  be  in  these  outlying  districts.  We  have  to 
rely  on  the  evidence  we  now  have  that  shows  the  amount  of  feed  that 
goes  into  a  hub  and  the  importance  of  that  feed  to  the  more  profitable 
routes  that  continue  beyond  and  assume,  then,  that  if  you  were  to  de- 
regulate the  low  density  routes  would  be  the  ones  in  which  service 
would  first  be  dropped,  and  as  it  is  dropped  then  the  public  trpnsnorta- 
tion  network  begins  to  be  compromised  and  there  is  a  chain  reaction 
all  the  way  through  to  the  main  levels  of  the  hubs  in  which  service  is 
dropped  there. 

Senator  Kenne'dy.  I  think  the  best  opportunity  would  be  to  look  to 
places  that  had  certificated  carriers  which  dropped  feeder  service  into 
these  hub  areas.  One  of  the  clearest  examples  is  my  own  area,  where 
Northeast  was  able  to  drop  certain  of  these  routes,  and  after  it  was 
merged  with  Delta,  virtually  all  of  them  were  dropped. 


107 

I  dare  say  the  smaller  lines  have  provided  a  much  greater  degree  of 
service  to  the  public,  and  I  dare  say,  and  I  will  be  glad  to  look  at  the 
statistics,  that  there  is  more  service  feeding  into  the  major  scheduled 
airlines  now  than  when  the  certificated  carriers  were  flying  the  DC-8's 
at  1  o'clock  in  the  morning  in  order  to  meet  with  CAB  requirements. 
We  have  seen  how  Northeast  used  to  fly  down  at  the  most  inopportune 
time  in  the  world,  and  would  be  down  here  4  or  5  months  later  saying 
look,  this  is  all  the  number  of  people  traveling  on  it,  and  trying  to  get 
permission  to  drop  it.  We  saw  instance  after  instance  in  which  they 
were  permitted  to  drop  service.  Now  we  have  been  able  to  see  the  devel- 
opment of  a  variety  of  different  carriers  ser\dng  this  area — from  Bos- 
ton all  the  way  up  the  coast  of  Maine  and  New  Hampshire  and  Ver- 
mont, and  we  find  a  much  more  efficient  and  effective  service,  and 
I  dare  say  the  numbers  would  show  they  are  bringing  many  more 
people  into  the  major  market  areas. 

If  you  are  goin^  to  make  a  statement  categorically  that  deregulation 
would  mean  inferior  service,  this  is  a  statement  that  I  think  ought  to  be 
supported  with  at  least  some  kind  of  figures  or  documentation  showing 
places  where  that  has  been  the  case  in  the  past.  If  you  have  some  we 
would  welcome  it. 

Dr.  James.  Senator,  I  do  not  believe  the  analogy  you  make  neces- 
sarily holds,  because  the  service  that  you  now  have  in  the  New  England 
area  is  still  a  scheduled  certificated  service.  For  example,  the  recent 
certificating  of  Air  New  England  as  a  regional  carrier. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  know  when  Air  New  England  was 
certificated  ? 

Dr.  James.  Well,  just  within  the  last  month. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  have  been  flying  it  for  the  last  2i/2  years.  So 
we  can  use  the  figures  before  it  was  certificated  if  you  want.  I  do  not 
want  to  debate  this  point. 

Dr.  James.  Perhaps  your  service  is  well  improved. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  have  been  very  satisfied  with  it.  If  they  can 
improve  it,  I  am  delighted. 

We  Avill  continue.  If  you  have  any  figures  or  statistics  or  studies  on 
this  particular  point  we  would  welcome  them,  because  obviously  the 
DOT  has  presented  a  statement.  We  will  ask  them  for  their  data  as 
well,  and  if  you  have  some  we  would  like  a  chance  to  examine  it.  You 
must  have  reviewed  this,  and  we  would  like  to  take  a  look  at  it. 

[In  a  letter  dated  February  7,  1975,  the  chairman  of  the  subcommit- 
tee made  more  explicit  his  request  of  Dr.  James  for  a  list  of  routes  that 
would  be  eliminated  under  the  conditions  discussed  above.  On  April  3, 
1975,  the  Air  Transport  Association  submitted  its  reply  which  totaled 
more  than  200  pages.  The  chairman  then  requested  independent  evalu- 
ations of  this  ATA  study  from  five  leading  economists  and  several 
Government  agencies.  The  ATA  study  and  the  evaluations,  together 
with  relevant  correspondence,  are  printed  at  the  end  of  Dr.  James' 
prepared  statement  following  his  testimony  of  this  day,  p.  139  ff. 
below.] 

Dr.  James.  Fine. 

the  interline  network  of  airlines 

Some  claim  that,  if  the  present  system  were  deregulated  and  present 
carriers  elected  to  leave  the  smaller  markets,  commuter  carriers  or 
forms  of  ground  transportation  would  be  adequate  substitutes.  Data 


108 

developed  by  Dr.  Gary  Fromm,  formerly  of  Data  Resources,  Inc., 
would  indicate  differently.  The  value  of  an  hour's  time  to  an  air 
traveler  is  approximately  $10.50.  Taking  into  account  the  slower  tinies 
for  accomplishing  the  same  trip  by  rail,  bus,  auto  or  lower  speed  air- 
craft, the  cost  to  individuals  and  therefore  to  the  economy  could 
approach  billions  of  dollars. 

The  replacement  of  many  of  these  markets  by  smaller  earner  opera- 
tions would  be  a  hazardous  one.  For  example,  in  1972,  of  all  U.S. 
cities  receiving  scheduled  passenger  commuter  service,  74,  or  17  per- 
cent were  abandoned  1  year  later  and  service  was  added  to  another 
104.  Thus,  in  that  time  period  178  cities  experienced  a  change  in 
scheduled  commuter  service— roughly  one-third  of  all  cities  receiving 
such  service. 

The  present  air  transport  system  represents  a  wholly  integrated  net- 
work of  scheduling,  connections,  interlining,  and  routing  among  and 
between  carriers  serving  cities  of  varying  size  and  geographic  prox- 
imity to  each  other.  A  glance  at  the  Official  Airline  Guide  (which 
contains  the  schedules  for  the  entire  air  transport  network)  provides 
dramatic  evidence  of  this  point.  For  example,  the  OAG  (North 
American  edition)  published  on  February  1,  1975,  is  898  pages  long. 
It  depicts  the  schedules  of  every  scheduled  carrier  in  North  America, 
to  and  from  virtually  every  community  served,  with  connections  indi- 
cated. It  is  this  network  which  would  be  jeopardized  by  drastically 
revising  or  dismantling  the  structure  so  carefully  constructed  over 
the  last  37  years. 

The  airline  industry  believes  that  the  regulatory  environment  within 
which  we  operate  has  served  the  public  interest  well.  We  believe  the 
results  support  that  conclusion. 

However,  in  certain  instances,  airlines  have  opposed  and  continue 
to  oppose  the  manner  in  which  the  regulatory  process  has  been  carried 
out.  And  we  believe  that  certain  areas  of  economic  regulation  of  our 
industry  do  require  increased  attention. 

For  example,  the  problem  of  regulatory  lag  is  endemic  to  the  regu- 
latory process  throughout  much  of  government.  There  are  areas  here 
where  productive  changes  can  be  made.  The  proper  requirement  for 
full  and  complete  industry  reporting  of  economic,  financial,  and  sta- 
tistical data  need  not  result  in  duplicate  and  redundant  effort  on  the 
part  of  the  industry  or  the  regulator.  We  believe  reasonable  cost- 
benefit  analysis  can  be  usefully  applied  to  certain  of  these  requirements. 

We  also  believe  that  the  precedent-setting  step  of  establishing  per- 
formance and  efficiency  standards  for  the  industry  should  be  subject 
to  regular  scrutiny  by  the  Board  and  amended  when  and  as  required 
in  the  public  interest.  These  should  be  done,  however,  always  keeping 
in  mind  the  need  for  continuing  understanding  on  the  part  of  the 
public  and  the  government  of  the  real  world  economics  of  the  air 
transport  system. 

We  also  believe  that  the  undertaking  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 
of  a  comprehensive  review  of  route  developement  policy  is  desirable. 
Careful  consideration  should  be  given  to  the  view  contained  in  an 
October  1974  report  by  the  Board  that :  "*  *  *  regulatory  route  and 
route-related  policies  should  be  directed  to  improving  the  efficiency 
and   quality   of   the   system,   through   careful   expansion   of   route 


109 

authority  when  required  by  traffic,  and  through  route  rationalization." 

We  are  also  in  favor  of  selected  changes  in  the  tariff  procedures.  We 
would  advocate  extending  the  filing  deadline  for  tariffs  from  30  to  45 
days  with  Board  decision  required  after  30  days.  This  process  would 
provide  15  days  advance  public  notice  of  tariff  changes.  A  corollary  of 
this  would  be  the  adoption  of  a  simplified  short -form  tariff  which 
would  work  to  enhance  public  understanding  of  a  given  tariff  change. 

In  conclusion,  the  kinds  of  changes  we  feel  are  worthy  of  con- 
sideration are  those  which  would  tend  to  improve  upon  the  present 
system,  and  not  destroy  it  or  affect  its  present  high  level  of  perform- 
ance. The  legulated  competitive  environment  of  the  air  transport 
system  has  not  only  fulfilled  all  of  the  objectives  of  an  unregulated 
environment  and  has  been  truly  responsive  to  public  service  needs. 

The  record  of  the  air  transport  industry  shows :  (1)  that  we  are  not 
high  priced;  (2)  we  are  consumer-responsive;  (3)  we  offer  a  high 
quality  of  service;  (4)  we  are  innovative  and  have  introduced  a  high 
degree  of  technology;  and  (5)  we  maintain  an  extensive  network  of 
public  service. 

We  believe  that  there  is  no  way  that  a  major  overhaul  of  the  regula- 
tory structure  of  air  transportation,  let  alone  deregulation,  could 
improve  on  this  record. 

Thank  you,  sir. 

I  am  open  to  additional  questions,  if  you  wish. 

FARE   FLEXIBILITY 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  Beyer  will  ask  some  questions,  but  before 
we  get  to  that,  what  was  your  reaction  to  some  of  the  proposals  made 
this  morning  by  the  DOT  in  terms  of  price  flexibility,  for  example, 
that  permit  at  least  some — I  think  they  talk  about  zone  of  flexibility. 

Dr.  James.  This  is  the  zone  of  reasonableness  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  In  terms  of  rates. 

Dr.  James.  Yes,  sir. 

The  carriers  are  divided.  There  will  be  carriers  who  might  show 
some  interest  in  that,  many  others  who  would  not.  I  am  not  in  a  posi- 
tion to  give  a  unified  industry  answer  to  it  except  to  say  that  one  does 
have  to  examine  what  the  purpose  would  be.  It  is  the  purpose  to 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  I  suppose  the  purpose  is  to  permit  some- 
body w^ho  wants  to  fly,  as  I  did  last  Thursday,  from  Washington  to 
San  Francisco,  to  go  for  $100  instead  of  $200. 

Dr.  James.  Yes,  sir.  We  have  introduced  just  this  month  the  op- 
portunity for  you  and  others  who  so  wish  to  use  it  to  fly  at  discount 
rates  at  those  distances,  and  in  effect  we  would  view  that  as  part  of  the 
zoning. 

Senator  Kennedy.  With  regard  to  that  point,  you  are  generally  ac- 
cepting that  proposal  that  they  mentioned  there.  As  I  understand  from 
what  you  are  saying  now,  you  have  no  real  problem  with  it. 

Dr.  James.  What  I  am  saying  at  this  point,  Senator,  is  that  in  many 
ways  the  present  practice  is  meeting  the  objective  that  you  are  seeking. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  if  they  do  not — then,  if  it  is  meeting  the  ob- 
jective and  you  are  saying  that  has  all  ready  been  done,  then  I  under- 
stand you  are  in  general  support  of  it.  You  say  that  has  already  been 
done,  it  is  not  necessary 


110 

Dr.  James.  I  am  in  general  support  of  the  wide  variety  of 
fares  which  the  industry  offers  the  public,  which  are  in  varying 
combinations. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  say  they  are  all  ready  doing  it  what  is 
your  reluctance  to  support  it?  I  do  not  understand  it.  You  say  they 
are  already  doing  it,  you  are  in  support  if  they  are  already  doing  it. 
You  cannot  have  it  both  ways. 

Dr.  James.  I  guess  what  I  am  really  saying,  Senator,  is  that  if  we 
are  already  doing  it  one  way  and  accomplishing  the  objective  a  second 
way,  why  do  it  the  second  way  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  then  you  are  against  jt  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  am  not  in  a  position  to  represent  an  industry  view,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  your  own  personal  view  ? 

Dr.  James.  That  we  are  already  meeting  a  zone  of  reasonableness 
by  the  variety  of  fares  that  we  are  offering  the  public. 

Senator  Kennedy.  This  is  not  different  from  your  industry  view? 

Dr.  James.  It  is  not  different  from  our  industry  practice.  The  in- 
dustry view  would  be  different  from  the  industry  practice,  depending 
upon  the  spectrum  of  answers  to  the  questionnaire  that  you  have  on 
this  same  subject. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  makes  it  very  clear. 

freer  route  entry 

How  about  freer  entry  into  the  market  area  ?  You  say  the  admin- 
istration strongly  supports  liberalization  of  entry  into  the  airline  in- 
dustry and  the  proposal  provides  substantial  entry  and  exit 
liberalization. 

Dr.  James.  Yes,  we  feel  very  strongly  that  if  you  had  complete 
freedom  of  entry  in  these  markets  that  only  the  larger  more  profitable 
markets  would  survive  and  only  a  few  carriers  would  survive,  and  the 
value  we  now  have  in  the  total  58,000  city-pair  markets  would  be 
destroyed,  and  it  would  not  be  too  long  until  we  find  that  our  ability 
to  get  more — to  get  service  between  more  than  70  to  200  pairs  out  of 
this  58,000  would  be  a  reality.  We  would  not  be  able  to  get  more  serv- 
ice than  that. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  how  do  you  respond  to  the  points  that  were 
given  this  morniup;  that,  if  some  carriers  diop  by  the  wayside  because 
they  are  poorly  administered,  they  do  so  because  they  are  inefficient? 
There  are  others  that  can  run  an  airline  better.  "Why  do  they  not  hove 
the  ability  to  come  in  and  offer  a  price  and  service  to  the  public 
that 

Dr.  James.  I  simply  do  not  accept  the  fact  that  we  have  as  a  group, 
a  poorly  managed  airline.  Between  1969  and  1974,  we  have  reduced 
our  employees  3i^  percent.  At  the  same  time  we  increased  our  volume 
of  traffic,  passengers  hauled  by  20  percent,  passenger-miles  by  30 
percent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  they  are  doing  such  a  good  job  what  do  they 
have  to  fear  from  anybody  coming  in  ? 

Dr.  James.  The  thing  you  have  to  fear  is  the  loss  of  some  57,000 
city-pair  services. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  do  you  say  that?  You  say  they  are  all  doing 
a  complete  job,  are  not  overpriced,  arc  consumer  responsive  and  innova- 


Ill 

tive  and  give  extensive  public  service,  so  what  should  they  have  to 
fear  ?  It  seems  to  me  the  people  who  have  something  to  fear  are  the 
people  who  are  sticking  their  neck  out. 

JJr.  James.  Sir,  I  think  it  is  the  public,  the  Government  that  should 
have  the  fear,  the  fear  that  the  public  service  to  all  of  these  city-pairs 
will  be  destroyed  or  effectively  compromised.  The  surviving  carriers 
in  this  should  have  nothing  to  fear,  but  there  would  be  few  of  them 
serving  very  few  markets. 

Senator  Kennedy.  At  a  lower  price,  I  suppose  ? 

Dr.  James.  Xot  necessarily,  because  if  you  compare  our  price  per- 
fonnance  over  the  past  30  yeare,  we  are  marketing  better  than  the 
economy.  That  is,  better  in  the  sense  that  we  are  priced  lower  rela- 
tively to  them. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  are  back  to  the  question  of  whether  fares 
might  not  be  even  less  if  you  had  competition  or  free  entry. 

It  reminds  me  of  the  patient  who  had  a  temperature  of  101  and  his 
temperature  was  98  one  day  and  went  up  to  101  the  next  and  102  the 
next,  and  the  doctor  said  you  are  getting  better  because  you  are  getting 
sicker  more  slowly. 

How  do  you  know  if,  with  competition,  you  might  not  be  doing 
better,  even  further  below  the  national  average  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  think  my  answer  would  be  this.  Could  anyone  say 
that  we  could  do  better — I  do  not  think  we  could — but  let  us  assume 
that  we  did,  on  70  markets,  and  with  two  or  three  carriers,  at  the  cost 
of  serving  the  rest  of  the  network  that  now  exists.  If  they  think  we 
would  improve  then  they  are  overlooking  the  cost,  the  cost  to  the  public 
in  particular. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  never  know,  though,  if  we  follow  your 
position,  because  you  Avould  not  permit  or  at  least  not  encourage  new 
entry  of  other  carriers  into  the  market.  The  way  that  I  understand 
your  answer  is  that  nothing  would  b3  more  disastrous  for  the  whole 
traveling  piiblic  than  if  you  opened  it  up  to  any  kind  of  competition. 
If  we  follow  your  testimony,  we  will  have  no  way  of  knowing,  will  we? 

Dr.  James.  I  think  in  response  to  that  question,  it  is  well  advised  to 
keep  in  mind  that  those  who  advocate  tliis,  as  they  essentiaPy  did  this 
morning,  were  also  in  extreme  wonderment  as  to  just  whether  or  not 
you  could  go  through  this  transition  and  not  effect  the  city  service  that 
we  now  have.  Many  questions  were  raised  on  their  part  as  well. 

Senator  Kennedy.  1  raised  most  of  them. 

Dr.  James.  You  did,  and  I  appreciate  that. 

CAB  authority  TO  IMMUNIZE  INTERCARRIER  AGREEMENTS  FROM  THE 
ANTITRUST   LAWS 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  about  the  antitrust  immunity?  How  do 
you  stand  on  that  ? 

Dr.  James.  I  would  like  to  refer,  if  I  may,  to  our  chief  legal  counsel, 
Mr.  Landry. 

]Mr.  Landry.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

If  I  could  just  add  one  comment  to  what  Dr.  James  has  been  saying 
about  the  consequences  of  free  entry  as  to  what  would  hapj^en.  As  he 
has  emphasized,  you  have  70  markets  equalling  the  support  from 
57,000  city-pairs.  That  fact  reminds  you  of  what  Willie  Sutton  said 


112 

when  they  asked  him  why  he  robbed  banks.  He  said  tliat  is  where  the 
money  is.  The  entrants  would  go  to  the  70  markets,  that  is  where  the 
money  is. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  hope  there  will  be  one  between  Boston  and 
Washington. 

Mr.  Landry.  If  I  may  get  to  the  other  question,  the  system  under 
414,  I  believe  it  would  be  a  mistake  and  a  serious  mistake  from  the 
consumer  point  of  view  to  do  away  with  the  antitrust  immunity,  to  do 
away  with  section  414.  There  is  a  tremendously  integrated  network  with 
some  24  carriers  serving  this  host  of  markets  in  which  a  number  of 
efficiencies  and  cost  savings  are  brought  about  through  intercarrier 
agreements.  Those  agreements  would  not  be  formulated  if  the  carriers 
were  fearful  of  the  very  drastic  consequences,  particularly  now  under 
the  new  law,  of  the  antitrust  violations. 

I  am  not  saying  these  agreements  are  worked  out  in  smoke-filled 
back  rooms  or  anything  of  that  sort.  They  are  worked  out  in  the  open, 
in  front  of  the  observers  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  the  Depart- 
ment of  Justice,  the  Department  of  Transportation.  I  have  had  the 
privilege  in  the  last  week,  for  example,  to  play  host  to  a  very  dramatic 
effort  of  carriers  around  the  world  to  try  to  cope  with  the  escalating 
price  of  fuel.  Some  75  carriers  have  gathered  together  to  see  if  they 
could  formulate  some  joint  actions  that  might  bring  the  price  of  fuel 
down,  to  the  benefit  of  the  consumers.  Those  carriers  held  a  giant 
meeting  last  week,  observed  from  beginning  to  end  by  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board,  DOT  was  present  throughout,  and  the  Depart- 
ment of  Justice  had  the  opportunity  to  be  there.  But  in  any  event, 
any  agreement  that  comes  out  of  that  will  only  go  into  effect  if  ap- 
proved by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  Under  the  holding  in  the 
local  cartage  case,  the  CAB,  if  it  sees  anticompetitive  effects,  it  is  not 
going  to  approve  any  such  agreement  unless  it  positively  and  affirma- 
tively finds  this  the  only  way  to  meet  a  serious  transportation  need 
or  to  secure  important  public  benefits.  So,  I  think  all  in  all  this  is 
very  close  scrutiny.  And,  the  system  is  working. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  they  keep  transcripts  of  those  meetings? 

Mr.  Landry.  Minutes  are  being  given  to  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board  and  they  are  public.  And,  they  allow  interested  persons  to  come 
in  and  address  the  meetings. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  support  keeping  transcripts,  as  we 
do  here  in  the  Senate? 

Mr.  Landry.  In  some  cases  they  have  transcripts. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  you  see  any  reason  why  they  should  not  keep 
transcripts?  You  just  talked  about  how  open  the  meeting  was.  Do 
you  have  any  reason  why  transcripts  should  not  be  kept? 

Mr.  Landry.  In  this  case — if  transcripts  were  made  available  to  the 
oil  companies.  I  imagine  that  the  dinlog  would  not  be  quite  as  free 
as  it  would  be  absent  such  a  transcript.  But  full  minutes  are  being 
submitted  to  the  CAB  today,  as  a  matter  of  fact. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  really  cannot  have  it  both  ways.  I  think  up 
to  this  year  the  Congress  was  one  of  the  biggest  offenders.  We  have 
executive  sessions  from  which  the  public  was  excluded,  and  conferences 
with  the  House  of  Eepresentatives  in  most  instances  were  closed.  That 
has  gone  on  for  some  time.  It  was  generally  felt  that  if  we  opened  up 
these  meetings,  either  the  Members  themselves  would  be  fighting  a 


113 

losing  battle  in  front  of  the  press  and  the  various  kinds  of  interested 
groups,  or  that  there  would  be  a  distortion  of  the  legislative  process. 
But  it  has  been  demonstrated,  and  I  think  quite  effectively,  that  this  is 
not  the  case  in  the  number  of  committees  which  have  held  the  open 
executive  sessions  in  considering  extremely  important  matters  of 
policy. 

I  am  just  wondering  why  we  should  not  have  these  airline  meetings 
open,  or  maintain  transcripts ;  what  reluctance  you  would  have  to 

Mr.  Landry.  Mr.  Chairman,  I  think  in  this  particular  set  of  discus- 
sions that  I  am  talking  about,  I  think,  it  is  unique  in  not  having  them 
open  with  a  transcript. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  they  should  be  open  with  tran- 
scripts unless  there  is  going  to  be  a  vote  taken  by  participants  to  close 
it? 

Mr.  Landry.  No  ;  I  believe  that  the  discussions,  for  example,  capacity 
discussions  and  so  forth,  have  had  consumer  groups  represented 
throughout  the  discussions.  I  believe  they  have  been  fully  open  to 
members  of  the  general  public  and  have  been  held  in  that  kind  of  gold- 
fish bowl  without  any  adverse  consequences. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Come  on,  do  you  favor  keeping  transcripts,  or  do 
you  not  ? 

Mr.  Landry.  There  were  transcripts,  I  believe,  of  those  capacity  dis- 
cussions and  any  discussions  of  that  nature.  So  I  say  about  90  percent 
of  the  time 

Senator  Kennedy.  It  is  the  other  10  percent  that  we  want  to  get.  The 
minimum  charter  discussions  that  we  had  last  fall,  I  think  the  tran- 
script of  that  meeting  would  have  been  fascinating. 

Mr.  Landry.  I  am  not  sure  of  the  ground  rules  for  those  discussions 
as  to  whether  there  was  a  transcript.  I  do  not  know. 

GENERAL   FARE    INCREASES    IN    PREVIOUS    YEARS 

Mr.  Breyer.  a  couple  of  minor  questions. 

First,  I  would  just  like  to  clarify  this,  because  we  are  making  an 
effort  to  keep  our  statistics  accurate,  I  have  gone  over  your  prepared 
testimony.  I  was  a  little  bit  disturbed  because  you  stated  that  contrary 
to  what  Senator  Kennedy  said — contrary  to  the  December  16  state- 
ment— last  year  the  domestic  airlines  were  granted  fare  increases  total- 
ing 10  percent.  I  went  back  and  checked  that  again  and  I  think  we 
were  accurate  on  that,  were  we  not  ? 

The  CAB,  on  December  16,  granted  a  5  percent  increase.  It  granted 
a  6  percent  increase  in  April  1964  and  there  was  a  4  percent  increase 
in  April  1974.  Then,  specifically  referred  to  in  the  speech,  the  CAB 
phased  out  discount  fares  which  amounted  to  a  5.4  percent  increase. 
These  total  19.4  percent.  Senator  Kennedy  described  the  increases  as 
"nearly  20  percent." 

So  I  would  appreciate  your  going  over  your  statement  because  we  are 
making  an  effort  to  be  accurate.  I  do  not  think  what  the  Senator  said 
is  contrary  to  the  facts. 

Dr.  James.  We  think  by  putting  the  discount  fare  changes  in  you 
are  mixing  apples  and  oranges,  which  is  something  many  others  have 
done  as  well.  If  you  talk  about  the  5  and  the  6  and  the  4,  the  15  for  the 
3  general  air  fare  increases,  you  are  talking  about  the  impact  we 


51-146    O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


114 

had  on  the  normal  traveler.  If  you  are  talking  about  the  discount  fares, 
they  affected  the  family  fare  traveler  and  the  youth  traveler.  To  many 
that  change  was  almost  as  much  as  40  percent  because  it  was  going  from 
66  to  75  percent  of  full  fare  up  to  full  fare  over  three  stages. 

Now,  in  turn,  however,  he  now  has  available,  beginning  this  month, 
20  to  25  percent  off.  So  the  change  to  many  perhaps  is  only  10  or  15 
percent  increase.  The  change  to  the  average  nondiscount  traveler,  the 
general  fare  increases  then  are  15  percent  in  that  time  period. 

Mr.  Breyer.  The  CAB  gave  us  that  number.  I  would  appreciate 
it  if  you  would  check  it  out. 

Dr.  James.  The  difference  is  whether  or  not  you  should  have  in  the 
calculations  the  discount  fare  changes  which  are  really  yield  changes. 

SMALL   TOWN    SERVICE    ( CROSS-SUBSIDY ) 

Mr.  Breyer.  I  just  want  to  stress  a  point  that  I  had  some  difficulty 
understanding.  I  am  not  certain  what  argument  you  are  making  when 
you  talk  about  the  complexity  of  the  network.  I  think  at  some  point 
what  you  are  saying  is  that  there  are  a  lot  of  unprofitable  routes  that 
are  being  subsiaized  by  other  profitable  routes.  Now,  if  that  is  the 
case,  what  is  interesting  to  me  about  that  is  the  Department  of  Trans- 
portation and  the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers  and  people  who  seri- 
ously studied  the  matter  for  a  number  of  years  argue  that  there  is 
not  any  substantial  cross-subsidy.  If  in  fact  you  did  have  more  competi- 
tion you  would  still  get  those  little  towns  served,  maybe  not  every 
one,  but  certainly  most  of  them,  perhaps  by  commuter  airlines.  But 
you  state  the  contrary  is  true. 

What  I  would  like  to  ask  you  to  do  is  to  substantiate  that  claim, 
come  up  with  lists  of  costs  or  lists  of  those  towns  that  would  be  cut 
off.  Can  you  prepare  this  computer  printout  or  whatever  cost  studies 
are  necessary,  because  we  have  cost  studies  on  one  side  and  I  think  it 
would  be  helpful  to  have  them  on  the  other. 

Dr.  James.  I  believe  there  are  two  questions  there,  one  on  cross- 
subsidy  and  our  ability  to  produce  this  feeder  information. 

On  the  cross-subsidy,  I  believe  that  that  is  a  concept  that  has  been 
misused  on  many  occasions,  and  I  would  cite  this,  that  if  you  take  the 
flight  that  we  have  from  Fresno  to  Denver  to  Chicago,  and  we  have 
27  passengers  that  are  coming  from  Fresno  to  Denver  that  continue 
on  to  Chicago.  Now,  they  are  on  that  major  hub  that  is  often  looked 
upon  as  subsidizing  the  smaller  feed  route  that  they  just  came  on. 
So  they  are  in  effect  subsidizing  themselves  if  you  call  it  cross-subsidy. 

Now,  what  about  the  passengers  who  are  on  that  flight  who  did 
indeed  originate  in  Denver  and  go  to  Chicago.  Are  they  subsidizing 
those  who  were  fed  into  Denver.  Well,  I  believe  you  can  look  upon 
that  as  if  they  are  not,  because  what  is  happening  there  is  that  they 
are  getting  a  higher  level  of  service  than  they  would  have  gotten 
without  the  feeding  routes  coming  into  Denver. 

Mr.  Breyer.  What  I  am  asking  is  that  you  make  a  serious  effort  to 
prepare  the  documentation  that  would  bear  out  the  statement.  In  Cali- 
fornia they  have  a  competitive  system  and  feeder  routes,  as  well.  Nore- 
theless,  you  think  if  there  were  freer  entry  the  feeder  systems  would 
be  destroyed.  I  am  asking  for  the  subcommittee  if  you  could  submit 
documentation. 


115 

Dr.  James.  All  right,  sir.  We  will  make  that  effort.  I  might  indicate 
that  you  will  find  tnere  are  other  sources,  and  among  them  larger  air- 
craft manufacturers  who  have  studied  the  same  problem,  and  it  is 
very  possible  that  they,  too,  could  produce  information  along  this  line. 
We  perhaps  can  lurnish  a  list  to  you  of  tliose  who  may  liave  such 
information  available. 

Mr.  Breyer.  I  think  it  is  relevant  to  the  question.  For  example,  you 
have  often  talked  about  the  need  for  regulation  to  provide  public  serv- 
ice. This  is  perhaps  a  different  question.  You  say  "adequate  public  serv- 
ice." In  California  there  is  a  choice  between  adequate  public  service 
supplied  by  a  regulated  line  and  unregulated  lines.  If  you  look  at  the 
PSA  figures,  a  line  that  is  not  subject  to  CAB  regulation  you  find  that 
far  more  people  fly  on  PSA  in  California  than  on  scheduled  service. 
When  people  seem  to  be  given  that  choice  they  seem  not  to  take  the 
scheduled,  CAB-regulated  service. 

Dr.  James.  We  think  there  is  a  lot  that  needs  to  be  illuminated  be- 
tween interstate  and  intrastate  operations,  and  we  of  course,  and  some 
of  the  carriers  as  well,  will  be  participating  in  your  February  14  hear- 
ing in  Boston. 

Mr.  Breyer.  This  afternoon  is  not  meant  to  fully  expose  the  indus- 
try's position.  We  hope  this  morning's  testimony  will  focus  the  dis- 
cussion. Anybody  in  the  industry  who  wishes  to  present  documentation 
is  invited  to  present  it  in  written  form  even  if  they  do  not  testify 
orally. 

Dr.  James.  Fine. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  want  to  thank  you  very  much  for  coming. 

I  think  Mr.  Breyer  indicated  we  are  looking  forward  to  the  testi- 
mony of  the  airlines  themselves  and  working  with  you  and  we  want 
to  tell  you  how  much  we  appreciate  your  presence  here  and  response  to 
the  questions. 

We  will  recess  until  next  week. 

The  subcommittee  stands  adjourned. 

[Whereupon,  at  4 :05  p.m.,  the  subcommittee  was  adjourned.] 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Dr.  James  follows :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Dr.  George  W.  James,  Air  Transport 
Association  of  America 

My  name  is  George  W.  James,  I  am  Senior  Vice  President  of  Economics  and 
Finance  of  the  Air  Transport  Association  of  America,  which  represents  virtually 
all  of  the  U.S.  scheduled  airlines.  I  am  accompanied  by  Mr.  James  Landry,  ATA 
General  Counsel,  and  Mr.  Gabriel  Phillips,  ATA  Vice  President-International. 

Because  our  industry  and  the  public  it  serves  are  directly  and  comprehensively 
affected  by  the  regulatory  environment  established  by  Congress,  we  welcome  the 
attention  being  focused  on  this  subject — in  these  hearings,  and  elsewhere  on  the 
part  of  the  Congress,  the  executive  branch  and  the  public. 

As  you  stated  on  December  16,  Mr.  Chairman,  the  basic  objective  of  airline 
regulation  is  adequate  service  at  reasonable  prices.  We  believe  airline  regulation 
has  met  that  test.  Nevertheless,  we  believe  that  consideration  by  this  panel  and 
others  of  the  issue  of  regulatory  reform  presents  opportunities  not  only  for 
thorough  review  of  the  existing  structure  and  procedures,  but — more  important — 
for  seeking  improvements  in  regulation.  These  improvements  can  lead  to  an  even 
more  effective  and  responsive  public  air  transportation  system. 

The  regulatory  environment  within  which  airlines  have  operated  since  1938 
has  resulted  in  "the  most  comprehensive  air  transportation  network  in  th3 
world."  This  is  pointed  up  by  the  fact  that,  in  1974,  the  scheduled  airlines,  with 
30,000  employees,  operated  a  modern  fleet  of  2,400  aircraft  on  13,000  flights  daily, 
and  carried  208  million  passenger's   (representing  about  75  percent  of  intercity 


116 

common  carrier  passenger  miles ) ,  3.3  million  tons  of  freight,  and  16  billion  pieces 
of  mail.  Further,  in  19.4  this  industry  transported  six  million  more  passengers 
than  in  1973,  and  used  about  one  billion  gallons  less  fuel  in  the  process.  These 
facts  demonstrate  clearly  the  size,  importance,  and  public  responsibility  of  the 
scheduled  airlines  within  the  $60  billion  U.S.  travel  industry. 

Dominating  the  1974  economic  picture  for  the  airlines,  as  for  the  nation,  was 
the  combined  impact  of  the  energy  crisis,  inflation,  and  recession.  Contrary  to 
your  December  16  statement,  Senator  Kennedy,  last  year  the  domestic  airlines 
were  granted  general  fare  increases  totalling  10  percent.  Another  5  percent  had 
been  granted  in  December  1973.  These  fare  increases  were  exceeded  by  inflation 
in  airline  costs  of  more  than  20  percent,  including  the  more  than  doubling  of  per 
gallon  fuel  cost  during  the  year.  The  fact  is  that  additional  revenues  provided  by 
the  April,  1974  fuel-related  domestic  fare  increase  and  the  fuel-related  portion  of 
the  4  percent  mid-November  increase  to  which  you  have  referred  will  total  about 
$400  million,  as  compared  to  the  1974  domestic  fuel  cost  increase  alone  of 
about  $700  million — a  shortfall  of  $300  million.  Yet,  despite  the  massive  chal- 
lenges which  have  confronted  our  industry  during  the  past  year,  our  record 
of  public  service — providing  quality  transportation  at  reasonable  fare  levels  to 
meet  the  needs  of  the  traveling  and  shipping  public — has  remained  strong. 

Simply  put,  the  experience  of  37  years  of  regulated  competition  has  resulted 
in  an  air  transportation  network  bringing  adequate,  integrated,  and  reliable 
public  transport  service  to  540  U.S.  airports  serving  thousands  of  communities, 
at  reasonable  and  cost-related  prices — as  a  matter  of  fact,  the  best  transportation 
system  in  the  world. 

This  industry  has  come  a  long  way  since  1938,  and  the  regulatory  environment 
within  which  it  has  operated  played  a  key  role  in  this  development.  The  CAB 
and  the  private,  competing  airline  managements  have  worked  within  the  frame- 
work of  regulated  competition  established  by  Congress  to  furnish  the  American 
people  this  unparalleled  system  of  transportation,  a  system,  we  believe,  that 
would  not  have  been  possible  except  through  a  balance  between  regulation  and 
competition  in  the  industry. 

Regulated  Competition 

The  system  of  air  transportation,  since  its  inception  as  an  effective  force  in 
the  American  economy  in  the  late  1930's,  has  been  founded  on  the  principle  of 
regulated  competition.  This  has  been  necessary  because  of  the  special  position 
of  public  transportation  in  the  economy.  In  the  spectrum  of  economic  activity, 
from  a  natural  monopoly  to  perfect  competition,  transportation  falls  in  between. 

Unlike  certain  specific  public  utilities  in  which  embedded  costs  are  immense 
and  therefore  economies  of  scale  so  apparent  ^  that  they  may  be  characterized 
as  natural  monopolies,  components  of  air  transportation  are  conducive  to  com- 
petition. While  the  cost  of  equipment  and  facilities  is  high,  and  rising,  airlines 
are  by  their  nature  mobile.  More  important,  airlines  are  embedded  in  the  essen- 
tially competitive  structures  of  market  economics,  requiring  efficient  and  adapt- 
able management  to  compete  effectively  against  unregulated  business  for  capital 
in  the  marketplace.^  Thus,  competition  has  properly  played  a  key  role  in  the 
development  of  U.S.  air  transportation. 

Still,  air  transportation  cannot  be  placed  in  the  perfect  or  workable  competi- 
tive environment  since,  as  historical  experience  has  shown,  without  degrees  of 
government  regulation  of  competition,  public  service  industries  have  become 
inadequate.  Nor  can  it  be  expected  that  abolishing  of  regulation  would  lead  to 
the  best  allocation  of  air  transportation  resources. 

The  Elements  of  Air  Transportation  Regxilation 

Air  transport  regulation  can  be  viewed  as  having  essentially  four  basic 
objectives : ^ 

1.  Prevent  unreasonable  prices  which  produce  excessive  earnings  ; 

2.  Ensure  profits  suflScient  for  the  development  and  expansion  of  the  industry; 

3.  Assure  that  a  wide  variety  of  services  are  offered  to  the  public ; 

4.  Maintain  certain  types  of  directly  unremunerative  services  that  serve  a 
broad  public  need. 


-  Me^-er.  John.  Competition.  MTUet  Structure  and  Regulatory  Institutions  in  Transporta- 
tion. .50  Vn.  L.  Rev.  212,  214  (1964). 

2Thi(1.  at  218. 

'Meyer,  John:  Peck,  Merton  ;  Stenason,  John;  Zwlck,  Chnrles.  The  Kf'onom'cs  of  Com- 
petition in  the  Transportation  Industries,  Harvard  University  Press,  1960,  p.  11. 


117 

With  the  exception  of  the  fourth  objective,  the  others  are  generally  considered 
to  be  the  normal  results  of  the  workings  of  a  competitive  marliet. 

Further,  there  are  certain  unique  elements  of  air  transportation  which,  if  left 
to  the  free  market  processes,  could  create  a  concentrated  industry  in  a  relatively 
short  period  of  time.*  These  characteristics  include  the  complexity  of  aircraft 
operations,  the  increasing  expense  of  individual  aircraft,  the  need  for  extensive 
maintenance  facilities,  and  the  fact  that  a  high  percentage  of  the  passenger 
markets  are  between  points  of  such  low  traffic  density  that  even  a  single  monopoly 
carrier  might  not  be  able  to  cover  costs.  Moreover,  though,  the  air  transportation 
system  still  must  purchase  its  own  goods  and  services  from  the  environment  of 
competition,  for  it  buys  its  supplies  at  prices  set  by  the  economy  as  a  whole,  it 
compensates  its  employees  at  wage  levels  uncontrolled  by  government,  and  it  must 
compete  for  both  the  consumer  dollar  and  the  capital  dollar  in  the  basically  un- 
regulated markets.^ 

All  of  the  above  shows  that  there  are  characteristics  of  the  air  transportation 
market  that  preclude  its  operating  in  perfect  of  workable  competition,  and  that 
the  middle  ground  between  a  natural  monopoly  and  deregulation  is  desirable 
from  the  standpoint  of  public  service  and  from  the  standpoint  of  economic  gains 
in  the  economy  as  a  whole. 

Air  transportation  is  perceived  as  performing  an  essential  public  service, 
namely,  the  movement  of  people  and  goods  throughout  the  nation,  lubricating 
the  flow  of  commerce.  It  is  this  fundamental  purpose,  superimposed  on  the 
natural  and  proper  competitive  environments,  which  government  seeks  to  achieve 
through  its  power  of  regulation. 

The  air  transportation  marketplace,  and  the  nature  of  the  business  itself, 
provide  a  special  role  in  the  economy.  Airline  customers,  including  government, 
business,  and  communities  relying  on  airline  services,  have  a  need  for  such  serv- 
ices at  times,  to  places,  and  under  circumstances  ordinary  business  would  not 
provide.  This  need  is  repeatedly  emphasized  in  the  demand  for  such  services 
expressed  by  the  public  at  route  hearings  before  the  CAB,  in  legislation  enacted 
by  Congress,  and  generally  in  the  marketplace. 

The  National  Air  Transportation  System 

Thus,  the  result  of  this  government  involvement,  combined  with  the  benefits 
of  a  vital  private  enterprise,  has  been  an  environment  of  regulated  competition. 
This  environment  has  provided  a  major  impetus  for  the  development  of  the 
present  national  air  transportation  system  sought  by  Congress  in  the  public 
interest  since  the  enactment  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938  in  response  to 
the  unregulated  economic  climate  and  resulting  chaos  characterizing  the  pre- 
ceding decade." 

The  national  air  transportation  system  is  characteri7ed  by  stability,  speed, 
reliability,  and,  above  all,  a  vast  network  of  interlocking  air  routes  connectinj? 
58,000  city-pairs.  Its  value  to  the  nation  and  the  public  is  derived  from  all  of  those 
essential  features — providing  society  with  speed,  mobility,  and  convenience 
through  the  integrated  service  network,  contributing  to  employment,  directly 
and  indirectly  through  allied  services  and  related  industries,  and  making  a 
significant  gross  contribution  to  the  total  output  of  the  United  States. 

It  is  the  continued  strengthening  of  this  system  in  the  public  interest  which 
the  issue  of  regulatory  reform  concerns,  and  which  is  the  stated  goal  of  these 
hearings. 

Objectives  of  Reform  :  Theory  and  the  "Real  World" 

Many  of  the  regulatory  policies  and  procedures  developed  over  the  years  by 
Congress  and  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  naturally  have  been  the  subject  of 
discussion  and  debate  among  articulate  and  learned  proponents  and  critics — 
in  government,  in  institutions  of  learning,  and  within  the  airline  industry.  Es- 
pecially in  recent  times,  the  debate  has  been  extended  even  to  question  the  con- 
tinued wif'dom  of  the  underlying  principle  of  regulated  competition  itself. 

Mr.  Chairman,  you  have  spoken  of  the  obligation  of  Congress,  in  its  role  as 
legslative  overseer  of  the  regulatory  structure,  to  examine  that  structure  to  as- 
sure that  the  CAB  carries  out  its  responsibility  to  regulate  air  carriers  in  the 
public  interest,  and  to  make  such  changes  as  may  be  required.  This  process  is 


«Ibid.,  p.  228. 

s  Tbid.,  p.  2. 

"  First  Annual  Report  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Authority,  1940,  p.  1. 


118 

not  only  useful,   but  patently  necessary,  we  believe,  to  assure  the  continued 
vitality  of  our  industry  and  the  public  service  it  provides. 

The  Real  World 

We  believe  it  essential  that  in  the  deliberations  today,  and  in  those  vphich 
will  follow,  special  care  be  taken  to  insure  that  it  is  the  "real  world"  of  air 
transportation  which  is  the  subject  of  scrutiny.  Hypothetical  models  alone — 
based  as  they  are,  not  on  the  actual  demonstrated  needs  of  the  traveling  and 
shipping  public,  but  rather  on  theories  applicable  only  in  an  insulated  theoret- 
ical environment — may  be  helpful  as  a  guide  to  thinking.  But  their  application 
beyond  the  classroom  or  the  text  book  must  be  carefully  considered  in  light  of 
existing,  real  circumstances. 

We  intend,  therefore,  to  look  to  this  "real  world",  today's  and  tomorrow's, 
to  review  what  the  objectives  of  air  transiX)rtation  and  the  underlying  regulatory 
principles  are;  to  identify  the  actual  results  of  our  system  of  regulated  com- 
petition ;  and  to  suggest  realistic  areas  of  improvement  in  that  system  to  render 
it  better  able  to  serve  public  needs  in  the  last  quarter  of  this  century. 

The   Critics'   View  and  Its  Inadequacies 

Many  of  those  who  have  found  fault  with  the  regulatory  environment  in  which 
air  transportation  now  operates  seek  to  achieve  a  laudatory  goal :  air  transport 
service  at  minimum  cost-based  prices,  principally  through  operation  at  higher 
load  factors  generally  termed  maximum  efficient  quality  of  service.  We  believe 
we  have  accomplished  that  goal  taking  into  account  another  equally  important 
goal,  the  need  for  adequate  public  service.  Little,  if  any,  attention  is  paid  in  the 
scholarly  works  published  by  the  critics  to  this  important  need  which  you  have 
cited.  Senator  Kennedy,  as  the  basic  objective  of  airline  regulation.  After  all, 
it  is  the  provision  of  adequate  public  service,  at  reasonable  prices,  which  by 
definition  characterizes  an  effective  public  transportation  system.  And  adequacy 
can  be  measured  in  many  ways,  in  respect  to  a  particular  market  for  example, 
by  a  precise  measurement  of  volume,  timing  of  schedules,  ability  to  obtain  seats 
on  a  particular  flight,  load  factor  on  flights  operating  at  convenient  times.'  To 
serve  the  public  adequately,  the  air  transportation  system  must  permit  reason- 
able access  between  all  points  on  the  system. 

Additionally,  the  critics  have  paid  little  attention  to  the  need  for  providing 
an  amply  differentiated  range  of  qualities  and  types  of  any  given  product  to 
choose  from,^  a  prime  objective  of  competition  in  our  nation's  economic  system. 
As  I  shall  demonstrate,  it  is  this  choice  of  product,  at  a  varying  range  of  price, 
which  today  characterizes  air  transportation  in  the  United  States,  and  it  is  a 
measurement  of  the  effectiveness  of  our  competitive  environment  in  serving  the 
public. 

A  system  which  would  fail  these  tests  clearly  would  not  be  providing  effec- 
tive public  service  and,  in  turn,  contributing  to  the  nation's  economic  strength. 

In  reviewing  the  results  to  date  of  regulated  competition  in  public  air  trans- 
portation, we  shall  focus  on  those  objectives  sought  by  critics,  always  mindful 
of  the  overriding  public  requirement  for  adequate  service. 

Achievements  of  Regulated  Competition  Since  1938 

The  True  Costs  of  Air  Transportation 

Since  1938,  average  scheduled  airline  passenger  fares,  in  constant  dollars, 
have  steadily  declined  relative  to  costs  of  all  U.S.  goods  and  services  (exhibit  1). 
The  fact  can  be  further  demonstrated  by  the  following  example :  When  compared 
to  prices  of  certain  other  commonly  purchased  items  in  the  years  1948  and  1974, 
air  fares  represent  a  bargain  to  the  consumer.  During  this  time  the  round  trip 
air  fare  between  New  York  and  San  Francisco  rose  21  percent ;  a  pound  of  round 
steak  increased  in  price  100  percent ;  a  pair  of  men's  shoes  increased  over  120  per- 
cent;  a  Chevrolet  automobile  increased  over  220  percent;  and  though  not 
commonly  purchased,  a  year's  tuition  at  Harvard  increased  over  640  percent 
(exhibit  2). 

Further,  in  comparison  with  other  modes  of  common  carrier  transportation,  air 
fares,  in  1938  constant  dollars,  have  dropped  markedly  more  than  either  bus  or 
coach  rail  fares  ( exhibit  3 ) . 


T  Milwaukee-Chicago-New  York  Restriction  Case.   11  CAB  reports,  310.  319   (1950). 
s  Clark,  .T.  M.,  Comnetition  :  Dynamic  Criteria  of  Appraisal,  Business  Organization  and 
Public  Policy,  Leven,  H.  O.,  ed.,  1958,  p.  8. 


119 

coff?o?nifn  ^""^^^  have  Similarly  experienced  a  continued  decline  relative  to 
costs  of  all  U.S.  goods  and  services  in  the  period  1946-1974  (exhibit  4)  ^^ 

Choice  of  Fares 

For  the  domestic  air  traveler,  a  wide  choice  of  fares  is  currentlv  available 
depending  on  time  of  day  or  week  traveled,  length  of  stay,  and  c?ass  of  service 
desired^xXotable  among  these  fares  is  the  recentlj  approved  broad  based  discount 
fare,  which  provides  an  attractive  bridge  between  charter  and  regular  fares 

Public  use  of  the  entire  range  of  available  fares  historically  has  been  extensive 
For  the  year  ending  September  1974,  for  example,  use  of  lower  than  full  fares 
accounted  for  almost  one-third  of  all  coach  revenue  passenger  miles  (exhibit  5). 
Price  Performance 

From  the  evidence  presented  here,  it  is  inaccurate  and  unfair  to  draw  the  con- 
clusion that  air  fares  are  high.  Further,  to  then  blame  it  on  a  lack  of  government 
regulation  or  the  nature  of  regulated  competition  is,  of  course,  also  inaccurate 
and  unfair.  Let  me  summarize  what  I  have  just  presented  regarding  air  fares : 

1.  The  record  of  regulated  competition  in  the  air  transport  industry  shows 
that,  in  constant  dollars,  air  fares  are  64  percent  less  than  they  were  in 
1938. 

2.  In  the  spectrum  of  price  changes  in  current  dollars,  since  1948  prices  of 
nearly  all  U.S.  goods  and  services  exceed  the  change  in  the  price  of  air  fares. 
Air  fares  have  averaged  less  than  1  percent  a  year  increase  over  this  time 
period. 

3.  The  use  of  scheduled  air  fares  includes  individuals  with  incomes  well 
below  the  average  in  the  U.S.  A  1974  Gallup  survey  showed  that  one  of  every 
seven  adults  making  less  than  $7,000  annual  income  flew  on  the  scheduled 
airlines.  Overall,  the  Gallup  data  revealed  that  18  percent  of  all  adults  mak- 
ing one  or  more  trips  by  air  made  less  than  $7,000  yearly  (exhibit  6). 

4.  Although  the  airlines  are  more  fuel  intensive  than  most  U.S.  industries 
and  have  had  to  absorb  $1  billion  of  additional  fuel  costs  in  the  past  year,  still 
general  air  fare  increases  in  1974  were  less  than  the  change  in  the  consumer 
price  index  and  considerably  less  than  the  change  in  the  wholesale  price 
index.  The  addition  of  the  5  percent  general  fare  increase  in  late  1973  would 
not  alter  this  comparison  appreciably. 

This  pricing  performance,  at  an  adequate  level  of  service,  either  in  the  long 
run  or  the  short  run,  could  not  have  been  matched  by  pricing  in  a  deregulated 
environment.  In  fact,  in  the  long  run,  as  evidenced  by  the  pricing  performance  of 
the  U.S.  economy  as  a  whole,  deregulation  of  the  air  transport  industry  would 
have  placed  prices  and  fares  at  a  much  higher  level  than  now  exists. 

CAB   Performance  Standards— The  Effect  of  the  DPFI 

Members  of  Congress  were  primarily  responsible  for  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board  initiating  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  in  January  1970.  As 
a  consequence,  the  CAB  conducted  a  most  thorough  and  comprehensive  review 
and  revision  of  the  procedures  by  which  domestic  passenger  fares  are  regulated. 
That  part  of  the  investigation  covering  fare  level  and  rate  of  return  procedures 
began  in  January  1970,  and  the  results  were  first  applied  in  May  1973.  It  in- 
volved thousands  of  hours  of  staff  work,  research,  and  open  public  hearings 
participated  in  by  any  who  so  desired.  Administrative  law  judges  listened  to 
the  arguments  of  interested  parties  for  assuring,  among  other  things,  that  the 
airline  industry  was  responsive  to  consumer  interests  and  needs,  and  that  such 
benefits  to  the  traveling  public  in  the  form  of  reasonable  air  fares  were  passed 
on.  The  results  produced  an  innovative  step  forward  in  regulatory  procedures, 
and  were  a  testimonial  to  the  air  transport  industry's  staying  well  ahead  of  any 
need  for  wholesale  regulatory  reform.  The  CAB  standards  of  efficiency  assure 
that  there  is  no  automatic  fare  increase  to  consumers  for  so-called  industry  cost 
mistakes  of  purchasing  excess  equipment,  of  misestimating  a  market  and  hauling 
too  few  people,  or  for  giving  away  business  through  discounting.  The  CAB 
standards  of  efficiency  adjust  for  all  of  these,  and  no  fare  increase  is  allowed 
until  these  adjustments  have  been  made. 

Since  May  1973  each  fare  increase  granted  to  the  industry,  including  the  4 
percent  increase  granted  last  November,  has  been  based  on  meeting  these 
standards. 

Many  of  the  participants  in  various  phases  of  the  investigation  include  those 
who  now  criticize  the  CAB  for  approving  fare  changes. 

These  CAB  fare  level  procedures,  resulting  from  open  public  hearings,  are  not 
arbitrary,  were  not  developed  from  clandestine  meetings,  and  have  a  clear  and 


120 

comprehensive  public  interest  platform  built  in.  Yet  the  opposite  and  misleading 

impression  is  often  given  by  critics  as  an  emotional  appeal  to  consumers.  As  we 

have  shown,  in  fact  it  is  the  consumer  who  is  the  primary  beneficiary  of  these 

procedures. 

Adequacy  of  Service — Load  Factors 

As  I  have  emphasized  previously,  in  addition  to  meeting  the  need  to  provide 
reasonable  prices,  the  primary  function  of  our  industry  is  to  provide  adequate 
and  reliable  service  throughout  the  nation,  to  permit  people  and  goods  to  move 
rapidly  and  smoothly  from  any  one  community  to  any  other.  This  system,  then, 
must  provide  service  at  the  times  and  places  desired  by  the  public. 

Senator  Kennedy,  in  your  statement  on  the  Senate  floor  on  December  16, 
you  referred  to  the  difficulty  a  student  in  Boston  might  experience  in  returning 
to  his  home  in  Detroit  because  of  a  lack  of  available  seats  on  that  route,  I  am 
sure  you  will  recall  that  the  system  load  factor  standard  established  by  the 
Board  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  was  55  percent.  But  the 
diflSculty  of  relating  any  particular  load  factor  to  adequacy  of  service  is  clearly 
illustrated  bv  vour  example. 

In  1974,  the  average  load  factors  experienced  by  the  single  carrier  with  nonstop 
operating  authority  in  the  Boston-Detroit  market  was  59  percent.  Thus,  though 
some  critics  of  our  industry  believe  our  sy.stem  load  factors  should  average  as 
high  as  65  percent,  you  have  cited  an  example  of  possible  inadequate  service  at 
a  load  factor  of  59  percent.  In  reality,  you  have  underscored  a  point  seldom  under- 
stood by  our  load  factor  critics.  To  average  59  percent,  the  Boston-Detroit 
market  shows  a  monthly  load  factor  range  from  52  to  67  ijercent,  this  example 
offering  further  demonstration  of  the  seasonality  of  our  markets  (exhibit  7). 
In  order  to  reach  the  higher  .system  average  load  factor  standards  suggested  by 
many,  the  airlines  would  be  required  to  adjust  capacity  to  conform  to  low- 
demand  periods,  inevitably  resulting  in  less  service  available  to  passengers  in 
busier  times. 

The  question  of  capacity,  then,  is  not  a  simple  one  in  the  real  world  we  serve. 
There  is  a  common  tendency  among  observers  of  the  scheduled  air  transport 
industry  to  overlook  the  fact  that,  although  30  percent  of  our  domestic  traffic 
is  produced  by  only  70  larger  city-pair  markets,  40  percent  is  derived  from  840 
markets,  and  another  30  percent  is  produced  in  some  57,000  smaller  markets 
(exhibit  8).  The  units  of  capacity  available  to  serve  the.se  disparate  markets 
are  not  infinitely  adjustable — they  are  not,  in  fact,  those  elusive  available  seat- 
miles  we  hear  and  read  about ;  they  are  airplanes,  each  containing  many  seats. 

Thus,  to  add  a  few  extra  seat  miles  in  a  market,  where  the  individual  aircraft 
have  maximum  seating  density,  requires  the  addition  of  significant  numbers  of 
seats,  represented  by  another  flight,  or  the  substitution  of  larger  aircraft.  It 
should  be  noted  that  increasing  the  size  of  aircraft  does  not  increase  frequency 
for  the  convenience  of  passengers  in  a  smaller  market.  Similarly,  the  reduction 
of  a  few  seat  miles  to  adjust  to  a  temporary  down-turn  in  traflEic  in  a  particular 
market  or  to  changing  economic  conditions  normally  requires  the  elimination 
of  a  flight.  For  example,  one  major  carrier  operates  a  single  nonstop  Boeing  707 
between  New  York  and  Phoenix,  producing  on  that  one  route  197  million  seat- 
miles  annually.  How  can  a  few  seats  be  added  or  reduced  on  that  route? 

Whether  or  not  the  real  world  facts  conform  with  any  theoretical  model, 
simply  stated,  the  decisional  units  our  industry  planners  work  with  are  not 
easily  flne-tuned.  They  cannot  be  easily  adjusted  without  the  danger  of  substan- 
tial elimination  of  needed  public  service,  and  without  potential  damage  to  the  in- 
tegrated air  transportation  network.  And  the  macro-analysis  frequently  applied 
to  our  industry  does  not  take  into  consideration  the  units  of  capacity  we  must 
deal  with  every  day. 

The  Integrated  Network — Through  Flights  and  Connections 

In  light  of  these  facts,  how  does  the  scheduled  air  transport  industry  provide 
service  for  more  than  57,000  smaller  markets,  and  integrate  those  markets  into 
the  network  including  the  70  major  markets? 

This  achievement  is  the  result  of  two  essential  devices — through  flights  and 
connections. 

Through  flights  constitute  extensions  of  flights  to  provide  service  for  a  smaller 
amount  of  local  traffic  to  extended  points  and  major  markets.  Similarly,  through 
the  connections  offered  by  the  integrated  scheduled  air  transportation  system,  it 
is  possible  to  make  transfers  onto  other  aircraft  in  order  to  reach  any  of  the 
540  aitiiorts  served.  Because  the  number  of  passengers  in  many  of  these  local 


121 

markets  is  far  below  the  level  required  to  supiport  single-plane  service,'  it  is  by 
the  use  of  through  flights  and  connections  that  carriers  are  able  to  provide  the 
present  significant  level  of  single  plane  service  and  transfer  service. 

Coineidentally,  then,  this  process  becomes  the  principal  basis  for  the  airlines' 
ability  to  serve  an  extended  network  of  cities.  Of  course,  it  also  results  in  lower 
industry  load  factors  which  are  brought  down  by  both  through  and  connecting 
flights  from  low  density  cities. 

The  Operation  of  the  Network 

In  a  clear  example  of  this  process,  one  of  the  major  scheduled  airlines  provides 
daily  DC-8  one-stop  through  service  from  Fresno,  California,  via  Denver  to 
Chicago.  At  Denver,  this  flight  is  connected  by  11  other  flights,  from  such  dis- 
parate originations  as:  Pueblo,  Colorado;  Cheyenne,  Wyoming;  Great  Falls, 
Montana  ;  Sacramento  and  San  Jose,  California.  Figure  1  depicts  this  complex 
for  an  average  of  a  peak  and  low  traffic  month.  On  this  eastbound  flight.  27 
passengers  originating  at  Fresno  ultimately  terminate  at  Chicago.  In  addition, 
approximately  42  passengers  board  the  flight  in  Denver  from  11  connecting  flights! 
Out  of  a  total  passenger  load  of  85  from  Denver  to  Chicago,  therefore,  over  three- 
fourths  do  not  originate  in  Denver.  The  majority  of  passengers  on  that  flight  are 
fed  to  it  through  the  highly  integrated  scheduled  system,  a  fabric  woven  over  37 
years  of  regulatory  supervision  of  air  transportation. 

■  "  «^*'x.P°'?,®f $l^i^°"J^  System— Analysis  and  Policy  Recommendations,  Bureau  of  Operat- 
ing Rights,  CAB,  October,  1974,  p.  79. 


122 


Figure   1 


On  the  return  flight,  originating  in  Pittsburgh,  operating  through  Chicago  and 
Denver,  and  terminating  in  Fresno,  the  intricate  fabric  of  through  flights  and 
connections  is  even  more  apparent,  as  shown  on  figure  2 


123 


Figure  2 


Unrestricted  entry  or  exit  would  cause  serious  consequences  to  this  system. 
There  can  be  little  doubt  that  if  one,  two,  three,  or  more  of  these  feeder  con- 
nections, or  the  beyond  segments  on  through  fliglits,  were  eliminated  from  this 
c(mii)lex  the  fabric  itself  would  disintegrate. 

As  is  clear  in  the  cited  examples,  the  profitability  of  the  primary  market,  in 
this  case  Denver-Chicago,  is  dependent  on  the  many  smaller  secondary  markets 
it  serves.  If  oven  a  few  of  the  secondary  markets  ceased  being  served  regularly 
and  dependably,  the  primary  market  may  well  become  less  profitable.  As  a  re.sult, 
it  would  receive  less  service,  and  the  remaining  smaller  feeder  markets  would 
also  receive  less  indirect  service.  The  ultimate  effect,  then,  of  small  market 
adjustments  can  be  extreme. 


124 

Further  dramatic  examples  of  this  principle  are  readily  available,  e.g.,  Albu- 
querque, New  Mexico;  Moline,  Illinois;  Nashville,  Tennessee;  Portland,  Oregon; 
Providence,  Rhode  Island ;  Tiicson,  Arizona,  are  readily  accessible  to  Akron/ 
Canton,  Ohio,  with  a  single  connection  and  never  more  than  a  single  stop. 

Furthermore,  in  1972  this  system  provided  single  plane  service  to  all  markets 
with  over  70  passengers  a  day,  and  to  all  but  three  markets  carrying  more  than 
60  passengers  daily^ — a  direct  result  of  the  combination  effect  of  through  traffic 
between  several  markets  on  a  single  linear  route.^"  Additionally,  in  1972  on  flights 
between  cities  less  than  100  miles  apart,  90  percent  of  all  passengers  transported 
connected  to  other  flights  or  were  carried  as  through  passengers ;  on  flights 
between  cities  600-800  miles  apart,  such  connecting  or  through  passengers  com- 
prised about  two-thirds  of  the  total  ^^  (exhibit  9). 

The  Interdependence  of  the  Network 

The  quality  of  service  to  the  57,000  smaller  relatively  low-demand  markets, 
therefore,  is  directly  dependent  on  the  highly  integrated,  stable  air  transport 
system.  The  system  operates  witliout  significant  changes  in  the  number  of  car- 
riers offering  service,  without  the  instability  which  would  characterize  unre- 
stricted freedom  of  entry  and  exit,  and  with  the  CAB-imposed  requirement  that 
service  continue  to  be  provided  where  warranted  in  the  public  interest.  Lapses  in 
service  resulting  from  carrier  failures,  from  large  scale  withdrawals  of  service, 
or  from  lack  of  a  tie-in  to  ticketing,  baggage  handling,  or  other  benefits  of  the 
present  system,  would  inevitably  disrupt  that  system,  and  would  inevitably  work 
hardship  first  on  those  living  in  smaller  communities  who  rely  on  quality 
scheduled  air  service  to  meet  their  transport  needs.  Moreover,  automobile  gaso- 
line consumption  would  increase  as  people  are  unable  to  use  air  transportation 
and  are  forced  into  the  use  of  ground  transportation.  Further,  it  would  represent 
a  major  cost  to  the  nation  in  time  lost  in  conducting  business  or  time  shortened 
for  personal  or  pleasure  reasons. 

In  January,  1973,  Dr.  Cary  Fromm  of  Data  Resources,  Inc.,  completed  a  study 
for  ATA  on  The  Value  of  Aviation  Activity.  The  study  estimated  cost  and  time 
differentials  in  1970  among  four  modes  of  service  over  the  average  airline  flight 
distance  of  679  miles.  Cost  and  time  estimates  covered  the  entire  trip,  including 
not  only  enroute  but  terminal  and  local  access  costs  and  time  as  well. 

The  DRI  study  also  estimated  the  average  family  income  of  an  air  traveler  in 
1970  to  be  $22,500  a  year.  If  such  a  traveler  valued  his  time  at  an  hourly  rate 
equivalent  to  his  annual  salary  ($10.47  per  hour),  the  following  table  would 
illustrate  the  monetary  value  of  traveling  by  air  versus  alternative  modes :  ^ 


Added  trip  cost 

of  air  versus 

alternative  mode 

Time  saved  in 

traveling  by  air 

(minutes) 

Monetary  sav- 
ings in  traveling 
by  air 

Air/rail.. 

Air/bus 

Air/auto... 

.--- 17 

441 
563 
508 

'1! 

72 

Birmingham,  Alabama,  to  Miami,  Florida,  is  about  the  same  trip  distance 
(661  miles)  as  the  average  distance  used  in  the  DRI  study.  In  1970  there  were 
an  estimated  29,000  passengers  in  this  market  who  started  their  air  trip  in  one 
of  these  cities  and  whose  final  destination  was  the  other  city.^"  The  dollar  value 
of  the  time  savings  in  this  market  alone  would  be  : 

Time  savings 
(in  millions) 

Air/rail      1.9 

Air/bus 2.4 

Air/auto  2.1 


i«Ibld.,  p.  62. 

11  Ibid.,  p.  65. 

^  Fromm,  Gary,  and  Data  Resources,  Inc,  Value  of  Aviation  Activity,  ATA,  January, 
1973.  pp.  9  and  12. 

"  CAB,  Origin-Destination  Survey  of  Airline  Passenger  Traffic,  Domestic,  table  8,  4th 
quarter  1970,  p.  86. 


125 

On  this  basis  elimination  of  air  service  to  thousands  of  smaller  city-pair 
markets  would  cost  the  national  economy  billions  of  dollars.  Substitution  of  less 
time-efficient  aircraft  would  also  cost  the  air  traveler  and  the  national  economy. 
Commuter  aircraft,  for  example,  cannot  fly  as  fast  as  larger  propellor  or  jet  air- 
craft nor  as  far.  Again,  application  of  this  time  loss  impact  to  thousands  of  city 
pairs  would  cost  the  economy  billions  of  dollars. 

Efficient  and  Productive  Operations 

Within  the  framework  of  regulated  competition,  the  scheduled  airlines  have 
produced,  through  operational  efficiency  and  productivity,  the  quality  public 
service  I  have  described. 

The  scheduled  airlines  have  operated  with  a  high  level  of  schedule  reliability. 
In  1974,  98  percent  of  all  miles  scheduled  were  actually  flown,  a  record  especially 
remarkable  in  view  of  the  variety  of  weather  conditions  experienced  and  the 
degree  of  mechanical  stress  placed  on  a  system  involving  13,000  daily  flight  opera- 
tions. A  non-integrated  system,  lacking  regulatory  controls,  could  not  be  expected 
to  approach  this  degree  of  reliability. 

Equally  remarkable,  the  scheduled  airlines  have  conducted  their  operations  in  a 
time  of  high  inflation  with  a  high  degree  of  cost  control — especially  over  those 
costs  which  were  peculiarly  within  the  power  of  airline  management  to  control. 
For  example,  advertising  costs  per  revenue  ton-mile  in  the  third  quarter  of  1974 
were  8  percent  less  than  in  1967,  and  passenger  food  costs  per  passenger  mile  rose 
less  than  5  percent  over  the  past  year.  On  the  other  hand,  since  1967  labor  cost 
per  employee  has  risen  about  92  percent  and  fuel  cost  per  gallon  by  150  percent 
(exhibit  10).  Nevertheless,  in  1974  the  scheduled  airlines  carried  20  percent  more 
passengers  than  in  1969,  accounting  for  30  percent  more  revenue  passenger  miles, 
hut  with  3.5  percent  fewer  employees. 

Clearly,  then,  the  management  record  of  the  scheduled  airlines  is  a  good  one, 
especially  under  conditions  of  great  stress,  and  the  payoff  for  the  public  has  been 
in  low  fare  levels  as  measured  in  comparison  with  other  goods  and  services  pro- 
vided in  the  economy  at  large. 

Finally,  it  is  important  to  note  that  the  speed  and  safety  record  of  the  industry, 
resulting  from  technological  improvements  which  the  airlines  helped  develop, 
has  permitted  the  public  to  travel  quickly  and  safely  across  the  nation.  The 
impact  of  these  developments  on  the  abilities  of  government  and  private  business- 
men to  conduct  their  important  affairs,  and  the  general  public  to  travel  on  per- 
sonal vacation  or  pleasure,  must  be  weighed  in  any  assessment  of  the  effectiveness 
of  regulated  competition. 

Impact  of  Regulatory   Reform 

Public  Policy,  Section  102 

The  scheduled  airlines  lielieve  that  this  review  of  the  regulatory  structure  and 
environment  in  which  air  transportation  operates  can  product  improvements  to 
the  excellent  system  that  exists.  We  shall  suggest,  today  and  in  later  stages  of 
your  deliberations,  some  areas  where  we  believe  adjustments  might  be  considered. 

Nevertheless,  while  any  of  our  carriers  may  be  critical  of  some  aspects  of  the 
specific  application  by  the  CAB  of  its  statutory  authority  pursuant  to  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act  of  1958,  we  believe  that  underlying  public  policy  contained  in  section 
102  of  that  Act  is  sound.  It  is  vital  to  our  nation's  long-term  interest  that  the 
precepts  established  in  section  102  be  reiiiforced,  not  discarded.  For,  as  the  real 
world  results  we  have  described  so  clearly  demonstrate,  those  principles  have 
worked  well  to  serve  the  broadest  public  interest.  In  fact,  if  section  102  did  not 
exist,  it  would  most  certainly  be  needed  now. 

Theory  Versus  Practice — The  Public  Interest 

No  one  can  be  certain  of  the  consequences  of  tampering  with  the  structure — 
least  of  all  those  who  base  their  proposals  on  so-called  "perfect"  econometric  or 
theoretical  models.  Such  models  are  perforce  based  on  assumptions  untested  in 
the  special  marketplace  and  operating  environment  which  controls  air  transpor- 
tation " — and  they  are  developed  fundamentally  wnthout  a  basic  regard  to  all  of 
the  public  interest  considerations  which  must  concern  Congress,  the  CAB,  the 


'*  Assumptions  on  these  models  generally  begin  with  ceterus  paribus,  i.e..  all  other 
things  remaining  equal.  In  the  real  world  all  other  things  do  not  remain  equal  and  the 
change  in  one  factor  must  be  reviewed  in  light  of  changes  in  all  other  factors. 


126 

airlines,  and  the  tliousands  of  U.S.  communities  served  by  scheduled  air  trans- 
portation. 

These  considerations,  broadly  termed  public  service,  are  not  susceptible  to  neat 
econometric  equations  and  tidy  quantification,  but  they  are  nonetheless  real,  and 
frequently  are  determinative  if  a  viable  national  air  transportation  network  is  to 
continue  and  contribute  to  the  national  economic  welfare,  operating  as  it  must 
within  the  matrix  of  conflicting  interests. 

Moreover,  in  meeting  the  critics  on  their  own  ground,  a  word  must  be  said 
with  respect  to  the  consequences  one  might  anticipate  from  wholesale,  so-called 
"free  market"  restructuring  of  the  system. 

Disintegration  of  the  Network 

The  present  system  represents  a  wholly  integrated  network  of  scheduling,  con- 
nections, interlining,  and  routing  among  and  between  carriers  serving  cities  of 
varying  size  and  geographic  proximity  to  each  other.  Despite  this  high  degree 
of  integration,  the  system  is  dynamic — it  is  continually  changing  to  meet  new 
traffic  needs.  A  glance  at  the  Official  Airline  Gride  (which  contains  the  schedules 
for  the  entire  air  transport  network)  provides  dramatic  evidence  of  this  point. 
For  example,  the  OAG  (North  American  edition)  published  on  February  1,  1975, 
is  898  pages  long.  This  massive  volume  depicts  the  schedules  of  every  scheduled 
carrier  in  North  America,  to  and  from  virtually  every  community  served,  with 
connections  indicated.  The  OAG  is  republished  every  two  weeks,  and  incorporates 
the  most  up-to-date  changes  in  schedules,  connections,  and  service  provided 
throughout  the  system,  throughout  the  58,000  U.S.  markets  (and  some  foreign 
markets)  served  by  the  scheduled  airlines. 

It  is  the  continuity  and  complete  integration  of  this  network  which  wOuld  be 
jeopardized  by  drastically  revising  or  dismantling  the  structure  so  carefully 
constructed,  and  continually  improved,  over  the  last  37  years.  And  with  what 
result? 

First,  there  can  be  little  doubt,  at  least  in  the  short  term,  that,  adaptable 
though  they  may  be,  scheduling,  connections,  interline  routings,  ticketing  and 
baggage  handling  would  be  severely  disrupted  by  airline  entry  into  and  exit 
from  markets  on  an  unrestricted  basis.  Customer  service  inevitably  would  be 
most  adversely  affected. 

Even  more  important,  as  some  have  properly  contended,  free  market  forces 
would  result  in  scheduled  airlines'  leaving  many  less  profitable  markets,  and 
concentrating  only  on  certain  of  the  major  routes,  with  the  consequence  that 
medium  and  smaller  size  cities  of  the  Northeast,  Midwest,  South,  and  Far 
West  would  suffer. 

How  would  they  suffer?  First,  their  access  to  major  markets  would  be  re- 
stricted severely.  Certainly  many  entrepreneurs  would  seek  to  serve  some  of  those 
markets.  Such  service  would  be  represented  by  airlines  of  varying  reliability, 
new  and  old,  some  of  erratic  or  marginal  financial  strength,  often  suffering  at  the 
outset  by  the  extraordinary  start-up  costs  required  for  purchase  of  aircraft  and 
establishment  at  airport  facilities. 

The  record  of  the  commuter  carrier  industry,  good  as  it  is  with  respect  to 
reinforcing  the  existing  scheduled  air  transportation  network,  offers  ample  proof 
of  the  foreseeable  circumstances  confronting  many  smaller  operators  seeking  to 
serve  the  many  less  dense  markets  now  served  well  through  the  effects  of  through 
and  connecting  scheduled  air  transportation.  While  much  has  been  said  and 
written  of  the  diseconomies  of  scale  in  air  transportation,  the  diseconomies  of 
small  scale  with  respect  to  stability,  dependability,  and  overall  adequacy  of 
service  are  particularly  hazardous  and  should  be  carefully  examined. 

For  example,  in  1972,  431  U.S.  cities  received  scheduled  pas.senger  commuter 
service.  Of  those  cities  seventy-four  (17  percent)  were  abandoned  in  1973,  and 
service  was  added  to  104  new,  previously  unserved  cities.  Thus,  in  a  single  year, 
178  cities  exi)erienced  a  change  in  scheduled  computer  service — roughly  one-third 
of  all  cities  receiving  such  service.  The  volatile  experience  of  the  largely  unregu- 
lated commuter  system  hardly  gives  one  confidence  that  the  consequences  of  a 
free  market  approach  to  air  transportation  would  represent  an  adequate  substitute 
for  the  benefits  of  the  stability  which  has  characterized  the  national  system 
wisely  devised  by  Congress  and  regulated  by  the  CAB  since  1938  Reliable  service 
to  small  and  medium  cities  especially  is  threatened  by  any  weakening  of  the 
integrated  stucture,  and  a  weakening  of  those  markets  threatens  the  continued 
strength  even  of  many  of  the  larger  markets. 


127 

Further,  the  cost  to  the  smaller  communities  of  operating  their  existing  airport 
facilities  in  the  absence  of  regular  scheduled  service  would  be  high.  Maintaining 
a  reasonably  up-to-date  facilty  for  uncertain  or  sporadic  service  ay  well  prove 
beyond  the  means  of  many  communities.  If  those  communities  were  to  require 
the  carrier  serving  the  community  to  bear  a  high  proi)ortion  of  these  expenses  on 
the  basis  of  irregular  operations,  the  cost  to  that  carrier  may  well  be  prohibitive 
even  for  the  level  of  service  it  is  otherwise  capable  of  jiroviding.  Thus,  the  dis- 
integration of  the  system  may  well  feed  on  itself — resulting  in  even  less  service 
to  many  U.S.  communities  not  closely  proximate  to  the  major  markets. 

The  Public  Cost  of  65%  Load  Factor 

The  relationship  between  load  factors  and  service  requirements  for  the  many 
communities  receiving  scheduled  air  service  is  profound.  Many  critics  of  the  air- 
line industry  have  criticized  the  load  factor  performance.  Yet,  the  55  percent 
load  factor  standard  established  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  taking  into 
account  load  factors  of  30-40  percent  on  some  low  density  routes  and  peaks  of 
80-95  percent  on  some  high  density  routes,  incorporates  an  allowance  for  a  level 
of  service  suitable  for  maintaining  the  expansive  network  of  hundreds  of  smaller 
communities  throughout  the  United  States.  In  order  for  these  commimities  to  be 
served,  average  system- wide  load  factors  cannot  be  high. 

This  result  is  graphically  exemplified  by  the  impact  on  air  transportation  of  the 
current  energy  crisis.  We  have  developed  estimates  of  possible  future  reductions 
in  service  as  measures  of  the  impact  of  the  Administration's  energy  proposals. 
In  order  to  meet  a  65  percent  domestic  system  load  factor  at  prevailing  fare 
levels,  as  suggested  by  some  as  a  solution  to  the  airlines  growing  fuel  cost 
problem,  availal)le  seat  miles  (system  capacity)  would  have  to  be  reduced  25 
percent,  and  hundreds  of  aircraft  grounded,  with  tens  of  thousands  of  employees 
released.  The  effect  of  cutbacks  of  this  magnitude  on  service  to  cities  large  and 
small  would  be  a  severe  penalty  to  public  service  and  to  the  economy  as  a  whole. 

Recommended  Regulatory  Reform  Considerattons 

In  general,  the  airline  industry  believes  that  the  regulatory  environment 
within  which  we  operate  has  served  the  public  interest  well.  We  believe  the 
results  support  that  conclusion. 

However,  in  certain  instances,  airlines  have  opposed  and  continue  to  oppose  the 
manner  in  which  the  regulatory  process  has  been  carried  out.  And  we  believe  that 
certain  areas  of  economic  regulation  of  our  industry  do  require  attention. 
Regulatory  Lag 

By  no  means  restricted  to  the  procedures  adopted  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board,  the  problem  of  regulatory  lag  (delay  in  regulatory  decisionmaking)  is 
endemic  to  the  regulatory  process  throughout  much  of  government.  As  a  conse- 
(luence,  decisions  when  made  may  no  longer  be  timely  or  well-suited  to  the  cir- 
cumstances. Notable  among  the  public  benefits  resulting  from  the  DPFI  has  been 
the  reduction  of  time  between  cost  changes  and  fare  adjustments,  particularly 
early  in  1974  with  respect  to  the  impact  of  the  fuel  crisis  on  airline  costs.  It  seems 
sensible  to  our  industry  that  the  application  to  other  areas  of  regulatory  decision- 
making of  more  efficient  and  streamlined  approaches,  with  full  public 
participation  at  all  stages,  would  result  in  a  more  responsive  regulatory  process. 
Reporting  Requirements 

As  with  respect  to  the  question  of  regulatory  lag,  we  strongly  believe  that  the 
proper  requirement  for  full  and  complete  industry  reporting  of  economic  and 
financial  statistical  data  need  not  result  in  duplicative  and  redundant  effort  on 
the  part  of  the  industry  or  the  regulator.  The  application  of  reasonable  cost  and 
benefit  analysis  of  the  current  reporting  requirements  will  result,  in  our  opinion, 
in  a  streamlining  of  this  effort  and  substantial  cost  savings  to  both  industry 
and  government,  without  in  any  way  impairing  the  public  interest  in  full  and 
complete  data.  In  fact,  through  simplification  and  elimination  of  redundancy, 
much  of  the  complex  data  now  available  could  be  rendered  more  understandable, 
and  therefore  more  useful  to  all  interested  parties  to  the  regulatory  process. 
Continued  Refinement  of  Regulatory  Standards 

The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  notably  in  the  DPFI,  has  established  standards 
for  measurement  of  industry  performance.  While  our  industry  has  generally 


128 

supported  their  adoption,  there  continue  to  be  differences  of  opinion  with  respect 
to  the  application  of  some  of  those  standards.  We  believe  regulatory  standards 
need  not  be  set  in  concrete.  On  the  contrary,  they  should  be  subject  to  continuing 
scrutiny  by  the  Board,  and  amended  when  and  as  required  in  the  public  interest. 
Such  continuing  refinement  would  characterize  a  regulatory  process  truly  respon- 
sive to  the  continuing  changes  in  the  dynamic  American  economy. 

Route  Development  Policy 

The  scheduled  airlines  believe  the  undertaking  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 
of  a  comprehensive  review  of  route  development  policy  is  desirable.  There  may 
be  different  opinions  within  our  industry  on  the  findings,  conclusions,  and  rec- 
ommendations contained  in  the  study  undertaken  by  the  CAB's  Bureau  of  Oper- 
ating Rights,  the  Domestic  Route  System :  Analysis  and  Policy  Recommenda- 
tions.^'^ However,  we  believe  careful  consideration  should  be  given  to  the  view 
contained  in  that  report  that : 

.  .  .  regulatory  route  and  route-related  policies  should  be  directed  to  im- 
proving the  efficiency  and  quality  of  the  system,  through  careful  expansion 
of  route  authority  when  required  by  traffic,  and  through  route  rationali- 
zation.^" 
Because  of  our  obligation  to  provide  the  public  adequate  service,  we  share  the 
Bureau's  statement  that  without  such  policies  : 

...  it  is  possible  that  the  quality  and  eflBciency  of  the  system  will  decline 
over  time  and,  ultimately,  adv'ersely  affect  the  general  economy." 
The  Board,  our  industry,  and  the  public  should  carefully  consider  the  Bureau's 
recommendations  with  respect  to  requirements  in  future  route  proceedings  for 
submission  of  data ;  implementation  of  published  standards  for  route  expansion 
consistent  with  the  Board's  DPFI  goals  and  traffic  requirements ;  and  route 
rationalization.  This  approach  could  represent  a  significant  step  in  dealing  with 
an  aspect  of  air  transport  regulation  deserving  attention. 

Tariffs 

Section  403  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958  provides  for  carrier  filing  of 
full  and  complete  tariffs  with  the  CAB  for  public  inspection. 

The  principle  embodied  in  this  statutory  requirement  is  clear — that  the  public 
interest  is  best  served  by  advance  notice  of  applicable  rates  and  services,  rules, 
regulations,  and  practices  for  air  transportation.  Under  current  procedures, 
achievement  of  this  objective  is  impeded  by  last-minute  approval  or  suspension 
of  tariffs  by  the  Board.  The  scheduled  airlines  have  advocated  a  change  in  these 
procedures,  to  extend  the  filing  deadline  from  30  days  prior  to  implementation 
to  45  days,  with  Board  decision  required  after  30  days,  thereby  providing  15 
days  advance  public  notice  of  tariff  changes.  Further,  in  view  of  the  necessary 
complexity  of  tariff  filings,  we  believe  adoption  of  a  simplified  short-form  tariff 
would  work  to  enhance  public  understanding  of  a  given  tariff  cliange.  The  short- 
form,  of  course,  would  not  replace  the  more  complete  tariff  filing  properly  re- 
quired for  complete  information  purposes.  However,  it  would  serve  to  render 
more  meaningful  to  the  consumer  the  effect  of  any  given  tariff  change. 

In  conclusion,  we  wish  to  reemphasize  our  support  for  the  effort  this  Sub- 
committee has  undertaken,  today  and  in  later  sessions,  to  review  the  effective- 
ness of  federal  regulation  of  the  scheduled  airline  industry.  We  believe  the  public 
benefits  derived  from  regulation  have  been  many  ;  and  we  urge  consideration 
of  the  suggestions  for  improvement  which  we  have  made,  and  will  make  in 
coming  hearings.  Out  of  this  process  and  the  continued  attention  of  Congress 
to  the  needs  of  the  public  for  essential  public  air  transportation  services,  we 
are  confident  the  strength  of  the  national  air  transport  system  is  assured. 

On  behalf  of  the  Air  Transport  Association,  I  wish  to  express  our  gratitude 
for  the  opportunity  to  discuss  with  this  Subcommittee  our  views  on  this  matter 
so  vital  to  our  nation's  economic  welfare. 


1"  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  CAB,  October.  1974. 
i«  Ibid.,  p.  9. 
I'Ibid.,  p.  146. 


129 

Exhibit  1 


AVERAGE  FARE  PER  PASSENGER  MILE 

DOMESTIC  SCHEDULED  SERVICES  --  TRUNK  AIRLINES 

(1938  Constant  Dollars)!/ 


AVERAGE 

REVENUE 

PER 

PASSENGER 

MILE 

6 


] 

\ 

\ 

v^ 

\ 

„        .  .„  Si 

\_l    Deflated  by  Implicit  Deflator  -  GNP,   Adjusted  to  1938  Base. 
2/     1974  Yield  for  First  Nine  Months. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  10 


130 

Exhibit  2 


CHANGES  IN  AIRFARES  COMPARED  WITH 

OTHER  U.S.   PRODUCTS  AND  SERVICES 

(Current  Dollars) 

Per  cent 
change 

Item  1948  1958  1968  1974  1948-1974 

House  $47,409         $59,558  $72,840  $100,000  +110.9% 

Family  Size  Chevrolet  $    1,255         $   2,  OSl  $2,656  $     4,119  +228.2% 

Newspaper 

(The  New  York  Times)  3(p  5<?  10(p  15<p  +     400% 

Ticket  to 

Broadway  Musical  $6.00         $      8.05  $    12.00  $      15.00  +      150% 

Ranch  Mink  Coat  $   4,200         $   4,000  $   4,200  $     4,500  +      7.1% 

Nathan's  Hot  Dog  20(p  25?  35(?  50?  +      150% 

Pair  of  Blue  Jeans  $      3.45         $      3.75  $      5.29  $      11.25  +226.1% 

Gallon  of  Gasoline  25.  9(p  30. 4(;  33.7?  55.6?  +114.8% 

Pair  of  Men's  Shoes  $9.95         $    11.95  $    16.95  $      21.95  +120.6% 

Year's  Tuition  at  Harvard  $        455         $    1,250  $   2,000  $      3,400  +647.3% 

Hospital  Cost 

per  in-patient  day  $    13.09         $   28.17  $   61.38  $    114.90  +777.8% 

Roundtrip  Airfare 

New  York-London  $        630         $453.60  $484.50  $  640  +      1.6% 

Phone  Call,   New  York  to 

Topeka,  Kansas  (day  rate)         $      1.90         $      1.80  $      1.40  $        1.25  -    34.2% 

Pound  of  Round  Steak  90.5?         $      1.04  $      1.14  $        1.81  +100.1% 

Pound  of  Chicken  61.2?  46.5?  39.8?  55.7?  -  9% 

Roundtrip  Airfare 

New  York-San  Francisco  $286.30         $        208  $        290  $   346.30  +   21.0% 


Median  Family  Income 


*  Projected 

Source:    New  York  Times  and  Official  Airline  Guide 


131 

Exhibit  3 


AVERAGE  FARH  PER  PASSENGER  MILE 
INDEX  1938=100 
(Constant  Dollars)-' 


1/    Deflated  by  Implicit  Deflator  -  GNP,   Adjusted  to  1938  Base. 
2/    1974  Data  for  First  Nine  Months. 


132 


Exhibit  4 
AVERAGE  AIR  FREIGHT  RATES  PER  TON  MILE 

DOM'  S lie  OPICRATIONS 
U.  .^^riTT'TJUT.TTi"  AiUi.lNI'S 
(1940  Constant  Dollars)I7 


AVERAGE 
REVENUE 
PER  TON  15 
MILE 


\  I  j  '  ' 


1960 
YEAR 


1/    Deflated  by  Implicit  Deflator  -  GNP,    Adjusted  to  1946  Bas 
2/     1974  Yield  for  First  Nine  Months. 


133 

Exhibit  5 

DISTRIBUTION  OF  TRUNK  AIRLINES  SCHEDULED  COACH  FARES 
YEAR  ENDED  SEPTEMBER  30,    1974 
48  STATE  DATA 


Revenue  Passenger 
Fare  Type  Miles  (OOP,  OOP) 

TOTAL  FULL  FARE 

TOTAL  DISCOUNT 

Youth  Standby 

Youth  Reservation 

Family 

Discover  America 

Military  Standby 

Military  Reservation 

Group 

Child 

Excursion 

Other 
TOTAL  95,820  100.0  6.99 

Source:    Monthly  carriers  submission  to  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 


65 

,  132 

30 

,688 

121 

797 

6, 

,  598 

3, 

,957 

738 

2, 

.555 

1, 

372 

1, 

683 

1, 

18P 

11, 

687 

95, 

820 

Percent  of 
Total 

Yield 
(C  per  RPM) 

68.0 

7.59 

32.0 

5.71 

0.1 

6.12 

0.8 

6.97 

6.9 

6.88 

4.  1 

5.75 

0.8 

3.80 

2.  7 

5.32 

1.4 

5.77 

1.8 

4.76 

1.2 

5.59 

12.2 

5.30 

134 

Exhibit  6 

INCOME  CHARACTERISTICS  OF  ADULTS 
WHO  HAVE  FLOWN  ON  REGULAR  PASSENGER  AIRLINE 


Percent  Within  Each 
Income  Group  Who 
Annual                          Have  Flown  During 
Family  Income  Past  12  Months 


Percent  of  Adults  Making 
One  or  More  Air  Trips 
During  Past  12  Months 
By  Income  Group 


$15,  000  and  over  41 

$10,000  -  $14,  999  22 

$    7,  000  -  $    9,999  16 

Less  than  $7,000  15 


46 


24 


18 


Undesignated 


TOTAL 


100 


Source:    The  Gallup  Organization,   Inc.  ,   The  Incidence  of 
Air  Travel  Among  the  General  Public.    1974 


135 

Exhibit  7 

1974  LOAD  FACTORS 
NON-STOP  SERVICES  --  BOSTON-DETROIT  MARKET 

Load  Factor 

(%) 

January  54 

February  53 

March  58 

April  64 

May  67 

June  67 

July  58 

August  63 

September  59 

October  59 

November  53 

December*  52 

Average  59 

"^    Estimated 

Source:    Company  records  of  carrier. 


136 

Exhibit  8 

DISTRIBUTION  OF  AIRLINE 
PASSENGER  TRAFFIC  BY  NUMBER 
OF  CITY  PAIRS 
(Year  Ended  June,    1974) 

Percent  of  Total  Number  of 

Passenger  Miles  City  Pairs 

10%  7 

20%  30 

30%  70 

40%  145 

50%  272 

60%  494 

70%  908 

1/ 
100%  58,000  (Approx.) 


1/    Includes  markets  partially  served  by  commuter 
airlines  when  a  part  of  a  trip  for  which  a  certifi- 
cated carrier  sells  the  ticket. 

Source:    CAB,   Origin-Destination  Survey  of  Airline 
Passenger  Traffic  -  Domestic^  Second 
Quarter  1974. 


137 

Exhibit  9 

PERCENT  OF  TRANSPORTED  PASSENGERS  WHO  ARE         . 
NOT  THROUGH  OR  CONNECTING,    BY  FLIGHT  DISTANCES-^ 
(For  City  Pairs  with  Non-Stop  Service) 


Mileage 


All  Mileage  43.4 

Less  than  100  miles  9.6 

100  to  199  miles  25.6 

200  to  299  miles  39.0 

300  to  399  miles  44.1 

400  to  499  miles  43.0 

500  to  599  miles  43.8 

600  to  699  miles  51.3 

700  to  799  miles  50.2 

800  to  899  miles  54.1 

900  to  999  miles  60.8 

1,  000  to  1,  499  miles  75.2 

1,  500  to  1,  999  miles  55.8 

2.  000  miles  and  over  92. 1 


1/    Excludes  city  pairs  with  fewer  than  2,  500 

nondirectional  O&D  passengers  (approximately 
6.8  per  day). 

Source:    CAB,   the  Domestic  Route  System;  Analysis 

and  Policy  Recommendations,   October,    1974. 


138 

Exhibit  10 

ATA  AIRLINE  COST  INDEX 
U.S.   TRUNKS  AND  LOCAL  SERVIC^ CARRIERS 
3  Qtr.    1974 


INDEX 
(1967=100) 

LABOR  192.4 

(Employment  Cost 
Per  Employee) 

CAPITAL  153.7 

(Interest  on  Long  Term  Debt) 

FUEL  250.9 

(Cost  Per  Gallon) 

PA  SSE  NGER  FOOD  125.3 

(Cost  Per  Revenue 
Passenger  Mile) 

ADVERTISING  &  PROMOTION  92.  1 

(Cost  Per  Revenue  Ton  Mile) 

LANDING  FEES  229.2 

(Cost  Per  Aircraft  Ton  Landed) 

AIRCRAFT  MAINTENANCE 
MATERIALS  91.8 

(Cost  Per  Available  Ton  Mile) 

TRAFFIC  COMMISSIONS- 
PASSENGER  199.3 
(Cost  Per  Revenue 
Passenger  Mile) 

ALL  OTHER  146.5 

(Implicit  Deflator  -  GNP) 

COMPOSITE  174.5 


Percent 
Change  Over 
3  Qtr.  1973 

7.3 


102.3 


i.5 


(    2.9) 


17. 


10.4 


Percent  of 
Total  Cash 
Operating 
Expensesi.' 

40.7 


3.3 

18.9 

3.6 


2.5 


2.9 


22.2 


100.0 


1/    Total  Operating  Expenses  plus  Interest  on  Long  Term  Debt 
~      Less  Depreciation  and  Amortization. 


139 

ATA    STUDY    ON    DEREGULATION 

[In  a  letter  dated  February  7, 1975  the  chairman  of  the  subcommittee 
made  more  explicit  a  request  of  Dr.  James  for  a  list  of  routes  that  would 
be  eliminated  under  more  competitive  conditions.  On  April  3,  1975 
the  Air  Transport  Association  submitted  to  the  subcommittee  a  reply 
extending  more  than  200  pages.  The  chairman  then  requested  evalua- 
tions of  this  ATA  study  from  the  U.S.  Department  of  Transportation, 
the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers,  the  Council  of  Wage  and  Price 
Stability,  the  General  Accounting  Office,  Prof.  John  W.  Drake,  Purdue 
University,  Prof.  Theodore  E.  Keeler,  University  of  California  at 
Berkeley,  Prof.  Sam  Peltzman,  University  of  Chicago,  Prof.  Roger 
Sherman,  University  of  Virginia,  and  Prof.  Andrew  Whinston, 
Purdue  University.  Their  replies  follow  the  ATA  study  in  that  order, 
p.  379  ff.,  below  except  that  the  replies  of  DOT  and  GAO  are  printed 
at  the  end  of  the  record  of  the  day  of  hearings  of  March  4,  1975,  p. 
2285  ft'.,  below,  because  they  were  received  too  late  for  inclusion  here.] 

U.S.  Senate, 
WasJimffton,  B.C.,  February  7,  1975. 
Mr.  George  W.  James, 
Air  Transport  Association, 
Washington,  B.C. 

Dear  Mr.  James  :  Thank  you  again  for  appearing  before  the  Subcommittee  on 
Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure  last  Thursday.  Your  testimony  and  state- 
ment were  very  lielpful. 

As  I  mentioned  at  the  hearing  I  should  appreciate  receiving  further  detailed 
specific  factual  information  from  you  concerning  the  following  questions  : 

1.  You  expressed  a  fear  that  under  a  more  competitive  system,  airlines  might 
abandon  unprofitable  routes,  severely  curtailing  service  to  many  communities. 
Would  you  please  provide  a  list  for  us  of  those  city-pairs  that  are  now  unprofit- 
able and  might  be  abandoned.  In  preparing  that  list,  you  should  specify  those 
city-pairs  of  which  the  cost  of  serving  exceeds  the  incremental  revenues  generated. 
I  ask  that  you  proceed  on  an  incremental  cost  basis  because  I  believe  that,  in 
competitive  industries,  services  and  products  are  provided  so  long  as  incremental 
revenues  exceed  incremental  costs.  Of  course,  if  you  wish  to  proceed  on  some  other 
accounting  basis,  please  feel  free  to  do  so  (but  I  should  then  appreciate  an 
appropriate  explanation). 

2.  It  may  be  that  the  "feeder"  line  argument  you  made  in  your  testimony 
amounts  to  more  than  a  simple  cross-subsidy  argument.  If  so,  will  you  please 
explain  it  more  fully  and  provide  empirical  support  ? 

3.  It  has  also  been  argued  that  a  competitive  airline  system  (of  the  sort  DOT 
suggested)  would  be  a  less  safe  system.  If  you  hold  this  view,  would  you  please 
provide  documentary  support  for  it? 

We  should  very  much  appreciate  receiving  this  information  before  our  last 
hearing  day  on  March  4.  as  we  shall  then  begin  to  write  our  report. 
Thank  you  very  much. 
Sincerely, 

Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
Chairman,  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure. 


Air  Transport  Association  of  America, 

Washington,  D.C.,  April  25,  J 97 5. 
Hon.  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
U.S.  Senate, 
Washington,  B.C. 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy  :  During  my  testimony  to  your  Subcommittee  on  Ad- 
ministrative Practice  and  Procedure,  and  subsequently  by  letter,  you  requested 
specific  information  on  the  impact  of  deregulation  on  the  present  scheduled  air 
transportation  network.  You  asked  us  to  identify  present  scheduled  routes  where 


140 

service  might  be  reduced  or  eliminated  if  each  airline  could  set  its  own  prices  and 
could  enter  or  exit  any  market  at  will.  Additionally,  you  requested  further  ex- 
planation of  the  "feeder  line"  argument  and  some  comments  on  safety  under 
deregulation. 

The  attached  report  represents  the  results  of  the  analysis  that  ATA  performed 
in  response  to  your  requests,  and  includes  the  application  of  a  computerized 
analysis  of  the  large  interrelated  domestic  trunk  carrier  system.  We  believe  this 
information  may  represent  the  first  aggregate  analysis  of  its  kind.  Results  of 
the  analysis  reveal  the  adverse  impact  on  scheduled  air  service  that  might  take 
place  under  the  assumption  of  total  deregulation  that  we  were  asked  to  make. 

As  we  have  discussed  with  members  of  your  staff,  our  analysis  shows  that 
under  deregulation  scheduled  air  service  might  be  eliminated  or  substantially 
reduced  on  1,820  nonstop  routes  throughout  the  nation.  A  list  of  these  routes  is 
attached.  The  1,267  nonsubsidized  routes  of  the  regional  carriers  were  not  in- 
cluded in  this  study. 

Currently,  trunk  carriers  serve  994  nonstop  routes.  Of  these,  372  could  be 
candidates  for  elimination  under  deregulation,  while  nearly  all  of  the  remaining 
622  could  experience  sharp  curtailment  of  service.  Although  a  similar  analysis 
has  not  been  applied  to  the  regional  carriers,  we  have  identified  S26  of  their  non- 
stop routes  as  currently  receiving  direct  subsidy  under  regulatory  procedures. 

It  is  conceivable  that  the  1,198  unprofitable,  and  subsidized,  routes  might  not 
survive  in  a  deregulated  environment  except  in  limited  instances  as  an  adjunct 
to  more  profitable  routes  or  under  large  subsidy  payments  by  cities  or  the  Federal 
Government. 

Enclosed  are  maps  of  each  of  the  48  contiguous  states  and  the  District  of  Co- 
lumbia with  an  identification  of  each  of  the  routes  that  could  be  jeopardized  as 
well  as  a  tabular  listing  of  these  routes. 

Although  each  of  the  1,198  routes  would  be  a  candidate  for  elimination  under 
deregulation,  it  is  recognized  that  some  might  be  held  for  such  reasons  as  feed- 
ing heavier  travelled  routes  or  aircraft  positioning.  Some  also  might  be  served 
by  smaller  commuter  airlines.  However,  where  such  routes  would  remain,  there 
would  be  a  service  instability  not  present  today  because  carriers  would  view  these 
routes  as  marginal  and  would  probably  move  in  and  out  as  circumstances  dictated. 

Our  analysis  has  also  been  extended  to  determine  the  impact  on  levels  of  serv- 
ice in  a  situation  where  significant  fare  reductions  are  made.  We  have  done  this 
for  the  domestic  trunk  system.  The  findings  show,  for  example,  that  where  fares 
are  reduced  20  percent,  the  unprofitable  routes  rise  from  372  to  564. 

Some  have  contended  that  deregulation  could  occur  while  subsidy  remained. 
In  contrast  with  today's  subsidy  level  of  less  than  $70  million  for  regional  car- 
riers only,  we  estimate  that  subsidy  costs  under  deregulation  could  run  as  high 
as  $1  billion  annually. 

The  analysis  you  requested  has  produced  data  shedding  new  light  on  load 
factors.  The  analysis  shows,  for  example,  that  to  raise  the  average  system  load 
factor  from  55-60  percent,  solely  by  eliminating  the  lowest  load  factor  routes, 
could  require  dropping  as  many  as  144,000  monthly  flights,  or  37  percent  of  all 
flights  flown.  If  eliminating  unprofitable  routes  were  the  only  criteria  for  raising 
load  factors,  the  data  show  that  approximately  20,000  monthly  flights,  or  9  per- 
cent of  the  route  system,  would  need  to  be  abandoned. 

One  final  point  of  interest  in  the  analysis  is  that  33  of  the  largest  100  markets 
of  the  scheduled  carriers  had  load  factors  in  the  60-85  percent  range.  PSA's  load 
factor  on  the  Los  Angeles/San  Francisco  route  during  this  time  period  was  60.9 
percent.  Similarly,  if  interstate  scheduled  carriers  served  only  the  33  interstate 
high  load  factor  routes,  they  could  operate  more  profitably  and  at  lower  fares. 
However,  service  in  the  present  U.S.  58,000  city-pair  network  would  be  shattered. 

We  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  present  relevant  information  regarding  the 
public  service  impact  of  deregulation.  We  had  hoped  that  this  information  will 
be  reflected  in  the  Subcommittee's  report. 
Sincerely, 

George  W.  James, 
Senior  Vice  President-Economics  and  Finance. 

Attachment. 


141 


CONSEQUENCES  OF  DEREGULATION 
OF  THE  SCHEDULED  AIR  TRANSPORT  INDUSTRY 

An  Analytical  Approach 


S 


A  study  in  response  to  questions  posed  by  the 
Chairman,  Senate  Judiciary  Subcommittee 
on  Administrative    Practice  and  Procedure 

conducted  by 
The  Air  Transport   Association  of   America 


APRIL.   1975 


143 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Question  No.    1 


From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman,    regarding 

abandonment  of  unprofitable  routes 1 


Question  No.   2 


From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman,   regarding 

"feeder"  lines  and  cross  subsidy 10 


Question  No.   3 


From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman,   regcirding 

the  effect  of  deregulation  on  safety 12 


Indirect  Cost  Factor  Derivation 
(Including  Designation  of  Marginal  Cost  Elements) 


Exhibit  B 


U.S.   Scheduled  Airline 

1973  Routes  (city-pairs)  Risking 

Loss  of  Service  as  a 

Consequence  of  Deregulation 

(In  Order  from  the  Least  to 

the  Most  Unprofitable) 


City-Pairs  Risking  Loss  of  Service 
By  State 


City-Pairs  Risking  Curtailment  of  Service 
By  State 


144 


CONSEQUENCES  OF  DEREGULATION  -  AN  ANALYTICAL  APPROACH 


Question  No.    1 
From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman 


"You  expressed  a  fear  that  under  a  more  competitive 
system  airlines  might  abandon  unprofitable  routes, 
severely  curtailing  service  to  many  communities. 
Would  you  please  provide  a  list  for  us  of  those  city 
pairs  that  are  now  unprofitable  and  might  be  abandoned. 
In  preparing  that  list,   you  should  specify  those  city 
pairs  of  which  the  cost  of  serving  exceeds  the  incre- 
mental revenues  generated.     1  ask  that  you  proceed  on 
an  incremental  cost  basis  because  1  believe  that,   in 
competitive  industries,   service  and  products  are  pro- 
vided so  long  as  incremental  revenues  exceed  incremental 
costs.     Of  course,    if  you  wish  to  proceed  on  some  other 
accounting  basis,  please  feel  free  to  do  so  (but  I  should 
then  appreciate  an  appropriate  explanation). 


There  are  several  significant  ways  to  examine  incremental  revenue 
and  incremental  cost  on  the  U.  S.  domestic  airline  system,  including: 

1.  Use  of  macro-theoretical  models  of  the  airline  industry; 

2.  Examination  of  past  experience  with  unregulated  airline  markets; 

3.  Employment  of  a  detailed  analytical  framework  that  simulates 
each  element  of  the  actual  airline  system. 

The  first  approach  (use  of  macro-theoretical  models),  though  perhaps 
intellectually  elegant,   has  the  disadvantage  that  it  cannot  be  validated  -- 
conclusions  cannot  be  tested  against  reality.     Policy  recommendations  based 
on  this  approach  are  extremely  risky,  because  results  of  an  altered  air  trans- 
port system  could  easily  be  quite  different  from  those  predicted  by  the  model 
builders,   and  costs  to  rectify  unforeseen  consequences  could  be  enormous. 

The  second  approach  (examination  of  past  experience)  is  limited  by 
the  paucity  of  such  experience:    the  pre- 1938  era  in  the  United  States,   or  the 
pre- 1965  era  of  intra- California  air  transport.     While  the  chaos  experienced 
in  both  periods  represents  a  useful  point  of  comparison  with  the  current 
stable  regulated  environment  nationally  and  in  California,   in  many  respects 
both  periods  are  incomplete  for  current  analogy. 


145 


The  third  approach,    involving  a  detailed  route-by-route  examination 
of  the  existing  system,   has  been  chosen  as  the  best  way  to  meet  the  short- 
comings of  the  other  two  approaches.     ATA,   utilizing  an  existing  computer 
simulation*,   has  analyzed  the  entire  domestic  trunk  industry  for  the  48 
contiguous  states  for  1973.     Broad  conclusions  of  the  study  show  that,   of 
the  994  trunk  non-stop  routes,    622  were  profitable  and  372  (or  37%)  were 
unprofitable.     The  372  unprofitable  routes  are  prime  candidates  for  aban- 
donment under  deregulation,   recognizing  that  some  of  them  might  be  retained 
for  such  purposes  as  providing  feeder  service  and  positioning  of  aircraft. 
Some  also  might  be  served  by  smaller  commuter  airlines. 

In  contrast.   United  Airlines,    in  a  letter  to  the  Chairman  of  the  Senate 
Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure,   pointed  out  the 
results  of  a  similar  analysis  on  its  route  system  showing  50%  of  its  non-stop 
routes  were  unprofitable. 


Airline  System  Simulation 

A  computer  program  known  as  the  Airline  System  Simulation,  which 
was  developed  by  and  is  the  property  of  the  Lockheed  Aircraft  Corporation, 
was  used  in  producing  a  substantial  portion  of  the  results  of  this  report. 

The  Airline  System  Simulation  is  the  result  of  extensive  research  in 
concepts  and  methods,   many  discussions  with  airline  representatives,   and 
participation  by  one  major  trunk  airline.     It  has  been  used  in  studies  for  air- 
lines,  the  United  States  Government,   and  Lockheed.     These  studies  have 
included  investigations  of  the  compositions  of  fleets,  the  assignment  of  flights, 
the  economics  of  the  supersonic  transport  (SST),   and  the  design  of  the  L-1011. 

The  simulation  has  been  in  continuous  use  since  1961.  It  is  important 
to  note  that  no  changes  were  made  in  the  Lockheed  model  in  order  to  perform 
the  simulation  of  this  study. 

The  srnulation  is  a  comprehensive  program  that  gives  explicit 
consideration  to  such  concepts  as  mixed  aircraft  types  on  a  route,   route 
interaction,   and  generation  and  allocation  of  demand,   all  of  which  are  ex- 
plained in  detaL  in  the  attached  booklet  on  the  Lockheed  Simulation  Model. 

Figure  1  is  a  summary  of  the  concepts  used  in  the  model. 


*  The  Lockheed  Airline  System  Simulation,   booklet  attached. 


51-146   O  -  76 


146 


MAXIMUM  EARNINGS 

•  COMPETITION 

•  REGULATION 


FLISHT  ASSIGNMENT  & 
FLEET  COMPOSITION 


AIRLINE  SYSTEM  SIMULATION  -  SUMMARY 


Data  Used  and  Comparative  Results 

Virtually  all  of  the  48  state  scheduled  domestic  trunk  passenger 
airline  system  for  the  calendar  year  1973  was  used  in  this  study.     994  non- 
stop route  segments  were  included  in  the  simulation.     Where  both  trunk  and 
regional  airlines  serve  the  same  segment,   their  traffic  is  included  in  the 
segment  total. 

The  following  types  of  aircraft  were  used  in  the  study  as  representa- 
tive of  the  actual  fleet  mix  in  1973: 


B-747 

L-lOll/DC-10 

DC-8-61 

B-707-300B/DC-8 

B-727-200 

DC-9-30/B-737 

DC-9-10 


147 


Since  all  passenger  aircraft  carry  significant  amounts  of  cargo, 
this  source  of  revenue  and  cost  was  included  in  the  study.     CAB  Form  41 
data  were  converted  to  an  average  amount  of  cargo  per  passenger.     These 
data  ranged  from  42  pounds  per  passenger  in  the  B-747  to  27  pounds  per 
passenger  in  the  DC-9-10.     The  overall  domestic  cargo  yield  for  U.S. 
trunk  carriers  in  1973  of  25.6  cents  per  ton  mile  was  used.     All-cargo 
aircraft  are  not  included  in  the  study. 

This  simulated  representation  captured  97.8  per  cent  of  the  revenue 
passenger  miles  as  reported  in  Form  41  to  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  (CAB). 
The  remaining  RPM's  were  contained  in  seasonal  markets  (those  served  less 
than  ten  months  per  year)  and  flight  diversions  due  to  weather  or  equipment 
problems. 

As  additional  points  of  comparison,   a  yield  of  6.  37  cents  per  :-evenue 
passenger  mile  was  achieved  from  the  simulation.     This  compares  favorably 
with  the  CAB  Form  41  figure  of  6.  38  cents.     The  average  flight  segment 
length  produced  by  the  simulation  was  580  statute  miles.     The  CAB  Form  41 
data  reports  577. 


Methodology  Employed 

The  Lockheed  Airline  System  Simulation  operates  through  a  sequential 
process  of  adding  flights  to  the  system  by  following  much  the  same  logical  pro- 
cess employed  by  airline  planning  staffs  in  developing  their  schedule  plans. 
Development  of  a  schedule  plan  begins  with  the  initial  assumption  of  no  flight 
operations  and  no  aircraft,   but  with  a  set  of  possible  routes  on  which  to  use 
the  aircraft.     The  economic  impact  of  each  possible  aircraft/route  combina- 
tion is  examined  in  sequence  as  shown  in  Figure  2.     Initially,   determination 
is  made  of  the  individual  increments  of  passenger  operating  revenue  and 
operating  costs  which  would  result  from  adding  a  flight  to  each  possible  route- 
with  each  possible  aircraft  type.     The  flight  addition  that  would  produce  the 
greatest  difference  between  the  increment  of  revenue  and  increment  of  cost 
is  then  added  to  the  system.     This  process  is  iterated  each  time  through  the 
994  route  segments  before  a  flight  is  added. 

The  costs  used  in  the  flight  selection  process  consist  of  only  those 
costs  directly  affected  by  the  addition  of  a  single  flight  (Figure  3  and  Exhibit  A). 
However,   the  total  costs  of  operating  at  any  given  scale  of  operation  consist 
of  the  marginal  costs  plus  those  other  costs  that  are  affected  only  by  an  over- 
all scale  of  operations,    i.e..   system  costs.  *    Therefore,   after  each  flight 
addition  is  made  on  the  basis  of  marginal  costs,  total  operating  costs  are 
adjusted  to  include  the  additional  system  costs. 


*  In  the  context  used  here  marginal  and  system  costs  equal  fully 
allocated  or  total  costs. 


148 


OLUtt 


149 


^ 

,'*« 


150 


FIGURE  3 

MARGINAL  COSTS 

Flight  Crew  Cabin  Attendant  Salary 
Fuel  and  Oil  and  Related  Expense 

Direct  Maintenance  Other  Passenger  Services 

Insurance  Aircraft  Handling 

Depreciation  Aircraft  Control 

Local  Expense  Landing  Fees 

Labor  -  Ground  Prop.   &  Equip.  Passenger  Handling 

Labor  -  Other  Services  Baggage  Handling 

Maintenance  Materials  Passenger  Commissions 
Food  and  Beverages 


The  selection  and  updating  process  is  continued  until  no  flight,   either 
in  the  form  of  an  added  frequency  on  a  route  already  selected  for  service  or 
a  first  flight  on  a  route  as  yet  unserved,   can  be  added  to  the  system  and  pro- 
duce an  increment  of  revenue  greater  than  the  required  increment  of  marginal 
cost.     Thus,   at  this  point,   the  system  consists  only  of  those  services  that  will 
produce  a  maximum  operating  profit. 

An  examination  of  the  composition  of  the  system  as  it  would  exist  at 
maximum  operating  profit  requires  several  important  observations: 

1.  No  airline  presently  operates  at  or  near  this  point; 

2.  Load  factors  at  this  point  would  be  about  80%.     Therefore,   large 
numbers  of  people  desiring  service  during  peak  periods  of  the 
day,   week,   and  season  would  be  unable  to  travel  by  air; 

3.  Many  routes  that  are  now  being  served  would  receive  no  service; 

4.  Many  other  routes  would  receive  less  frequent  service  than 
currently  provided. 


Results  of  ATA  Study 

Application  of  the  Model. 

The  simulation  model  produces  an  ordered  list  of  non-stop  routes 
served,   starting  with  the  most  profitable  route/aircraft  combination,   and 
adding  flights  until  all  profitable  flights  are  listed  in  decreasing  order  of 
profitability.     The  simulation  then  continues  to  list  unprofitable  flights, 
starting  with  the  least  unprofitable  and  proceeding  to  the  most  unprofitable. 


151 


From  this  listing,   it  is  possible  to  construct  a  graph  of  system 
earnings  versus  number  of  flights  (Figure  4),   depicting  the  earnings  per 
day  for  each  level  of  service.     Figure  4  shows  that,   as  more  and  more  un- 
profitable flights  are  added  to  the  system,   daily  earnings  and  load  factors 
decrease. 

Figures  5A,    5B,    5C,   and  5D  depict  the  U.S.   trunk  48-state  system, 
divided  into  four  subsystems  employed  in  the  simulation,   and  Figure  6  repre- 
sents the  372  currently  served  non-stop  trunk  routes  identified  by  the  simulation 
as  unprofitable  and  consequently  risking  loss  of  service  in  the  event  of  deregu- 
lation.    These  372  unprofitable  routes  are  tabulated  in  Exhibit  B.     Figure  7 
sets  forth  the  826  subsidized  regional  carrier  markets  that  would  also  risk 
loss  of  service  in  a  deregulated  environment. 

Thus,   in  the  event  of  deregulation,   routes  appearing  in  Figures  6  and 
7  can  be  considered  as  prime  candidates  for  abandonment.     Not  included  are 
other  unprofitable  markets  currently  served  by  regional  carriers  and  not 
eligible  for  subsidy. 

Exhibit  C  presents  the  unprofitable  and  subsidized  routes  on  a  state- 
by-state  basis. 

Exhibit  D  lists  all  profitable  routes  in  the  trunk  system,  showing  the 
reduced  level  of  service  that  might  be  experienced  with  a  maximum  earnings 
objective. 

Effect  of  Fare  Reductions 


In  addition  to  consideration  of  the  system  under  1973  fare  levels,  the 
analysis  was  extended  to  explore  conditions  where  these  levels  were  reduced 
10  and  20%. 

Results  of  running  those  two  hypothetical  cases  are  shown  in  Figi. 


The  upper  curve  is  identical  to  Figure  4,    indicating  the  results  of  1973  opera- 
tion at  1973  yields.     Other  curves  show  the  results  which  could  have  been 
expected  in  1973  if  fares  had  been  reduced  10%  and  20%,   respectively. 

Figure  9  demonstrates  these  results  in  tabular  form  --as  fares 
decrease,   the  maximum  earnings  and  number  of  profitable  flights  are  lower. 
Further,    if  fares  were  reduced  10%,   there  would  be  an  increase  in  the  number 
of  unprofitable  routes  from  372  to  471.     In  the  case  of  20%  fare  reduction,   un- 
profitable routes  rise  from  372  to  564. 


152 


XI 

"1 

hI 

H 
O 

^ 
P 
^ 

J 

M 

\M 

w 

z 

m 

A 

■^ 

K 

O 

< 

<s 

j5 

Yy 

Z 

Ui 

<; 

X 

w 

H 

^ 

ro 

w 

H 

U) 

>H 

H 

'< 

H 

CO 

•* 

"I 

f 

g 

fe 

^^ 

J. 

^ 

^ 

-J 

, 

'^7 

^ 



if 

^ 

^ 

..^ 

c^ 


suonniM  $ 


153 


154 


155 


J   s 


a: 


(0 
UJ 

>     S 
!     O 

i     ui 

'     I- 

< 

0) 


?  -r 


'  .  "f^/; 


■•',  -.'//I 


^''' 


r^K^r;  j/ 


I       1  -  °l  "5 


J   K    "J.        J 


i  :!'="    I 


>  4        ^  *  ^:  ;"  ^  i' 


156 


!^     I" 

lU        (A 

1  g 


D 
I        1 


3  J 


,    <,■ 


157 


-,.""'''»  ,;•)?' 


4    5 


UJ  UJ 

UJ  (£ 


S5io  I 

-I  OC  t^    o) 
U.  )-  o>    <1> 


V;3-\f^T>V^ 


5^'^^- 


i  s° 

i     a.  lu 


;■  '>.-. 


/ 


/i^^^  * 


^■i*«.sS«Hs^Jvi,'. 


158 


O  I   . 


Z  c 

UJ  (U 

^"  - 

Ui  T-  CO 

tn  ^ 

H  «> 

X 

O 


[I 


< 
o 
o 


^-> 


/>  ;.    ■■■•  ■■*-,  f''^\< 


Hi 


^'.>  ^ 


1  rV-^ 


7- 

\S" 

J     ^ 

%•  -i;^;.  - 

■      A 

t   .' 


'i^.\,- 


I    f,  J 


/?     ?  iJi 


159 


t^ 

2: 

c: 

H 

<" 

^- 

^ 

<« 

UJ 

fil 

C 

?', 

tf 

■D 

<; 

(S 

w 

2 

Lj 

K 

m 

H 

> 

4) 

J 

U> 

W 

fa 

r" 

<; 

S 

"  i 


suonniAi  $ 


160 


FIGURE  9 

SOME  EFFECTS  OF  REDUCED  FARES 

Maximum 

Number  of 

Number  of 

Daily 

Profitable 

Unprofitable 

Yields 

Earnings 
(Millions) 

Flights 

Non-Stop  Routes 

1973  Yields 

$5.5 

2.500 

372 

10%  Reduct 

:ion 

4.3 

2.170 

471 

2  0%  Reduction 

3.1 

1,978 

564 

In  making  these  simulation  runs,   it  was  assumed  that  elasticity  of 
demand  was  -1.2.     This  figure  is  the  assumption  for  discount  fares  only 
adopted  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  in  its  computation  of  the  adjusted 
return  on  investment.     The  CAB  elasticity  factor  for  all  fares,   however,    was 
-0.  7.     For  purposes  of  this  analysis  only,   to  test  the  hypothesis  that  a  dis- 
proportionate increase  in  demand  would  still  reduce  service,    it  is  assumed 
that  a  10%  decrease  in  fares  would  result  in  a  13%  increase  in  demand,   and 
a  20%  decrease  would  result  in  a  31%  increase  in  demand.  * 

The  results  of  examining  the  system  at  10%  and  20%  yield  reduction 
show  that  lowering  of  fares,    for  example,   by  new  competitors  free  of  regula- 
tory restraint,   would  increasingly  result  in  economic  pressures  to  abandon 
unprofitable  routes.     Further,   the  number  of  candidates  for  discontinuation 
of  service  increases  as  fares  decrease. 

Load  Factors 

It  should  be  emphasized  that  the  ATA  study  demonstrates  that  achieve- 
ment of  high  load  factors  is  not  necessarily  consistent  with  a  high  level  of 
service  to  communities  across  the  nation.     For  example,  two  ways  of  achieving 
higher  system  load  factors  would  be  to  remove  service  to  those  communities 
with  the  lowest  load  factors  and/or  abandon  unprofitable  routes. 

•        Abandonment  of  lowest  load  factor  flights.     In  order  to  determine  the 
impact  of  this  method  of  raising  system  load  factors  from  55%  to  60%, 
ATA  arrayed  all  flights  for  August,    1973,   from  lowest  to  highest  load 
factors,   using  segment  data  (ER-586)  for  trunk  and  local  service  air- 
lines.    Figure  10  is  a  summary  of  these  data. 

System  load  factor  for  that  month  was  55,  7%.     In  order  to  raise  the 
system  load  factor  to  60%,    it  would  have  been  necessary  to  eliminate 
144.000  flights  during  the  month,  or  37%  of  all  flights  (Figure  11). 


This  uses  the  CAB  calculation  of  elasticity  impact. 


161 


o  o 

o  d 
o  o 


li 


-1  in  o  c^ 


E  -5^ 


o  r>  -.  in  -H  . 


of  o 
en  J 


o  ro  c-  00  Tj. 


to   00   -<   m 


Oinoinoinoino 


S"  o 

00  J 


__^mcno5cno5mi^(ncnaio)030)03OTcncnaio> 

°  S  g  S  S  S'  2  S  S"  S  S  ?  S  5?  S  S  w  ^  "^  ■*' 


162 


ANALYSIS  OF  FLIGHT/SEGMENT  LOAD  FACTORS 

U.S.   Certificated  Airlines 

48  State  Services 

August,    1973 


Number  of  Flights  Requiring  Elimination  From  Lowest  Load 
Factors  to  Raise  System  Average  From  55.  7%  to: 


Number 

Percent 

Highest 

of 

of  All 

Load  Factor 

Flights 

Flights 

Remaining 

60% 

144.000 

37.0 

49.3% 

65% 

226.000 

58.1 

56.0% 

70% 

296.000 

76.1 

62.2% 

75% 

340.000 

87.3 

6  7.5% 

80% 

365.000 

93.7 

7  3.2% 

Notes:     (1)    Average  load  factor  for  the  segment  is  used  for 
each  flight  flown  on  that  segment. 

(2)    Segments  with  less  than  four  services  per  month 
not  included. 


163 


The  remaining  system  would  exclude  flights  for  which  the  average 
monthly  load  factor  was  49.3%  or  less.     To  raise  the  system  load 
factor  to  65%.   a  total  of  226,000  flights  (or  58.  1%  of  all  flights) 
would  have  had  to  be  eliminated.     At  65%  load  factor,   flights  with 
average  monthly  load  factor  of  56%  or  lower  would  be  eliminated. 

These  data  do  not  take  into  account  the  fact  that  some  of  the  traffic 
on  discontinued  flights  would  be  diverted  to  other  flights.     Some 
segments,   however,   would  lose  all  service. 

An  illustration  of  a  typical  monthly  distribution  of  load  factors  is 
shown  in  Figure  12,   using  the  August,    1973  data. 

•        Abandonment  of  the  most  unprofitable  flights.     Use  of  the  Lockheed 
Airline  System  Simulation  makes  it  possible  to  determine  the  impact 
of  raising  load  factors  by  eliminating  the  most  unprofitable  flights. 
If  trunk  airlines  were  to  pursue  this  policy  alternative,   approximately 
20,000  monthly  flights,   or  9%  of  total  trunk  service,   would  be  aban- 
doned in  order  to  raise  load  factors  to  60%.     41,  000  monthly  flights 
would  be  eliminated  to  reach  a  65%  load  factor. 

A  significant  consideration  with  respect  to  the  impact  of  high  average 
load  factors  on  public  service  is  the  problem  of  unserved  demand.     Experience 
with  airline  reservations  systems  makes  it  clear  that  some  passengers  cannot 
obtain  confirmed  reservations  on  flights  that  finally  depart  with  80%  load 
factors.     This  phenomenon  results  from  the  practice  of  passengers  booking 
reservations  and  failing  to  cancel  if  the  reservations  are  not  used.     In  this 
case  other  passengers  will  have  been  turned  down  because  the  flight  appeared 
to  be  fully  booked.     During  peak  vacation  periods,   this  situation  is  particularly 
acute. 

Previous  analysis  has  shown  that  increasing  average  load  factors  would 
result  in  curtailment  of  service.     But  average  load  factors  do  not  fully  account 
for  the  extent  to  which  the  public  is  inconvenienced.     Examination  of  actual 
monthly  flight  load  factor  data,    in  a  special  ATA  study,    shows  that,    even  with 
average  route  load  factors'  as  low  as  40%,   many  individual  flights  on  these 
routes  carry  load  factors  in  the  70  to  90%  range.     This  means  that,   at  certain 
times  of  the  day  and  on  certain  days  of  the  week,   hundreds  of  passengers  are 
turned  away  on  flights  of  their  choice  even  though,   on  the  average  for  the 
month,   60%  of  the  seats  in  the  system  are  empty.     Demand  is  highly  peaked 
by  hour  of  the  day,   by  day  of  the  week,   by  season,   and  by  direction. 

These  findings  demonstrate  that  passengers  must  forego  travel  or 
change  their  plans  to  travel  at  less  convenient  times  even  when  load  factors 
are  at  a  system  average  of  55%. 


164 


5 

r 

o 

(, 

<! 

<!" 

T) 

> 

i^ 

1- 

Q 

n 

w 

< 

;rt 

<u 

n 

'r! 

nl 

J 

C^ 

H 

C) 

00 

?^ 

^ 

W 

CD 

p 

(000) 
s;m3iU  jo  JaquinN 


165 


Conclusions 

Currently  U.S.   scheduled  trunk  and  regional  carriers  serve  3,087 
non-stop  routes  which  link  58,000  city  pairs  throughout  the  U.S.    Of  these, 
1.  158  (or  37.5%)  are  unprofitable  and  risk  abandonment  under  deregulation. 
Nearly  all  of  the  remaining  1,929  routes  might  well  experience  significant 
reduction  in  service. 

Where  certain  of  the  unprofitable  or  subsidized  routes  might  be  held 
for  such  purposes  as  providing  feeder  traffic,   aircraft  positioning,   or  market 
growth,   or  might  be  served  by  smaller  commuter  airlines,   these  routes  could 
be  subject  to  instability  not  present  today,   since  carriers  would  be  competing 
for  them  as  marginal  routes  and  would  move  in  and  out  as  current  circum- 
stances dictated. 

Attempting  to  subsidize  these  routes,  to  try  to  maintain  today's  level 
of  service,   could  require  as  much  as  a  billion  dollars. 

Further,  raising  average  system  load  factors  has  a  public  service 
penalty  attached  to  it.  Most  particularly,  this  occurs  with  an  increase  in 
denied  service  during  certain  daily,   weekly,   and  monthly  peak  periods. 

Accordingly,   as  this  study  demonstrates,   under  a  deregulated  system 
the  level  of  service  available  to  the  public  could  be  markedly  reduced. 


166 


Question  No.   2 
From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman 


"it  may  be  that  the  'feeder'  line  argument  you 
made  in  your  testimony  amounts  to  more  than 
a  simple  cross  subsidy  argument.     If  so,   will 
you  please  explain  it  more  fully  and  provide 
empirical  support? 


As  the  question  implies,  the  concept  of  cross  subsidization*  appears 
simple  at  first  glance.     In  practice  it  is  complex,   and  the  variety  of  attitudes, 
beliefs,   and  opinions  on  the  subject  reflected  in  the  testimony  before  the 
Subcommittee  amply  demonstrate  that  complexity. 

The  single  essential  point  that  must  be  understood  is  that  a  form  of 
cross  subsidy  begins  when  a  system  exists  with  only  one  non-stop  route. 
Costs  of  operating  a  route  vary  by  time  of  day,   season  of  the  year,   weather 
conditions,   and  by  many  other  factors.     Thus,  to  completely  eliminate  the 
effect  of  cross  subsidization  is  not  possible  on  one  non-stop  route  in  each 
system,   let  alone  on  an  entire  system. 

The  efficient  deployment  of  aircraft  and  other  airline  resources 
across  the  national  air  transportation  network  requires  their  use  on  a  com- 
bination of  non-stop,   multi- segment,   and  connecting  routes  where  the  optimum 
application  of  resources  is  normally  not  possible.     For  example,   an  aircraft 
can  seldom  be  operated  on  the  optimum  distance  for  which  it  was  designed. 
When  it  is,   however,   per  mile  costs  are  less  than  on  its  other  routes,   and 
a  form  of  cross  subsidy  occurs. 

As  ATA  reported  in  its  February  6  testimony  before  the  Subcommittee, 
the  national  air  transportation  system  is  comprised  of  many  connecting  and 
through  flights,   constituting  a  network  of  service  throughout  the  58,  000  city 
pairs  served  by  scheduled  airlines.     These  connecting  and  one-stop  and  multi- 
stop  flights  exist  in  part  because  segments  (connecting  or  through)  that  may 
be  individually  unprofitable  can  be  combined  to  make  a  total  profitable  flight. 
Consider  three  cities  --  A,   B,   and  C  --  and  suppose  that  traffic  between 
each  of  the  three  pairs  (AB,   BC,   AC)  is  too  light  to  justify  even  a  single 
daily  flight.     If,   however,   one  flight  is  operated  from  A  to  B  to  C.   the  seg- 
ment from  A  to  B  may  still  be  unprofitable  but  the  segment  from  B  to  C, 
bolstered  by  traffic  from  A  destined  for  C,   may  now  be  profitable  enough  to 
make  the  flight  as  a  whole  profitable.     In  such  a  situation,   it  could  be  said 
that  passengers  destined  from  B  to  C  subsidize  passengers  destined  from 
A  to  B.     But  what  about  passengers  destined  from  A  to  C?    They  are 
"recipients"  on  one  segment  (A  to  B)  and  "donors"  on  the  other  (B  to  C). 


Sometimes  viewed  as  "internal  subsidization 


167 


Availability  of  a  high  degree  of  scheduled  frequency  to  communities, 
large,   medium,   and  small  in  terms  of  population  across  the  nation,   is  un- 
paralleled in  the  world.     The  operation  of  this  network,   however,   requires 
a  high  percentage  of  multi-stop  and  connecting  flights.     Approximately  70% 
of  scheduled  carrier  operations  involves  multi-stop  flights. 

Every  passenger  or  shipper  using  the  comprehensive,   integrated 
system  receives  a  clear  economic  benefit  flowing  from  that  system  --  the 
ability  of  anyone  to  get  almost  anywhere  in  the  country  on  a  regularly 
scheduled  basis,   on  business,   on  personal  emergency,   or  for  any  other 
reason. 

The  effect  of  cross  subsidy,  therefore,  is  to  render  operable  an 
essentially  self-supporting,  comprehensive,  integrated  national  air  trans- 
portation system.  Without  it,  that  system  would  disintegrate.  If  the  many 
smaller  or  medium  sized  communities  now  receiving  service  through  con- 
necting or  through  flight  feeder  operations  are  to  receive  adequate  service, 
absent  the  present  self-supporting  system  self-financed  by  cross  subsidy, 
large  direct  subsidies  would  be  required  in  order  to  provide  service  at  the 
levels  now  available. 


168 


Question  No.    3 
From  the  Subcommittee  Chairman 


"it  has  been  argued  that  a  competitive  airline 
system  (of  the  sort  DOT  suggested)  would  be  a 
less  safe  system.     If  you  hold  this  view,   would 
you  please  provide  documentary  support  for  it? 


The  impact  of  deregulation  on  safety  is  not  susceptible  to  ready 
measurement  and  one  cannot  predict  with  certainty  what  that  impact  might 
be. 

In  light  of  the  consequences  of  the  operation  of  a  less  stable  air 
transport  industry  resulting  from  deregulation  and  related  shifts  in  service 
patterns,   one  must  presume  that  the  Federal  Aviation  Administration  would 
continue  to  take  all  actions  necessary  in  the  public  interest  to  assure  the 
highest  possible  level  of  safety  for  all  operations  within  its  statutory 
jurisdiction. 


EXHIBIT  A 

INDIRECT  COST  FACTOR  DERIVATION 
(INCLUDING  DESIGNATION  OF  MARGINAL  COST  ELEMENTS) 


170 


Hi 

: 

: 

: 

' 

: 

z 

: 

: 

: 

s 

ill 

III 

il 

II: 

5 

s 
1 

1 
1 

J 
i 

1 
1 

1 
I 

1 
1 
1 

1 

I 

i 
1 
1 

i 
% 

ill 

ill 

1! 

II 

iii 

° 

s 

1 

1 

8 

1 

1 

1 

iii 

0 

'Hi 

i 

i 

1 

g 

*: 

s 

S 

S 

§ 
»" 

? 

i: 

s 
S 
a 

1 

iiti- 

£ 

ii.f. 

II; 

1 

1 

H 

m 

■.Ml. 

ip 

ft 

i 
<i 

1 

a" 
<i 

1 

2 

i  3 1 

d= 

thi 

mi 

w 

i 

ii. 

ir 

:    i 

m 

1 

3 

i 

I 
l 

!i- 

iirii 

! 

< 

$' 

liii 

r 

til  - 

lis  = 

d 

1 

ll= 

ipfli 

j 

3< 

1 

1 S 

1 

d 

5 

if- 

!iN 

i 

<<] 

i 

2 

-  3 

"5j 

1 

1  1 

n 

it 

1 

if! 

III 

hi 

M 
nil 

s 

A 
fi 

I 

I 

1 

i 
1 

1 

■■I 

ill 

Ii 

It 

ii 

1 

1 
1 

ll 

Ii 
1! 

Eli 

I 

III 


ill  Pi 


ife: 


.6  5    & 


.fin 


171 


EXHIBIT  B 


U.  S.  SCHEDULED  AIRLINE 
1973  ROUTES  (CITY-PAIRS)  RISKING 

LOSS  OF  SERVICE  AS  A 

CONSEQUENCE  OF  DEREGULATION 

(IN  ORDER  FROM  THE  LEAST  TO 

THE  MOST  UNPROFITABLE) 


172 


Page  1 


1. 

ATL-CAE 

2. 

MCO-MIA 

3, 

JAN- MS  Y 

4. 

PBI-TPA 

5. 

DSM-STL 

6. 

ABE-CLE 

7. 

GFK-MSP 

8. 

PHF-WAS 

9. 

CHS-JAX 

10. 

CMH-PIT 

11. 

BAL-NYC 

12. 

BOI-SLC 

13. 

DAL-IAH 

14. 

JAX-TPA 

15. 

ABE- WAS 

16. 

ATL-TYS 

17. 

DAL- SAT 

18. 

BNA-TYS 

19. 

CLE-CVG 

20. 

DTW-MKE 

21. 

CRW-CVG 

22. 

CRW-PIT 

23. 

LEX-TYS 

24. 

ATL-AVL 

25. 

EVV-STL 

26. 

CHS-CLT 

27. 

MCI-STL 

28. 

PHX-SAN 

29. 

CMH-DTW 

30. 

ALB-NYC 

31. 

LIT-MEM 

32. 

ORD-STL 

33. 

IND-STL 

34. 

DTW-IND 

35. 

DSM-MSP 

36. 

MCO-PBI 

37. 

CLE-SBN 

38. 

ORE- WAS 

39. 

DTW-ORD 

40. 

EVV-IND 

Tex. 


Tex. 


Atlanta,  Ga. 

Orlando,    Fla. 

Jackson/Vicksburg,   Miss, 

West  Palm  Beach,    Fla. 

Des  Moines,   Iowa 

Allentown,    Pa. 

Grand  Forks.   N.  D. 

Newport  News,    Va. 

Charleston.   S.  C. 

Columbus,   Ohio 

Baltimore,   Md. 

Boise,   Id. 

Dallas/ Ft.    Worth, 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

Allentown.    Pa. 

Atlanta.  Ga. 

Dallas/ Ft.    Worth. 

Nashville,   Tenn. 

Cleveland,  Ohio 

Detroit,   Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

Charleston,   W.  Va. 

Charleston,   W.  Va. 

Lexington,  Ky, 

Atlanta,   Ga. 

Evansville,   Ind. 

Charleston.   S.C. 

Kansas  City.   Mo. 

Phoenix.   Ariz. 

Columbus.   Ohio 

Albany.   N.Y. 

Little  Rock,   Ark. 

Chicago,   111.    (O'Hare) 

Indianapolis,    Ind. 

Detroit,   Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

Des  Moines,   Iowa 

Orlando,    Fla. 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

Norfolk.   Va. 

Detroit,    Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

Evansville,   Ind. 


Columbia,   S.C. 

Miami.   Fla. 

New  Orleans.    La. 

Tampa,    Fla. 

St.    Louis,   Mo. 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

Minneapolis/St.    Paul.    Minn. 

Washington.   D.C. 

Jacksonville.    Fla. 

Pittsburgh.    Pa. 

New  York,   N.Y. 

Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

Houston,   Tex. 

Tampa,    Fla. 

Washington,   D.C. 

Knoxville,   Tenn. 

San  Antonio,   Tex. 

Knoxville,   Tenn. 

Cincinnati.   Ohio 

Milwaukee.   Wis. 

Cincinnati.  Ohio 

Pittsburgh.   Pa. 

Knoxville.   Tenn. 

Asheville,   N.C. 

St.   Louis,   Mo. 

Charlotte,  N.C. 

St.   Louis,   Mo. 

San  Diego,   Calif. 

Detroit,    Mich,    (Metropolitan) 

New  York,   N.Y. 

Memphis.   Tenn. 

St.    Louis.   Mo. 

St.    Louis,    Mo. 

Indianapolis.    Ind. 

Minneapolis/St.    Paul.   Minn, 

West  Palm  Beach.    Fla. 

South  Bend.   Ind. 

Washington.   D.C. 

Chicago,    111.   (O'Hare) 

Indianapolis,   Ind. 


173 


Page 


41. 

DAL-TUL 

42. 

CLE-IND 

43. 

BUF-SYR 

44. 

AGS-ATL 

45. 

CVG-ORD 

46. 

NYC-PVD 

47. 

IND-ORD 

48. 

ATL-MGM 

49. 

DAY-ORD 

50. 

GEG-GTF 

51. 

NYC-ORH 

52. 

BOI-GEG 

53. 

MCI-TUL 

54. 

MCI-SGF 

55. 

CLE-GRR 

56. 

IND-SDF 

57. 

PHL-WAS 

58. 

ATL-GSP 

59. 

lAH-SAT 

60. 

FSM-LIT 

61. 

JAN-MLU 

62. 

MIA-MLB 

63. 

MBS-ORD 

64. 

JAX-TLH 

65, 

CVG-SDF 

66. 

CLT-RDU 

67. 

DAY-DTW 

68. 

CID-ORD 

69. 

MOB-MSY 

70. 

ATL-BHM 

71. 

SBA-SFO 

72. 

RDU-RIC 

73. 

CLE-FWA 

74. 

BNA-SDF 

75. 

MLI-OMA 

76. 

DAL-OKC 

77. 

BAL-RDU 

78. 

ELP-TUS 

79. 

JAX-MCO 

80. 

A  US -DAL 

Dallas/ Ft.    Worth.   Tex. 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

Buffalo,   N.Y. 

Augusta,   Ga. 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

New  York,   N.Y. 

Indianapolis,    Ind. 

Atlanta,   Ga. 

Dayton,   Ohio 

Spokane,   Wash. 

New  York,   N.Y. 

Boise,    Id. 

Kansas  City,    Mo. 

Kansas  City,   Mo. 

Cleveland,  Ohio 

Indianapolis,    Ind. 

Philadelphia,    Pa. 

Atlanta,   Ga. 

Houston,   Tex. 

Ft.   Smith,   Ark. 

Jackson/ Vicksburg,    Miss. 

Miami.    Fla. 

Saginaw,    Mich. 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

Cincinnati,   Ohio 

Charlotte,   N.C. 

Dayton,   Ohio 

Cedar  Rapids /Iowa  City,   la. 

Mobile,   Ala. 

Atlanta,   Ga. 

Santa  Barbara,   Calif. 

Raleigh/ Durham,   N.C. 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

Nashville,   Tenn. 

Moline,    HI. 

Dallas/ Ft.    Worth.   Tex. 

Baltimore,    Md. 

El  Paso.   Texas 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

Austin,   Tex. 


Tulsa,  Okla. 
Indianapolis,    Ind. 
Syracuse,   N.Y. 
Atlanta,   Ga. 
Chicago,   111.    (O'Hare) 
Providence,   R.I. 
Chicago,    111.    (O'Hare) 
Montgomery,   Ala. 
Chicago,    111.    (O'Hare) 
Great  Falls.   Mont. 
Worcester,   Mass. 
Spokane,    Wash. 
Tulsa,  Okla. 
Springfield,    Mo. 
Grand  Rapids,    Mich. 
Louisville,   Ky. 
Washington,   D.C. 
Greenville/Spartanburg,   S.C. 
San  Antonio,   Tex. 
Little  Rock.   Ark. 
Monroe,    La. 
Melbourne,    Fla. 
Chicago,   111.    (O'Hare) 
Tallahassee,   Fla. 
Louisville,   Ky. 
Raleigh/ Durham,   N.C. 
Detroit,    Mich.    (Metropolitan) 
Chicago,    111.    (O'Hare) 
New  Orleans,    La. 
Birmingham,   Ala. 
San  Francisco,   Calif. 
Richmond,    Va. 
Ft.    Wayne,    Ind. 
Louisville,  Ky. 
Omaha,   Neb. 
Oklahoma  City,   Okla. 
Raleigh/Durham,   N.C. 
Tucson,   Ariz. 
Orlando,    Fla. 
Dallas /Ft.  Worth,   Tex. 


174 


Page  3 


81. 

ICT-MCI 

Wichita.   Kan. 

Kansas  City.    Mo. 

82. 

ORD-TOL 

Chicago.   Ul.    (O'Hare) 

Toledo.   Ohio 

83. 

FLL-MCO 

Ft.    Lauderdale,    Fla. 

Orlando,    Fla. 

84. 

CLE-PIT 

Cleveland.   Ohio 

Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

85. 

ESF-SHV 

Alexandria.   La. 

Shreveport,    La. 

86. 

FNT-ORD 

Flint.    Mich. 

Chicago,   111.    (O'Hare) 

87. 

BAL-BDL 

Baltimore.   Md. 

Hartford.   Conn. 

88. 

CLE- DAY 

Cleveland.   Ohio 

Dayton.  Ohio 

80. 

MCI-OMA 

Kansas  City.    Mo. 

Omaha,   Neb. 

90. 

LAS-SAN 

Las  Vegas.   Nev. 

San  Diego.   Calif. 

91. 

PFN-PNS 

Panama  City,    Fla. 

Pensacola.    Fla. 

92. 

CRP-DEN 

Casper,   Wyo. 

Denver.   Colo. 

93. 

PHX-PSP 

Phoenix,   Ariz. 

Palm  Springs.   Calif. 

94. 

JAX-SAV 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

Savannah,   Ga. 

95. 

RIC-WAS 

Richmond,    Va. 

Washington,    D.  C. 

96. 

DAL-MLU 

Dallas/ Ft.   Worth,   Tex. 

Monroe,    La. 

97. 

CRP-IAH 

Corpus  Christi,   Tex. 

Houston,   Tex. 

98. 

FSM-TUL 

Ft.   Smith,    Ark. 

Tulsa,  Okla. 

99. 

PIT-ROA 

Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

Roanoke,   Va. 

100. 

CAE-CHS 

Columbia,   S.  C. 

Charleston.   S.C. 

101. 

CMH-TOL 

Columbus,   Ohio 

Toledo.  Ohio 

102. 

MLI-ORD 

Moline.    m. 

Chicago.    111.    (O'Hare) 

103. 

BOS-PWM 

Boston,    Mass. 

Portland.    Maine 

104. 

FMY-MIA 

Fort  Myers,    Fla. 

Miami.    Fla. 

105. 

DSM-MCI 

Des  Moines,   Iowa 

Kansas  City,   Mo. 

106. 

LAS- LAX 

Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

Los  Angeles,    Calif. 

107. 

AUS-IAH 

Austin,   Tex. 

Houston,    Tex. 

108. 

DAB-JAX 

Daytona  Beach,    Fla. 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

109. 

FAT -LAX 

Fresno,   Calif. 

Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

110. 

MLU-SHV 

Monroe,    La, 

Shreveport,    La. 

111. 

CMH-IND 

Columbus,   Ohio 

Indianapolis,    Ind. 

112. 

LAN-ORD 

Lansing,    Mich. 

Chicago,    ni.    (O'Hare) 

113. 

MLB-TPA 

Melbourne.    F.'a. 

Tampa,    Fla. 

114. 

FMY-TPA 

Fort  Myers.    Fla. 

Tampa,    Fla. 

115. 

BNA-STL 

Nashville.   Tenn. 

St.    Louis,   Mo. 

116. 

CLE-MBS 

Cleveland.   Ohio 

Saginaw,   Mich. 

117. 

EVV-SDF 

Evansville.   Ind. 

Louisville,  Ky. 

118. 

EEN-NYC 

Keene.   N.  H. 

New  York,  N.Y. 

119. 

ATL-CHA 

Atlanta.   Ga, 

Chattanooga,   Tenn. 

120. 

BDL-NYC 

Hartford.   Conn. 

New  York,    N.Y. 

175 


Page  4 


121. 

BOS-BTV 

Boston.    Mass. 

122. 

ICT-OKC 

Wichita,   Kan. 

123. 

BFL-SFO 

Bakersfield.   Calif. 

124. 

MEM- PAH 

Memphis,    Tenn. 

125. 

AMA-ICT 

Amarillo.   Tex. 

126. 

DAL-ICT 

Dallas /Ft.    Worth,   Tex. 

127. 

G EG- SEA 

Spokane,   Wash. 

128. 

LIT-SGF 

Little  Rock.   Ark. 

129. 

ABQ-ELP 

Albuquerque,    N. M. 

130. 

FAR-MSP 

Fargo,   N.D. 

131. 

FWA-ORD 

Ft.    Wayne,    Ind. 

132. 

FSD-MSP 

Sioux  Falls,    S.  D. 

133. 

DEN-GJT 

Denver,    Colo. 

134. 

MSN-MSP 

Madison,    Wis. 

135, 

CLE-LAN 

Cleveland.   Ohio 

136. 

GSO-RIC 

Greensboro/High  Point, 

N.C, 

137. 

ICT-TUL 

Wichita.  Kan. 

138. 

BAL-PHF 

Baltimore.   Md. 

139. 

CLE-FNT 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

140. 

BAL-ORF 

Baltimore,   Md. 

141. 

BPT-SHV 

Beaumont/ Port  Arthur, 

Tex. 

142. 

GRR-ORD 

Grand  Rapids.    Mich. 

143. 

AVL-CRW 

Asheville.   N.C. 

144. 

OKC-TUL 

Oklahoma  City.   Okla. 

145. 

ABQ-AMA 

Albuquerque.   N. M. 

146. 

CLE-CMH 

Cleveland,   Ohio 

147. 

ROC-SYR 

Rochester.   N.Y. 

148. 

FAT-SFO 

Fresno.   Calif. 

149. 

RNO-SFO 

Reno.  Nev. 

150. 

CHA-TYS 

Chattanooga.   Tenn. 

151. 

BTR-SHV 

Baton  Rouge.    La. 

152. 

LBB-MAF 

Lubbock.   Tex. 

153. 

FSD-PIR 

Sioux  Falls,    S.  D. 

154. 

BTR-ESF 

Baton  Rouge,    La. 

155. 

ELP-MAF 

El  Paso,    Tex. 

156. 

GEG-MSO 

Spokane,    Wash. 

157. 

BHM-PNS 

Birmingham,   Ala. 

158. 

DAY-IND 

Dayton,   Ohio 

159. 

BGR-PWM 

Bangor,   Me. 

160. 

FSM-SHV 

Ft.   Smith.   Ark. 

Burlington,   Vt. 
Oklahoma  City,   Okla. 
San  Francisco,   Calif. 
Paducah,   Ky. 
Wichita,   Kan. 
Wichita,   Kan. 
Seattle,    Wash. 
Springfield,    Mo. 
El  Paso,   Tex. 

Minneapolis/St.   Paul.    Minn. 
Chicago,    111.    (O'Hare) 
Minneapolis/St.    Paul,    Minn. 
Grand  Junction,    Colo. 
Minneapolis /St.    Paul,    Minn. 
Lansing,    Mich. 
Richmond.    Va. 
Tulsa.  Okla. 
Newport  News,    Va. 
Flint,    Mich. 
Norfolk,   Va. 
Shreveport,    La. 
Chicago,   III.    (O'Hare) 
Charleston,    W.  Va. 
Tulsa.   Okla. 
Amarillo,   Tex. 
Columbus,   Ohio 
Syracuse.   N.  Y. 
San  Francisco.   Calif. 
San  Francisco,   Calif. 
Knoxville.   Tenn. 
Shreveport.    La. 
Midland/Odessa.   Tex. 
Pierre.   S.D. 
Alexandria.    La. 
Midland/Odessa,   Tex. 
Missoula.   Mont. 
Pensacola,    Fla. 
Indianapolis,   Ind. 
Portland,   Me. 
Shreveport,    La. 


176 


Page  5 


161. 

CLE-DTW 

Cleveland.  Ohio 

162. 

CVG-MSP 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

163. 

CLT-GSP 

Charlotte.  N.C. 

164. 

BIL-GTF 

Billings,   Mont. 

165. 

CAK-YNG 

Akron/ Canton.   Ohio 

166. 

ATL-MCN 

Atlanta,  Ga, 

167. 

CVG-IND 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

168. 

CMH-CVG 

Columbus,   Ohio 

169. 

CHA-CVG 

Chattanooga,   Tenn. 

170. 

MCO-TPA 

Orlando.    Fla. 

171. 

PFN-TLH 

Panama  City,    Fla. 

172. 

AGS-CLT 

Augusta,   Ga. 

173. 

BTR-MSY 

Baton  Rouge,   La. 

174. 

MKG-ORD 

Muskegon,   Mich. 

175. 

PDT-PDX 

Pendleton.   Ore. 

176. 

BOI-PDT 

Boise.  Id. 

177. 

PIH-SLC 

Pocatello.   Id. 

178. 

ATL-CSG 

Atlanta.  Ga. 

179. 

CLE-TOL 

Cleveland.  Ohio 

180. 

FWA-IND 

Ft.   Wayne.   Ind. 

181. 

CLT-GSO 

Charlotte.   N.C. 

182. 

AVP-WAS 

Wilkes- Barre/Scranton.    Pa, 

183. 

AMA-LBB 

AmarUlo.   Texas 

184. 

PBI-TLH 

West  Palm  Beach.   Fla. 

185. 

IDA-SLC 

Idaho  Falls,   Id. 

186. 

CHS-SAV 

Charleston,   S.  C. 

187. 

CRP-RAP 

Casper,   Wyo. 

188. 

CVG-LEX 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

189. 

CLE-CRW 

Cleveland,  Ohio 

190. 

CAK-PIT 

Akron/ Canton.  Ohio 

191. 

JMS-MSP 

Jamestown,  N.  D. 

192. 

CAE-CLT 

Columbia,   S.  C. 

193. 

BIL-BZN 

Billings.   Mont 

194. 

DSM-OMA 

Des  Moines,   Iowa 

195. 

PDX-SEA 

Portland,  Ore. 

196. 

BAL-PHL 

Baltimore,   Md. 

197. 

LEX-SDF 

Lexington,  Ky. 

198. 

BDL-BOS 

Hartford,   Conn. 

199. 

BIL-CRP 

Billings,    Mont. 

200. 

NYC-PHL 

New  York.   N.Y. 

Detroit,   Mich.   (Metropolitan) 
Minneapolis /St.    Paul,   Minn. 
Greenville/Spartanburg.   S.C. 
Great  Falls.  Mont. 
Youngstown.   Ohio 
Macon.   Ga. 
Indianapolis.  Ind. 
Cincinnati,  Ohio 
Cincinnati,  Ohio 
Tampa,   Fla. 
Tallahassee,    Fla. 
Charlotte,   N.C. 
New  Orleans.   La. 
Chicago.   Ul.    (O'Hare) 
Portland.  Ore. 
Pendleton,   Ore. 
Salt  Lake  City.   Utah 
Columbus,   Ga. 
Toledo,   Ohio 
Indianapolis,   Ind. 
Greensboro/High  Point,   N.C. 
Washington,   D.  C. 
Lubbock,   Texas 
Tallahassee,   Fla. 
Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 
Savannah,  Ga. 
Rapid  City,   S.D. 
Lexington,   Ky. 
Charleston,   W.  Va. 
Pittsburgh,   Pa. 
Minneapolis /St.   Paul,   Minn. 
Charlotte,   N.C. 
Bozeman,   Mont. 
Omaha,  Neb. 
Seattle,   Wash. 
Philadelphia,   Pa. 
Louisville,  Ky. 
Boston,   Mass. 
Casper,   Wyo. 
Philadelphia,   Pa. 


177 


Page  6 


201. 

BIL-HLN 

Billings.   Mont. 

202. 

BTM-IDA 

Butte.   Mont. 

203. 

GSO-ROA 

Greensboro/High  Point,   N.C. 

204. 

MIA-PBI 

Miami,    Fla. 

205. 

FIR-RAP 

Pierre.   S.  D. 

206. 

MOB-PNS 

Mobile.   Ala. 

207, 

PHX-TUS 

Phoenix,   Ariz. 

208. 

MSN-ORD 

Madison,    Wis. 

209. 

BFL-LAX 

Bakersfield.   Calif. 

210. 

CID-OMA 

Cedar  Rapids/Iowa  City.    la. 

211. 

FLL-PBI 

Ft.    Lauderdale.    Fla. 

212. 

DTW/FWA 

Detroit,   Mich.   (Metropolitan) 

213, 

BDL-PVD 

Hartford.   Conn. 

214. 

GSO-RDU 

Greensboro/High  Point,   N.C. 

215. 

MSN-RST 

Madison.   Wis. 

216. 

FMY-SRQ 

Fort  Myers.    Fla. 

217, 

AGS-CAE 

Augusta.   Ga. 

218, 

PSP-TUS 

Palm  Springs,   Calif. 

219. 

CSG-MGM 

Columbus.   Ga. 

220. 

LAX-SBA 

Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

221. 

CYS-DEN 

Cheyenne.    Wyo. 

222. 

ELP-SFO 

El  Paso.   Tex. 

223. 

BIS-FAR 

Bismarck.   N.  D. 

224. 

SAN-SFO 

San  Diego.    Calif. 

225. 

EUG-PDX 

Eugene.  Ore. 

226, 

DAB- T  PA 

Daytona  Beach,    Fla. 

227. 

LAX- SAN 

Los  Angeles,    Calif. 

228. 

ORD-SBN 

Chicago,   111. 

229. 

LAX-PSP 

Los  Angeles.    Calif. 

230. 

PDX-STL 

Portland,  Ore. 

231. 

AVL-RDU 

Asheville.   N.C, 

232. 

RNO-SMF 

Reno.  Nev, 

233. 

EUG-MFR 

Eugene,  Ore. 

234. 

DAY- LAX 

Dayton.  Ohio 

235. 

CHA-LEX 

Chattanooga,   Tenn. 

236. 

CRP-CYS 

Casper,   Wyo. 

237. 

CID-DSM 

Cedar  Rapids/Iowa  City.   la. 

238. 

LAX-VIS 

Los  Angeles,   Calif, 

239. 

COS-OKC 

Colorado  Springs.   Colo. 

240. 

JAN-MEI 

Jackson/Vicksburg.   Miss. 

Helena.    Mont. 
Idaho  Falls.    Id. 
Roanoke.    Va. 
West  Palm  Beach,   Fla. 
Rapid  City.   S.  D. 
Pensacola,    Fla. 
Tucson.   Ariz. 
Chicago,   111.    (O'Hare) 
Los  Angeles,   Calif. 
Omaha,   Neb. 
West  Palm  Beach,   Fla. 
Ft.    Wayne,   Ind, 
Providence,    R.I. 
Raleigh/ Durham,   N.C. 
Rochester,   Minn. 
Sarasota.    Fla. 
Columbia,   S.C. 
Tucson,   Ariz. 
Montgomery,   Ala. 
Santa  Barbara,   Calif. 
Denver,   Colo. 
San  Francisco,   Calif. 
Fargo,   N.D. 
San  Francisco.   Calif. 
Portland.   Ore. 
Tampa,    Fla, 
San  Diego.   Calif, 
South  Bend,    Ind. 
Palm  Springs.    Calif. 
St.   Louis.   Mo. 
Raleigh/ Durham,  N.C. 
Sacramento.   Calif. 
Medford.   Ore. 
Los  Angeles.    Calif. 
Lexington,   Ky. 
Cheyenne,   Wyo. 
Des  Moines.    la, 
Visalia,   Calif. 
Oklahoma  City.   Okla. 
Meridian.   Miss. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


178 


Page  7 


241. 

SHV-TUL 

Shreveport,   La. 

242. 

BHM-BNA 

Birmingham,   Ala. 

243. 

HLN-MSO 

Helena.   Mont. 

244. 

EVV-PAH 

EvansvUle.   Ind. 

245. 

CVG-LAX 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

246. 

PIT-YNG 

Pittsburgh.   Pa. 

247. 

BUF-ROC 

Buffalo.   N.Y. 

248. 

CID-MLI 

Cedar  Rapids/Iowa  City,   la. 

249. 

BAL-LAS 

Baltimore.   Md. 

250. 

CMH-DAY 

Columbus,  Ohio 

251. 

BTM-SLC 

Butte.    Mont. 

252. 

MKE-MSN 

MUwaukee.  Wis. 

253. 

MRY-SFO 

Monterey.    Calif. 

254. 

LAW-OKC 

Lawton,   Okla. 

255. 

MSP- EST 

Minneapolis/St.    Paul,   Minn. 

256. 

BTM-GEG 

Butte,   Mont. 

257. 

AVL-TYS 

Asheville.   N.  C. 

258. 

NYC-TUL 

New  York,   N.Y. 

259. 

SFO-SMF 

San  Francisco,   Calif. 

260. 

AGS-SAV 

Augusta,   Ga. 

261. 

SEA- WAS 

Seattle,   Wash. 

262. 

SAN-TUS 

San  Diego,   Calif. 

263. 

FWA-SBN 

Ft.    Wayne,   Ind. 

264. 

LBB-SPS 

Lubbock,   Tex. 

265. 

BAL-WAS 

Baltimore.   Md. 

266. 

COS-DEN 

Colorado  Springs.   Colo. 

267. 

MCI-OKC 

Kansas  City.   Mo. 

268. 

SCK-SFO 

Stockton.   Calif. 

269. 

SRQ-TPA 

Sarasota.   Fla. 

270. 

DSM-MLI 

Des  Moines.   Iowa 

271. 

AUS-ELP 

Austin.   Tex. 

272. 

BIL-FAR 

Billings.   Mont. 

273. 

MKE-SFO 

Milwaukee.   Wis. 

274. 

MCI-TUS 

Kansas  City.   Mo. 

2  75. 

MKE-ORD 

Milwaukee.   Wis. 

276. 

DTW-MSY 

Detroit.   Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

277. 

CAK-NYC 

Akron/ Canton.  Ohio 

278. 

BTM-BZN 

Butte.   Mont. 

279. 

CLT-DTW 

Charlotte.  N.  C. 

280. 

FWA-NYC 

Ft.   Wayne.   Ind. 

Tulsa,  Okla. 

Nashville.  Tenn. 

Missoula.   Mont. 

Paducah.  Ky. 

Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

Youngstown.  Ohio 

Rochester,  N.Y. 

Moline,   111. 

Las  Vegas.  Nev. 

Dayton,  Ohio 

Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

Madison,    Wis. 

San  Francisco,   Calif. 

Oklahoma  City,  Okla. 

Rochester,   Minn. 

Spokane,   Wash. 

Knoxville,    Tenn. 

Tulsa,  Okla. 

Sacramento.   Calif. 

Savannah.   Ga. 

Washington.   D.  C. 

Tucson,   Ariz. 

South  Bend,   Ind. 

Wichita  Falls,   Tex. 

Washington,   D.  C. 

Denver,   Colo. 

Oklahoma  City,  Okla. 

San  Francisco,   Calif. 

Tampa,   Fla. 

Moline,   111. 

El  Paso,   Tex. 

Fargo,   N.D. 

San  Francisco,   Calif. 

Tucson,   Ariz. 

Chicago,    ni.    (O'Hare) 

New  Orleans.    La. 

New  York,   N.Y. 

Bozeman,   Mont. 

Detroit,   Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

New  York.   N.Y. 


179 


Page 


281. 

FAR-GFK 

Fargo,   N.D. 

282. 

OMA-PDX 

Omaha.   Neb. 

283. 

ORF-PHF 

Norfolk.   Va. 

284. 

NYC-OMA 

New  York.   N.  Y. 

285. 

FLL-MIA 

Ft.   Lauderdale.    Fla. 

286. 

FNT-MBS 

Flint.   Mich. 

287. 

IND-LEX 

Indianapolis.   Ind. 

288. 

CHA-CMH 

Chattanooga.   Term. 

289. 

AUS-SAT 

Austin.   Tex. 

290. 

CLT-DAB 

Charlotte.   N.  C. 

291, 

CHA-SDF 

Chattanooga.   Tenn. 

292. 

IDA-PIH 

Idaho  Falls.   Id. 

293. 

ABE-AVP 

Allentown.    Pa. 

294, 

LAS-TPA 

Las  Vegas.  Nev. 

295. 

LNK-OMA 

Lincoln.   Neb, 

296. 

CLT-RIC 

Charlotte.   N,  C. 

297. 

HSV-BNA 

HuntsvUle/Decatur,   Ala. 

298. 

lAH-MCI 

Houston.   Tex. 

299, 

BPT-IAH 

Beaumont /Port  Arthur.    Tex. 

300. 

BFL-SBA 

Bakersfield.   Calif. 

301. 

CRP-SHR 

Casper.   Wyo. 

302. 

DTW-TOL 

Detroit.   Mich.    (Metropolitan) 

303. 

DAB-MCO 

Daytona  Beach.    Fla, 

304. 

BFL-FAT 

Bakersfield.   Calif. 

305, 

MSP-SAN 

Minneapolis/ St,    Paul,   Minn. 

306, 

BAL-BUF 

Baltimore,   Md. 

307. 

BIS-JMS 

Bismarck.   N.D, 

308. 

EKO-RNO 

Elko,   Nev. 

309. 

DAY-SDF 

Dayton.   Ohio 

310. 

MSY-OKC 

New  Orleans.    La. 

311. 

CVG-TOL 

Cincinnati.  Ohio 

312. 

BHM-MLU 

Birmingham.   Ala, 

313. 

ILG-WAS 

Wilmington,   Del, 

314. 

DAY-PHL 

Dayton,   Ohio 

315. 

BTM-HLN 

Butte.   Mont, 

316, 

BTM-GTF 

Butte.   Mont. 

317, 

MCE-VIS 

Merced,   Calif. 

318, 

MHT-ORH 

Manchester,   N.  H.  . 

319, 

JAX-MLB 

Jacksonville.    Fla. 

320, 

BAL-SEA 

Baltimore.   Md. 

Grand  Forks.   N.D, 
Portland.  Ore. 
Newport  News.   Va. 
Omaha.   Neb. 
Miami.    Fla. 
Saginaw.   Mich. 
Lexington.    Ky. 
Columbus,   Ohio 
San  Antonio.   Tex. 
Daytona  Beach,    Fla. 
Louisville,   Ky. 
Pocatello.    Id. 
Wilkes- Barre/Scranton. 
Tampa.    Fla, 
Omaha.  Neb. 
Richmond,    Va. 
Nashville,   Tenn. 
Kansas  City.   Mo, 
Houston.    Tex. 
Santa  Barbara,   Calif. 
Sheridan,   Wyo. 
Toledo.  Ohio 
Orlando.    Fla. 
Fresno.   Calif. 
San  Diego,   Calif. 
Buffalo,   N.  Y, 
Jamestown,   N.  D. 
Reno,   Nev. 
Louisville,   Ky. 
Oklahoma  City.  Okla. 
Toledo.   Ohio 
Monroe,   La. 
Washington,   D,  C, 
Philadelphia,    Pa. 
Helena,    Mont. 
Great  Falls,   Mont. 
Visalia,   Calif. 
Worcester,    Mass. 
Melbourne.   Fla. 
Seattle.   Wash, 


180 


Page  9 


321. 

BOS-IAH 

Boston.   Mass. 

322. 

CLT-JAX 

Charlotte,   N.C. 

323. 

EVV-MEM 

Evansville.   Ind. 

324. 

JAX-SRQ 

Jacksonville,    Fla. 

325. 

BTV-PWM 

Burlington,    Vt. 

326. 

GRR-MBS 

Grand  Rapids,    Mich. 

327. 

CVG-DAY 

Cincinnati,  Ohio 

328. 

MHT-PWM 

Manchester,   N.H. 

329. 

MOD-SCK 

Modesto,   Calif. 

330. 

BOS-PVD 

Boston,   Mass. 

331. 

BAL-ROC 

Baltimore,   Md. 

332. 

CMH-TYS 

Columbus,   Ohio 

333. 

ELP-IAH 

El  Paso,   Tex. 

334. 

BHM-TYS 

Birmingham,   Ala. 

335. 

MCE-MOD 

Merced,   Calif. 

336. 

EVV-LEX 

Evansville,   Ind. 

337. 

CHA-IND 

Chattanooga,   Tenn. 

338. 

MIA-SRQ 

Miami,    Fla. 

339. 

NEA-MCN 

Brunswick,   Ga. 

340. 

RDU-WAS 

Raleigh/ Durham,   N.C. 

341. 

CAK-CLE 

Akron/ Canton,  Ohio 

342. 

BHM-BTR 

Birmingham,   Ala. 

343. 

GNV-TLX 

Gainesville,   Fla. 

344. 

FNT-LAN 

Flint,    Mich. 

345. 

LAW-SPS 

Lawton,  Okla. 

346. 

GTF-HLN 

Great  Falls,   Mont. 

347. 

CID-LNK 

Cedar  Rapids/Iowa  City, 

la. 

348. 

FMY-MCO 

Fort  Myers,    Fla. 

349. 

PDX-SLE 

Portland,   Ore. 

350. 

BAL-HVN 

Baltimore,   Md. 

351. 

MKE-RST 

Milwaukee,   Wis. 

352. 

FWA-TOL 

Ft.   Wayne,   Ind. 

353. 

LEB-NYC 

Lebanon,   N.H. 

354. 

DAY-TOL 

Dayton,   Ohio 

355. 

MCO-MLB 

Orlando.    Fla. 

356. 

EKO-ELY 

Elko,  Nev. 

357. 

BOS-MHT 

Boston,    Mass. 

358. 

ELY-SLC 

Ely,   Nev. 

359. 

NEA-SAV 

Brunswick,   Ga. 

360. 

EWB-NYC 

New  Bedford,    Mass. 

Houston,   Texas 
Jacksonville.    Fla. 
Memphis.   Tenn. 
Sarasota,    Fla. 
Portland,   Me. 
Saginaw,    Mich. 
Dayton,   Ohio 
Portland,    Me. 
Stockton,   Calif. 
Providence,   R.I. 
Rochester,  N.  Y. 
Knoxville.   Tenn. 
Houston.   Tex. 
Knoxville.   Tenn. 
Modesto,   Calif. 
Lexington,   Ky. 
Indianapolis,    Ind. 
Sarasota,    Fla. 
Macon,   Ga. 
Washington,    D.  C. 
Cleveland,   Ohio 
Baton  Rouge,   La. 
Titusville,    Fla. 
Lansing,   Mich. 
Wichita  Falls,   Tex. 
Helena,   Mont. 
Lincoln,   Neb. 
Orlando,    Fla. 
Salem,   Ore. 
New  Haven,   Conn. 
Rochester,   Minn. 
Toledo,  Ohio 
New  York,  N.  Y. 
Toledo.  Ohio 
Melbourne,    Fla. 
Ely,   Nev. 
Manchester,  N.  H. 
Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 
Savannah,   Ga. 
New  York,  N.  Y. 


181 


Page  10 


361. 

DAB-FLL 

362. 

AGS-CHS 

363. 

EEN-LEB 

364. 

BIL-SHR 

365. 

CMH-LEX 

366, 

DSM-LNK 

367. 

BZN-HLN 

368. 

MHT-NYC 

369. 

BOS-EWB 

370. 

MOD-SFO 

371. 

JAX-NEA 

372. 

EEN-MHT 

Daytona  Beach,    FIs 
Augusta,   Ga. 
Keene.   N.  H. 
Billings,    Mont. 
Columbus,   Ohio 
Des  Moines,   Iowa 
Bozeman,    Mont. 
Manchester,   N.  H. 
Boston,    Mass. 
Modesto,   Calif. 
Jacksonville,    Fla. 
Keene,   N.  H. 


Ft.    Lauderdale,    Fla. 
Charleston,    S.  C. 
Lebanon.   N.  H. 
Sheridan,   Wyo. 
Lexington,   Ky. 
Lincoln,   Neb. 
Helena,   Moat. 
New  York,  N.  Y. 
New  Bedford,   Mass. 
San  Francisco,    Calif. 
Brunswick,   Ga. 
Manchester,  N.  H. 


182 


EXHIBIT  C 


CITY  PAIRS  RISKING  LOSS  OF  SERVICE 
BY  STATE 


183 


184 


oo 


iS 

?      iS  < 

M     . 

.2  »  ffl 

u 

QC   ClJ 

W  CM 

Ittanooi 
bile,   A 
ntgome 
scle  Sh 

to      , 

6  aS 

5^ 

J3     O     O     3 

u  2§  § 

O    3    S 

«r  «  :;!  ^  X 


<:  m  «  2  §  Q< 


•S  1 

O  at 

^  C 

(U  (1) 


|1 


185 


—t(i)tD 


.2  S    . 


.2  2 

K  .5 


186 


187 


m  < 


•  <:     ^  .2  <: 

rt    O  c    M  O  (0    o 


a 


pq  O 


si' 2* 


to  5! 


^  SS< 


^^ 

o" 

CO 

^  s.  X- 

(0  W  .3 

go 

(2 

to    E    0) 

—<   c 

C  ,^    o 

«    rt 

cc    nj  ^ 

a  c« 

W 

M  fc  fc 

188 


189 


^^ 


» 


^^-^^' 

^    ^-^    ^^-5    J^    ^ 

c  .S  0  .2  o 
S  2  «  3 

las/Ft, 
ettevil 
Spring 
sas  Ci 
le  Roc 
ihoma 
is.   Te 
Louis, 
3a,   Ok 

C^iiJ  s 

^   ^^   c  :^  ^   u       .i; 

cd    O   ti     •    p 

avsoa^a^ci-p 

E  K  J  m  H 

Q&hE!^JOPhwH 

5   B   a; 


2  O 


'  ^   a 


U 


190 


JH 


■s  -^ 

1^. 


1  s 

o  jS 


II 

31 


191 


192 


01    -^ 


m  o  - 

t«  <"  M 

m   c  PQ 

><  a 

en    CD  c 

cd    o  rt 

J  J  OT 


M    .2 

IS 


c  <  . 

<    01  g 

01    c  '-' 

O    rt  3 

J   M  PH 


5151 


"5 


y  rt      S 


S  J  ^  2  < 


Sh      3     -      CO 

U  W  §  CO 


o  ^ 


>■  u 


_0   o 


;;:|    eg  .  M  Q.  °fi5 

03     C       -    o     <U   W    .S   W 

ca.t3nJtinln!nlnl 


j2    d 
P4   H 


to  c:  o  o 
ni  ■-'  J2  3 
J  S  Ph  H 


T3  ^ 

O  cd 


193 


JS      -   cii 

III 
A  Ph  c5? 


o  2  O 

d  m  ra 

o  c  c 

W  OT  OT 


1)  ;:3 
O  U 


tin    o 
C 

"to    ^ 
^1 


a  5 

►li    CO 


.    ro  r  1 
a) 

OS  ^  ^ 

,0  ^    a. 

"D  5  o"  2 

W  CO  K  CO 


2S 


'^  U 

^  o 
.  o 
O    m 

C  '2 
<"    S 

B  t 

as  [jj 
CO   CO 


U 

2h 


^  =«•  "^ 


£5^  ^u 

^    nJ     '  U  ■ 

.  ^    O    n  ^ 


A    2    ^ 


S  .2 


W  fe  S  §  S  « 


CO    CO   CO    CO 


-146    O  -  76  -  pt. 


194 


195 


o  Z 
o     . 

"  § 

Q  tM 


^c5 


^"^ 


c  ^'  o  c  .i;  _r 


.  o 

<v  U 


— I   -J  ..;  x;   D 


u   o 

cfl     O 


^B 


o 


OO^JjggA 


o   § 


196 


u -t     o 


i  J     t 


fa  o  S  § 


u  a 

a  a 
<  J 


197 


O  7Z 

z 
o 


198 


m 

(0 

0) 

u 

> 

u 

V 

a 

en 

O 

T3 

0) 

N 

o 

-a 

M 

m 

Q) 

SI 

K 

nj    0) 


199 


200 


§>^' 


CD    a, 


O     .K 

o  ■-;   0) 
m    <n  '5' 


01  O 

&<     • 

Q 


■C    o 

■a  -5 


t«'  £  o 
5  2^ 


•2.  mZ 


2  £ 


H      S 


201 


s5 


\ 


202 


ii^ 


2         ^-  U    o  o 


.    .   <u  U'  ^  Z 


,  Q  2    S 


-a   o     .  o   o  en 


> 

'C 

u 

(H 

^ 

U 

T3 

1 

2 

2 

to 

^ 

« 

w 

^   t.       U  U  Q  O  ffi 


■?■  S  S  S  ra 


5    c    tm 
^  ?  S  o  3  ^ 


2j2Z2Kot^^^ 


U 

0 

nJ 

2 

> 

pi  6  . 

^ 

^ 

W 

(U 

(1( 

•a 

^ 

.•.'!> 

to 

~a) 

Q 

2 

>tQ..- 

c 

0 

o 

t! 

^"  "a!^   o 

C 

B 

a 

^ 

Slfl 

4) 

m 

01 

1 

!h  r:^  ^  o 

a 

QJ 

o  -c   CO  .ii 

<  pq  2  2  CL,  K  K 

OT 

^^ 

203 


^H 


--§1  -T— Z-OL-^^V'  ^ 


I  ^  /  s   /: 


c     2 


204 


s 

3        ^    ^ 

nj 

Is  SOS 

§ 

|g§ 

|5£  ^  c 

2 

|.2£ 

73    O    O    0)    CS 

:S  o  o 

<;  O  Q  Z  CM 

> 

<  O  Q 

^5 


U  fe  o 


E  O 


„-  PQ    S  .     - 

ti    n)    5i    O  <i    n) 

o  a  S  "o  o  S 


p    rt    nJ    >.  ■ 


UUQSOotw   fehS 


^   ^-  -3  .2  2 

£  £  §  §  ^ 


6  J?.^ 


m  S  ^ 


205 


•■3  u  E  6 

c  (d     .  ™ 
™  Ph  H  ^ 


--  ^  fe   t  ^ 
m    m  :;:!    CO    (D  t^ 


o  ^ 


206 


207 


-§5 


CO         *  <; 

5  I  s  I 


Soon) 

<  U  Q  O 


<  <  o 


•  <  i2     ■ 


<:  2  ^ 


^  ^  o  ^  g  5  ^-  o  c"  -3 

£  O    «J         o  w 


<;     „ 
-  "  <  S  o; 

cDEcoc(i;'aocnS;ii::i'e^crto-3-" 

C0Oti£l.^nl."rtil'0>~'3nJ3rt— '•-< 


'  E  ^'  «■  ^ 


^  s  1  £  i  i  s  g  §  s" 

tn3.3x;oot,E:"io 


.^6 

,  2   OT 

s:  s:  'o' 

u  u  u 


1    •  o 


1  S  w     S 


3  x:   !tf 


u 


208 


■       .       •   M 

o  o  2;    , 

OT   M   ij"    ^ 


s  "* 


05 

3   cd 
E  o 

O  > 


209 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  15 


210 


15   o  oi5 

2  -S  •  rt  2 
-2-g2    . 

O  •-■  o    nJ    C 

-C    g  tn    o  -g 

J5    <u  rt    O    > 

2  J  fe  &<  H 


CD  •  x:  3) 

^  >  ,  cS 

^  .  (P  c  ^ 

t«  O  ^  nj  <S 

^  Si  i^  -^  ::i 

-g  "  CO  o  ca 

W  PL,  CO  W  > 


C  (l> 

c  iJ  o 

CU  rt  Q. 

dl  CO  w 


C   U 


J2 
Hi 

2  >^ 


u  3 


211 


°  o 

s  -I' 


212 


5^ 

o  ^ 


.  5  £  rt 
^  *  ■*-.   -  <l:  (u  i^ 


(D  ^'       .  ^   O   C 

1  ^   ^  "   •■ 


>^  o  P  0)  "M   9^ 


U     - 


■^-S 


el=^ 


.3"-^  ;s  .2      o 


w        U  fc  w 


u 


s-^i 


s^ 


S  «3 


i^ 


^  13 


>     3 


Q  O 


213 


CD     (S     ^ 

u  u  c 


-  "S  ti  o 

5  <S  £  u 

'-  "S  "2  £ 

o   o  «-   « 

t-  2:  X  ■= 


P  o 


a-       c  «   p 


214 


-a  a 


215 


ri    X     3     ?   T3 
^     0)     O    0^    rt    ^• 

£  hJ  J  §  a.  W 


'2  .2 

^"6 


U  U  Q  ►S  2;  H 


_■  O  o  O   o 


6s 


>     3 

ii     O 

u  u 


Q  Q 


o  ■§■ 

^-  O  " 

cti    a;  "^ 

y  ^  t! 

S  i!  o 

U  U  t^ 


CO  .SJ 


216 


o  < 


y 


217 


rt    W    O     T 

O     0)     C    i-J 


-     .    o     .  - 

>5  --|  >-'  ^  .  m 

U  "    ctf  "  fJ  "S 

rt    o  t;   a,  g   o 

§  S  O  Oh  K  OT 


x:    3   "i    o 
U  Q  2  § 


3^ 


O    S  u 


U  §  S  K 


II 


SiU 


«§^ 


O  ;o 

0)    X) 


S  Z  n  :^  ^ 
CO  c  §-  „r  .- 


218 


§5 


S  rt  § 

U   O   M 


ca   o 


U 
13 


219 


220 


.  o 


S5 


s  J 


^,1 


5  (2 


o  Q      o  M 


a!  ^ 
'Si  o- 
c/3  i-i 


H  ^  ^  3     -<  3  S^ 
_c     .  g  ^  ^  .2       O     -. 


6    - 
o  ts 

Xi  Xi 


C    J     03 


PtnOOwMHH^ 


<  P 


n!    to 

O  H 


221 


222 


^'h 

o. 

,^^ 

.-^.^^ 

r-,           .     ^ 

r-i  dj 

^    Cd 

01     (U 

1# 

.Su 

1?    C 

u   Z 

O    i^ 

^00 

^    0    Cd    ^• 

•t:t 

tf  H 

U  H 

u  0  J 

U   J  0,  OT 

h  S 

ta  M 

"•o 

,-J     q; 

a  S 

.2  3 

bD  CO 

4)    .D 

K   3 

S^ 


.00 


£  I   i  S  S   ^ 

5  .s  -s  ^  I  § 

o  u  u  w  5  t^ 


§0       .-a 

-O   o 


■^5        d        >»  S 
-O   o  -'     'iii  C, 

O     ^    O    r-l      o      g     <D 


S  S  c  >  rt  -Sor 
i5  .3  o  g  c  g'  > 

u  U  Q  W  £  J  z 


Ufa 

W    J   S   OT 


223 


\    \ 


<: 

o  < 


.^\ 


T-^ 


3       V 


^V 


1 

\ 

\ 

r^ 

\    f- 

- — -V- 

^      T\ 

y 

V       '^ 

V         ^ 

\  / 

^^i' 

\      1' 

^ 

^^t  ' 

xvi.^ 

-7^ 

\ 

^^•'^J 

u> 

224 


§  ra 


CO  £i 
eiS    BJ 


II 


o    § 


.S  O 
J  z 


cd    tt) 
U  H 

"o     - 

~-    3       . 

•a   ^ 

V    -^     N 

rt     (U 

^     CD     S 

u  X 

£•1^ 

SI 

"d    rt    rt 

t-i    o 

OK  a 

H  J 

;<  J 


m  Q 


_<;  a 


-a  PC   o   B 

S     r-     E    1^ 

S  S  d  ^ 


S^lS   ^ 


I  cq  fe  E-i 


225 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  16 


226 


ra  ^  ^  t; 

O     D     O     ™ 

m  s  Ph  ^ 


§      -^ 


Id' 


S)ll| 

c    m    ;^    g 

m  m  ra  § 


227 


228 


>H    o  Z  ^    ^ 


^njni(l)a>0<D£taO(p 


CQKJZZZZPh 


rt    o   a,  ^ 

K  K  w  ^ 


229 


230 


c  Z 


.  >" 


b    a  en  2 


.S  '^  O    w 

s  gtfs 


,  g  5  rt  -3  ^  f^  S 
^ ■  1)  -^  ^  J;5  S  S  iS  o 


)    s-    .-I 


.s§ 


"^     CO 


0)  M 

s     » 

>     5 


rt  b  ^ 

K  §  Z 


>•§ 


^•2  S 


,Ot^ 


t3   ^       , 


:  ffi  2  z  Hi  c^ 


-Z 

Si 

0)    o 
o  "^ 

22 


u 


231 


232 


■"  ^*  S  s      =3  3  §  ^ 
•b  .s  =3  -3,     -^  S  s  S5 


-gs 


0   ^ 

»  5 


H    c        •-<„ 


o§  § 


O  J  §  S  S  CO  H 


o  o 
O  6 


2  J 
>  .■ 


o      _:0 


O     §0^-^     c*rt"3^     O" 

rt  Si  ^  3  >,     -^  ^  ^ii 

xiSiiocd-J'S-^    (DO 


XI    ■" 

^  -  rt 

0   S§ 

?1 

o    S§K 

^-3  . 

t* 

nj  "S      -  "3 

sll 

o 

•y  ^s  S 

3 

O  U  E 

o 

U  O  fe  o 

o 


233 


3      CQ 

S  -3  C 


.y§ 


1^ 


g^ 


fq   o  -3 
c  S  ^ 

m     ^     O 


234 


235 


^^i3 


ii   o 


§^       §& 


O^^       U^ 


U 


0^.5,- 
.5    §     O    T3 


CO  w 

cm  0) 


r§ 


to  ^ 


236 


237 


-^ 


>0 


238 


H§ 


■<  §    S 


.2§ 


c  <u 


<;  <  §  § 


-"am 

O     3     3 

§  H  H 


S  s 


§§ 


v    u         ni    <u   aj 


H3 


<  § 


a  6 


no  m 

<L>   J2 

K 


o  5 


239 


£  < 

§  s  s 

a  flj 

C    ^     Q. 

15  ^  ^ 

S  ^ 

SJ|  s 

rt    rt    a; 

■-5   J   Z 

Ih= 

t,  y  <u 

240 


J^ 


W  M 


\ 


r 

I 


I  cJ 


^^^■ 

V- 



— r' 

1 

\^^/ " 

"^X^ 

CO 

1 

I 

1      'vv         ^ 

»! 

H 

=    w 

v^ 

^ 

g 

% 

►1 

\ 

3 

>.,^ 

O 

4 

241 


I  d  ^ 


U  S  Ah 


^^ 


fe  W  H 


.2  t:  S;    nj    ^    rt 
■O  "^        Jj    c    ^ 


2i 


Ssllll^ll 


•2  2 

0)  Si 
K 


I    .S  i-l     CI    m   J3 


:^  O 


0)  o  -!<!  E 
Q  K  O  O 


'w  H  H  ^ 


"^   CO   nj  :i 


XI    ti  t^ 


II 


242 


to 

m 

(1> 

u 

o 

u 

u 

t( 

(U 

d 

w 

O 

t3 

V 

0) 

N 

C 

0 

•a 

M 

(U 

« 

w 

3nja>(il-i-'"'±i^«>^Q. 
fflOQfefe§SOCL,0'co 


243 


244 


o§§ 


O  U  Q 


§  w 


Q 


S   ^2 


s     » 


5    c   o  fe 


^6  5 
m  m  § 


u 

3    O 
U    U 

H 
1=) 


245 


246 


U  m       a  hJ  o 


J  ^la 


•S  g  £ 

J  O  Q 


B  IS 


-o  -c  S^  o     . 

0)  C  (D  -S 

o  o  C  ^<  ►^     - 

C  fci  0)  (U     rH     b 


^  rt 

^    nl      . 

£  ^ 

^t° 

.  ° 

o  g 

.    I-H     "^i 

U)"  '"' 

" 

x>      * 

TJ       "    ^ 

-ii    03 

n.  a> 

a  <u  -ti 

«  o 

O     rn 

^  § 

^§     rt 

efl  ^ 

etf  "^    CO 

■s  s 

T3    to    C 

<u    0)    nl 

U  Q 

U  Q  i^ 

0)    o 


4)    V 

n(     ■ 
U 


247 


248 


u  c  B 
4)   m    Qfl 

M  fe  « 


sr<  to 


ni 
O    o 


Wc5?        CQJotH        Wotoo 


249 


250 


>> 


Si 

Boston,   Mas 
Lebanon,  N. 
New  York,   1 
Worcester, 

Ui 

111 

m  §  z 

^   u 

b  S 

«>  w 

^■o 

•-J     (U 

S  '^ 

o  y 

MM 

(u  XI 

«^ 

2    ^ 

D     D 

a  2 


0)    >H 


cj:^ 


251 


252 


-Z       (H 


2  5z 


rt    O   2  .2   M   <»    J-  rt 

j3  !a  .ii  r^  ™  <u  ni  -S 


§  2 
o  |3 

MOT 


;  2  ?' 


< 


rt  -o 


aj    0)   0)   "i    a»   fa 


253 


254 


3   o   o  u  ^.   o 


^1 


I  0,  5 

^  W  O 


5  <:  J  s 


S    n    t^    C    L,   ^    ni 
i2  ii    O    <U    3    CO    Sh 

^  ><  U  Q  Q  O  O 


n)  .5 


U 


255 


c  ^  -a  in 

a  c   S   a; 
OT    g    ™    ^ 


m 

(U 

u 

a; 

C 

> 

a 

OT 

U 

■a 

1 

(U 

O  TJl 

■nH 

U)  ml 

(U 

x> 

K 

^1 

(1)  ,0-0 

3  to    to    C 

^  >  |1h  :;:! 

<  U  W  § 


256 


257 


>h' 

0       2    . 

>h" 

CD 

o5     . 

c   o  ^ 

2 

(1) 
Z 

Z 

i§>^^^ 

2 

6..^^^  . 

»c5"p 

>^"|a:'   . 

|(S' 

;s 

0) 

-C 

o 
K 

o  ^    t.  >^  -Q 

§11  M 

m  o  w  2;  n. 

c 

0 

g 
cd 

1-5 

lit: 

U  Z  0.  p 

1  -  §  c 

O    M'J    2 

»:2  &  » 

O    t,    0)    rt 

«  cq  z  ^ 

W  2  £  p 

u    . 

Z  0, 

t  ^ 

^^ 

^^ 

1^ 

o  -v 

Mm 

<U   JO 

K^ 

o 

c 

(DO)       -    O;     "H  to 

J2   03     2   "O   "5    -*    m 


45JS20&.AH^ 


258 


ni  X 


3    C 


^  'fc!  :::; 


0)   ^"    (u        ^H    nj  :r^ 
J  §  Z       CQ  K  ^ 


^2 


259 


260 


nJCDfjOcnl— c 


O  § 


fe  ^  § 


u 


.2  Q)  >  cq 

•9  c  o  a; 

C  0)  en  ^ 

U  fe  ►?  §K  ^ 


C    i;   cd  .-I 

Q  S  K  H 


ni     •    «J     . 


to 


.en    .  -g  x:  '^ 

.  I  cd-  n  S  ^  ■;  -g  -  £ 
2  S  I  S  .t{  "  §  §  >  §  I 

miiSonCSScEo 

.a  £  .y  g 

K  C  «  « 


cd  S  S  2  S  I  S  .t{  2  §  2  > 

jS<dO  Q0cd.5>-.i3lUoOIU 

tZixIC  3jSO<d<Ut.rt-it, 

<;UW  <UUQQOh,«ci 


85 
"id  J3 


a  «  ^ 


u-S 


261 


CO 

S 
0 

> 

u 

U 

T3 

rt 

0) 

s 

■2 

0 

■p 

M 

OD 

0)  J2| 

« 

<^l 

U  J" 

2     , 

■So 

ra  zi  o  .t; 


"2 


u  u 

nj  Q  2 


2  «  ^  ^ 


u 

.  U  w  u" 


w 


•t;2 
o  2  ^-  >  2 


u 


p,    O  ^  0)    O    n)    ni 
fc-  a  §  22  K  ^ 


o 


6  S^^ 
"  ^2  - 


O   5    O    >^   O    «i 

U  fe  O  §  2  ^ 


262 


o      d 

u 

"■      "  .d 

tr.  'J  2 

2 J  _.• 

a,  Ga. 
eville,   N. 
n,   N.   G. 
burg,    Va. 
5  Beach,   S 
ern,   N.  C 
ngton,   D. 

ille,   N.  C 
a,   Ga. 
lie,   Va. 
sboro,   N. 
burg,   Va. 
!h,   N.   C. 
ke,   Va. 
ity  Airport 
ngton,   D. 

i;  «   >, 

55   o  S 

^^5-ga"S 

^c-sS-g-jguiH 

lit 

gZffi 

Gree 

Kins 
Norf 
Rich 

<  ti.  ;i:  J  S  2  ^ 

52 


263 


264 


u 


^5° 
2 


<J  Q  §  tf 


P 
15  Q 


O^ 


.'id 


SSh 


-i  oj   a 


Q  o  ^- 
►,•  S  ^ 

•  S    T3     O 


S 

:;3 
> 

a 

m 

Q 

fe 

; 

< 

H 

O 

M 

< 

D 

ffi 

H 

(4 

O 

. 

. 

z 

§R 

1 

g 

Q 

J§^ 

% 

s 

z 

B 

. 

d«. 

l3l 

m" 

m 

o  '^ 

.■|£ 

1 

a 

£'t 


S  S  o 


265 


266 


^2 


O   XI 


O  c 

O  >H      .  S  >•  a;              -g 

J-  c  nj  —  —    .-  •^ 

-     -  jr;    fe  ?  W) 

"^  •^   ab  S  o  o 


"  O 
m   g   o     - 


£  ^  O  o  .2  -g    .  "  ^\.  .Si  ^  I  " 


267 


.tu  .'^  d, 


^-  O  .2   o   „.  H  W 
cuo    -  5  ^  ■'^ 

ni   5  c  -ti  2  V  M  =' 


O     0)    Ji     CL 


■"  .2  .2 


O  § 


o   o 

x;  -rt    rt    0)  ^ 
U  U  Q  Q  ^ 


3    C 


t^  J  (i; 


g|1o §3 


;  o   o  x: 
i  J  -1  0. 


s  1 1  i  I  ■?  ^ 

S  .5  I  I  S?  ■  ■ 


5  u  u  u 


Q  Q  ti 


268 


\ 

\ 

\ 
\ 
s    \ 


s      1 

X 

X 

y  1 

6 

/^ 

s. 

\ 
\ 

/ 

C>; 

^  _/ 


/ 
/ 


269 


(n 

m 

o 

U 

1 

CO 

u 

73 

rt 

<U 

C 

O 

is 

<u 

-O 

K 

D 

OT 

O  CB 

CO  U 

u  c 

c8  O 


s  _  « 

S  3  ^ 

t^  c  ;::) 

rt  o  x: 

Ph  fu  M 


■S   ^    ci      -3 

.<  >;!  so 
^  £-  ;l  o  «  ^■ 

^  t  U     _     .0, 
^  "p    m    S    rt    rt 

w  £  ;^  -1  J  w 


(1)     g       .    M 

t;  c  c  o 

m   OT    .=:    ^ 


o  H  u 


2  rt   o  O 
:::!  c  ^  ? 


ni  CO 


u    ro    CO    to     n/    -J  ,  vw    -«- 


C    ^ 

rt    <u 


270 


271 


^  o 


3  *-  t; 

o   o   S 
E  Cl<  c/j 


">  o  ;2 

JJ  O  O 

3  «;  rt 

W  S  Oh 


U 


zi  n   c 


»* 


°  6 


O  "O 


4>     o    O    S     60   to 


9  ^ 


w  o  a:  v^  '^.  '^ 


272 


273 


t, 

0) 

<u 

•-< 
(-. 
u 

u 

0) 

w 

U 

T3 

N 

c 

o 

2 

M 

ra 

<u 

J3 

« 

■3 

W  2  ^ 


.2  -c" 


^^^        0. 


O       .t,2-gg3t, 

^•03        2;goj33 

C^hXI-  O-"t0J3 

u  w  i:  H^  §  0,  Oh 


a,    Oh   £ 


us 


U  OT  ^ 


2    o  2 

cfl    rt    oi    rt 
m  Q  2  ^ 


t^     o 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


274 


275 


00     In     ^ 
O     CD     (1) 

P  ffi  z 


■p    <u 
cd    0 


276 


277 


u  u 


2;  ^- 

o'  ^ 


<  o      <;  o  o 


o  "  3  o  3 


"3    M   >,^ 
-^     3    tfl     O 

<;  <  fe  a 


u 

2 


^  c  g  >  U  -g 

x;  S  0)  o  -^  nj 

m  ii  !h  c  S-.  x: 

<:  <;  O  M  H  U 


O  fe 


™    w  ii    °         ™    ° 


s 

m 

o 

^ 

"5! 

OJ 

u 

tn 

w 

ni 

_a) 

O 

3 

C 

rt 

3 

^H 

o 

H 

a 

c 

p 

278 


u 


I       2  (p-      (/i  Q 


a  c  0) 

O    o  m 


279 


280 


w 

U2 

u, 

> 

u 

0) 

a 

Crt 

O 

T3 

N 

c 

o 

T3 

M 

<D 

XI 

K 

3 

^ 

Q 

ni 

W 

z 

s 

t/2 

P 

_m 

o 

M 

^- 

OT* 

rt 

o 
u 

O 

0 

fa 

2 

3 

s  £ 

0 

1 

Q     . 

^   Q 
o  Z 

si 


?§ 


p  w 

J  2    2 


o   u   c 
u   a  --^ 

m  fe  S 


u  cu      §  Ph 


281 


282 


■?  t 


c  o 


O   > 

§-8 

U  J 


Or;  S 

-s  "^      t 


^-5 
OP. 


is  I  >; 

<;  m  o  t^ 


!?  c       •-  ^  ^ 


o  5,  o  ^  ;g  ;;; 


ti     t.     3    O 


CU   H   t3 


s  t 


rt 

o 

o 

m" 

UJ 

1^ 

O 

rt 

to" 

3 

a 

1 

oT 

1 

1 

g 

c 

3 
0 

<  u  u 

J  h3 

<  H  -i^    .  S 


<  M  § 

i  i  i 

E  'E  o 

2  .2  J 

C     D 


283 


c  .2 

.2  is 

0)   XI 


^  H  ^ 
wo™ 
cs  o  -a 

u^(2 


§  s 


t^      .    CD 


j=  :^  ^  ■?  o. 


J  J  K  ^ 


284 


285 


H    o 


3    C 


g   o   aj   2   o 

.  o  H  H  "o 

2  U     .       U 


2  ffi  o  S  -i 

>  c  -Q  r-i  -^ 

O  C  ^  T!  0) 

,i;  CD  3  r^  3 

u  J  J  S  a, 


-  ^  c 

o    CJ    dJ 

J    hJ    § 


o  U 


;7*     (n 


<     kJ     ^ 


£h.2 
%-| 

Q    ffi   OT 


r      H 


h:^^5 


K  §  O  H  ^ 


aT  5  £  £  "  - 

3   c  o  a  tn  c 

_Q     CO  3  T3  c  " 

<;  <i  K  §  w  H 


^    en 
O    ni 


286 


%  t 


J 


5^    to  H  < 


U     ID 

■^  ^  ;^  >d  ^  •  H  -^  „-   -  >< 

-•Sg    -^  S  °  2  S 

^-  !3  ^  ^  §  I  ^  S  -  ^ 


HH 


<;  J  S 


c 

•a  . 

U  .  cfl 

"©■So; 

•a  O  H 

CO  a 

o  >   tT 

'-<  j:;   ^ 

W  M  H 


s  t 


a)    d 


U 
^  -1=1 


287 


be    • 

2  ^ 
'u     . 


nj 

r^   o    o   a 
U  tC  K  w 


■H  t^ 


Q  J  H 


288 


I 


1 

^^ 

\y 

1      / 

1 

289 


Si  ^    to":? 


290 


291 


j§ 


X) 

§1 


S     ^ 

4)     0) 

s^  2 


292 


293 


£ 

CO 

i) 

t 

't 

^ 

u 

■o 

1 

.2 

o 

X) 

^r^ 

•^ 

bO 

CQ 

0) 

J3 

K 

^ 

^  3  m 
O  5  ^ 
tC  c/2  ^ 


6^ 

Q  6 
(1) 

C    CO 
O   OT 

■S   o 


<;  o  K  J  ^  ^ 


>  > 


K  w 


U 

^ .  >       U  6  ^, 
■-'.    m   rt  Q  Z    B 


•>:  o  d  .S  .S  o 

<  2  «  ^  ^^ 


_  Z  U  2 

O      -  5'*  -J' 

Z   ^      .3 
SCO 

c   g   0)  S; 

5  Sm  >. 
CO  I;  "3 

■w    nl    «    O 
i£;  ^  2  « 


o"     . 

U   M 


Z^ 


O  O  K  ^ 


1 1 


S.2 

O  T3. 


294 


II 


"■  >  *  s  »■  2' 


Sh   ^    ii     3    ^    ^ 


U 

en 

t;  o 


«^ 


295 


296 


3^ 


O  ^       rt  o 


-^ 


.2  M  &  t:  "S  ^ 

o  d   lu   o   S  cfl 

CQ  W  J  Dh  OT  >" 


?i  2  ^.  I 
■g  -2  Id  6 

m    §  ^  15 

<  J  ^  >^ 


Ctf     0) 


M     O     g     g 

^  to  ;:3  S 


So    - 


(i;^ 


s  t 


I  I  I  I        ^-  ^ 

S  ■«    O    g.^  0    3 

DP  ft.  w  ^     m  m 


O    J      -g 


-  jj   o 

<U    1;;    rn 


OS 


297 


I 


\ 


298 


>o 


>  H 


•>    ci 


aJ  o  rt  ■- ' 
J=  C  O  Sh 
U  «  «  H 


2     •       ^   ^  - 

.  ^  h"    -  S    •> 

ij     ..Si    o  5  -a     . 

ra    <u  t!    3    o  •"    o 
<:  CQO  W  §  K  K 


^  J=   g 

O    M  .ii 

Sac 

O   ^    cil 
S   P.   ^ 


-  rt   S      " 


r:!  c  rt   3 


299 


^'  o  o 


CO 

CD 

o 

'> 

'C 

u 

1 

U 

73 

c 

o 

"V 

.ii 

M 

CO 

v 

X! 

K 

3 

OT 

I)     O     3    S 

•3  .S  o  S 

«  U  U  0, 


300 


301 


3^ 


en         tn  ^ 

c  ^  .i  ^  - 

5   (D  "^   (u  :::! 


cH-  5   tn  .2  "^^     . 


?» 


s| 


U    I 


^    "    ^    ^     C 


3     "     b     c     c     C 

"3  w  2  o  I'  £ 

Q  W  O  i  S  K 


QQot      oo      §o      uo 


3.1 


ol    CO 

01     (U 


■:5   c   o 
U  S  K 


o    -  S  ^ 


302 


d  -5  §  „: 


o  ^  o  -s 

M   "     O     g 


OW^§ 


2^     .§^ 


^  .2 


a§§« 


303 


304 


^^ 


IS 


^  ° 


<«-       § 


J  «       O  Q  J  w 


>^  o 
^  U 


O 


305 


EXHIBIT  D 


CITY  PAIRS  RISKING  CURTAILMENT  OF  SERVICE 
BY  STATE 


51-146    O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  21 


306 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.  Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand, 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 

ALABAMA 

Between: 

Birmingham 

and: 

-  Chicago,   ni. 

6 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas /Ft.  Worth,   ' 

Tex. 

2 

-  Jackson/ Vicksburg, 

Miss 

9 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

3 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

9 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

3 

-  Mobile.  Ala. 

6 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

7 

-  New  York.  N.Y. 

5 

HuntsvUle/ Decatur 

and: 

-  Greensboro,   N.C. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Knoxville,   Tenn. 

-  Orlando,   Fla. 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

-  Washington.   D.C. 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


and: 

-  Atlanta.  Ga. 

-  Birmingham.   Ala. 


Montgomery 
and: 

-  Jackson/Vicksburg. 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 


307 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 
Non-stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximuni  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


Between: 
Phoenix 


and: 

-  Albuquerque.   N.  M. 

-  Amarillo,   Texas 

-  Chicago,    111. 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

-  El  Paso,   Texas 

-  Houston,   Texas 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

-  Los  Angeles,    Calif. 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul, 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

-  Oklahoma  City.  Okla. 

-  Portland,   Ore. 

-  St.    Louis,   Mo. 

-  San  Antonio,   Texas 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

-  Washington,   D.  C. 


and: 

-  Chicago,   m. 

-  Dallas.   Texas 

-  Los  Angeles.    Calif. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 


308 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 
Services                Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

ARKANSAS 
Between: 
Little  Rock 
and: 

-  Dallas,   Texas                                   14  4 

-  Houston.   Texas                                  2  2 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo.                                2  2 

-  Memphis,   Tenn.                                31  2 

-  Nashville,   Tenn.                                  2  2 

-  Oklahoma  City.  Okla.                      2  2 

-  St.    Louis,   Mo.                                     6  4 

-  Shreveport,   La.                                 4  2 


309 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 

CALIFORNIA 

Between: 

Los  Angeles 

and: 

-  Albuquerque.   N. M. 

12 

-  Atlanta.   Ga. 

13 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

3 

-  Birmingham,   Ala. 

3 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

7 

-  Chicago,   111. 

42 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

9 

-  Colorado  Springs,    Colo. 

2 

-  Columbus,  Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

26 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

26 

-  Des  Moines,    Iowa 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

10 

-  El  Paso.   Texas 

14 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

4 

-  Houston,   Texas 

14 

-  Huntsville/ Decatur,   Ala, 

3 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind. 

2 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

12 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

8 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

4 

-  Milwaukee,    Wis. 

4 

-  Minneapolis /St.    Paul,    M 

linn.       13 

-  Monterey,    Calif. 

11 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

6 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

25 

-  Oklahoma  City,   Okla. 

8 

-  Omaha,   Neb. 

6 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

10 

Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


310 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


CALIFORNIA  (cont'd) 


Between: 

Los  Angeles  (cont'd) 

and: 

-  Phoenix.   Ariz. 

29 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

3 

-  Portland,  Ore. 

16 

-  Reno,   Nev. 

6 

-  Sacramento,   Calif. 

13 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

11 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

12 

-  San  Antonio,   Texas 

3 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

80 

-  Seattle.  Wash. 

18 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

1 

-  Tucson.  Ariz. 

10 

-  Washington,  D.C. 

11 

Monterey 

and: 

-  Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

11 

Sacramento 

and: 

-  Chicago,   111. 

4 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

4 

-  Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

13 

-  Portland,  Ore. 

2 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

2 

San  Diego 

and: 

-  Chicago.   111. 

13 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

6 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

6 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

3 

-  Seattle,   Wash. 

2 

-  Washington.   D.C. 

4 

San  Francisco 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.M. 

12 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

7 

-  Baltimore.   Md. 

4 

311 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Page  3 


Average  Daily 

Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop 

at 

Services 

Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual) 

(Simulation) 

CALIFORNIA  (cont'd) 

Between: 

San  Francisco  (cont'd) 

and: 

-  Boise.   Idaho 

4 

2 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

7 

4 

-  Chicago,   ni. 

29 

12 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

2 

2 

-  Dallas,    Texas 

18 

2 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

26 

6 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

9 

2 

-  Eugene,  Ore. 

8 

2 

-  Houston,   Texas 

5 

2 

-  Kansas  City,    Mo. 

5 

2 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

31 

14 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

80 

48 

-  Medford,  Ore. 

6 

4 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

4 

2 

-  Minneapolis /St.   Paul, 

Minn.       11 

2 

-  New  Orleans,    La. 

2 

2 

-  New  York.   N.   Y. 

19 

2 

-  Oklahoma  City.   Okla. 

3 

2 

-  Omaha.   Neb. 

2 

2 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

7 

2 

-  Phoenix.   Ariz. 

9 

6 

-  Pittsburgh.   Pa. 

2 

2 

-  Portland.   Ore. 

28 

10 

-  St.   Louis.   Mo. 

4 

2 

-  Salt  Lake  City.   Utah 

11 

2 

-  San  Antonio.   Texas 

3 

2 

-  Seattle.   Wash. 

31 

10 

-  Spokane,   Wash. 

4 

2 

-  Tucson,   Ariz. 

4 

2 

-  Washington,   D.   C. 

7 

2 

312 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


COLORADO 
Between: 
Colorado  Springs 
and: 

-  Albuquerque,    N.  M. 

-  Chicago,   IlL 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

-  Los  Angeles,    Calif. 


and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.  M. 

15 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

2 

-  Billings,   Mont. 

4 

-  Boise,   Idaho 

4 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

4 

-  Chicago,   111. 

16 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

25 

-  Des  Moines,   Iowa 

6 

-  Detroit,    Mich. 

5 

-  Fresno,    Calif. 

2 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

9 

-  Kansas  City.   Mo. 

19 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev. 

14 

-  Lincoln,    Neb. 

4 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

26 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

2 

-  Midland/Odessa,   Tex. 

2 

313 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  2 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


COLORADO  (cont'd) 
Between: 
Denver 
and: 

-  Milwaukee,  Wis.  6 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul,  Minn.  16 

-  Moline,   111.  2 

-  New  Orleans,   La.  1 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  16 

-  Oklahoma  City,   Okla.  5 

-  Omaha,   Neb.  15 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa.  2 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz.  18 

-  Portland,  Ore.  14 

-  Rapid  City,   S.  D.  6 

-  Reno,   Nev.  4 

-  Sacramento,   Calif.  4 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah  26 

-  San  Diego.   Calif.  6 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif.  26 

-  Seattle,   Wash.  13 

-  Sioiix  Falls.   S.  D.  4 

-  Spokane,   Wash.  3 

-  St.    Louis.   Mo.  14 

-  Tulsa.  Okla.  2 

-  Washington.   D.C.  9 

-  Wichita.   Kan.  10 


Grand  Junction 


Las  Vegas.   Nev. 


314 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


CONNECTICUT 
Between: 
Hartford 
and: 

-  Atlanta,  Ga. 

-  Chicago,  111. 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,   Fla. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

-  Washington,  D.  C. 


New  Haven 
and: 
-  Washington,   D.  C. 


315 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


DELAWARE 


316 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.  Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
mcLximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peEik  demand. 


Average  DaUy 

Non-stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 

DISTRICT  OF  COLUMBIA 

Between: 

Washington 

and: 

-  Atlanta.   Ga, 

30 

-  Austin.   Tex. 

2 

-  Boston.   Mass, 

44 

-  Buffalo.  N.Y. 

11 

-  Charleston.  S.C. 

4 

-  Charlotte.   N.  C. 

6 

-  Chicago,   m. 

52 

-  Cleveland.  Ohio 

19 

-  Cincinnati.   Ohio 

7 

-  Columbia.   S.C. 

2 

-  Columbus.  Ohio 

9 

-  Dallas.   Tex. 

14 

-  Dayton.   Ohio 

8 

-  Denver,  Colo. 

9 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

17 

-  Greensboro/ High  Point, 

N.C.       6 

-  Greenville.   Spartanburg. 

S.C.     2 

-  Hartford.   Conn. 

14 

-  Houston.   Tex. 

4 

-  Huntsville/Decatur. 

Ala. 

2 

-  Indianapolis.   Ind. 

3 

-  Jacksonville.   Fla. 

5 

-  Kansas  City.   Mo. 

1 

-  KnoxvUle,   Tenn. 

7 

-  Lexington,  Ky. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

11 

-  Louisville.   Ky. 

6 

-  Memphis.   Tenn. 

8 

Services  Assigned 


Maximum  Ear 


nings 


(Simulation) 


317 

Page  2 
Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


:.-.                                                   Average  Daily 

Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop 

at 

Services 

Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual) 

(Simulation) 

DISTRICT  OF  COLUMBIA  (cont'd) 

Between: 

Washington 

and: 

-  Miami,    Fla.                                         17 

4 

-  Milwaukee.   Wis.                                2 

2 

-  Minneapolis /St.    Paul.    Minn.       11 

2 

-  Nashville,   Tenn.                                8 

4 

-  New  Haven,   Conn.                              5 

2 

-  New  York,  N.  Y.                              128 

36 

-  Orlando.   Fla.                                      6 

4 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz.                                   4 

2 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa.                                15 

6 

-  Providence.   R.I.                               11 

4 

-  Rochester,   N.Y.                                  8 

4 

-  St.    Louis,   Mo.                                   11 

4 

-  San  Diego,   Calif.                               4 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif.                      7 

2 

-  Syracuse,   N.Y.                                  10 

2 

-  Tampa.   Fla.                                        6 

2 

-  Tulsa,  Okla.                                          2 

2 

-  West  Palm  Beach.   Fla,                   3 

2 

318 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

FLORIDA 
Between: 
Daytona  Beach 
and: 
-  Atlanta,    Ga,  9  * 


[iami,    Fla. 


6  2 


-  New  York,   N.Y.  1  2 

Ft.   Lauderdale 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga.  23  6 

-  Baltimore,   Md.  4  2 

-  Boston,   Mass.  S  4 

-  Chicago,   111.  14  4 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio  6  4 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

-  Jacksonville,   Fla.  4  2 

-  New  York,   N.Y.  44  14 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 


3  2 

3  2 


7  2 

5  4 

13  4 


-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

-  Tampa,    Fla. 

Gainesville 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga.  4  2 

Jacksonville 
and: 

-  Atlanta.   Ga.  30  14 


Chicago,   111. 
Ft.   Lauderdale, 


4  2 

2 


319 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Page  2 


FLORIDA  (Cont'd.) 
Between 
Jacksonville  (Cont'd, 
and: 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

-  New  Orleans, 

-  New  York,   N. 

-  Norfolk,    Va. 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

-  West  Palm  Beach. 


La. 
Y. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 
Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


Melbourne 


Atlanta,   Ga. 


Miami 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

34 

-  Baltimore,   Md, 

5 

-  Birmingham,   Ala. 

3 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

13 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y. 

2 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

4 

-  Chicago,   111. 

18 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

4 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

5 

-  Columbus,   Ohio 

4 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

11 

-  Daytona  Beach,   Fla. 

6 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

7 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

3 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

7 

-  Jacksonville,    Fla. 

8 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

4 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

8 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

66 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

14 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

10 

-Raleigh/Durham,   N.C. 

2 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

5 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

4 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

34 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

17 

320 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd. 


Page  3 


FLORIDA  (Cont'd. ) 
Between: 
Orlando 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 
Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

26 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

3 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

2 

-  Chicago,   111. 

7 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

2 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

3 

-  Huntsville/Decatur,   Ala 

2 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

17 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

6 

Panama  City 

and: 

-  Tampa,    Fla. 

3 

Pensacola 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

12 

Sarasota 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

7 

-  Chicago,  111. 

2 

Tallahassee 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

10 

Tampa 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

37 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

6 

-  Chicago,   111. 

16 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

4 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

5 

-  Columbus,   Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas,    Tex. 

7 

321 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  4 


(1973  Actual) 

FLORIDA  (cont'd) 

Between: 

Tampa  (cont'd) 

and: 

-  Dayton,  Ohio 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

9 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,    Fla. 

13 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

1 

-  Los  Angeles.    Calif. 

1 

-  Louisville,  Ky. 

2 

-  Miami.    Fla. 

34 

-  Milwaukee,    Wis. 

2 

-  Nashville.   Tenn. 

2 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

9 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

20 

-  Panama  City,    Fla. 

3 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

8 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

6 

-  St.   Louis.    Mo. 

5 

-  Washington.    D.  C. 

6 

West  Palm  Beach 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

17 

-  Chicago,   m. 

2 

-  Jacksonville,    Fla. 

5 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

9 

-  Washington,   D.  C. 

3 

Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


322 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


Between: 
Atlanta 


and: 

-  Akron/Canton,  Ohio  2 

-  Baltimore,   Md.  18 

-  Baton  Rouge,   La.  3 

-  Boston,   Mass.  H 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y.  9 

-  Charleston,   S.C.  6 

-  Charleston,   W.   Va.  3 

-  Charlotte,    N.C.  25 

-  Chicago,   111.  34 

-  Columbus,   Ohio  5 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio  14 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio  12 

-  Dallas/Ft.  Worth,   Tex.  31 

-  Dayton,   Ohio  11 

-  Daytona  Beach,   Fla.  9 

-  Detroit,  Mich.  10 

-  Evansville,   Ind.  2 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,   Fla.  23 

-  Gainesville,    Fla.  * 

-  Greensboro/High  Point,   N.C.    12 

-  Hartford,   Conn.  8 

-  Houston,   Tex.  26 

-  Indianapolis,    Ind.  13 

-  Jackson/Vicksburg,  Miss.  8 

-  Jacksonville,   Fla.  30 


323 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Page  2 


GEORGIA  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily 

Non-stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


Between: 

Atlanta  (cont'd.  ) 

and: 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

6 

-  Las  Vegas.   Nev. 

2 

-  Lexington,    Ky. 

2 

-  Louisville,    Ky. 

23 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

13 

-  Melbourne,   Fla. 

7 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

18 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

34 

-  Milwaukee,   Wis. 

6 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul,   Minn. 

10 

-  Mobile,   Ala. 

12 

-  Nashville,    Tenn. 

14 

-  New  Orleans,    La. 

29 

-  Newport  News,   Va. 

2 

-  New  York,    N.  Y. 

57 

-  Norfolk,    Va. 

5 

-  Orlando,   Fla. 

26 

-  Pensacola,   Fla. 

12 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

25 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

15 

-  Providence,   R.L 

2 

-Raleigh/Durham,    N.C. 

12 

-  Richmond,   Va. 

8 

-  Rochester,   N.Y. 

3 

-  San  Antonio,   Tex. 

7 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

7 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo, 

18 

-  Sarasota,   Fla. 

7 

-  Savannah,    Ga. 

13 

-  Shreveport,   La. 

2 

-  Syracuse,    N.  Y. 

4 

-  Tallahassee,    Fla. 

10 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

37 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

30 

-  West  Palm  Beach,   Fla. 

17^ 

Savannah 

Atlanta,    Ga. 


324 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simiilated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services 
(1973  Actual) 


Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


Between: 

Boise 

and: 

-  Chicago,   111. 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

-  Portland.   Ore. 

-  Reno,   Nev. 

-  San  Francisco, 

-  Seattle.  Wash. 


325 

COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Between: 

Chicago 

and: 

-  Akron/Canton,   Ohio 

7 

-  Albany,    N.Y. 

6 

-Albuquerque,    N.Mex. 

9 

-  AUentown,   Pa. 

3 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

34 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

14 

-  Billings,   Mont. 

2 

-  Birmingham,  Ala. 

6 

-  Boise.   Idaho 

2 

-  Boston,  Mass. 

29 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y. 

15 

-  Charlotte.   N.C. 

7 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

34 

-  Colorado  Springs,   Colo. 

3 

-  Columbia,    S.   C. 

2 

-  Columbus,   Ohio 

15 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

25 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

41 

-  Des  Moines,   Iowa 

19 

-  El  Paso,   Tex. 

3 

-  Evansville,   Ind. 

6 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,    Fla. 

14 

-  Greensboro/High 

Point,   N.C. 

8 

-  Harrisburg,   Pa. 

2 

-  Hartford,  Conn. 

18 

326 


Page  2 
Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily 
Non-stop 
Services 

Services  Assigned 

at 
Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual) 

(Simulation) 

ILLINOIS  (cont'd.) 

Between; 

Chicago  (cont'd.  ) 

and: 
-  Houston,   Tex. 

14 

4 

-  Islip,    N.Y. 

-  Jacksonville,   Fla. 

2 
4 

2 
2 

-  Kansas  City,  Mo. 

41 

12 

-  Knoxville,    Tenn. 

2 

2 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev. 

19 

8 

-  Lincoln,    Nebr. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Louisville,   Ky. 

4 
42 
16 

2 

16 

8 

-  Memphis,    Tenn. 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul, 

-  Nashville,   Tenn. 

19 

18 

Minn.       56 

12 

6 

6 

32 

-  New  Orleans,    La, 

8 

-  Newport  News,    Va. 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

2 
117 

36 

-  Norfolk,   Va. 

7 

-  Oklahoma  City,   Okla. 

-  Omaha,   Nebr. 

7 
19 

10 

-  Orlando.   Fla. 

7 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

18 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

-  Portland,   Oreg. 

-  Providence,   R.    I. 
-Raleigh/Durham,    N.C 

-  Reno,    Nev. 

44 

11 

4 

6 

2 

10 

-  Rochester,   Minn. 

12 

-  Rochester,   N.Y. 

12 

-  Sacramento,   Calif, 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

-  San  Antonio,   Tex. 

-  San  Diego,   Calif. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

4 
15 

7 
13 
29 

12 

-  Sarasota,   Fla. 

-  Seattle,   Wash. 

15 

2 
6 

-  Spokane,    Wash. 

-  Syracuse,    N.Y. 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

2 

6 

16 

2 
4 
6 

327 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Page  3 


ILLINOIS  (cont'd.) 
Between: 
Chicago  (cont'd.  ) 
and: 

-  Tucson,   Ariz. 

-  Tulsa,   Okla. 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

-  West  Palm  Beach,   Fla. 

-  Wichita,    Kan. 

-  Youngstown,   Ohio 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 


Maxi 


mm  Earnings 


(Simulation) 


Moli 


Denver,   Colo. 


328 

COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximizatio 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Between: 

Evansville 

and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga. 

2 

-  Chicago,   111. 

6 

Indianapolis 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

13 

-  Dallas,    Tex. 

5 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

4 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

2 

-  Memphis,    Tenn. 

7 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul,   Minn.         2 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

8 

-  Philadelphia.   Pa. 

2 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

5 

-  Washington,   D.  C. 

3 

Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


329 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

IOWA 
Between: 
Cedar  Rapids 
and: 
-  Chicago,    111.  11  6 

Des  Moines 


Chicago,   111. 

Denver,   Colo. 

Los  Angeles,   Calif. 


330 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE;       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Between: 

Wichita 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.  M.  2  2 

-  Chicago,   111.  6  2 

-  Denver,   Colo.  10  4 


331 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 
Services                Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

KENTUCKY 
Between: 
Lexington 
and: 

-  New  York,   N.Y.                                  2  2 

-  Washington,  B.C.                              2  2 

Louisville 
and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga.                                         23  6 

-  Chicago,    111.                                        16  8 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio                                 4  2 

-  Columbus,   Ohio                                   4  2 

-  Dallas,   Tex.                                          3  2 

-  Detroit,   Mich.                                      7  4 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo.                                2  2 

-  Knoxville,   Tenn.                                  4  2 

-  Memphis,   Tenn.                                  4  2 

-  New  York,   N.Y.                                   5  .4 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo.                                      5  2 

-  Tampa,    Fla.                                          2  2 
-Washington,   B.C.                                6  2 


332 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
liiaximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 


LOUISIANA 
Between: 
Alexandria 


(1973  Actual) 


(Simulation) 


Dallas,   Texas 


New  Orleans 

and: 
-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

29 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

4 

-  Birmingham,   Ala. 

-  Boston,    Mass. 

7 
2 

-  Chicago,    111. 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

8 

24 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

1 

-  Houston,   Texas 

36 

-  Jacksonville,    Fla. 

2 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

2 
6 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

15 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

-  Montgomery,    Ala. 

-  Nashville.   Tenn. 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

8 
4 
2 
12 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

-  St.   Louis,    Mo. 

3 
4 
4 

-  San  Antonio,   Texas 

3 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

2 

-  Shreveport,    La. 

-  Tampa,    Fla. 

8 

9 

333 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  2 


Average  Daily 
Non-stop 
Services 


LOUISIANA  (cont'd) 
Between: 
Shreveport 
and: 

-  Atlanta,  Ga. 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

-  Houston,   Texas 

-  Jackson/Vicksburg,   Miss 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark. 

-  Memphis.   Tenn. 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 


(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


334 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maiximum  Earnings 


(1973  Actual) 


(Simulation) 


Between: 
Bangor 
and: 
-  Boston.   Mass. 

Portland 


New  York,  N.  Y. 


Presque  Isle 
and: 
-  Boston,   Mass. 


335 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:         This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 

MARYLAND 

Between: 

Baltimore 

and: 

-  Atlanta.   Ga. 

18 

-  Boston,    Mass. 

16 

-  Chicago,   111 

14 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

4 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

5 

-  Denver.   Colo, 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

4 

-  Ft.    Lauderdale.    Fla. 

4 

-  Houston.   Texas 

2 

-  Kansas  City.   Mo. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

3 

-  Miami.    Fla. 

5 

-  New  Orleans,  La. 

4. 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

12 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

4 

Services  Assigned 


Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


336 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:         This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 
MASSACHUSETTS 


Between: 

Boston 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

11 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

16 

-  Bangor,   Maine 

9 

-  Buffalo.   N.Y. 

8 

-  Charlotte.   N.C. 

2 

-  Chicago,   Ul. 

29 

-  Cleveland.  Ohio 

10 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

5 

-  Columbus.  Ohio 

3 

-  Dallas.   Texas 

2 

-  Denver.   Colo. 

4 

-  Detroit.   Mich. 

8 

-  Ft.    Lauderdale.    Fla. 

6 

-  Los  Angeles.    Calif. 

7 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

13 

-  Milwaukee.    Wis. 

2 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul,    Minn.         4 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

2 

-  New  York.   N.Y. 

121 

-  Orlando,    Fla. 

3 

-  Philadelphia.   Pa. 

42 

-  Pittsburgh.    Pa. 

11 

-  Presque  Isle.   Me, 

4 

-  St.    Louis,   Mo. 

4 

-  San  Francisco.   Calif. 

7 

-  Tampa.    Fla. 

6 

-  Washington.    D.  C. 

44 

337 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -   Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  fr-equcncies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Between: 

Detroit 
and: 

-  Albany.   N.Y. 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

4 
10 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

4 

-  Boston,    Mass. 

8 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y. 

11 

-  Burlington,    Vt. 

2 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

-  Dallas.   Texas 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

14 
7 

5 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,    Fla. 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

3 
6 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

4 
2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Louisville,   Ky. 

10 
7 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

-  Miami.    Ha. 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul.    Mii 

-  New  York.   N.  Y. 

3 

7 

m.         5 

56 

-  Orlando.    Fla. 

3 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

14 
14 

-  Rochester,    N.Y. 

-  St.    Louis,    Mo. 

12 

6 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

9 

-  Syracuse,   N.  Y. 

2 

-  Tampa.    Fla. 

-  Washington,   D.  C. 

9 
17 

51-146  O  -  76  -  Dt. 


338 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


MICHIGAN  (cont  'd ) 
Between: 
Saginaw 
and: 
-  New  York,    N.  Y. 


Page 


339 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE;       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 

MINNESOTA 

Between: 

Minneapolis/St.   Paul 

and; 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

10 

-  Billings,   Mont. 

2 

-  Bismarck,   N.   Dak. 

2 

-  Boston,  Mass. 

4 

-  Chicago,   111. 

56 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

4 

-  Dallas.   Tex. 

4 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

16 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

5 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind. 

2 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

6 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev. 

3 

-  Los  Angeles,  Calif. 

13 

-  Milwaukee,   Wis. 

12 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

16 

-  Omaha,    Nebr. 

13 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

4 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

2 

-  Rapid  City,    S.   Dak. 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

11 

-  Seattle.   Wash. 

8 

-  Spokane,   Wash. 

4 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

6 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

n 

Rochester 

and: 

. 

-  Chicago.   111. 

12 

340 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE;       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

MISSISSIPPI 
Between: 
Jackson/ Vicks burg 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga.  8  4 

-  Birmingham,   Ala.  9  4 

-  Dallas,   Tex.  3  2 

-  Memphis,    Tenn,  16  4 

-  Montgomery,   Ala.  5  2 

-  Shreveport,   La.  12  4 


341 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:        This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Avera 

ge  Daily 

Non 

i-Stop 

Ser 

vices 

MISSOURI 

(1973 

Actual) 

Between: 

Kansas  City 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.M. 

4 

-  Amarillo,   Tex. 

2 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

6 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

2 

-  Chicago,    111. 

41 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

2 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

18 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

19 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

4 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind. 

4 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev. 

2 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

12 

-  Louisville,    Ky. 

2 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

8 

-  Minneapolis /St.   Paul, 

Minn. 

6 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

2 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

4 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

2 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

3 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

5 

-  Seattle,   Wash. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

1 

Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


342 


Page  2 


Comparison 


of  Non-stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily 
Non-stop 
Services 


(1973  Actual) 


MISSOURI  (cont'd.) 
Between: 
St.   Louis 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

-  Baltimore,  Md. 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

-  Dayton,   Ohio 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

-  Huntsville/Decatur,   Ala. 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark. 

-  Louisville,   Ky. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Memphis.  Tenn. 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul,   Mi 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

-  Oklahoma  City,  Okla. 

-  Omaha,   Nebr. 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

-  Seattle,  Wash. 

-  Tulsa,   Okla. 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

-  Washington,  D.C. 


2 
4 
2 

9 
10 
14 
10 
14 
6 
8 
2 
3 
6 
5 
11 
26 
5 
6 
4 
18 
2 
9 
5 
7 
8 
4 
3 
11 
5 
11 


Services 

at 

Maximum 


Assigned 
Earnings 


(Simulation) 


343 

COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Between; 

Billings 

and: 

-  Chicago,    111.  2  2 

-  Denver,   Colo.  4  2 

-  Minneapolis /St.   Paul,   Minn.         2  2 

Great  Falls 
and: 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah  2  2 


344 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 

1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

NEBRASKA 
Between: 
Lincoln 
and: 

-  Chicago,    111.  4  2 

-  Denver,   Colo.  4  2 

Omaha 
and: 

-  Chicago,    111.  19  10 

-  Denver,   Colo.  15  2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif.  6  2 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul,   Minn.       13  6 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif.  2  2 

-  Seattle,   Wash.  3  2 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo.  9  4 


345 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  B 


oth  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 


Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


Between: 
Las  Vegas 
and: 


-  Albuquerque,    N.M. 

5 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

2 

-  Chicago,    111. 

19 

-  Dallas,   Tex. 

6 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

14 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

2 

-  Grand  Junction,  Colo. 

2 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

6 

-  Kansas  City,  Mo. 

2 

-  Milwaukee,   Wis. 

1 

-  Minneapolis /St.   Paul,   Minn.         3 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

7 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

.  14 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

2 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

17 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

31 

:eno 

and; 

-  Boise,   Idaho 

2 

-  Chicago,    111. 

2 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

4 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

6 

-  Portland,   Oreg. 

6 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

7 

-  Seattle,   Wash. 

2 

346 

COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and.it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


NEW  HAMPSHIRE 
Between: 
Manchester 
and: 
Cleveland,   Ohio 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-  Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


347 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
,  adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 
NEW  JERSEY 

None. 


348 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

NEW  MEXICO 
Between: 
Albuquerque 
and: 

-  Chicago.    111.  9  4 

-  Colorado  Springs,    Colo.  5  2 


Dallas,   Tex.  n 

-  Denver,   Colo.  15 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo.  4 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev.  5 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif.  12 

-  Lubbock,    Tex.  2 

-  Midland,   Tex.  3 


Oklahoma  City,   Okla.  2  2 

Phoenix,   Ariz.  4  2 

San  Antonio,   Tex.  2  2 

San  Francisco,   Calif.  5  4 

Wichita,  Kan.  2  2 


349 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 


Non-Stop 

at 

Services 

Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual) 

(Simulation) 

NEW  YORK 

Between: 

Albany 

and: 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

9 

2 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y. 

11 

2 

-  Chicago,   ni. 

6 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

4 

2 

Buffalo 

and: 

-  Chicago.   111. 

15 

6 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

13 

4 

-  Detroit,    Mich. 

11 

2 

-  Miami.    Fla, 

2 

2 

-  New  York.   N.Y. 

29 

10 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

4 

2 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

17 

6 

-  Washington,    D.C. 

11 

2 

Islip 

and: 

-  Chicago,    ni. 

2 

2 

New  York 

and 

-  Atlanta.   Ga. 

57 

14 

-  Birmingham,   Ala. 

5 

2 

-  Boston,    Mass. 

121 

60 

-  Buffalo.   N.Y. 

29 

10 

-  Charleston,   S.  C. 

2 

2 

350 


r>^^p..i..on  of  Non-stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  2 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


NEW  YORK  (cont'd) 
Between: 
New  York  (cont'd) 
and: 

-  Charleston,   W.  Va. 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

-  Chicago,   111. 

-  Cincinnati,  Ohio 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

-  Columbia,   S.  C. 

-  Columbus,  Ohio 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

-  Dayton,  Ohio 

-  Daytona  Beach,    Fla. 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

-  Detroit,    Mich. 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,    Fla. 

-  Greensboro,   N.C. 
-Greenville/Spartanburg.   S.C, 

-  Houston.   Texas 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind, 

-  Jacksonville,   Fla. 

-  Kansas  City.   Mo. 

-  Knoxville,    Tenn. 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

-  Lexington,  Ky. 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  Louisville,   Ky. 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

-  Milwaukee,   Wis. 

-  Minneapolis /St.    Pool,    Minn. 

-  Nashville,   Tenn. 

-  Norfolk.   Va. 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

-  Newport  News,   Va. 

-  Oklahoma  City,  Okla. 

-  Orlando.   Fla. 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

-  Portland,   Maine 

-  Raleigh/ Durham,  N.C. 


2 
18 
117 
15 
43 
6 
14 
25 
11 
1 
16 
56 
44 
13 
.   6 
5 
8 
2 
4 
5 
7 
2 
25 


16 

16 

6 

14 

12 

3 

2 

17 


2 
4 
36 
4 
12 
2 
4 
8 
4 
2 
4 
12 
14 
2 
2 
4 
4 
4 
2 
2 
4 
2 

12 
4 
4 
20 
6 
4 


351 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  3 


NEW  YORK  (cont'd) 
Between: 
New  York  (cont'd) 
and: 

-  Richmond.    Va. 

-  Rochester,   N.  Y. 

-  Saginaw,    Mich. 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah 

-  St.   Louis,    Mo. 

-  San  Diego,   Calif. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

-  Seattle.   Wash. 

-  Syracuse,   N,  Y. 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

-  Toledo,   Ohio 

-  Washington,    D.  C. 

-  West  Palm  Beach,    Fla. 

-  Youngstown,   Ohio 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


Rochester 
and: 

-  Atlanta.   Ga. 

-  Chicago,   ni. 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

-  Detroit.   Mich. 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

-  Philadelphia.   Pa. 

-  Pittsburgh.    Pa. 

-  Washington.   D.  C. 

Syracuse 
and: 

-  Atlanta.   Ga. 

-  Chicago,   111. 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

-  New  York.   N.  Y. 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

-  Washington,    D.C. 


352 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 

This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


NORTH  CAROLINA 


Between 

Charlotte 

and: 

-  Akron/Canton,   Ohio 

2 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

25 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

2 

-  Chattanooga,    Tenn. 

6 

-  Chicago,   111. 

7 

-  Columbus,   Ohio 

4 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

4 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

4 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

18 

-  Orlando,   Fla. 

2 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

6 

-  Pittsburgh.    Pa. 

8 

-  St.   Louis,    Mo. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

6 

Greensboro 

and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga. 

12 

-  Chicago,   111. 

8 

-  Huntsville/Decatur,   Ala. 

2 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

13 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

6 

353 


Page  2 

Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

TT973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

NORTH  CAROLINA  (Cont'd.) 
Between: 
Raleigh/Durham 


and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga.  12 


6  4 


Chicago,  HI 
Miami,  Fla. 
New  York,  I 
Philadelphia,    Pa.  2  2 


Miami,    Fla.  2  2 

New  York,   N.  Y.  12  4 


354 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

NORTH  DAKOTA 


Between; 
Bismarck 


and: 
-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul, 


355 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:        This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Ear 


(1973  Actual) 

OHIO 

Between 

Akron/Canton 

and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga. 

2 

-  Charlotte,    N.C. 

2 

-  Chicago.    111. 

7 

Cleveland 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

12 

-  Baltimore,    Md. 

4 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

10 

-  Chicago,   111. 

34 

-  Dallas,    Tex. 

5 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

2 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,    Fla. 

6 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

4 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

9 

-  Louisville,    Ky. 

4 

-  Manchester,    N.H. 

2 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

5 

-  Milwaukee,    Wis. 

6 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul, 

Minn. 

4 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

43 

-  Norfolk,   Va. 

2 

-  Orlando,   Fla. 

2 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

15 

-  Providence,   R.  I. 

2 

-  Rochester,   N.Y. 

4 

(Si 


ition) 


ungs 


356 


Page  2 
Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

OHIO  (Cont'd.) 
Between: 
Celveland  (cont'd.) 
and: 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif.  2  2 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo.  9  4 

-  Tampa,    Fla.  5  2 

-  Washington,   D,C.  19  2 


and: 

-  Atlanta,  Ga. 

14 

-  Birmingham,  Ala. 

2 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

5 

-  Dallas,    Tex. 

7 

-  Detroit,    Mich. 

14 

-  Kansas  City,    Mo. 

2 

-  Knoxville,   Tenn. 

5 

-  Memphis,    Tenn. 

3 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

4 

-  Nashville,   Tenn. 

7 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

15 

-  Orlando,    Fla. 

2 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

2 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

9 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

10 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

4 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

7 

Columbus 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

5 

-  Boston.  Mass. 

3 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

4 

-  Chicago,   111. 

15 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

2 

-  Louisville,    Ky. 

4 

-  Miami,    Fla. 

4 

-  New  York,    N.Y. 

14 

-  Philadelphia,    Pa. 

5 

-  Tampa,    Fla. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

9 

357 


Page  3 

Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 


OHIO  (Cont'd.) 
Between: 
Dayton 
and: 
-  Atlanta,    Ga.  11 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


-  Memphis,    Tenn.  2  2 

-  New  York,    N.  Y.  11  4 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo.  10  2 

-  Tampa,   Fla,  2  2 

-  Washington,   D.C.  8  4 

Toledo 
and: 

-  New  York,   N.  Y,  2  2 

Youngstown 
and: 

-  Chicago,   111.  5  2 

-  New  York.   N.  Y.  2  2 


358 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE;       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Services  Assigned 

Non-stop 

at 

Services 

Maximi 
(Sir 

jm  Earnings 

(1973  Actual) 

nulation) 

OKLAHOMA 

Between: 

Oklahoma  City 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.M. 

2 

2 

-  Chicago,   111. 

7 

4 

-  Dallas,   Tex, 

26 

4 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

3 

2 

-  Little  Rock,  Ark. 

2 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,  Calif. 

8 

4 

-  New  York.   N.Y. 

2 

2 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

4 

2 

-  St.   Louis,' Mo. 

2 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

3 

2 

Tulsa 

and: 

-  Chicago,   111. 

7 

4 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

2 

2 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

5 

4 

-  Nashville,  Tenn. 

2 

2 

-  St.   Louis.  Mo. 

11 

4 

-  Washington,  B.C. 

2 

2 

359 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE;    This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


(1973  Actual) 

OREGON 

Between: 

Eugene 

and: 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

8 

Medford 

and: 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

6 

Portland 

and: 

-  Boise,   Idaho 

4 

-  Chicago,   III. 

11 

-  Dallas,    Tex. 

4 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

14 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

16 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

2 

-  Reno,   Nev. 

6 

-  Sacramento,   Calif. 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

28 

-  Spokane,   Wash. 

8 

360 

COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

PENNSYLVANIA 


Between: 

AUentown 

and: 

-  Chicago,   III. 

3 

-  Pittsburgh.   Pa. 

7 

Scranton/Wilkes  Barre 

and: 

-  Chicago,   111. 

2 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

18 

Philadelphia 

and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

25 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

42 

-  Buffalo,   N.Y. 

4 

-  Charlotte,   N.C. 

6 

-  Cincinnati,  Ohio 

2 

-  Cleveland.  Ohio 

15 

-  Columbus,   Ohio 

5 

-  Dallas,  Tex. 

5 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

2 

-  Detroit,   Mich. 

14 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,   Fla. 

7 

-  Hartford,   Conn. 

11 

-  Houston,   Tex. 

2 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind. 

2 

-  Jacksonville,   Fla. 

3 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

10 

361 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.  ) 


Page  2 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 
(1973  Actual) 
PENNSYLVANIA  (cont'd. ) 
Between; 
Philadelphia  (cont'd.  ) 
and: 

-  Miami,    Fla.  14 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul,   Minn.  4 

-  New  Orleans,   La.  3 

-  Norfolk,    Va.  11 

-  Orlando,    Fla.  2 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa.  39 

-  Providence,   R.I.  7 

-  Raleigh/Durham,  N.C.  2 

-  Rochester,    N.  Y.  3 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo.  5 

-  San  Francisco,    Calif.  7 

-  Tampa,   Fla.  8 

-  Syracuse,   N.  Y.  6 

Pittsburgh 
and: 

-  AUentown,    Pa.  7 

-  Atlanta,    Ga.  15 

-  Baltimore,   Md.  12 

-  Boston,   Mass.  11 

-  Buffalo,    N.  Y.  17 

-  Charlotte,    N.C.  8 

-  Chicago,   111.  44 

-  Cincinnati,   Ohio  9 

-  Dallas.   Tex.  4 

-  Detroit,   Mich.  14 

-  Ft.   Lauderdale,   Fla.  5 

-  Greensboro/High  Point,    N.C.         2 

-  Harrisburg,   Pa.  18 

-  Hartford,   Conn.  10 

-  Houston,   Tex.  2 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind.  5 

-  Knoxville,   Tenn.  2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif.  3 

-  Miami,   Fla.  10 

-  Milwaukee,   Wis.  2 

-  New  Orleans,   La.  4 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  61 


Services  Assigned 

at 
Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


362 


Page  3 
Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd.) 

Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop 


PENNSYLVANIA  (cont'd.  ) 
Between: 
Pittsburgh  (cont'd. ) 
and: 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

-  Rochester,   N.Y. 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

-  Tri  City,  Tenn. 

-  Washington,   D.C. 


at 
Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


!9  12 

4  2 

8  4 

2  2 


6  2 

2  2 

15  6 


363 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 

NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 
Services               Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 
RHODE  ISLAND 
Between: 
Providence 
and: 

-  Atlanta.  Ga.                                              2  2 

-  Chicago,   ni.                                           4  2 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio                                    2  2 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa.                                 7  2 

-  Washington.   D.  C.                               11  4 


364 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simvilated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


SOUTH  CAROLINA 
Between: 
Charleston 


and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga.  6  4 

-  New  York.  N.Y.  2  2 

-  Norfolk.   Va.  6  2 

-  Washington.   D.  C.  4  4 

Columbia 
and: 

-  Chicago,   ni.  2  2 

-  New  York.  N.Y.  6  2 

-  Washington.  D.  C.  2  2 

Greenville /Spartanburg 
and: 

-  New  York.   N.Y.  6  2 

-  Washington.    D.  C.  2  2 


365 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

SOUTH  DAKOTA 
Between 
Rapid  City 
and: 

-  Denver,   Colo.  6  4 

-  Minneapolis /St.    Paul,   Minn.  2  2 

-  Salt  Lake  City.   Utah  2  2 

Sioux  Falls 
and: 

-  Denver,   Colo.  4  2 

-  Salt  Lake  City,   Utah  2  2 


;uu> 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
197S  Actual  vs.  Simulat«si  for  Profit  Maximisation 


Flighti 


Both  Directions 


NOTE:        This  oom|>i»r\son  does  not  include  c»t,v-fvj»»rs  \i\  which  profit 
maxmiiKation  xH'Ould  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
uviicato  t*\e  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
;»dts^uAte  frtx^uonoics  to  meet  peak  demand. 


TENNESSEE 
Betxreen: 
Chattamx>ga 
aivi: 
-  Charlotte.  N.C 


Aver;\j;e  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1S17S  Actual^ 


Services  Assipied 

at 

Maximum  Farniivgs 

(Simulation^ 


Knoxville 
and: 

-  Chicago.   111. 

-  Cincuuiati,  Ohio 

-  HuntsvUle/Decatur. 

-  Louisville,  K>'. 

-  Memphis.  Tenn. 

-  NashvUIe.   Tenn. 

-  Nevr  York.  N.Y. 

-  Pittsburgh.   Pa. 

-  Washington.  D.  C. 


Memphis 
aixi: 

-  Atlanta.  Oa.  18 

-  Birmingham,  Ala.  9 

-  Charlotte,  N.C.  4 

-  Chicago,  111.  19 

-  Cincinnati,  Ohio  S 

-  Dallas,   Texas  15 

-  Da>-ton,  Ohio  i 

-  Denver,  Colo.  i 

-  Detroit,  Mich.  3 

-  Houston.   Texas  S 

-  Indianapolis.   Ind.  7 

-  Jackson  Vicksburs:.    Miss.  16 


'MM 


CoinpariBon  of  Non-Stop  SchfJulfd  Servicee  (cont'd) 


l'at;<r  2 


TENNESSEF:  (cont'd) 
Between: 
MemphJB  (cont'd) 
and: 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

-  Knoxville,   Tenn. 

-  Little  Rock.   Ark. 

-  LoB  Angeles,   Calil 

-  Louisville,   Ky. 

-  Nashville,   Tenn. 

-  New  Orleans,    La. 

-  New  York,   N.  Y. 

-  St.    Louis,    Mo. 

-  Shreveport,    La. 

-  Washington,   D.  C. 


Average  Daily  Servicee  Aissigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Service  Maximum  EarningB 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Nashville 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

-  Chicago,   lU. 

-  Cincinnati,  Ohio 

-  Dallas/ Ft.    Worth,   Texas 

-  Houston,   Texas 

-  Knoxville,  Tenn. 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark. 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

-  New  York.   N.  Y. 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

-  Tulsa,  Okla. 

-  Washington,   D.C. 


ill 


Pittsburgh,   Pa. 


368 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:         This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


Between: 
Amarillo 
and: 

-  Dallas.   Texas 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo. 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 


Midland,  Texas 
Washington.   D.C. 


Brownsville 


Houston,   Texas 


Corpus  Christi 

and: 

-  Dallas.   Texas 

4 

Dallas 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N. M. 

11 

-  Alexandria,    La. 

4 

-  Amarillo,   Texas 

6 

-  Atlanta,  Ga. 

31 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

5 

-  Boston,    Mass. 

2 

-  Chicago,   111. 

25 

-  Cincinnati,  Ohio 

7 

-  Cleveland,  Ohio 

5 

Page  2 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


TEXAS  (cont'd) 
Between: 
Dallas  (cont'd) 


and: 

-  Colorado  Springs,   Colo.  3 

-  Corpus  Christi,   Texas  4 

-  Denver,  Colo.  25 

-  Detroit,   Mich.  7 

-  El  Paso,   Texas  12 

-  Indianapolis,   Ind.  5 

-  Jackson/ Vicksburgh,   Miss.  3 

-  Kansas  City,   Mo.  18 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev.  6 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark.  14 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif.  26 

-  Louisville,   Ky.  3 

-  Lubbock,   Texas  19 

-  Memphis,   Tenn.  15 

-  Miami,   Fla.  11 

-  Midland/Odessa,   Texas  15 

-  Minneapolis /St.   Paul,   Minn.         4 

-  Nashville,   Tenn.  9 

-  New  Orleans,   La.  24 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  25 

-  Orlando,   Fla.  2 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa.  5 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz.  17 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa.  4 

-  Portland,   Ore.  4 

-  St.    Louis,   Mo.  14 

-  San  Diego.   Calif.  6 

-  San  Francisco,  Calif.  18 

-  Seattle,   Wash.  4 

-  Shreveport,   La.  17 

-  Tampa,   Fla.  7 

-  Tucson,  Ariz.  6 

-  Washington,   D,  C.  14 


Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


El  Paso 
and: 

-  Chicago,   Illinois 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

-  Los  Angeles,  Calif. 

-  San  Antonio.  Texas 


370 


Pages 


Comparison  o 


f  Non-stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


Services  Assigned 


TEXAS  (cont'd) 
Between: 
Houston 
and: 


-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

26 

-  Baltimore,   Md. 

2 

-  Brownsville,    Texas 

5 

-  Chicago,   111. 

14 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

2 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

9 

-  Las  Vegas,   Nev. 

6 

-  Little  Rock,   Ark. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

14 

-  Memphis,   Tenn. 

3 

-  Miami,   Fla. 

7 

-  Midland/Odessa,   Texas 

2 

-  Nashville,   Tenn. 

2 

-  New  Orleans,    La. 

36 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

5 

-  Oklahoma  City,   Okla. 

3 

-  Philadelphia,   Pa. 

2 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

1 

-  Pittsburgh,   Pa. 

2 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

8 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

5 

-  Shreveport,   La. 

7 

-  Tampa,    Fla. 

1 

-  Tulsa,   Okla. 

5 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

4 

Lubbock 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.M. 

2 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

19 

-  El  Paso,   Texas 

4 

Midland/Odessa 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,    N.M. 

3 

-  Austin,    Texas 

4 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

15 

-  Denver,  Colo. 

2 

-  Houston,   Texas 

2 

-  San  Antonio,   Texas 

6 

Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


2 

2 

4 

2 

2 

2 

2 

6 

2 

2 

2 

2 
14 
4 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
2 
4 
2 


371 


Comparison  of  Non-Stop  Scheduled  Services  (cont'd) 


Page  4 


Average  Daily 
Non-Stop 
Services 

(1973  Actual) 


TEXAS  (cont'd) 

Between: 

San  Antonio 

and: 

-  Albuquerque,   N.  M. 

2 

-  Atlanta,   Ga. 

7 

-  Chicago,   111. 

7 

-  El  Paso,   Texas 

10 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

3 

-  Midland/Odessa,   Texas 

6 

-  New  Orleans,   La. 

3 

-  Phoenix,   Ariz. 

2 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

3 

Services  Assigned 

at 

Maximum  Earnings 

(Simulation) 


372 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Pi 


rections 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-stop  at 


Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


UTAH 
Between: 
Salt  Lake  City 
and: 

-  Casper,   Wyo. 

-  Chicago,   111. 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

-  Great  Falls,   Mont. 

-  Las  Vegas,  Nev.  1|^ 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

-  New  York.   N.  Y. 

-  Rapid  City,   S.  D. 

-  Reno,   Nev. 

-  Sacramento,   Calif. 

-  San  Francisco,   Calif. 

-  Sioux  Falls,   S.D. 


2  2 

15  6 

26  14 

2  2 

7  8 

12  6 

2  2 

2  2 

7  4 

2  2 

11  2 

2  2 


373 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:    This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


VERMONT 
Between: 
Burlington 
and: 
-   Detroit, 


374 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


Between: 
Newport- News 
and: 

-  Atlanta,   Ga.  2  2 

-  Chicago,   111.  2  2 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  3  2 


and: 

-  Atlanta.  Ga.  5  4 

-  Charleston.   S.  C.  6  2 

-  Chicago,   111.  7  4 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio  2  2 

-  Jacksonville,    Fla.  1  2 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  14  6 

Richmond 
and: 

-  Atlanta.  Ga.  8  4 

-  New  York,   N.  Y.  10  6 


375 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:      This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 

WASHINGTON 


Between: 

Seattle 

and: 

-  Boise,   Idaho 

2 

-  Chicago,   m. 

15 

-  Dallas,   Texas 

4 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

13 

-  Kansas  City.   Mo. 

2 

-  Los  Angeles.   Calif. 

18 

-  Minneapolis/St.    Paul,   Minn.            8 

-  New  York.   N.  Y. 

5 

-  Omaha.   Neb. 

3 

-  Reno,   Nev. 

2 

-  St.   Louis,   Mo. 

3 

-  San  Diego.   Calif. 

2 

-  San  Francisco.   Calif. 

31 

Spokane 

and: 

-  Chicago,   ni. 

2 

-  Denver.   Colo. 

3 

-   Minneapolis /St.    Paul.    Minn.            4 

-  Portland.   Ore. 

8 

-  San  Francisco.   Calif. 

4 

376 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  ys.    Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  Include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assi 

Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnin 


(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


gs 


WEST  VIRGINIA 
Between: 
Charleston: 
and; 
-  New  York,    N.  Y. 


377 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,   and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily 

Non-Stop 

Services 

(1973  Actual) 


WISCONSIN 

Between; 

Milwaukee 

and: 

-  Atlanta,    Ga. 

6 

-  Boston,   Mass. 

2 

-  Cleveland,   Ohio 

6 

-  Denver,   Colo. 

6 

-  Las  Vegas,    Nev. 

1 

-  Los  Angeles,   Calif. 

4 

-  Minneapolis/St.   Paul.   Minn.       12 

-  New  York,   N.Y. 

16 

-  Pittsburgh,    Pa. 

2 

-  Tampa,   Fla. 

2 

-  Washington,   D.C. 

2 

Services  Assigned 


Maximum  Earnings 
(Simulation) 


378 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICE.- 
1973  Actual  vs.   Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 

Flights  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


This  comparison  does  not  include  city-paii-s  in  which  profi 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,    and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Assigned 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 
(1973  Actual)  (Simulatior,) 


Between; 
Casper 
and: 
-  Salt  Lake  City,    Utah 


379 

U.S.  Senate, 
Washinffton,  B.C.,  May  2,   1975. 
Mr.   George  W.   .Tames, 
Air  Transport  Association, 
Washinffton,  D.G. 

Dear  Mr.  James  :  I  have  received  and  reviewed  your  April  25  letter  and  the 
accompanying  study  relating  to  possible  consequences  of  deregulation  of  the 
scheduled  air  transport  industry.  I  want  to  thank  you  for  complying  with  the 
subcommittee's  request  that  you  undertake  a  study  and  for  the  efforts  you  and 
others  have  made  to  complete  it  in  a  timely  fashion. 

A  preliminary  review  of  the  study  suggests  that  basing  the  study's  computer 
model  on  the  predicted  behavior  of  a  monopolist,  as  was  done,  materially  affects 
the  accuracy  and  predictive  value  of  the  study.  This  monopolist  model  does  not 
take  into  account  the  fundamental  fact  that  deregulation  means  there  would  be 
a  competitive,  multiairline  environment,  in  which  any  particular  airline  would 
have  to  behave  as  a  competitor,  not  a  monopolist. 

Even  if  your  study  were  based  on  a  model  that  could  reasonably  identify 
"unprofitable"  routes  in  a  competitive  system,  the  conclusions  you  chose  to  draw 
in  your  letter  to  me  may  seriously  misstate  the  probable  level  of  air  service 
under  deregulation.  First,  several  of  the  nonstop  route  segments  identified  by 
the  ATA  as  candidates  for  cessation  or  reduction  of  service  have  in  fact  already 
been  abandoned  by  the  trunk  carriers  under  CAB  regulation.  Second,  of  those 
segments  presently  receiving  nonstop  trunk  service,  many  are  simultaneously 
served  by  local  .service,  intrastate,  or  commuter  carriers,  who  would  l)e  likely  to 
continue  or  even  increase  service  if  the  competing  trunk  carrier  reduced  or  dis- 
continued its  service.  Third,  a  significant  number  of  the  segments  do  in  fact  now 
receive  connecting,  one-  or  multistop  service  by  trunks,  local  service,  intrastate 
or  commuter  carriers,  so  reduction  or  discontinuance  of  nonstop  trunk  service 
would  certainly  not  mean  cessation  of  all  air  service  to  the  commiuiities  involved. 

One  further  ix)int.  According  to  United  Air  Lines,  which  serves  a  large  percent- 
age of  the  routes  you  claim  would  be  abandoned  if  carriers  were  free  to  do  so, 
many  of  the  so-called  "unprofitable"  nonstop  trunk  segments  are  in  reality  profit- 
able. As  United  explained  to  the  subcommittee  staff,  they  would  continue  to  be 
served  on  a  nonstop  basis  because  they  are  flown  in  order  to  feed  passengers  to 
other  segments  or  flights  which,  when  taken  together,  generate  sufl5cient  revenues 
to  cover  or  exceed  costs.  Even  other  nonstop  segments  you  identified  for  possible 
extinction  would  still  be  flown,  according  to  United,  because  they  are  used  to 
ferry  or  position  aircraft  that  are  better  flown  with  some  passengers  than  empty. 
There  is  every  reason  to  believe,  therefore,  that  the  otlier  trunk  airlines  would 
make  a  similar  analysis  of  their  so-called  "unprofitable"  routes. 

It  is  my  understanding  that  many  of  the  points  I  have  raised  were  discussed 
with  you  by  the  subcommittee  staff  prior  to  the  release  of  your  study,  and  that  the 
ATA  would  make  an  effort  to  verify  and  include  then  in  the  final  presentation 
and  release  of  the  study  itself.  In  any  case,  I  am  sure  you  would  agree  that  it  is 
important  to  present  a  fuller  and  more  accurate  analysis  than  is  implied  by  your 
April  25  letter  to  the  many  governmental,  industry  and  consumer  parties  who  are 
genuinely  interested  in  the  i.isues  of  regulatory  reform.  Accordingly,  I  would 
suggest  that  a  copy  of  this  letter  be  furnished  to  those  who  have  been  or  will  be 
furnished  copies  of  the  study. 

The  study  and  your  accompanying  conl^lusions  are  now  being  analyzed  more 
fully  by  tlie  subcommittee,  several  executive  agencies,  and  by  a  number  of 
economists  at  various  universities.  AVhen  these  analyses  are  completed,  I  will 
make  then  available  to  you. 

Thank  you  for  your  continuing  participation  in  the  subcommittee's  inquiry. 
Sincerely, 

Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
Chairman,  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure. 


380 

Air  Transport  Association  of  America, 

Washington,  D.C.,  May  8, 1975. 
Hon.  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
U.S.  Senate, 
Washington,  D.C. 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy  :  Thank  you  for  your  May  2,  1975,  letter  commenting 
on  the  Air  Transport  Association's  April  25  study  on  "The  Consequences  of  De- 
regulation of  the  Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry."  We  appreciate  the  elforts 
you  and  your  staff  have  made  in  reviewing  the  comprehensive  analysis  of  de- 
regulation of  the  present  airline  system  which  we  prepared  in  response  to  your 
request  of  February  7, 1975. 

Based  on  your  May  2  letter,  there  appears  to  be  a  shift  in  the  frame  of  refer- 
ence from  your  original  request  to  us  on  February  7,  in  that  your  interpretation 
of  the  study  is  based  on  a  different  premise  than  your  original  request  to  us. 

1.  In  your  February  7  letter,  which  is  attached,  you  asked  us  for  "a  list  of 
those  city-pairs  that  are  now  unprofitable  and  might  be  abandoned."  We  furnished 
such  a  list.  As  requested,  the  study  looked  at  each  route  in  the  present  trunk 
system  using  the  latest  available  data.  It  identified  372  nonstop  routes  where 
incremental  cost  exceeded  incremental  revenue,  a  condition  of  unprofitability 
which  highlights  such  routes  as  prime  candidates  for  abandonment.  These  372 
unprofitable  trunk  routes,  together  with  the  826  subsidized  routes  of  the  regional 
air  carriers,  comprised  the  list  you  requested  of  scheduled  airline  routes  which 
"are  now  unprofitable  and  might  be  abandoned." 

2.  You  suggest  that  our  study  may  be  inaccurate  because  you  feel  it  is  based 
on  the  "predicted  behavior  of  a  monopolist."  We  believe  such  a  conclusion  is  in- 
correct since  our  analysis  was  based  on  the  competitive,  multiairline  environ- 
ment actually  in  ))eing  in  the  present  route  patterns  of  18  trunk  and  regional 
air  carriers.  We  attempted  neither  to  contrive  a  monopolist  system  nor  to  recast 
the  present  national  system  of  competitive  air  service.  We  did,  however,  extend 
our  analysis  of  the  present  system  by  examining  the  possibility  of  increased  com- 
petition entering  the  currently  profitable  routes.  The  results  showed  a  lowering 
of  profitability  on  these  routes  as  well  as  an  increase  in  the  number  of  currently 
unprofitable  routes. 

3.  You  also  suggested  that  our  study  may  overstate  the  probable  decline  in 
air  service  resulting  from  deregulaton.  Mr.  Stephen  Breyer  of  your  staff  made 
similar  points  when  we  provided  him  with  a  preliminary  review  of  our  study 
on  April  17.  However,  as  indicated  in  my  letter  of  April  25.  some  service  over 
the  unprofitable  routes  identified  in  our  study  might  be  continued  for  such 
purposes  as  "feeding  heavier  traveled  routes  or  aircraft  positioning."  Neverthe- 
less, as  pointed  out  by  United  Air  Lines,  even  after  taking  these  factors  into 
account,  its  judgement  is  that  approximately  22  percent  of  all  United's  nonstop 
routes  would  likely  be  abandoned.  However,  it  is  our  belief  that  some  of  the ' 
possible  effect  of  deregulation  may  well  be  understated  in  our  report  when  all 
air  carrier  routes  are  considered,  since  deregulation  would  encourage  a  heavier 
concentration  on  the  more  productive  city-pair  markets  and  less  service  in  the 
marginal  markets. 

In  response  to  the  request  in  your  May  2  letter,  we  will  send  a  copy  of  that  letter, 
along  with  our  response,  to  those  who  were  or  will  be  furnished  a  copy  of  our 
original  study. 
Sincerely, 

George  W.  James, 
Senior  Vice  President.  Economics  and  Finance. 


[Sample  of  the  letters  requesting  an  evaluation  of  the  ATA  study :] 

U.S.  Senate, 
April  29,  1915. 
Prof.  Roger  Sherman, 

Department  of  Economics,  University  of  Virginia, 
Charlottesville,  Va. 

Dear  Professor  Sherman  :  The  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and 
Procedure,  which  I  chair,  has  just  completed  10  days  of  public  hearings  on  Fed- 


381 

eral  regulation  of  the  airlines.  During  the  course  of  those  hearings,  Dr.  George 
James  of  the  Air  Transport  As.sociation  of  America  testified  that  in  his  view 
deregulation  would  result  in  substantial  reduction  of  air  service  to  small  com- 
munities, and  promised  to  undertake  an  empirical  study  concerning  that  assertion. 
I  am  enclosing  a  copy  of  the  completed  study  and  the  covering  letter  from 
Dr.  James. 

The  subcommittee  would  find  it  most  helpful  if  you  would  undertake  to  re- 
view the  ATA  study  and  provide  comments  to  the  subcommittee  concerning  the 
technical,  economic,  and  policy  implications  of  the  study.  I  would  specifically 
appreciate  your  views  on  whether  the  conclusions  stated  in  Dr.  James'  letter  are 
in  fact  supported  by  the  study  itself.  As  an  independent  economist  of  recognized 
ability,  your  assistance  in  this  regard  will  be  most  valuable. 

If  you  have  any  questions,  please  contact  Mr.  Stephen  Breyer,  special  counsel  to 
the  subcommittee,  at  (617)  495-i276  or  Mr.  Philip  Bakes,  assistant  counsel,  at 
(202)  224-5617. 

Thank  you  for  your  assistance  and  cooperation. 
Sincerely, 

Edward  M.  Kennedy, 

Chairman. 


THE  CHAIRMAN   OF  Th 
COUNCIL  OF   ECONOMIC  AC 
WASHINGTON 


May  1,    1975 


Dear  Senator  Kennedy: 

This  is  in  response  to  your  letter  of  April  28,    1975,    requesting 
the  Council's  views  on  the  recent  Air  Transport  Association  report. 
Consequences  of  Deregulation  of  the  Scheduled  Air  Transport  System: 
An  Analytical  Approach  and  the  conclusions  stated  in  Dr.   George 
James'  letter  of  transmittal  dated  April  25,    1975, 

I  have  asked  James  C.    Miller,    Senior  Staff  Economist  at  the 
Council  of  Economic  Advisers  in  the  transportation  and  regulation 
area  to  evaluate  that  study  and  the  letter  of  transmittal.     His  report 
to  me  is  attached.     As  you  will  note,    Dr.    Miller  questions  both  the 
adequacy  and  the  conclusions  reached  by  the  ATA   study.     He  especially 
takes  issue  with  the  conclusion  that  deregulation  would  lead  to  a 
substantial  reduction  in  scheduled  air  service. 

Thank  you  for  giving  the  Council  an  opportunity  to  express  its 
views  on  this  important  matter. 


Alan  G 


Senator  Edward  M.    Kennedy 

Chairman,    Subcommittee  on  Administrative 

Practice  and  Procedure 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,   D.   C.     20510 


OV-UT'O^V^ 


^e^ 


5 


(382) 


383 


UNITED  STATES  GOVERNMENT 

Memorandum 


Alan  Greenspan 
Chairman 


date:   May  1,  1975 


III 
'I   Economist 


Air  Transport  Association's  Analysis  of  the  Consequences 
of  Airline  Deregulation 


This  is  in  response  to  your  request  for  my  assess- 
ment of  the  Air  Transport  Association's  (ATA's)  recent 
report,  Consequences  of  Deregulation  of  the  Scheduled 
Air  Transport  Industry;   An  Analytical  Approach,  and 
whether  it  supports  the  conclusions  contained  in  Dr.  James 
letter  of  transmittal  to  Senator  Kennedy  dated  April  25, 
1975. 

The  ATA  study  is  in  response  to  Senator  Kennedy's 
request  for  the  industry  to  identify  those  "scheduled 
routes  where  service  might  be  reduced  or  eliminated  if 
each  airline  could  set  its  own  prices  and  could  enter  or 
exit  any  market  at  will"  (Dr.  James'  letter,  p.l).   The 
study  concludes  that  of  the  994  trunk-carrier  routes 
analyzed,  "372  could  be  candidates  for  elimination  under 
deregulation,  while  nearly  all  of  the  remaining  622  could 
experience  sharp  curtailment  of  service"  (letter,  p.  1) . 
The  ATA  also  suggests  that  the  826  nonstop  routes  of  the 
local  service  carriers  identified  as  presently  receiving 
subsidy  would  be  candidates  for  elimination  under  de- 
regulation.  The  ATA  therefore  concludes  that,  "[i]t  is 
conceivable  that  the  1,198  unprofitable,  and  subsidized, 
routes  might  not  survive  in  a  deregulated  environment 
except  in  limited  instances  as  an  adjunct  to  more  profit- 
able routes  or  under  large  subsidy  payments  by  cities  or 
the  federal  government"  (letter,  p.  2) . 

This  memorandum  evaluates  the  operations  research 
model  on  which  most  of  the  ATA's  conclusions  are  based, 
ATA's  interpretation  of  that  model,  the  ATA's  other 
analysis,  and  the  issue  of  cross-subsidy. 


Buy  U.S.  Savings  Bonds  Regularly  on  the  Payroll  Savings  Plan 


384 

-  2  - 

Lockheed's  Airline  System  Simulation-^ 

With  respect  to  the  effects  of  deregulation  on  trunk 
airline  service,  the  ATA's  conclusions  arc  based  primarily 
on  Lockheed's  Airline  System  Simulation  ("simulation"  or  *| 
"model").   The  development  of  this  model  was  begun  in  1959 
under  the  overall  direction  of  William  A.  Gunn.   It  was 
improved  during  1960  and  1961  and  became  operational  at' 
that  time.   In  its  present  configuration  the  model  is  cap- 
able of  simulating  an  airline  routing  network  of  up  to 
250  city  pairs.   The  model's  objective  is  to  maximize  (net) 
earnings  and  its  major  outputs  are  the  number  and  kinds 
of  (optimal)  aircraft  and  the  routes  served. 

As  airline  simulations  go,  the  Lockheed  model  is 
a  good  one,  being  widely  used  and  well  respected.   However, 
in  my  judgement  models  of  this  type  should  be  used  with 
extreme  caution  when  put  to  special  uses  for  which  they 
were  not  primarily  designed,  such  as  identifying  markets 
likely  to  be  abandoned  under   "deregulation"  .£./ Models 
such  as  these  may  be  valuable  tools  for  designing  new 
aircraft  (payload,  range,  et  cetera)  or  for  suggesting 
to  airline  scheduling  officials  which  markets  to  consider 
exploiting  and  which  to  consider  abandoning,  but  they  are 
inherently  limited  when  it  comes  to  answering  specific 
questions  such  as  whether  the  route  between  points  A  and 
3  is  presently  uneconomic,  much  less  whether  under  a 
changed  market  environment  (i.e.,  deregulation)  the  route 
would  be  uneconomic  and,  therefore  presumably,  abandoned. 


\/   This  discussion  is  based  on  descriptions  found  in 
the  following  publications:  Consequences  of  Deregulation 
of  the  Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry;  An  Analytical 
Approach  (Washington:  Air  Transport  Association,  April  1975); 
Lockheed  Airline  System  Simulation  (Burbank:  Lockheed- 
California  Company,  i;.d.);  Revisions  to  1969  Lockheed 
Indirect  Operating  Expense  Method  (BurbanK:  Lockheed- 
California  Company,  July  1974);  and  William  A.  Gunn,  "Airline 
System  Simulation,"  Operations  Research   (March  1964) , pp. 206- 
29. 

2/   For  purposes  of  this  memorandum,  "deregulation"  may 
be  regarded  as  the  removal  of  all  economic  (but  not  safety) 
regulation  and  subjecting  the  industry  to  the  antitrust  laws. 
This  appears  to  be  what  the  ATA  means  by  the  term.   It  is 
notable  that  none  of  the  Administration  proposals  presently 
under  review  contemplate  this  extreme  form  of  deregulation. 
Although  regulatory  controls  would  be  substantially  reduced, 
some  economic  regulation  would  remain. 


385 


A  first  problem  is  the  degree  of  realism  that  these 
models  are  able  to  achieve.   In  my  Ph.D.  disseration  ,  ±/ 
for  example,  I  attempted  to  construct  a  "realistic"  airline 
routing  model  —  one  that  accounted  for  indivisibility 
problems  as  well  as  for  consumer  preferences  concerning 
the  time  of  day  they  travel.   The  result  was  that  a  single 
run  of  this  one  city-pair  market  simulation  took  over  half 
an  hour,  utilizing  the  entire  32  thousand  word  core  of  a 
Burroughs  5500  computer.   Since  the  complexity  of  the  problem 
tends  to  increase  geometrically  with  the  number  of  city 
pairs  examined,  any  model  which  accommodates  up  to  250  city 
pairs  must  make  simplifying  assumptions.   As  I  concluded 
later  in  a  work  based  on  that  disseration, 

"The  utilization  of  scheduling  models... to 
appraise  airline  efficiency  awaits  the  develop- 
ment of  technically  superior,  operational  programs. 
But  just  as  importantly,  much  work  needs  to  be 
done  in  the  formulation  and  testing  of  behavioral 
assumptions,  for  only  then  can  we  place  a  great 
deal  of  confidence  in  our  results. "£/ 

In  terms  of  the  Lockheed  model's  specific  assumptions 
(as  they  relate  to  the  question  of  uneconomic  flight  seg- 
ments) ,  the  cost  issues  are  perhaps  the  most  important. 
While  the  simulation  bases  its  decisions  to  add  route 
segments  on  "marginal  costs,"  included  in  these  marginal 
costs  are  depreciation  expenses  (ATA  study,  p.  5) .   The 
reason  is  that  the  simulation  "purchases"  aircraft  to  assign 
to  the  routes  brought  into  the  system.   During  off-peak 
hours,  the  relevant  (opportunity)  cost  of  equipment  may  well 
be  zero  and  thus  inclusion  of  depreciation  in  the  decision 
calculus  tends  to  eliminate  some  routes  that  might  well  be  . 
served  by  a  profit-maximizing  air  carrier.   Certainly,  we 
observe  a  tendency  today  for  "marginal"  routes  to  be  served 
during  off-peak  hours.   A  similar  overestimation  of  costs 
on  "marginal"  routes  may  obtain  when  aircraft  have  to  be 
"positioned"  to  meet  the  daily  cycle,  for  maintenance,  and 
for  other  purposes. 

1/   James  C.  Miller  III,  Scheduling  and  Airline 
Efficiency  (Charlottesville:  Department  of  Economics, 
University  of  Virginia,  1969) . 

2/   James  C.  Miller  III,  "A  Time-of-Day  Model  for 
Aircraft  Scheduling,"  Transportation  Science  (August  1972), 
p.  243. 


386 


-  4  - 

On  the  revenue  side,  there  is  likewise  a  problem 
of  allocation.   As  is  well  known,  carriers  are  perfectly 
willing  to  engage  in  the  practice  of  scheduling  "feeder" 
routes,  even  though  the  conventionally-apportioned  costs 
of  such  routes  may  fall  short  of  the  revenues  conventionally 
attributed  to  them.   The  reason  is  that  many  feeder  passengers 
connect  to  other  flights  of  the  same  carrier  on  which  pro- 
fits would  be  recorded.   In  other  words,  the  carrier  earns 
more  money  by  scheduling  allegedly  uneconomic  services. 
This  is  not  to  suggest  that  there  is  cross-subsidization 
of  routes:   merely,  the  conventionally  recorded  revenue/ 
cost  margins  do  not  reflect  the  relevant  revenue/cost 
margins  (i.e.,  those  perceived  by  the  carrier).   While  the 
sequential  mapping  of  flights  accomplished  by  the  model  takes 
into  account  some  of  this  phenomenon,  it  may  not  accomodate 
it  all  and  therefore  may  identify  many  routes  as  uneconomic 
which  a  profit-maximizing  carrier  would  choose  to  operate. 

Finally,  as  will  be  stressed  in  the  next  section,  the 
model  is  incapable  of  simulating  competition.   It  is 
designed  for  an  analysis  of  a  single  firm.   The  model  can 
simulate  the  reaction  of  rivals  with  what  appears  to  be 
either  of  two  extreme  assumptions  (at  the  option  of  the 
user):   (a)  completely  passive  behavior  (i.e.,  rival  firms 
make  no  change  in  their  scheduling  plans  when  the  initiating 
carrier  makes  changes) ,  and  (b)  proportional  market  shares 
(i.e.,  rival  firms  react  to  any  schedule  change  so  as  to 
maintain  a  fixed  market  share) .   Under  the  second  assump- 
tion, the  result  is  clearly  a  price-regulated  monopoly 
solution  in  each  market. 1/   Under  conditions  where  there  is 
no  rival  Tas  must  be  the  case  in  the  analysis  performed 
for  ATA),  the  same  (regulated-monopoly)  result  obtains. 

ATA's  Interpreation  of  the  Simulation 

The  interpretation  the  ATA  has  placed  on  the 
simulation  excessively  overstates  the  extent  of  route 
abandonments  that  might  take  place  under  deregulation. 
As  mentioned  above,  the  model  is  capable  of  simulating 
price-regulated  monopoly,  but  not  free  and  open  competition . 2/ 

1/   See  George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C.  Miller  III, 
Economic  Regulation  of  Domestic  Air  Transport:  Theory  and 
Policy  (Washington:  The  Brookings  Institution,  1974), 
Chapter  IV. 

2/  This,  interestingly,  contradicts  the  usual  industry 
assessment  that  the  result  of  deregulation  would  be  excess 
(not  insufficient)  competition. 


387 


At  best  the  model  can  identify  uneconomic  routes  —  and, 
as  I  have  indicated,  there  is  reason  to  believe  that  the 
model  tends  to  overstate  these. 

A  better  idea  of  what  the  simulation  .u'compliGhes 
can  be  obtained  by  referring  to  the  attached  figure, 
adapted  from  Figure  8  of  the  ATA  study.   As  shown,  under 
the  prices  prevailing  in  1973,  a  nation-wide  (price- 
regulated)  monopoly  air  carrier  (or  a  perfectly  administered 
price-regulated  airline  cartel)  would  schedule  2,500  flights 
daily,  would  realize  average  load  factors  of  81.6  percent, 
and  would  earn  net  revenue  of  $5.5  million  per  day  (see 
also  ATA  study,  p.  7).   If  all  fares  were  reduced  (the 
same  percentage) ,  the  monopoly  level  of  flights  and  earnings 
would  fall,  but  average  load  factors  would  increase  (reference 
curves  labeled  "-10%"  and  "-20%").   These  levels  of  opera- 
tions ATA  contrasts  with  1973  regulated  operations  of 
approximately  7,300  daily  flights,  a  system-wide  average 
load  factor  of  55.7  percent,  and  approximately  $1.1  million 
in  daily  net  earnings. V  If  there  were  deregulation,  accord- 
ing to  the  ATA,  the  model  would  indicate  a  deletion  of 
approximately  4,800  daily  flights  based  on  a  1973  level  of 
operations.   With  a  fare  reduction  of  10  percent,  approxi- 
mately 5,130  flights  would  be  eliminated;  and  with  a  20 
percent  fare  reduction  approximately  5,322  flights  would  be 
dropped.   The  ATA  also  concludes  that  in  eliminating  the 
flights  the  industry  would  abandon  372  non-stop  markets 
at  1973  fares,  471  non-stop  markets  at  a  10  percent  fare 
decrease,  and  564  non-stop  markets  at  a  20  percent  fare 
decrease  (ATA  study,  p.  7). 

The  logic  of  ATA's  assumption  of  a  price-regulated 
monopoly  outcome  under  deregulation  can  be  tested  with 
common  sense.   An  earnings  level  of  $5.5  million  per  day 
(1973  fares)  translates  into  yearly  earnings  of  approxi- 
mately $2,008  million.   On  the  basis  of  1973  total  domestic 
trunkline  investment  of  $8,051  million,  this  translates 
into  a  rate  of  return  on  investment  (ROI)  of  approximately 
25  percent.!/  Presumably,  however,  in  equilibrium,  the 


1/  The  1973  levels  of  flights  and  earnings  are 
approximate  since  they  are  read  from  the  figure;  the  ATA 
does  not  present  the  data. 

2/  The  ATA  study  is  not  clear  whether  these 
earnings  are  profits  before  interest  payments  on  long- 
term  debt  and  before  taxes,  after  interest  payments  on 
long-term  debt  but  before  taxea,  or  before  interest  pay- 
ments on  long-term  debt  but  after  taxes.   Comparisons  of 
ROI  would  of  course  depend  on  the  definition  used. 


388 


389 


-  7  - 

industry  would  reduce  its  investment  base  consonant  with 
the  lower  level  of  operations.   Assuming  a  proportional 
reduction,  the  (1973)  investment  base  would  be  approxi- 
mately $2,757  million,  indicating  a  ROI  of  api)roximatcly 
73  percent.   To  presume  that  under  conditions  of  free  entry 
a  73  percent  ROI  would  not  attract  new  entrants  is  pre- 
posterous! 

What  would  likely  occur  under  deregulation  can  be 
inferred  from  the  graph.   First,  assuming  for  the  sake 
of  argument  that  1973  fares  prevailed  and  that  cost  levels 
did  not  change,  increased  scheduling  would  occur  until 
load  factors  had  been  driven  down  to  approximately  55 
percent  —  the  1973  break-even  level.   At  that  point  there 
would  be  approximately  7,400  flights  daily  and  the  industry's 
daily  earnings  would  be  approximately  $1.0  million.   Now, 
assuming  again  that  costs  did  not  change,  on  the  basis  of 
my  work  with  George  Douglas,  1^/  one  might  predict  that 
average  fares  (or  average  yield)  would  decrease  approxi- 
mately 16  percent,  raising  the  break-even  load  factor  to 
approximately  65  percent.   As  can  be  inferred  from  the  figure 
(see  added  straight  line  connected  to  "L.F.  =  75%"  point 
on  1973  curve  )  ,  the  result  would  be  a  decrease  in  scheduling 
from  approximately  7,300  flights  per  day  to  approximately 
6,800  flights  per  day. 2/  Using  ATA's  1973  route  abandonment 
figure  of  372  and  applying  a  rule  of  proportionality,  this 
\;ould  imply  the  abandonment  of  approximately  39  non-stop 
city-pair  markets.    However,  any  decrease  in  costs  under 
deregulation  (less  circuitous  routings,  greater  management 
efficiency,  et  cetera)  would  shift  all  of  the  curves  to  the 
right.   Depending  on  the  degree  of  efficiency  gains,  the 
result  might  well  be  an  increase  in  total  scheduling  and 
an  increase  in  the  number  of  city-pair  markets  served  under 
deregulation,  not  decreases. 

ATA's  Other  Analysis 

The  ATA  also  identifies  1,198  local  service  carrier 
routes  which  are  presently  receiving  subsidy  and  thus 
might  not  be  served  if  there  were  deregulation.   While 

_!/  Douglas  and  Miller,   ibid. 

2/   The  exact  position  of  this  line  cannot  be  ascer- 
tained without  access  to  the  simulation.   The  position 
shown  is  an  informed  judgement.   (It  must  slope  downward 
to  the  right  since,  with  lower  fares  and  more  passengers, 
scheduling  must  increase  in  order  to  maintain  the  same  load 
factor  level. ) 


390 


undoubtedly  some  of  these  routes  might  be  deleted  under 
deregulation,  it  would  be  a  mistake  to  conclude  that  under 
deregulation  all,  or  even  a  substantial  part,  of  them  would 
receive  no  air  service. 

First,  the  CAB's  subsidy  program  (in  theory  nt  least) 
covers  all  the  losses  the  local  service  carriers  incur  in 
serving  these  routes.   Deregulation  does  not  necessarily 
imply  elimination  of  the  subsidy  program. V  With  continued 
subsidy  there  is  little  reason  to  believe  that  carriers 
would  not  willingly  serve  the  substantial  majority  of  these 
markets.  2^/ 

Second,  the  combination  of  subsidy  and  regulation  has 
tended  to  escalate  the  costs  of  the  local  service  carriers. 
An  example  with  which  I  am  familiar  illustrates.   In  1973 
Texas  International  Airways,  a  local  service  carrier, 
applied  to  the  CAB  to  delete  service  at  College  Station, 
Texas.   Reason?   Texas  International  was  losing  its  market 
to  a  small  College  Station-based  commuter,  Davis  Airlines. 
Both  were  offering  service  to  Dallas  and  to  Houston.   Both 
charged  $27  to  Dallas,  while  Davis's  $20  rate  to  Houston 
was  a  dollar  less  than  Texas  International's.   But  while 
Davis  was  making  money  at  these  rates,  the  Board  was  forced 
to  conclude  that  Texas  International  was  losing  $41  per 
enplaned  passenger. V  In  short   while  Davis's  cost  per 
passenger  was  in  the  neighborhood  of  $20-$27,  Texas 
International's  cost  was  in  the  neighborhood  of  $62-$68. 
Thus,  under  deregulation  the  local  service  carriers  might 
well  become  more  efficient  and  thus  be  able  to  serve  some 
markets  now  receiving  Federal  support  without  the  need  of 
subsidy. 

Third,  even  if  local  service  carriers  abandoned 
these  markets  one  must  not  overlook  the  outstanding  success 
of  the  (unregulated)  commuter  airlines  in  providing  service 
to  small  communities  and  serving  low-density  markets. 
According  to  the  commuter  airlines'  trade  association, 131 
commuter  airlines  listed  schedules  in  the  October  1,  1974 
issue  of  the  Official  Airline  Guide.   Of  the  665  airports 

"y   The  regulatory  reform  proposals  the  Administration 
presently  has  under  review  do  not  alter  the  Board's  subsidy 
program. 

2/   Indeed,  if  the  subsidy  program  were  improved,  then 
many  more  routes  might  receive  service  for  the  same  cost  to 
the  Federal  Government.  [See  George  C.  Eads,  The  Local  Service 
Airline  Experiment  (Washington:  The  Brookings  Institution, 
1972).] 

3/  See  CAB  Order  73-4-49  (April  10,  1973). 


391 


-  9  - 

analyzed,  210  (31.6  percent)  wera  served  exclusively  by 
commuter  airlines;  256  (38.5  percent)  were  served  ex- 
clusively by  CAB-certif icated  airlines;  and  199  (29.9 
percent)  were  served  jointly  by  certificated  and  commuter 
airlines.   In  serving  a  total  of  409  airports,  the  commuter 
airlines  served  over  1,530  city-pair  markets. V  These 
unregulated  carriers  have  accomplished  this  record  despite 
constraints  on  the  size  of  aircraft  they  may  fly.2_/  One 
must  conclude  that  of  local  service  markets  that  were 
abandoned  under  deregulation,  most  of  them  would  be  picked 
up  by  commuter  carriers. 

The  ATA  also  presents  an  analysis  of  flight  segment 
load  factors  and  concludes  that  raising  system  load 
factors  from  55.7  percent  to  60  percent  would  have  required 
the  elimination  of  144,000  (or  37  percent  of  all)  flights 
during  the  month  of  August  1973, and  raising  average  load 
factors  to  65  percent  would  have  required  the  elimination 
of  226,000  flights  (ATA  study,  Figure  11). 

This  analysis  is  grossly  misleading.   First,  it  assumes 
that  passengers  on  deleted  (low-load  factor)  flights 
are  lost  entirely.   In  markets  where  flights  are  reduced 
(but  not  eliminated) ,  many  of  these  passengers  would  travel 
on  the  remaining  flights;  although  this  would  raise  the 
system  average  load  factor,  the  ATA  analysis  ignores  the 
effect.   Second,  an  increase  in  load  factors  would  pre- 
sumably be  accompanied  by  a  fare  reduction.   Although  waiting 
time  would  increase,  the  full  cost  of  service  (i.e.,  ticket 
price  plus  cost  of  waiting)  would  diminish.   This  would 
bring  forth  additional  passengers  and  raise  load  factors  — 
another  important  effect  the  ATA  analysis  ignores.   Finally, 
as  mentioned  before,  deregulation  may  be  expected  to  increase 
carrier  efficiency  (lowering  costs)  so  that  even  with  the 
increased  system  average  load  factor  the  amount  of 
scheduling  might  actually  increase. 


1/   National  Air  Transportation  Association,  "AirTran 
News" (April  1975),  p.  16. 

2/  CAB  Part  298  regulations  limit  commuters  to 
operating  aircraft  of  not  more  than  30  passengers  and  not 
more  than  7,500  pounds  payload.   (Exceptions  to  these 
limitations  are  occasionally  granted  on  a  case-by-case 
basis.  ) 


392 


-  10  - 

The  Issue  of  Cross-Subsidy 

Underpinning  the  ATA's  conclusion  that  there  would 
be  significant  abandonment  of  service  is  the  assumption 
that  the  industry  is  presently  characterized  by  a 
significant  degree  of  cross-subsidy.   Such  an  assumption 
is  inappropriate.   First,  the  work  Douglas,  I,  and  some 
others  have  done  suggests  that  the  extent  of  cross-subsidy 
presently  existing  is  miniscule.   For  example,  the  major 
alleged  source  of  cross-subsidy  is  in  the  structure  of 
fares  with  respect  to  distance  (i.e.,  long-haul  flights 
subsidize  short-haul  flights) .   However,  taking  into 
account  the  fact  that  directly  subsidized  markets  are 
predominantly  short-haul  and  the  "feeder"  characteristic 
of  scheduling  described  above,  average  load  factors  show 
a  monotonic  decrease  with  respect  to  distance,  consistent 
with  the  argument  that  carriers,  through  non-price  competi- 
tion, configure  scheduling  so  as  to  approximate  break  even, 
whatever  the  distance.   Second,  I  understand  from  experts 
on  CAB  certificates  that  a  large  proportion  of  the  routes 
served  by  trunk  carriers  which  are  alleged  to  be  uneconomic 
are  capable  of  being  abandoned  without  CAB  approval.   It  is 
unreasonable  to  assume  that  carrier  management  views  their 
respective  firms  as  eleemosynary  institutions.   If  they  do, 
then  surely  their  stockholderE  should  be  made  aware  of 
this  fact! 

To  the  extent  that  cross-subsidy  does  obtain,  on 
economic  efficiency  grounds  it  ought  to  be  eliminated.!/ 
There  is  no  such  thing  as  a  "free"  lunch.   If  some  un- 
economic services  are  being  provided,  this  means  that 
travelers  on  "profitable"  routes  are  paying  excessive 
fares.   Besides  the  efficiency  question,  there  is  an 
equity  problem.   In  the  words  of  Richard  Caves,  "there  is 
no  reason  why  impoverished  grandmothers  flying   from  New 
York  to  Los  Angeles  should  be  the  ones  to  subsidize  well- 
off  businessmen  traveling  between  small  towns.  "2^/  Moreover, 
cross -subsidy  is  a  hiaden  subsidy.   It  would  appear  that 
from  the  standpoint  of  economic  efficiency,  equity,  and 
rational  decision  making,  the  subsidy  should  be  made  explicit. 


1/  Importantly,  the  CAB  has  concluded  that  cross- 
subsidy  is  contrary  to  the  public  interest  and  has  taken 
steps  to  eliminate  whatever  remains.   See  CAB  Order  73-3-82 
(March  18,  1974) . 

2/  Richard  E.  Caves,  Air  Transport  and  Its  Regulators; 
An  Industry  Study  (Cambridge:  Harvard  University  Press, 
1962),  p.  436. 


393 


-  11  - 

If  it  is  in  the  national  interest  to  provide  service 

that  otherwise  would  not  be  provided,  then  there  should 

be  a  Federal  direct  subsidy.   If  the  interest  is  "regional", 

then  perhaps  States  should  defray  the  costs;  if  the  interest 

is  purely  local,  then  communities  should  provide  the  support. 

Conclusions 

While  the  ATA  has  made  a  bold  attempt  to  identify 
the  services  that  might  be  abandoned  under  deregulation, 
its  analysis  is  grossly  wide  of  the  mark.   First, 
simulation  models,  calibrated  on  industry  performance 
under  regulation,  have  limited  usefulness  in  predicting 
outcomes  under  deregulation.   The  particular  model  utilized 
by  the  ATA,  while  reoutable,  incorporates  several  assump- 
tions that  may  lead  to  an  overstatement  of  uneconomic  routes . 
Second,  the  ATA  has  misinterpreted  what  the  model  accomplishes. 
While  the  ATA  claims  the  model  simulates  competition  it 
does  nothing  of  the  sort;  rather,  it  simulates  a  price- 
regulated  monopolist.   Third,  to  the  degree  the  model's 
outcome  can  be  interpreted,  it  suggests  that,  given  the 
existing  cost  level,  deregulation  would  lead  to  only  a  minor 
decrease  in  service;  efficiency  gains  under  deregulation 
might  well  result  in  more,  rather  than  less,  service.   Fourth, 
while  under  deregulation  some  city  pairs  might  lose  service 
by  the  certificated  (trunk  and  local  service)  carriers, 
there  is  good  reason  to  believe  that  commuter-type  (scheduled) 
airlines  would  provide  replacement  service. 

Finally,  the  argument  that  under  deregulation  city  pairs 
would  lose  service  assumes  that  there  exists  a  considerable 
degree  of  cross-subsidy.   Theory  and  evidonco  does  not 
support  this  view,  and  in  any  event  the  Board  has  enunciated 
a  policy  of  purging  it  from  the  system.   Cross-subsidy  is 
economically  inefficient,  inequitable,  and,  given  its 
hidden  nature,  tends  to  lead  to  inefficient  political 
decision  making.   To  the  degree  there  is  a  public  interest 
in  providing  services  that  otherwise  would  be  abandoned, 
such  support  should  come  directly  from  the  government. 


394 


EXECUTIVE  OFFICE   OF  THE  PRESIDENT 

COUNCIL  ON  WAGE  AND  PRICE  STABILITY 

WASHINGTON,  D.C.   20506 


May  1,  1975 


Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy 
Chairman,  Subconunittee  on 

Administrative  Practice 

eund  Procedure 
Committee  on  Government  Operations 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,  D.  C.   20510 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy: 

As  requested  by  your  letter  of  April  28, 
I  have  had  my  staff  analyze  the  Air  Transport  Asso- 
ciation Study  "Consequences  of  Deregulation  of 
Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry."   I  am  attaching 
two  staff  memos  by  George  Eads  which  contain  his 
reaction  to  the  ATA  analysis.   As  you  will  see, 
Mr.  Eads  concludes  that  the  ATA  simulation  provides 
no  useful  information  about  the  likely  effects  of 
"deregulation"  since  the  system  being  simulated  by 
the  ATA  bears  no  resemblance  to  the  current  U.S.  air 
transport  system.   Specifically,  the  model  simulates 
the  behavior  of  monopolist;  we  currently  have  a  system 
with  multiple  competitors. 

I  hope  this  material  will  be  of  assistance 
to  you. 

Sincerely, 


CuJL^(2su^ 


Albert  Rees 
Director 


Enclosures 


395 


eXECUTIVE  OFFICE   OF  TME  PRESIDENT 

CXHiNCIL  ON  WAGE  AND  PRICE  STABILITY 

WASHINGTON,  D.C.   30S06 


April  29,  1975 


MEMORANDUM  TO:    Albert  Rees,  Director 

Council  on  Wage  and  Price  Stability 

FROM:  George  Eads,  Assistant  Director    ju.t- 

Government  Operations  and  Research 

SUBJECT:  Analysis  of  the  ATA  Simulation  Model: 

"Consequences  of  Deregulation  of  the 
Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry" 

In  drafting  legislation  to  reform  economic  regu- 
lation of  the  airline  industry,  we  in  the  Administration 
have  always  been  aware  that  a  balance  must  be  struck  between 
preserving  those  features  of  the  current  system  that  are 
necessary  to  protect  the  public  interest  while  modifying 
those  which  do  not.   We  welcome  the  input  of  the  Air  Trans- 
port Association.   We  believe  that  they  provide  a  perspective 
that  needs  presenting. 

However,  the  current  ATA  effort  titled  "Consequences 
of  Deregulation  of  the  Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry"  does 
nothing  to  aid  us  in  settling  these  admittedly  complex  issues. 
It  raises,  as  though  they  were  novel,  analytical  issues  that 
have  long  been  settled  as  the  result  of  extensive  study, 
evidentiary  hearing,  and  cross-examination.   In  particular, 
it  raises  the  specter  of  wholesale  route  abandonment  and 
flight  curtailment  as  a  result  of  the  elimination  of  "cross- 
subsidy,"  a  concept  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  itself 
discredited  as  a  workable  feature  of  the  current  air  trans- 
port system  in  its  decision  in  Phase  9  of  the  Domestic 
Passenger  Fare  Investigation.   ATA  resurrects  this  argument 
m  the  context  of  an  extremely  sophisticated  simulation  of 
what  purports  to  be  the  current  air  transport  network. 
However,  as  I  will  explain,  the  system  being  simulated  is 
not  the  current  air  transport  system  but  one  which  the 
Congress  discarded  as  an  option  when  it  passed  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Act  of  1938. 

The  system  being  simulated  is  one  in  which  there 
is  a  single  monopoly  airline,  subject  to  price  regulation 
by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  free  to  pick  and  choose 
which  routes  to  enter  and  exit,  and  totally  protected  from 


396 


-  2 


entr>'  by  any  other  competitor.   The  model  indicates  that 
this  monopolist,  if  free  to  maximize  his  dollar  profits 
at  this  fixed  fare  level,  will  do  so  by  dropping  certain 
routes  entirely  and  by  cutting  back  flights  on  other 
routes,  thereby  raising  his  average  load  factor  substantially. 
The  profits  that  this  monopolist  could  earn  under  such  a 
system  would  indeed  be  enormous  —  approximately  $2  billion 
during  the  simulation  year  (1973)  . 

This  result  is  by  no  means  a  novel  one.   The 
analytical  proof  was  demonstrated  in  an  article  by 
Professor  White  of  Princeton  University  titled  "Quality 
Variation  When  Prices  Are  Regulated"   (Bell  Journal, 
Autumn  1972).   In  a  paper  delivered  in  the  Fall  of  1972 
at  a  Brookings  Conference,  I  presented  evidence  to  confirm 
the  proposition  that  load  factors  in  monopoly  markets  are 
indeed  higher  than  load  factors  in  competitive  markets 
provided  prices  are  regulated  but  scheduling  is  not.   The 
ATA  simulation  provides  an  indication  of  what  the  magnitude 
of  such  a  load  factor  increase  might  be  in  such  an  idealized 
system  and  how  profi^^able  the  monopolist  would  find  this 
state  of  affairs.   It  conclusively  demonstrates  that  such 
a  scheme  of  regulation  —  monopoly  with  prices  regulated, 
entry  (save  for  the  monopolist)  blockaded,  and  exit  by  the 
monopolist  totally  free  —  is  undesirable  public  policy. 

The  simulation  also  shows  the  potential  magnitude 
of  the  profits  that  might  be  available  to  support  cross- 
subsidization  by  such  a  monopolist  —  approximately  $1.6 
billion  —  in  the  event  that  the  CAB  could  indeed  force 
him  to  serve  routes  that  the  model  indicates  are  in  some 
sense  unprofitable.   (I  would  note  that  the  apparent 
unprof itability  of  many  routes  is  an  artifact  of  the 
simulation.   More  on  this  below.)   However,  as  the  CAB 
found  in  the  recent  New  England  Service  Investigation, 
neither  the  Board  nor  any  other  regulatory  agency  can 
compel  an  unwilling  carrier  to  provide  adequate,  responsive, 
efficient,  money-losing  service  where  the  carrier  can 
effectively  lower  its  costs  by  degrading  the  quality  of 
the  service  (See  Board  Order  74-7-70,  pp.  10-11).   The 
entire  history  of  the  local  service  airline  subsidy  program 
and  the  experience  of  rail  passenger  service  in  this  country 
over  the  last  half-century  provides  ample  additional  evidence 
of  the  validity  of  this  finding. 


397 


This  is  what  the  simulation  is.   What  is  it  not? 
Most  specifically,  it  is  not  a  simulation  of  the  airline 
system  we  have  in  the  United  States  at  this  time.   Indeed, 
the  closest  domestic  analog  would  appear  to  be  the  Bell 
System.   The  FCC,  therefore,  might  find  the  model  useful 
in  its  struggle  to  understand  the  consequences  of  allowing 
competition  in  this  system.   However,  this  Nation's  airline 
system  is  not  a  monopoly,  but  is  composed  of  many  carriers. 
The  CAB  regulates  maximum  and  minimum  fares,  controls 
entry  into  new  city-pair  markets  and  exit  from  these  city- 
pair  markets.   With  regard  to  entry  and  exit,  however, 
the  cab's  effective  authority  over  nonstop  service  in 
city-pair  markets  is  quite  limited.   Carriers  currently 
have  —  and  exercise  --  a  great  deal  of  freedom  to  enter 
or  exit  from  a  large  variety  of  markets  under  the  broad 
authority  conferred  upon  them  by  their  operating  certifi- 
cates.  Furthermore,  since  the  Board  cannot  control  the 
number  of  flights  a  carrier  offers  in  a  particular  city- 
pair  market,  carriers  are  free  to  reduce  schedules  sub- 
stantially from  their  current  levels  without  Board 
approval.   The  fact  that  they  currently  operate  what, 
according  to  the  model,  are  vast  numbers  of  unprofitable 
flights  and  routes  —  not  because  of  CAB  compulsion  but 
because  they  find  it  is  in  their  best  economic  interest 
to  do  so  —  only  casts  further  doubt  upon  the  credibility 
of  the  ATA  results. 

We  have  it  on  the  word  of  the  CAB  (see  its 
Phase  9  opinion  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation) 
that  this  scheduling  competition,  given  fixed  price,  tends 
substantially  to  eliminate  excess  profits  on  competitive 
routes  by  driving  load  factors  down  to  the  breakeven  level 
(where  breakeven  is  defined  to  include  a  normal  rate  of 
return).   Certain  major  carriers  --  principally,  TWA, 
American,  and  United  --  have  argued  that  this  scheduling 
competition  is  so  fierce  that  it  does  more  than  eliminate 
excess  profits  on  these  competitive  routes.   According  to 
these  carriers,  such  practices  produce  actual  losses 
absent  capacity  agreements  which  would  control  this  level 
of  competition.   A  CAB  Administrative  Law  Judge  recently 
found  this  latter  contention  to  be  contrary  to  fact  in 
ruling  against  such  agreements.   (See  Initial  Decision 
of  Administrative  Law  Judge  E.  Robert  Seaver,  Capacity 
Reduction  Agreements  Case,  Docket  22908,  served  November  18, 
1974.) 


398 


4  - 


The  crucial  point  to  understand  is  that  if 
scheduling  competition  tends  sharply  to  limit  the  level 
of  excess  profits  that  a  competitive  airline  system 
generates,  the  ability  of  this  system  to  support  a  large 
amount  of  unprofitable  service  is  substantially  impaired. 
Thus,  the  ability  of  the  airline  industry  to  operate  in 
a  competitive  environment  —  competitive  as  to  schedules, 
at  least  —  while  avoiding  the  staggering  level  of  losses 
that  the  ATA  simulation  predicts  should  today  be  occurring 
demonstrates  conclusively  that  the  simulation  is  faulty 
both  as  a  description  of  current  reality  and  as  a  predic- 
tion of  future  behavior. 

What  of  the  apparently  "unprofitable"  routes 
and  flights  that  the  model  finds?   I  would  suggest  that, 
given  the  way  the  current  domestic  air  transport  system 
actually  operates,  these  are  more  likely  artifacts  of  the 
simulation  than  reflections  of  reality.   In  performing 
any  simulation  of  this  sort,  the  designer  of  the  model 
must  make  many  simplifying  assumptions.   In  the  real  world, 
many  costs  are  common  to  more  than  one  flight  or  more  than 
one  route,  yet  the  simulation  demands  that  an  artificial 
allocation  be  made.   Furthermore,  certain  routes  generate 
traffic  for  the  system  as  a  whole,  yet  no  means  exists  to 
properly  allocate  the  revenues  produced  by  this  traffic 
to  these  routes.   Thus,  certain  routes  appear  to  be  more 
profitable  than  they  are  in  reality;  others  appear  to  be 
losing  money  when  they,  in  fact,  are  not.   This  is  not 
the  fault  of  the  simulation  —  arbitrary  assumptions  are 
necessary  if  the  simulation  is  to  be  made  to  work.   But 
that  is  why  we  call  the  exercise  a  "simulation."   A 
knowledgeable  airline  scheduler  familiar  with  the  opera- 
tional characteristics  of  his  particular  system  would 
recognize  these  anomolies  and  disregard  them.   A  person 
unfamiliar  with  the  system  —  or  a  computer  mechanically 
adding  up  "profits"  and  "losses"  —  will  not.   That  is 
why  in  the  real  world,  airline  scheduling  is  performed  not 
by  computers  employing  simulation  models,  but  by  skilled 
and  experienced  men  who  use  such  tools  as  computers  and 
simulation  models  merely  as  initial  inputs  into  the  process. 

This  is  not  to  say  that  all  the  loss  markets 
and  flights  indicated  by  the  ATA  simulation  are,  in  reality, 
profitable.   Under  a  less  regulated  system  where  both  entry 
and  exit  were  freer,  certain  flights  and  certain  cities 
would  be  dropped  by  the  carriers  currently  providing  them. 
After  all,  the  current  route  system  is  a  somewhat  crazy 
patchwork  that  originated  in  the  days  when  the  DC-3  was 


399 


the  Nation's  largest  and  most  efficient  airliner.   This 
is  not  to  say,  however,  that  all  these  cities  that  would 
be  dropped  would  lose  all  airline  service.   Certain  nonstop 
flights  would  be  downgraded  to  one-stop.   Certain  routes 
would  fit  better  into  the  route  systems  of  carriers  other 
than  those  currently  providing  service  over  them.   Certain 
others  would  be  picked  up  by  commuter  carriers  whose 
specialized  operations  and  smaller  aircraft  allow  them 
to  tailor  service  closely  to  the  needs  of  the  small 
communities . 

But  when  all  this  had  happened,  some  city-pairs 
would  indeed  have  service  reduced  and  others  might  well 
lose  all  service.   However,  this  would  not  occur  because 
of  the  elimination  of  cross-subsidy  —  cross-subsidy  does 
not  now  exist  to  any  substantial  degree  —  but  would 
result  from  a  bidding  down  of  fares.   As  fares  fell,  the 
breakeven  load  factors  would  increase.   As  the  CAB  found 
in  Phase  6B  of  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation, 
this  vtpuld  induce  carriers  to  reduce  the  number  of  flights 
they  offer,  thereby  raising  actual  load  factors.   In  some 
cases,  this  new  higher  breakeven  factor  might  be  unsustain- 
ahly   high,  rendering  nonstop  service  on  that  particular 
segment  impossible.   In  this  latter  case,  if  it  were 
determined  that  the  public  interest  demanded  a  continuation 
of  service,  public  subsidies  should  be  voted.   These  subsidies 
would,  however,  need  to  be  nowhere  near  the  one  billion  dollars 
per  year  level  mentioned  by  the  ATA  document. 


400 


eXECUTIVE  OFFICE    OF  THE  PRESIDENT 

COUNCIL  ON  WAGE  AND  PRICE  STABILITY 

WASHINGTON.  D.C.    20506 


May  1,  1975 


MEMORANDUM  FOR:     Albert  Rees,  Director,  Council  on 
Wage  sind  Price  Stability 

FROM:  George  Eads,  Assistant  Director    px.- 

Government  Operations  and  Research  ' 

SUBJECT:  Further  Analysis  of  the  ATA  Simulation 

Model:   "Consequences  of  Regulation  of 
Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry" 


Since  sending  you  my  memorandum  of  April  29,  I 
have  continued  to  analyze  the  ATA  simulation  results  in 
more  detail.   In  particular,  I  have  had  my  staff  focus  on 
the  results  as  they  apply  to  one  state  —  Arizona.   I  made 
this  choice  because,  having  grown  up  in  Arizona,  I  am  quite 
familiar  with  the  pattern  of  air  service  that  exists  there. 

Figure  1  is  taken  frcsn  the  ATA  report  and  shows 
the  routes  which  would  "lose"  service  under  "deregulation." 
Table  1  shows  the  reduction  in  service  predicted  by  the 
model  on  those  Arizona  routes  that  would  be  retained. 

The  first  thing  that  should  be  noted  about 
Figure  1  is  that  it  includes  (as  do  all  of  the  ATA  state 
maps)  the  subsidized  services  currently  provided  by  the 
regional  (i..e. ,  "local  service")  carriers.   The  implica- 
tion is  conveyed  that  these  services  would  be  lost  under 
■deregulation."   This  is  clearly  a  false  issue  calculated 
to  raise  scare  headlines.   We  have  made  it  very  clear  that 
amy  Administration  bill  will  not  propose  an  end  to  the 
current  subsidy  program.   This  is  not  to  say  that  con- 
siderable improvement  could  not  be  made  in  the  program. 
Both  the  CAB  (in  its  study  Service  To  S^.all  Communities) 
and  I  (in  my  Brookings  book  The  Local  Service  Airline 
Experiment)  have  shown  how  better  service  could  be  provided 
at  lower  cost  to  the  Government  by  major  changes  in  the 
way  the  current  subsidy  program  is  run.   The  relevant 
point,  however,  is  that  none  of  this  service  will  be  in 
any  danger  from  "deregulation." 


401 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


402 


Ubie  I 


COMPARISON  OF  NON-STOP  SCHEDULED  SERVICES 
1973  Actual  vs.  Simulated  for  Profit  Maximization 


Fli^ta  Per  Day  -  Both  Directions 


NOTE:       This  comparison  does  not  include  city- pairs  in  which  profit 
maximization  would  result  in  no  service,  and  it  does  not 
indicate  the  public  service  consequences  of  elimination  of 
adequate  frequencies  to  meet  peak  demand. 


Average  Daily  Services  Ar.signed 
Non-Stop  at 

Services  Maximum  Earnings 

(1973  Actual)  (Simulation) 


ARIZONA 
Between: 
Fboenix 


and: 

-  Albuquerque,  N. M.  4 

-  AmarUlo,  Texas  2 

-  Chicago,  m.  18 
.  Dallas.  Texas  17 

-  Denver.  Colo.  18 

-  El  Paso,  Texas  4 

-  Houston.  Texas  1 

-  Kansas  City,  Mo.  3 

-  Las  Vegas.  Nev,  14 

-  Loa  Angeles,  Calif,  29 
-    -  Minneapolis/St.   Paul,   Minn.        2 

-  New  York,  N.Y.  6 

-  Oklahoma  City,  Okla.  4 

-  Portland.  Ore.  2 

-  St.  Louis,  Mo.  7 

-  San  Antonio,  Texas  2 

-  San  Francisco.  Calif.  9 

-  Washington.  D.C.  4 


and: 

-  Chicago,  m. 

9 

-  Dallas.  Texas 

8 

. .  -  Loa  Angeles.  Calif. 

10 

-  San  Francisco.  Calif. 

4 

403 


This  leaves  seven  routes  that  are  identified 
as  "unprofitable."   These  are  Phoenix-Palm  Springs, 
Phoenix-San  Diego,  Phoenix-Tucson,  Tucson-El  Paso, 
Tucson-Kansas  City,  Tucson-Palm  Springs,  and  Tucson- 
San  Diego. 

I  have  directed  Roger  Mallet  to  examine  the 
pattern  of  air  service  that  these  routes  received 
during  July  1973,  the  mid-point  of  the  year  the  ATA 
chose  to  simulate.   Appendix  A  lists  all  flights  in 
both  directions  together  with  the  flight  itineraries. 

As  you  can  see,  with  only  one  exception  (American 
Airlines  Flight  374  from  Tucson  to  San  Diego) ,  all 
flights  offered  during  July  1973  were  segments  of 
longer  flights.   They  are  thus,  subject  to  the  cost  and 
revenue  allocation  problems  I  mentioned  in  my  memo  of 
April  29.   This  means  that  any  indication  by  the  model 
of  "unprof itability"  needs  to  be  examined  very  carefully. 

Let  us  focus  particularly  on  the  Tucson-Phoenix 
segment.   During  July  1973  there  were  18  flights  per  day 
between  Phoenix  and  Tucson  and  17  flights  per  day  between 
Tucson  and  Phoenix.   (These  totals  do  not  include  four 
daily  nonstop  flights  in  each  direction  by  an  unsub- 
sidized  commuter  carrier  which  has  total  freedom  to 
enter  and  exit  the  market  at  will.)   All  of  those  35 
daily  flights  were  offered  as  segments  of  longer  flights. 
In  many  cases,  these  flights  clearly  were  "feed"  flights. 
For  example,  American  Airlines  Flight  177,  Boston- 
New  York/JFK-Phoenix-Tucson  is  clearly  operated  as  a 
means  of  providing  single-plane  service  to  both  cities 
from  the  East  Coast.   It  is  no  more  run  by  American 
solely  because  of  its  Phoenix-Tucson  segment  than  it 
is  because  of  its  Boston-New  York  segment  (which  I  am 
certain  is  "unprofitable"  judged  by  itself) . 

This  example  reflects  the  fact  that  airlines 
do  not  schedule  flights  on  a  city-pair  basis.   They  are 
scheduled   on  a  total  flight  basis.   That  is,  what  the 
scheduler  tries  to  achieve  is  a  situation  in  which  the 
revenues  attributable  to  a  particular  flight  equal   or 
exceed   the  costs  attributable  to  that  flight.   In 
deciding  whether  or  not  to  include  a  particular  segment 
(e.g.,  Tucson-El  Paso  segment  on  American's  Flight  116 
wTtn  an  itinerary  consisting  of  San  Francisco-Phoenix- 
Tucson-El  Paso-Chicago-Newark) ,  the  scheduler  decides 


404 


-  3 


what  additional  traffic  he  can  pick  up  by  including 
the  segment  (he  doesn't  particularly  care  whether  this 
is  local  Tucson-El  Paso  traffic  or  whether  it  travels 
beyond  El  Paso  —  it  is  the  revenue  he  is  concerned 
about)  and  what  additional  costs  American  will  incur 
by  serving  the  segment.   This  additional  cost  may  or 
may  not  be  related  to  what  the  CAB  terms  "direct 
operating  expense."   "Direct  operating  expense"  is 
merely  an  accounting  convention.   If  attributable 
revenues  exceed  attributable  costs,  the  segment  is 
included.   If  not,  it  is  deleted. 

Deleting  such  a  segment  on  a  given  flight 
would  only  require  CAB  approval  if  it  represented  the 
carrier's  only  service  at  either  of  the  two  cities 
under  authority  of  a  given  "route  segment."   It  is 
important  to  note  that  CAB  approval  often  is  not 
required  either  to  add  the  first  nonstop  or  delete  the 
last  nonstop  in  a  given  city-pair  market.   For  example, 
nothing  in  American  Airlines'  certificate  currently 
compels  it  to  offer  nonstop  service  in  any  of  the 
Arizona  city-pairs  mentioned  in  the  ATA  simulation. 
Indeed,  during  July  1973,  American  eliminated,  without 
seeking  CAB  approval,  the  Palm  Springs  segments  from 
Flights  159,  221,  and  622,  thus  ending  nonstop  service 
by  American  between  Palm  Springs,  on  the  one  hand,  and 
Phoenix  and  Tucson,  on  the  other. 

To  see  how  widespread  this  carrier  authority  to 
add  and  delete  service  currently  is,  I  had  Mike  Roach 
check  the  certificates  of  the  carriers  serving  the  Arizona 
markets.   He  informs  me  that,  perhaps  with  the  single  ex- 
ception of  Frontier's  Phoenix-Tucson  service,  the  carriers 
involved  are  currently  free  to  terminate  service  over  all 
the  indicated  segments.   In  other  words,  American,  under 
its  current  certificate,  has  no  obligation  to  provide 
service  in  any  of  the  six  city-pairs  where  it  currently 
is  certificated  (it  does  not  hold  a  certificate  allowing 
it  to  fly  between  Kansas  City  and  Tucson) . 

This  brings  me  to  my  final  point  —  service 
reductions  on  segments  that  the  ATA  model  predicts  would 
be  retained.   As  you  can  see,  in  many  cases,  the  hypo- 
thetical reductions  indeed  would  be  massive.   Chicago- 
Phoenix  service  would  be  cut  from  18  to  8  flights  per 
day.   Again  it  is  vital  to  be  clear  about  what  is  and 
is  not  being  simulated  by  the  ATA  model.   As  I  indicated 


405 


4  - 


in  my  April  29  memo,  the  ATA  model  simulates  the 
response  of  a  monopolist.   I  am  not  surprised  that  a 
monopolist,  if  free  to  drop  all  flights  he  didn't 
wish  to  offer,  and  protected  from  entry  by  other  car- 
riers, would  choose  substantially  to  curtail  service. 
He  might  even  drop  the  amount  of  service  that  the  ATA 
model  indicates. 

However,  the  current  air  transport  system  is 
not  a  monopoly.   It  is  a  competitive  system  where 
carriers  face  controlled  prices,  are  free  to  determine 
the  amount  of  service  they  wish  to  provide  at  these 
controlled  prices,  and  are  even  free  to  exit  from  many 
city-pairs  without  explicit  permission  of  the  CAB  if 
they  find  their  operations  unprofitable.   The  fact 
that  they  currently  choose  to  operate  large  numbers 
of  flights  and  routes  which  the  simulation  indicates 
are  "unprofitable"  indicates  not  that  there  is  cross- 
subsidization  in  the  system,  but  that  the  simulation 
is  faulty  in  the  way  it  determines  whether  a  particular 
route  or  flight  if  "profitable"  or  "unprofitable." 


406 


^-t^ 


tai=^^ 


— I — • — ' r— e — I    .'    X  \\    .1    <-^ 


r 


r^f^^^ 


'^?s¥^ 


Is-^ 


^3 


407 


408 


409 


Mtiiii 


i?J  |5i  N 


410 


MEMORANDUM 


To:      Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  Chairman 

Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure 
United  States  Senate 

From:     Dr.  John  W.  Drake,  Professor  of  Air  Transportation 
School  of  Aeronautics  and  Astronautics 
Purdue  University 
West  Lafayette,  Indiana  47907 

Subject:  Comments  re:  A.T.A.  study  of  Consequences  of  Deregulation 
of  the  Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry 

Date:     15  May  1975 


Summary 

The  ATA  model  misapplies  costs  In  such  a  way  as  to 
make  more  segments  appear  unprofitable. 

The  ATA  model  probably  understates  short  and  thinly 
travelled  segment  yields,  thus  making  more  appear 
unprofitable. 

The  ATA  model  leaves  out  all  aircraft  less  expen- 
sive to  operate  than  a  DC-9-10,  thus  making  more 
segments  appear  unprofitable. 

The  $50  billion  spent  on  the  Interstate  system  has 
Indeed  succeeded  in  providing  superior  alternative 
service  over  many  of  the  segments  enumerated.  This 
should  not  be  viewed  as  a  catastrophe. 

The  model  used  is  very  questionable  for  this  appli- 
cation, for  both  reasons  of  oversimpl iflcation  and 
for  more  fundamental  reasons  of  methodology. 


DRAKE        •        TRAN«POnTATION  CONaULTANT 


411 


Introduction 

The  ATA  study  referred  to  concern*,  the  application  of  a  model  to  the 
question  of  profitability  of  Individual  segments  of  the  airline  route 
network  of  the  United  States.  There  are  a  host  of  questions  one  may  a'.k 
about  any  such  study,  many  of  which  get  Involved  with  fine  points  which 
do  not.  In  fact,  matter  too  much.  The  Important  thing  therefore  Is  to 
try  to  address  the  Important  questions.  These  seern  to  me  to  be  (more  or 
less  1n  order) : 

•  Does  the  simulation,  as  run,  use  reasonably  good 
cost  data? 

•  Does  the  simulation,  a',  run,  use  reasonably  good 
revenue  data? 

•  May  the  simulation  method  used  be  expected  to 
t1ve  the  answers  It  proports  to  give  (I.e., 
reasonably  credible  answers  re.  probable  route 
abandonments)? 

My  belief  concerning  these  questions  Is,  briefly:  "No,"  "Perhaps," 

and  "No." 

Analysis 

Basically  the  simulation  steps  flights  into  the  network  on  a  segment 
by  segment  basis  and  computes  proported  costs  of  flying  and  revenue  from 
the  services  offered.  The  difference,  profit i  is  used  to  determine 
whether  to  add  a  flight  and  where  te  add  It,  and  thus  what  and  how 
many  routes  are  candidates  for  abandonment.  Being  a  difference  between 
two  "i^r^   nearly  equal  numbers  the  profit  criterion  is  much  more  sensitive 
to  errors  in  either  the  cost  or  revenue  estimates  than  they  are  them- 
selves. Thus  the  distinct  Interest  1n  whether  or  not  the  cost  or  revenue 

JOHN   W.   O^^JUM.        •         TnAr^aPOKTATIOM  COr4SUl.TA^4r 


412 


assumptions  used  are  to  be  relied  upon,  since  either  overly  high  costs 
or  overly  low  revenues  will  quickly  turn  routes  from  profit  to  loss. 

Costs 

If  all  costs  of  operating  were  proportional  to  the  number  of 
passengers  carried  or  flights  flown,  airline  route  analysis  would  be 
a  vastly  simplified  matter.  However,  as  in  many  businesses,  costs  are 
very  much  a  mixture  of  fixed  and  variable.  Furthermore  what  is  fixed  in 
the  short  run  may,  sometimes,  be  variable  in  the  long  run.  In  addition, 
fixed  costs  are  fixed  on  a  number  of  levels  themselves.*  The  ATA  in  its 


*J.E.D.  Williams  in  his  excellent  book  "The  Operation  of  Airliners" 
(Hutchinson  Scientific  &  Technical ,  London,  1964)  divides  costs  as  follows 
in  his  Chapter  12,  "The  Anatomy  of  Operational  Costs": 

Operator's  Overheads,  A.  Those  costs  which  would  be  incurred 
whether  the  particular  fleet  under  discussion  existed  or  not. 

Fleet  Overheads,  B.  The  costs  necessarily  incurred  by  having 
the  particular  fleet,  whatever  its  size  and  whether  used  or  not. 

Aircraft  Fixed  Costs,  C.  The  marginal  cost  of  having  one 
extra  aircraft  "in  the  fleet  whether  used  or  not. 

Station  Fixed  Costs,  D.  The  cost  of  maintaining  the  basic 
establishment  of  personnel  and  facility  at  a  station. 

Sector  Costs,  E.  Those  marginal  costs  of  operating  one  flight 
on  a  sector  which  are  independent  of  how  the  flight  is  operated. 

Hourly  Costs,  F.  Those  marginal  costs  of  flying  the  aircraft 
for  one  hour  which  are  independent  of  how  the  aircraft  is  flown. 
Hourly  costs  per  flight  are  computed  on  the  basis  of  block  time, 
i.e.,  from  the  start  of  taxiing  out  to  the  end  of  taxiing  in. 

Passenger-hour  Costs,  G.  The  costs  of  providing  a  passenger 
with  service  for  one  hour  not  otherwise  incurred.  For  some  purposes 
it  is  convenient  to  consider  passenger-hour  costs  as  a  charge  on 
revenue. 

Fuel  and  Oil ,  H.  The  cost  of  fuel  and  oil  loaded  at  the 
refueling  point.  Fuel  is  bought  by  the  gallon  and  metered  by  the 
pound,  and  produced  thrust  by  the  B.T.U.  For  many  purposes  (but 
not,  for  example,  selection  of  minimum-cost  cruise)  fuel  and  oil 
costs  may  be  considered  a  part  of  the  hourly  variable  cost  F. 

(continued) 


JOHN  W.   DRAKE        •        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


413 


study  treated  costs  in  a  very  unrealistic  manner.  As  explained  on  page 
4,  "marginal"  costs  were  used  to  select  the  flight  to  be  added  but  then 

"after  each  flight  addition  is  made total  operating  costs  are 

adjusted  to  include  the  additional  system  costs*  [to  produce  fully  allo- 
cated costs]."  This  prorating  of  fixed  costs  of  all  kinds  over  the 
variables  of  all  kinds  on  a  percentage  basis  will  permit  the  model  to 
make  incremental  decisions  in  a  way  which  is  quite  removed  from  reality. 
For  example,  it  may  in  effect  by  "paying  for"  10%  or  129%  of  a  DC-9 
maintenance  base  when  as  a  matter  of  fact  for  many  of  the  items  which 
make  up  such  a  base  you  simply  have  one  or  you  don't,  thus  producing  a 
large  fixed  and  lower  variable  cost.  Rather  than  being  added  prorata, 
major  portions  of  the  fixed  costs  whould  be  treated  by  the  model  simply 
as  they  are:  fixed,  by  system,  fleet,  station,  etc.  This  leads  to  very 
much  lower  marginal  costs  and  a  sort  of  "steady  by  jerks"  behavior  of 


Charges  on  Revenue.  Certain  costs  such  as  the  agent's  cormiis- 
sion  are  necessarily  incurred  by  the  act  of  selling  a  ticket.  For 
the  purposes  of  aircraft  operational  studies  these  can  conveniently 
be  regarded  as  a  charge  on  revenue.  Reference  in  this  book  is 
always  to  net  revenue,  that  is,  the  residual  revenue  after  deduction 
of  items  under  this  heading. 

The  advantage  of  this  classification  is  that  if  values  are 
assigned  to  A,  B,  C,  D,  E,  F,  G  and  H  it  is  possible  to  see 
precisely  how  changes  in  the  operation,  such  as  fleet-size,  schedule, 
route-structure,  load  factor,  operating  technique,  etc.,  affect  the 
economy  of  operation.  The  snag  is  the  difficulty  of  assigning 
costs  under  these  headings,  but  this  analysis  must  nevertheless  be 
undertaken  if  the  operator  is  to  ensure  that  the  operating  posture 
is  at  maximum  profitability. 

*fixed  costs 

i.e.,  a  big  "jerk"  when  one  goes  to  two  DC-9  maintenance  bases,  opens  a 
new  station,  or  buys  a  new  type  of  equipment. 


JOHN  W.   DRAKE        •        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


414 


a  substantial  fixed  cost  and  immediately  pour  flights  into  the  most 
profitable  routes.  However,  once  that  were  done  it  would  \ye   created 
much  of  its  infrastructure  and  would  find  it  profitable  to  keep  adding 
flights  on  an  incremental  basis  in  a  manner  very  different  than  the  way 
the  model  used  in  the  ATA  study  does  in  its  phase  1.*  It  would  add  more 
until  it  came  to  a  step  in  the  fixed  costs  and  then  hesitate  until 
traffic  pressure  built  up.  A  good  many  of  the  "more"  would,  it  seems  to 
me,  be  on  the  routes  the  ATA  suggests  are  threatened,  albeit  mostly 
between  cities  each  of  which  already  had  a  station  (and  thus  many  fixed 
costs). 

If  one  were  simulating  competitive  practice  it  would  mean  that,  in 
the  above  example,  the  stations  would  need  to  be  of  the  same  carrier 
(although  interchange  flights  could  be  used  as  well  as  other  techniques). 
The  most  important  thing  however  is  that  in  a  competitive  environment 
everyone's  fixed  cost  steps  are  not  identical  in  time  and  place.  One 
carrier  may  be  reluctant  to  add  a  flight  of  a  certain  kind  but  another 
carrier  which  has  just  bought  the  right  aircraft  type  may  well  be  anxious 
to  do  so. 

In  sum,  I  believe  the  treatment  of  costs  in  the  first  phase  of  the 
model  used  (the  fully  allocated  cost  phase)  greatly  distorts  the  models 
process  of  adding  flights,^  and  does  so  because  of  the  model's  demand/ 
frequency  assumption,   in  the  direction  of  concentrating  flights  in  the 


♦i.e.,  as  shown  in  Figure  2  page  4  of  the  ATA  study  and  expanded  upon  in 
the  Lockheed  brochure  CTR  2007,  Lockheed  Airline  System  Simulation, 
revised  May  1970,  charts  884-09229  through  886-09229. 

"•"ibid.,  Lockheed  chart  889-05180. 

*^^One  may  ask  why  this  was  done.  I  believe  there  are  a  number  of  reasons 

JOHN  W.   DRAKE        •        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


415 


major  markets.* 

Revenues 

Revenues  are  less  clear.  Individual  segment-by-segment  coach  fares 
were  used.  They  were  then  reduced  by  a  constant  percentage  to  reflect 
recent  system-wide  average  discount  experience.  Thus  short  haul  flights 
and  lightly  travelled  segments  were  discounted  to  the  same  degree  as  long 
haul  and  dense  segments.  I  do  not  have  data  immediately  at  hand  from 
which  to  analyze  discounts  including  the  effect  of  the  fare  pro-rate  on 
joint  fare  routings  by  segment  type;  however,  a  few  observations  are 
obvious. 

1.  By  Trunk  Carrier,  in  1969,  there  is  a  recognizable 
tendency  toward  less  discounting  in  shorter  hauls  based 

on  comparing  each  carrier's  %   Full  Fare  revenue  from  the  DPFI 
Phase  5  Decision,  Appendix  B,  with  the  coach  lengths  of 
haul ,  Appendix  L. 

2.  Many  of  the  present  day  (1975)  discount  fares  do  not 
apply  on  thin  routes  (e.g.,  no  TGC  from  IND->SEA)  nor 
on  short  routes  (e.g.,  no  Bicentennial  below  750  miles, 

no  demand  scheduling  below  very  long  haul). 


but  in  this  case  it  is  most  probably  a  combination  of  the  background 
of  the  modelers  (technical  more  than  economic)  and  the  state  of  the  art 
when  the  model  was  begun  (ca.  1959).  For  further  discussion  of  the 
problems  associated  with  models  not  doing  what  decision  makers  want 
models  to  do,  see  my  book:  The  Administration  of  Transportation  Model- 
ing Projects,  D.  C.  Heath,  Lexington,  Mass. ,  1973. 

*I  do  not  wish  to  suggest  that  I  propose  the  modifications  I  have  sug- 
gested as  all  that  is  needed  to  perfect  the.model  under  discussion.  I 
recognize  full  well,  for  example,  that  if  my  modifications  were  made 
one  could  get  vastly  different  answers  if  you  ran  the  model  from  zero 
frequencies  upwards  and  from  many  frequencies  downwards.  It  would  be 
more  realistic,  however,  as  this  is  exactly  what  happens  in  real  life. 
In  truth,  I  favor  a  mathematical  programming  approach  using  origin  and 
destination  data  rather  than  segment  flow  data.  Such  a  model  would 
break  the  perpetuation  of  the  present  route  structure  just  because  it 
is  the  present  route  structure.  Such  a  mathematical  programming 
approach  is  now  just  within  the  state  of  the  art,  I  believe.  See  the 
discussion  later  in  this  memo. 


JOHN  W.   DRAKE        .        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


416 


Thus,  given  a  choice,  I  would  have  to  guess  that  the  ATA  underesti- 
mated the  "endangered"  segment  actual  gields.  The  prorate  situation  is 
more  of  an  unknown,  however,  so  to  be  certain  one  must  have  the  real 
data. 

Aircraft  Types 

Clearly  another  way  in  which  the  ATA  study  suggested  such  a  large 
number  of  endangered  segments  was  by  its  choice  of  equipment.  The  list 
on  page  3  is  long  enough  but  not  diverse  enough: 

ATA  Possible 

B-747  *  B-747 

L-lOll/DC-10  *  L-lOll/DC-10 

DC-8-61  *  DC-8-61 

B-707-300B/DC-8  B-707-300B/DC-8-50 

B-727-200  *  B-727-200 

DC-9-30/B-737  *  DC-9-30/B-737 

DC-9-10  DC-9-10  (?) 

*  Convair  580 

*  FH-227B 

Allegheny  Conversion  of 
Nord  262  (Mohawk  298) 

*  DHC-7 
Short  SC-30 

*  Fairchild/Schwearingen 
Metroliner 

Clearly  not  all  need  to  be  included--perhaps  only  the  asterisked 

ones.  Running  time  would  go  up  slightly  but  I  dare  say  some  endangered 

segments  would  suddenly  survive,  which  leads  "VoiU!"  to  the  third  level 

carriers  and  their  willingness  to  step  in.  To  be  sure,  as  the  ATA  says, 

Lafayette,  Indiana, (where  I  write  this)-Chicago  service  by  Allegheny  is 


TRANSPORTATION  CONeULTANT 


417 


endangered.  It's  so  endangered  it's  been  gone  for  well  over  a  year. 
But  we  have  eight  (weekday)  non-stops  to  Chicago  on  fast  pressurized 
Air  Wisconsin  planes.  Who  is  suffering? 

Interstate  Highways 

One  must  also  not  lose  sight  of  another  factor:  the  interstate 
highway  system.  I  will  use  Indiana  as  an  example  since  I  now  reside 
there  and  travel  extensively.  I  reproduce  the  map  from  the  ATA  study 
and  the  same  map  with  the  interstate  highways  added.  Having  now  spent 
something  approaching  $50,000,000,000  to  build  a  vast  system  of  inter- 
state highways,  is  it  any  wonder  that  Indianapolis  -  Fort  Wayne  service 
might  be  threatened,  and  so  should  a  lot  of  the  others?  We  should  not 
cry  if  we  sometimes  succeed  in  transportation!  This  does  point  to  the 
most  important  of  all  aspects  of  this  whole  deregulation  questions, 
however,  which  is  simply  that  of  "What  is  our  national  transportation 
policy?"  As  of  now  we  don't  have  one.  We  need  one.  Otherwise  we  are 
in  the  silly  situation  of  crying  over  things  that  either  won't  happen  or 
that  we've  spent  billions  trying  to  get  to  happen.*  With  no  integrated 
intermodal  transportation  policy,  we  don't  know  when  we  are  well  off! 

Model  Methodology 

One  must  still  address  the  question  of  whether  the  model  used  is 
fundamentally  appropriate  to  the  problem.  That  is,  if  it  were  merely 
improved  and  had  everybody's  nit-picking  objections  taken  care  of  and 
computer  time  were  no  object,  could  it  do  the  desired  job  in  this 


*0r  in  the  case  of  the  trains,  happened  when  we  didn't  want  them  to, 
because  of  disjointed  policies  toward  air,  rail,  water  and  highway 
transportation. 


JOHN  W.   DRAKE        •        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  28 


418 


Map  of 
INDIANA 


ATA  Study  Map  of  Indiana 


JOHN  W.  ORAKB 


.        TRANSPORTATION  CONSULTANT 


419 


Map  of 
INDIANA 


ATA  Study  Map  of  Indiana  with  the  Interstate  Highways  Added 


JOHN  W.  ORAKK        •        TWANi^OWTATION  CONSUI-TANT 


420 


11 


instance?  I  have  hinted  at  the  answer  in  tny  earlier  footnote  (see  page 
7  at  the  end  of  the  costs  section).  Let  me  reiterate  and  expand 
slightly. 

1.  If  the  model  would  realistically  simulate  business 
behavior  by  incrementally  adding  flights  (using  good 
cost  steps,  si i pes,  etc.,  etc.,  etc.),  it  wouldn't 
reproduce  its  results  when  run  backwards,  taking  away 
flights  from  a  vast  superfluity,  but  both  answers  would 
be  equally  valid!  They  would  simply  highlight  a  major 
policy  question:  Should  the  government  still  view  air 
transport  as  an  Infant  industry  needing  a  boost,  or 
not? 

2.  If  one  really  wants  to  see  what  segments  of  a  route 
network  the  U.  S.  ought  to  want  to  have  in  the  interest 
of  maximizing  its  efficient  use  of  resources,  use  of 
the  existing  segment  flow  data  ("service  segment  data" 
from  the  ER  586' s)  is  the  wrong  way  to  go.  A  mathe- 
matical programming  approach  using  origin  and  destina- 
tion data,  though  not  without  problems,  is  a  better 
way.  Ideally  it  should  be  a  mixed-integer  program  but, 
depending  upon  the  time  horizon, that  is  not  as  essential 
as  it  first  appears.  Such  analyses  are  now  within  our 
grasp  and  should  be  done. 


JOHN  W.  DRAKK        •        TRANSPOfrTATION  CONSULTANT 


421 


UNIVERSITY  OF  CM.lKOIiM  A,  lU.Kkl  ,1  .i:V 


"iil 


June  A,    1975 


Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy 
Chairman,  Subcommittee  on 

Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,  D.C.   20510 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy: 

Please  forgive  my  long  but  unavoidable  delay  in  responding  to  your  letter  of 
April  29,  requesting  an  evaluation  of  the  April  25  letter  of  Dr.  George  James, 
and  on  the  Air  Transport  Association  report  used  to  back  up  the  main  points  in 
that  letter.   The  previous  letters  of  other  economists  have  covered  most  of  the 
Important  weaknesses  of  the  James  letter  and  the  ATA  report,  so  I  shall  limit 
myself  to  a  few  additional  comments . 

As  previous  comments  on  the  ATA  model  have  Indicated,  Its  primary  weakness  is 
that  it  assumes  that  in  the  absence  of  regulation,  the  carriers  in  any  given 
market  would  behave  as  a  single  monopolist,  at  least'/'the  service  quality 
offered.   Thus,  the  report  argues  that  without  regulation,  flights  on  currently 
unprofitable  routes  would  be  abandoned,  and  flights  on  profitable  routes  would 
be  cut  back  to  achieve  maximum  profits. 

This  conclusion  is  not  only  based  on  faulty  analysis  (as  previous  comments  have 
already  pointed  out),  but  also,  the  study  starts  off  with  what  seems  to  me  to 
be  a  totally  mistaken  assumption  about  how  the  CAB  currently  affects  airline 
behavior.   The  study  implicitly  assumes  that  there  is  something  which  the  CAB 
is  doing,  through  exercise  of  Its  legal  powers,  to  prevent  flight  cutbacks  on 
main  routes,  so  as  to  prevent  load  factors  from  rising  to  a  profit-maximizing 
level  (mentioned  to  be  81  per  cent).   And  yet  there  is  nothing  which  the  CAB 
has  done  to  prevent  "profit-maximizing  cutbacks"  in  flights  to  such  a  load  fac- 
tor.  It  does  not  have  to,  because  the  airlines  compete  among  themselves  in 
service  quality,  driving  load  factors  down  until  profits  reach  a  normal  level. 
Why  this  would  change  in  the  absence  of  CAB  regulation  is  never  stated,  either 
by  Dr.  James  or  by  the  report  (antitrust  laws  would  of  course  prevent  collusion 
in  restraint  of  trade  on  the  part  of  the  airlines  in  the  absence  of  regulation. 
Just  as  they  do  now).   It  would  thus  appear  that  the  ATA  study  is  vesting  the 
CAB  with  powers  which  it  does  not  have,  and  which  it  clearly  does  not  need.   As 
a  result,  the  study  is  irrelevant  to  the  question  at  hand. 

The  second  point  which  I  want  to  make  regards  the  empirical  validity  of  the 
results  of  the  ATA  study.   It  asserts  that  if  money-losing  routes  were  abandoned. 


422 


372  routes  would  lose  Crunk  service.   Professor  Peltzman,  In  his  excellent 
comment,  points  out  that  of  these,  there  are  seven  Texas  and  California  routes 
which  currently  receive  service  from  non-subsidized  intrastate  carriers  at 
below-CAB  fares. 

I  count  even  more  such  routes  than  Professor  Peltzman:   in  addition  to  the 
ones  he  mentions  ar§  Fresno-Los  Angeles,  Fresno-San  Francisco,  Stockton- 
San  Francisco,  and  Los  Angeles-Palm  Springs.   Thus,  all  told,  eleven  of  the 
routes  which  the  ATA  report  predicts  would  lose  service  in  the  absence  of  regu- 
lation are  in  fact  being  served  by  non-subsidized  carriers  at  below-CAB  fares . 

Third,  as  any  reference  to  the  Official  Airline  Guide  will  Indicate,  commuter 
carriers  have  served  profitably  many  routes  of  too  low  a  density  for  even  the 
subsidized  local  service  carriers.  Nearly  all  routes  currently  served  by  the 
trunks  are  of  higher  density  than  that.  Thus,  any  town  which  lost  trunk  air 
service  would  be  almost  certain  of  being  served  by  a  nonsubsldized  commuter 
carrier,  and  many  cities  would  stand  a  good  chance  of  being  served  by  a  larger 
carrier  such  as  PSA  or  Southwest  Airlines. 

I  am  most  inclined,  however,  not  to  believe  that  these  routes  are  unprofitable 
in  the  first  place.   As  Dr.  Eads  has  commented  in  his  letter  of  May  1,  the 
trunk  carriers  are  free  to  abandon  service  on  most  of  these  "unprofitable" 
routes,  and  the  fact  that  they  have  not  done  so  indicates  either  that  the 
routes  are  profitable,  or  that  the  managements  of  the  airlines  represented  by 
the  ATA  are  incompetent,  in  failing  to  maximize  profits  given  the  existing 
regulatory  structure.   I  believe  that  the  routes  are  profitable.   To  the  extent, 
then,  that  the  CAB  is  not  currently  requiring  the  airlines  to  provide  as  much 
service  as  they  do  on  these  "unprofitable"  routes,  it  is  difficult  to  see  how 
elimination  of  CAB  regulation  would  have  any  Impact  whatsoever  on  service 
provided.   Again,  the  ATA  report  is  basically  irrelevant  as  regards  the  effects 
of  CAB  regulations. 

To  conclude,  I  think  that  the  ATA  study  is  an  interesting  (if  highly  Inaccurate) 
exercise  to  determine  what  would  happen  if,  by  regulatory  fiat,  one  carrier 
were  granted  a  complete  monopoly  on  every  route  in  the  country.   But  it  has 
little  if  anything  at  all  to  do  with  the  potential  effects  of  deregulation  of 
the  trunk  airline  industry  in  the  United  States. 

Sincerely 


Theodore  E.  Keeler 

Assistant  Professor  of  Economics 


TEK:jst 


423 


UNIVERSITY    OF    CHICAGO 

GRADUATE    SCHOOL    OF   BUSINESS 

5836     GREENWOOD     AVENUE     •     CHICAGO,     ILLINOIS     60637 

May  5,  1975 


Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy 

Chairman 

U.  S.  Senate  Subcommittee  on  Administrative 

Practice  and  Procedxire 
Senate  Office  Building 
Washington,  D.C.  20510 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy: 

I  am  pleased  to  reply  to  your  request  of  April  29  for  a  review  of  the 
Air  Transport  Association's  study  on  the  possible  consequences  of 
deregulation  of  the  airline  industry. 

In  my  opinion,  the  weaknesses  of  this  study  are  so  glaring  that  the 
study  simply  cannot  support  the  case  the  ATA  wants  to  make.  In  fact, 
if  it  does  anything,  it  strengthens  the  case  for  deregulation. 

The  heart  of  the  study  is  a  list  of  372  nonstop  routes  which  "are  prime 
candidates  for  abandonment  under  deregulation."  One  indicator  of  the 
weakness  of  the  study  is  its  inclusion  among  these  372  routes  of  seven 
Texas  and  California  routes  already  being  served  by  non-CAB- regulated 
carriers  at  below-regulated  rates.  These  are: 

San  Francisco-Sacramento 
San  Francisco-San  Diego 
Los  Angeles- San  Diego 

Dallas-Houston 
Harlingen-Hous  ton 
San  Antonio-Houston 
San  Antonio-Dallas. 

Clearly,  if  unregulated  service  is  already  being  supplied  to  these  markets 
it  is  absurd  to  claim  that  they  will  be  left  without  service  under  deregu- 
lation. Since  the  entry  of  unregulated  carriers  has,  in  virtually  all  these 
markets,  led  to  improved  service,  a  legitimate  question  may  be  raised  against 
the  ATA's  claim  that  extending  deregulation  to  the  remaining  365  markets  will 
lead  to  the  cessation  of  (nonstop)  service  to  them.  Indeed,  if  one  checks 
this  list,  numerous  instances  will  be  found  where  nonstop  service  is  in  fact 
being  provided  by  lightly  regulated  commuter  air  carriers.  I  comment  on  this 
subsequently. 

I  believe  that  the  major  weakness  of  the  study,  and  perhaps  the  primary 
source  of  anomalies  like  those  I  have  Just  cited,  lies  in  its  methodology. 
This  methodology  is  not  described  clearly,  but  it  appears  to  rely  heavily 


424 


on  estimates  of  the  profit  or  loss  engendered  by  the  addition  of  nonstop 
flights  to  specified  city  pairs.   The  defect  of  this  methodology  is  im- 
plicitly recognized  in  the  April  25,  1975  covering  letter  to  you  from 
George  "w.  James,  ATA  Senior  Vice-President—Economics  and  Finance,  in 
which  he  states  that  "it  is  recognized  that  some  [of  the  listed  "unprof- 
itable routes"]  might  be  held  [under  deregulation]  for  such  reasons  as 
feeding  heavier  traveled  routes  or  aircraft  positioning."  This  appears 
to  recognize  that  a  nonstop  route  can  be  profitable  even  if  the  traffic 
generated  on  that  route  alone  could  not  support  nonstop  service.  For 
example,  there  may  be  30  passengers  between  City  1  and  City  3,   and  another 
30  between  intermediate  City  2  and  City  3-   These  may  separately  be  insuf- 
ficient to  warrant  1-3  and  2-3  nonstop  service,  but  may  make  a  1-3  flight 
with  a  stop  at  2  profitable.  Consequently,  the  total  market  involved  can 
support  what  will  show  up  as  two  nonstop  flights  (1-2  and  2-3).   Thus, 
when  a  particular  segment  of  a  longer  route  cannot  support  nonstop  service 
by  itself,  it  is  invalid  to  infer  that  this  segment  will  be  abandoned. 

The  vast  majority  of  the  "prime  candidates  for  abandonment  under  deregula- 
tion" appear  to  have  precisely  this  characteristic;  they  are  primarily 
segments  of  longer  routes.  The  extent  to  which  this  is  the  case  may^be 
indicated  by  an  examination  I  made  of  every  tenth  city  pair  on  the  list  of 
372  in  Exhibit  B  of  the  ATA  study.   Of  the  37  pairs  I  examined,  7  m  fact 
had  no  nonstop  service  listed  in  the  April  15,  1975-  edition  of  the  Official 
Airline  Guide  (numbers  ll^O,  210,  280,  310,  320,  350,  360  on  the  ATA  list). 
Of  the  remaining  30,  there  was  no  case  in  which  more  than  half  of  the  non- 
stop flights  were  operated  exclusively  between  the  two  cities.   In  one  case, 
(number  90),  half  the  nonstop  flights  did  originate  in  one  city  and  terminate 
in  the  other.  In  each  of  the  remaining  29,  the  majority,  and  in  most  cases 
virtualiy  all,  of  the  nonstop  flights  were  segments  of  longer  routes.   It 
may  also  be  of  some  interest  that  7  of  the  37  city  pairs,  including  one  of 
those  which  in  fact  had  no  nonstop  service  by  regulated  carriers,  had  non- 
stop service  provided  by  commuter  airlines  (numbers  30,  120,  140,  150,  170, 
200,  220). 

This  examination  leads  me  to  conclude  that  the  ATA  study  simply  cannot  be 
relied  upon  to  predict  the  likely  configuration  of  airline  service  under 
deregulation.  Its  inclusion  of  so  many  markets  already  being  served  by  non- 
CAB-regulated  carriers  may  in  fact  indicate  the  potential  that  reduced 
regulation  has  for  improving  service  in  other  markets.  But,  in  any  case, 
the  spectre  of  mass  abandonment  of  nonstop  service  under  deregulation  is 
produced  by  a  methodology  so  flawed  that  it  merits  the  most  extreme 
skepticism. 

There  are  other  aspects  of  the  study  that  also  merit  skepticism.  For  exam- 
ple, the  implicit  identification  of  service  quality  with  nonstop  service  is 
questionable.   There  is  clearly  a  tradeoff  between  limited  nonstop  service 
and  more  extensive  service  with  seme  stops.  The  conclusion  that  lower  fares 


425 


will  always  reduce  flight  frequency  on  profitable  routes  is  also  question- 
able, because  it  is  based  on  the  existing  regulated  airline  cost-structure 
and  regulatory  restriction  of  entry.  The  plain  fact  is  that  where  entry  by 
unregulated  carriers  has  occurred,  as  in  Texas  and  California,  lower  fares 
have  widened  the  market  sufficiently  to  produce  more  rather  than  less  fre- 
quent flights. 

I  hope  that  my  comments  are  of  some  assistance  to  you. 

Sincerely  vours, 


/     /, 


Professor  of  Business 
Economics 


SP:gb 


426 


UNIVERSITY  OF  VIRGINIA 

JAMES    WILSON    DEPARTMENT    OF    ECXJNOMICS 
CHARLOTTESVILLE 


May  12,  1975 


The  Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy 
Chairman,  Subcommittee  on  Administrative 

Practice  and  Procedure  of  the 

Committee  on  the  Judiciary 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,  D.C.  20510 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy: 

I  write  in  reply  to  your  request  of  April  29,  1975  for 
a  review  of  the  Air  Transport  Association  of  America  study 


_,..ied 
V..V-  *-6..w  >-  r Even  given  this  in- 
adequate scope,  the  study's  categorization  of  routes  as  "profit 
able"  or  "unprofitable"  is  unreliable  and  cannot  sustain  the 
implications  under  its  assumptions,  namely  that  certain  routes 
will  be  denied  service  under  deregulation. 

The  conclusions  stated  in  Dr.  James'  letter  cannot  be 
supported  by  the  ATA  study.   No  claim  that  "scheduled  air 
service  might  be  eliminated"  is  possible  because  no  evidence 
is  presented  showing  that  a  new  entrant  would  not  be  motivated 
to  offer  service.   Indeed,  the  ATA  analysis  implies  enormous 
profit  for  the  Airline  System,  which  under  deregulation  should 
invite  abundant  new  entry  and  thereby  undercut  any  claim  that 
service  would  be  eliminated.   Nor  is  there  any  basis  for 
assertions  at  page  2  that  subsidized  routes  might  not  survive 
or  that  service  would  be  unstable.   Claims  that  lower  rates 
would  make  many  more  routes  unprofitable  and  would  increase 
subsidy  needs  also  cannot  be  supported  by  the  ATA  study. 


427 


The  outstanding  weakness  of  the  ATA  study  is  that  it  gives 
no  attention  to  the  functioning  of  market  processes,  which 
surely  will  accompany  deregulation.   In  particular,  despite 
the  enormous  profit  rates  implied  by  the  ATA  simulation,  the 
reader  will  look  in  vain  for  any  consideration  of  the  possibility 
of  entry  into  the  airline  industry  by  a  new  firm.   The  analysis 
simulates  the  action  of  a  gigantic  Airline  System  controlling 
completely  the  provision  of  airline  service  without  giving  any 
consideration  to  the  possibility  that  a  firm  outside  this  organi- 
zation would  see  how  profitable  the  airline  industry  is  and 
decide  to  enter  it.   Although  it  thereby  casts  the  airline  in- 
dustry virtually  as  a  monopoly  and  examines  how  much  service  it 
would  offer,  the  study  never  pursues  the  equally  important 
monopolist's  decision  about  fares,  but  rather  it  merely  maintains 
1973  fares.   So  even  as  an  analysis  of  monopolistic  organization 
of  the  airline  industry  the  study  is  incomplete. 

Any  study  of  effects  on  the  airline  industry  of  deregulation 
must  focus  on  the  prospects  for  entry  by  new  firms.   For  it  is 
through  entry  and  exit  that  competitive  markets  achieve  their 
efficiencies.   A  well  known  and  most  crucial  feature  of  current 
airline  regulation  is  its  restriction  on  new  entrants  seeking  to 
provide  various  categories  of  airline  service.   Indeed,  the  exit 
of  firms  from  the  industry,  or  the  termination  of  service  between 
city  pairs  which  is  emphasized  in  the  ATA  study,  is  a  much  less 
important  issue  than  entry,  particularly  when  exit  often  is 
already  allowed  much  more  readily  than  entry  under  current  regu- 
latory practices.   To  examine  the  consequences  of  deregulation 
it  is  essential  that  entry  and  exit  be  probed. 

The  ATA  study  ignores  the  possibility  of  new  entry  and 
indeed  it  does  not  even  consider  1,267  non-subsidized  routes  of 
regional  air  carriers  which  already  are  in  existence.   As  a  con- 
sequence its  implications  simply  are  of  no  interest  for  the 
question  at  issue,  namely,  what  will  happen  as  a  result  of  de- 
regulation?  Having  implicitly  ruled  out  by  assumption  a  major 
source  of  airline  service  to  be  expected  under  deregulation,  that 
by  new  carriers,  any  claim  by  ATA  that  service  will  not  exist  in 
any  market  is  obviously  unreliable.   One  need  not  seek  mistakes 
in  calculations  or  faulty  execution  of  ATA ' s  method;  the  method 
of  analysis  is  inadequate  and  inappropriate  in  its  assumptions 
and  in  its  design,  and  therefore  it  is  incapable  of  predicting 
loss  of  service  under  deregulation.   Ignoring  new  entry  in  this 
way  is  also  certain  to  lead  to  misleading  results  because 


428 


profit  is  so  high  that  entry  will  be  motivated. 

One  flaw  does  seem  obvious  in  the  study,  however,  even 
apart  from  its  excessively  limited  scope  in  ignoring  new  entry, 
although  not  enough  information  is  provided  in  the  study  to 
allow  definitive  analysis  of  the  flaw's  effects.   The  division 
of  routes  by  ATA  into  "profitable"  and  "unprofitable"  categories 
apparently  does  not  consider  explicitly  that  passengers  carried 
on  some  routes  labeled  "unprofitable"  by  ATA  actually  travel 
farther  and  cause  profit  to  be  earned  on  routes  labeled  "profit- 
able" by  ATA.   The  importance  of  this  possibility  is  that  it 
means  part  of  the  profit  assigned  by  ATA  to  "profitable"  routes 
actually  should  have  been  assigned  to  routes  classified  by  ATA 
as  "unprofitable."   Thus  the  profitability  categorization  by 
ATA  is  potentially  spurious,  and  it  certainly  cannot  sustain 
any  claim  that  routes  categorized  as  "unprofitable"  under  ATA ' s 
method  would  not  continue  to  be  served  by  the  source  of  service 
ATA  considered  (not  to  mention  alternative  sources,  which  were 
arbitrarily  and  inappropriately  ignored  in  the  ATA  study). 

It  is  possible  that  some  of  the  economies  claimed  in  the 
ATA  study  through  higher  load  factors  actually  can  be  achieved 
under  deregulation,  because  current  regulatory  practices  can 
lead  to  lower  than  optimal  load  factors,  which  raise  costs.   We 
presently  rely  on  control  over  price  plus  competition  in  non- 
price  areas  among  existing  air  carriers  who  are  protected  from 
new  entry,  as  our  means  of  economic  regulation  of  airlines.   If 
price  is  set  too  high  under  this  arrangement  the  competing 
carriers  will  have  an  incentive  to  schedule  many  flights  because 
flights  are  so  profitable  (see  George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C. 
Miller  III,  Economic  Regulation  of  Domestic  Air  Transportation: 
Theory  and  Policy  (Washington,  D.C.:   The  Brookings  Institution, 
1974)  for  an  excellent  analysis  of  this  consequence  of  current 
regulation),  with  the  result  that  load  factors  will  fall.   The 
competition  of  existing  airlines  thus  effectively  raises  costs, 
at  least  until  only  normal  profits  are  earned  and  further  non- 
price  competition  is  not  motivated.   If  new  carriers  were  allowed 
to  enter  the  market,  price  control  would  not  be  needed  and  so 
such  a  result  could  not  persist,  because  the  new  entrants  would 
force  price  down.   The  ultimate  equilibrium  would  be  tailored 
more  to  consumers'  preferences  between  flight  frequency  (and 
other  non-safety  aspects  of  service  quality)  and  price.   Such 
important  consequences  of  deregulation  were  not  broached  in 
the  ATA  study,  however. 

The  ATA  study  also  implies  that  profitability  will  increase 
enormously  under  deregulation.   Profit  from  airline  services  as 


429 


considered  by  ATA  will  more  than  double  while  the  amount  of 
service  and.  in  turn,  the  needed  level  of  investment  will  be 
only  a  fraction  of  what  it  is  now.   The  implied  rate -of -retu: 
on  airline  investment  is  consequently  very  high    We  have 
abundant  evidence  that  without  laws  preventing  them,  high 
rates  of  return  always  bring  expansion  and  new  entry,  so  the 
arbitrary  exclusion  of  such  consequences  by  ATA  obviously  is 
crucial  to  the  results  obtained.   It  is  inconceivable  that 


accompanied  by  high  prof it .  for  such  results  together  would  be 
inconsistent  with  the  functioning  of  competitive  markets. 

It  should  be  mentioned  here  again  that  the  ATA  study 
fectL^  ^  -jaintains  1973  fares.   Were  the  Airline  System  pro- 
tected as  fully  from  new  entry  as  the  ATA  study  assumes,  the 
System  almost  certainly  would  move  to  higher  fares  and,  depending 
on  consumer  responses  which  are  not  treated  in  the  study,  it  is 
possible  that  routes  would  then  be  even  more  profitable  and 

in  lin^t^  ^'"^"^''°"'-^^^^"'^^  ^y  ^^^  ^""I'i  "°t  be  motivated.   Thus 
in  addition  to  ignoring  new  entry,  by  considering  no  mechanism 
for  changing  price  from  1973  levels  (except  for  arbitrary  per- 
centage reductions  due  to  causes  that  are  never  explained) ^the 
tltl         ""    Ignores  the  role  of  market  mechanisms  fo?  determining 
III    in^lu         '    ^'    '"'■^^""  °"'P"^-   Although  it  may  be  of  UmUed 
use  m  the  present  regulatory  environment,  since  the  ATA  study 
does  not  allow  for  the  functioning  of  market  processes   it  ?s 
wholly  inadequate  to  deal  with  the  consequences  of  der;g;iat ion . 

ATA   J"/°"^l"ding  so  firmly  that  the  findings  of  the  present 
ATA  study  are  without  merit  I  do  not  wish  to  criticize  the  ATA 
ev^'tu:ti;rc;n/'  "^^    "°'  unreasonable  of  the  iTA^ti'^urn^for'' 
evaluating  consequences  to  the  simulation  model  which  it  already 


RS/jbm 


)herms 
'rol^ssor   of   Economics 


430 


Purdue    University 

KRANNERT      GRADUATE      SCHOOL 

O  F 

INDUSTRIAL      ADMINISTRATION 

KRANNERT    BUILDING 

WEST    LAFAYETTE,    INDIANA    47907 


May  9,  1975 


Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  Chairmaji 
Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice 

and  Procedure 
United  States  Senate 
Washington,  D.  C  20510 

Deax  Senator  Kennedy: 

This  letter  is  in  response  to  your  correspondence  of  May  1,  1975, 
which  asked  me  to  comment  upon  the  Air  Transport  Association  Study, 
"Consequences  of  Deregulation  of  Scheduled  Air  Transport  Industry." 
My  basic  conclusion  is  that  the  ATA  simvilation  is  an   inappropriate 
model  to  use  in  order  to  investigate  the  resulting  changes  in  a 
deregulated  narket  for  the  tr\ink  earners.  Its  results  of  elimina- 
tion or  vast  curtailment  of  service  must  then  be  considered  highly 
suspect.   In  this  regard,  my  analysis  echoes  those  of  the  Greenspan- 
Miller  and  Rees-Eads  letters,  which  you  were  so  kind  to  enclose. 

The  crucial  question  the  committee  faces  regarding  the  issues  of 
deregulation  is  the  following:  "What  system  of  controls  (if  any) 
should  be  imposed  in  order  to  maJte  the  public  best  off?"  From  an 
economic  standpoint,  I  will  argue  that  a  competitive  market  is  best 
for  a  number  of  reasons. 

I  feel  that  a  closer  examination  should  be  made  using  the  examples 
of  intrastate  commerce  (not  under  CAB  price  regulations),  in  order 
to  investigate  the  possible  consequences  of  deregulation.  Two  of 
my  colleagues,  Ron  Adelsman  and  Mike  Pustay  provided  me  with  useful 
insights  into  the  problem.  My  opinions  expressed  here  are  my  own 
and  do  not  reflect  the  views  of  Purdue  University. 

I  hope  this  material  will  be  of  assistance  to  you;  thank  you  for 
your  consideration. 

Sincerely, 

a.,..^ou  .'^ih..  ■^y/'^, 

Andrew  Whinston 

Professor  of  Economics,  Management 

and  Computer  Science 

AW/lg 

End. 


431 


COMMENTS  ON  AIR  TRANSPORT  ASSOCIATICHJ'  S  ANALYSIS 
CF  THE  CONSEQUENCES  OF  AIRLINE  DERBGrULATION 

In  the  ATA  stxidy,  Dr.  James  states  that  there  are  basically  three 
ajrproaches  one  can  take  in  analyzing  the  consequences  of  a  deregulated 
maxket:  simulation,  macroeconomic,  or  study  of  a  deregulated  environment. 
The  macroeconomic  model  is  dismissed  as  "intellectually  elegant,  has  the 
dlssuivantage  that  it  cannot  be  validated."  Two  examples  of  the  last 
approach  are  given:  the  pre-1938  era  and  the  California  (intrastate) 
market.  The  author  discards  the  first  beca\ise  the  airline  market  today 
is  vastly  different  (l  agree),  and  he  casually  dismisses  the  second  by 
terming  it  "chaotic."  Thus,  ve  are  left  vrLth  no  choice  but  to  take  the 
simulation  approach. 

There  is  nothing  inherently  wrong  with  performing  a  simulation  per 
se,  and  certainly  the  Lockheed  simulator  is  well  respected  and  widely  lised, 
as  was  pointed  out  by  Dr.  Miller  in  his  letter  (page  2).  But,  if  the  model 
is  misused  by  subjecting  it  to  a  ta^k  for  which  it  was  not  designed  and 
is  ill  prepared  to  handle,  we  face  possibly  disastrous  consequences  for 
timsting  its  output,  as  was  mentioned  by  Dr.  James  himself.  As  has  been 
described  by  the  other  letters,  the  simulation  is  indeed  faulty   in  a 
number  of  areas.  Furthermore,  the  ATA  seems  somehow  to  have  misconstrued 
the  present  legislation  before  the  committee.  As  a  result,  the  conclusion 
that  of  the  99U  trunk-carrier  routes  analyzed,  "372  would  be  candidates 
for  elimination  under  deregulation,  while  nearly  all  of  the  remaining  622 
could  experience  a  sharp  curtailment  of  service"  (page  1)  has  no  legitimate 
basis  for  support. 

In  order  to  bolster  the  claim  that  the  output  of  the  model  is  in 
error,  one  can  take  two  approaches :  discredit  the  model  itself  by  point- 
ing out  its  inadeqiiacies  and/or  show  that  the  output  provides  irrational, 
answers  to  the  input  questions.  At  this  jvmcture,  I  will  reiterate  the 
main  problems  in  using  the  Lockheed  simulator  to  answer  the  question  of 
"What  would  happen  to  flight  service  in  a  deregulated  environment?" 


432 


Faiilts  of  the  A3A  Simulation  Approach 

The  model  does  not  simulate  competition;  it  assvmies  either  a  monopolistic 
airline  or  a  firm  with  a  constant  market  share.  Since  the  proposed 
legislation  of  deregulating  prices,  if  passed,  wovdd  have  the  primary 
impact  of  stimulating  competition,  a  model  that  ignores  this  basic 
issue  is  inadequate  at  best. 

The  city-pair  method  of  analysis  is  a  heuristic  approach  to  the  problem 
that  has  two  attendant  faults.  Since  a  full-costing  approach  has  been 
taken,  some  common  fixed  costs,  such  as  depreciation,  mxist  be  artificially 
allocated.  This  procedure  is  not  an  Incremental  analysis  as  was  re- 
quested by  the  committee.  Ftcrthermore,  the  concept  of  one  leg  of  a 
multi-stop  trip  being  a  loss  leader  for  the  entire  tour  has  been  sup- 
pressed. 


.B 


Not        Very 
profitable    Profitable 


Small  Profits 


Small  Profits 


Thus,  although  Profit  could  well  exceed  Profit  ,  since  the  leg  AB 
is  a  loss  leader,  fliglit  service  wovQd  erroneously  be  cut  from  city  A 
to  city  B.  Tliis  can  result  when  most  of  the  passengers  from  A  wish 
to  travel  to  C. 

Althoi\gh  the  ATA  study  does  investigate  the  effects  due  to  the  price 
elasticity  of  demand  (cuts  in  fares  of  10^  and  20^),  it  completely 
ignores  the  effects  due  to  the  service  elasticity  of  demand.  Suppose, 
for  the  sake  of  argument,  that  service  between  cities  A  and  B  were 


433 
-  3  - 

curtailed.  Then,  those  displaced  passengers  would  have  three  choices : 
cancel  their  trip,  travel  by  another  mode  of  transportation,  or  travel 
CO  one  of  the  remaining  flights.  The  proportion  that  exercised  the 
last  option  would  increase  load  factors  and  profits  of  the  airlines 
retaining  service.  This  service  elasticity  has  not  been  ta>.en  into 
account  by  the  AIA  study.  It  would  manifest  itself  most  strongly  be- 
tween city-pairs  at  longer  distances  and  with  few  current  flights.  In 
the  extreme  case,  vdiere  there  was  only  one  flight,  that  airline  would 
control  the  market  and  would  act  as  a  monopolist.  If  his  return  on 
investment  were  inordinately  high,  competition  would  reenter  the  marketj 
thus  reducing  economic  profit. 

The  other  line  of  attack  against  the  conclusions  of  the  AIA  study  is  to 
investigate  the  reasonableness  of  its  conclusion.  Again,  most  of  these 
points  have  also  been  mentioned  previously. 

Issue 

1.  The  output  of  the  ATA  study  shows  that  given  1973  costs  and  revenues, 
the  trunk  airlines  would  eliminate  or  curtail  service  if  they  could  do 
so.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  those  airlines  do  have  the  capability  of 
vastly  cui't ailing- their  service  under  present  CAB  regulations,  but  for 
"some  reason"  have  chosen  not  to  do  so.  Tlie  certificate  of  serive 
only  imposes  lower  bounds  (usually  one  or  two  daily  flights)  into  and 
out  of  a  city  —  note:  not  between  city-pairs.  Thus,  the  trunks  can 
presently  cut  their  service  levels,  a  fact  that  casts  doubt  upon  the 
validity  of  the  ATA  model.  Since  airline  managements  are  presumably 
profit  maximizers,  the  fact  that  service  has  been  maintained  is  an 
indication  that  they  feel  that  there  is  a  realization  of  incremental 
profit,  contrary  to  the  sim'olation  results. 

2.  As  \«is  indicated  by  the  other  two  letters  operating  at  so-called 
optiraality  wo-old  yield  a  $2  billion  profit  with  a  ROI  over  70^,  a 
patently  ridiculous  result  which  can  occur  by  misapplying  the  model 
which  ignores  competition  to  its  extremes. 

3.  The  proposed  legislation  at  present  does  not  deal  with  elimination  of 
subsidies  to  the  local  airlines,  a  complex  issue  in  its  own  right. 


51-146  O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  29 


434 


Yet,  the  ATA  study  monetheless  lumps  these  1,198  local  service  routes 
Into  their  results,  claiming  (with  no  support)  that  these  too  would 
be  candidates  for  elimination.  a3ieir  inclusion  in  the  graphs  (as 
pointed  out  by  George  Eads)  appears  to  be  a  smoke  screen  aimed  at 
buttressing  their  argument. 

Having  hopefuUiy  laid  to  rest  the  specter  of  mass  cancellation  of  flights 
(since  this  tactic  is  presently  available  and  has  not  been  exercised),  I 
will  now  turn  to  what  I  feel  is  the  relevant  issue  before  the  committee: 
"What  are  the  costs  and  benefits  associated  with  the  deregulation  of  prices 
for  the  trunk  airlines?"  From  an  economic  perspective,  the  following 
arguments  can  be  advanced: 

1.  Currently  aTL  price  variations  are  subject  to  CAB  approval.  The 
delay  factor  in  seeking  and  getting  approval  for  fare  changes 
inhibits  rapid  adaptation  to  changing  demand  patterns  in  the  market. 
In  a  "ftree"  market  no  longer  would  this  flexibility  be  retarded. 

2.  Fixing  prices  reduces  competition  and  protects  inefficiency. 
Basically  each  airline  firm  faces  three  kinds  of  competition: 
substitution  effect  -  traveling  via  another  mode  of  transportation, 
price  effect  —  traveling  on  another  airline  that  flies  more  cheaply, 
and  differentiation  effect  -  traveling  on  another  airline  because 
it  is  more  preferred  for  reasons  other  than  price.  When  prices  are 
set,  the  first  two  components  of  competition  are  also  fixed.  Thus, 
intra-industry  competition  has  been  substantially  reduced.  If  the 
set  price  is  too  low,  firms  will  not  make  a  profit  and  will  elimin- 
ate Eci-vice  (get  out  of  the  market),  which  they  can  do,  in  general. 
If  the  set  price  is  "on  the  mark"  no  harm  will  have  been  done, 

But,  if  the  price  is  too  high,  the  consumer  is  in  effect  subsidizing 
the  trunks  with  the  Impiicit  sanction  of  the  government.  Carriers 
vrtiich  norraaUy  could  not  derive  a  profit  can  continue  to  exist  on 
this  subsidy.  Furthermore,  by  their  very  existence  they  raise  the 
cost  of  entry  to  the  market.  Thus,  other  firms,  presently  outside 
of  the  market,  might  be  able  to  fiy  routes  more  economically,  but 
current  market  penetration  by  inefficient  carriers  prevents  their 
entrance  into  the  market  place. 


435 


-  5  - 

3.  Due  to  reduced  price  competition,  the  airline  industry  may  tend 
to  overallocate  expenditures  in  seversLL  areas  as  advertising  and 
other  non-price  promotional  categories. 
k.     There  is  no  real  Justification  for  setting  prices.  The  airline 

industry  is  not  monopolistic,  nor  is  it  a  public  utility.  Certainly, 
minimum  safety  standards  must  be  maintained;  but  allowing  price 
competition  has  no  bearing  on  this  issue. 
I  have  argued  from  an  economic  perspective  irtiy  deregulation  should  be 
undertaken.  The  gnawing  question  of  what  would  then  happen  still  remains. 
Would  prices  remain  fixed  or  go  dovm?  Would  service  decrease  or  increase? 
No  one  has  a  crystal  ball.  The  AIA  looked  at  the  problem  only  from  the 
service  angle;  I  believe  their  excmination  was  faulty.  According  to  its 
Hiase  9  opinion  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation,  the  CAB 
concludes  that  price  setting  results  in  an  elimination  of  excess  profits 
via  a  supersatxaration  of  flights  in  the  market  (thus  diminishing  load  factors 
to  the  breakeven  level) .  If  the  trunk  market  were  deregxolated,  the  following 
fare-service  situations  coxild  occur  for  a  given  city -pair: 

1.  No  change  in  price  because  the  regulated  price  accurately  reflected 
the  free  market  clearing  value.  In  that  case  the  trunks  would  have 
no  incentive, to  change  their  service  (everything  else  remaining  the 
same). 

2.  Price  of  fares  decrease  because  the  public  "subsidy"  has  been 
eliminated.  Indeed,  service  most  likely  would  be  curtailed  some- 
what, the  amo\jnt  depending  on  both  the  price  and  the  service  elas- 
ticities of  demand.  The  airlines  would  become  more  competitive 
and  efficient;  their  scheduling  times  would  cater  more  to  the 
variations  of  customer  demand.  The  profit  picture  of  the  trunks 
WDXild  not  significantly  change;  in  neither  the  pre-  nor  the  post- 
deregulation  periods  would  they  be  making  excess  profits.   In 
fact,  if  anyone  would  be  adversely  affected,  it  would  be  the  equip- 
ment manufacturers.  The  public  would  be  better  off  because  their 
fares  would  be  reduced,  and  the  airlines  would  be  more  rapidly 
responsive  to  their  changing  demand  patterns.  The  amount  of  the 
drop  in  service,  I  feel,  would  not  be  significant.   In  any  event, 


436 


-6  - 

the  wholesale  cancellation  of  scheduled  fli^ats  would  not  occur  for 

reasons  mentioned  previously. 
Since  the  simulation  model  has  not  provided  definitive  answers  to  the 
questions  posed  by  the  connittee,  the  next  task  is  to  seek  the  appropriate 
avenue  of  investigation.  There  ore  basically  the  three  approaches  mentioned 
by  Dr.  James  in  his  letter: 

1.  Build  a  macroeconomic  model.  To  construct  such  a  model  from 
scratch  in  which  one  could  place  faith  in  its  output  would  be  a 
most  difficult  task. 

2.  Build  a  simulation  model  that  appropriately  reflects  the  problem 
at  hand.  To  incorporate  congjetition,  service  elasticity  of  demand, 
and  correct  the  misallocation  of  costs  via  the  city-pair  method 
would  be  a  formidable  job. 

3.  Study  the  effects  of  non-regulation  in  price  in  some  of  the  larger 
states  ~  say  California  and  Texas.  The  market  in  these  states 
could  then  serve  as  a  microcosm  for  a  nationwide  projection.  In 
partic\alar,  I  feel  that  a  more  thorough  analysis  of  fare  and  service 
rate  changes  should  be  made  with  regard  to  the  entrance  into  the 
market  of  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  (PSA)  and  Southwest  Airlines 
(WN). 


' 


437 

Prepared  Statement  of  George  W.  Douglas 

I  am  grateful  for  the  opportunity  to  come  before  you  today  to  comment  on  the 
regulation  and  performance  of  our  airline  industry.  In  the  current  inflationary 
environment  it  is  particularly  appropriate  that  your  committee  undertake  to 
examine  the  operations  and  policies  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  For  while  in 
the  early  years  of  the  industry  the  modus  operandi  and  protective  policies  of  the 
Board  ma.v  have  served  a  useful  role,  they  are  in  large  measure  now  outmoded 
and  now  serve  primarily  to  significantly  increase  the  costs,  energy  usage,  and 
prices  of  air  transportation.  Certainly  in  an  era  of  inflation,  energy  shortage,  and 
general  financial  stringency  we  can  ill  afford  to  perpetuate  these  costly  and  waste- 
ful practices. 

I  should  like  to  note  at  the  outset  that  I  do  not  attribute  this  state  of  affairs  to 
venality  of  the  regulators :  tliey  have  not  structured  or  regulated  the  industry 
so  as  to  bestow  excessive  profits  on  the  air  carriers.  Rather,  the  effect  of  the 
traditional  regulatory  practices  and  policies  of  the  CAB  has  been  substantial  in- 
creases in  the  costs  of  the  carriers  and  fares  paid  by  the  public  for  air  travel. 
While  the  regulatory  policies  which  increase  costs  and  prices  are  numerous,  by 
far  the  dominant  aspect  of  waste  is  associated  with  the  excessive  level  of  empty 
seats  carried  in  the  system.  While  the  nature  of  the  market  requires  that  some 
proportion  of  the  seats  on  average  be  unfilled,  the  level  which  prevails  is  exces- 
sive. I  have  calculated  that  from  this  source  alone,  the  costs  and  fares  of  pas- 
sengers in  1969  were  in  the  range  of  $366  million  to  $538  million  in  excess  of  the 
fares  they  would  have  paid  in  the  absence  of  this  waste.  While  I  have  not  access 
to  current  data  which  would  enable  me  to  completely  reestimate  these  results  for 
1974.  by  extrapolation  they  would  be  on  the  order  of  $850  million.  One  can  gain  a 
similar  "real  world"  perspective  of  these  costs  by  comparing  the  fares  which 
prevail  in  the  intrastate  markets  of  California  and  Texas  and  those  of  similar 
interstate  markets  on  the  east  coast.  I  have  described  these  fares  in  table  1,  and  as 
as  you  can  see  those  in  the  CAB  regulated  interstate  markets  are  from  29  percent 
to  109  percent  higher.  I  have  also  calculated  in  an  earlier  study  the  fares  which 
could  prevail  in  other  interstate  markets,  taking  into  account  all  tho.se  factors 
which  would  affect  the  level  of  eflScient  costs,  such  as  distance,  market  density, 
aircraft  t.vpe,  service  quality  and  convenience.  These  "optimal"  fares  and  the 
actual  coach  fares  of  1972  are  reported  for  several  markets  in  table  2.  While 
some  minor  portion  of  the  observed  differences  can  be  attributed  to  other  sources 
(i.e.,  weather  and  traffic  delays,  terminal  costs  and  landing  fees),  the  major  rea- 
son why  the  California  and  Texas  carriers  can  operate  profitably  at  such  a  con- 
siderably lower  fare  is  their  significantly  higher  load  factor  (i.e.,  proportion  of  the 
total  seats  filled).  Since  most  of  the  costs  in  air  transport  are  simply  those  of 
flying  the  aircraft  from  terminal  to  terminal,  clearly  the  average  cost  per  pas- 
senger is  reduced  by  increasing  the  number  of  passengers  per  flight.  There  is  ab- 
solutely no  reason  why  the  invisible  state  boundaries  over  which  the  aircraft  pass 
on  these  and  other  interstate  routes  should  change  the  nature  of  the  airline  mar- 
kets so  that  these  passengers  should  continue  to  pay  these  excessive  fares. 

TABLE  I.-COMPARISON  OF  FARES  IN  SELECTED  INTRASTATE  AND  INTERSTATE  MARKETS  (DECEMBER  1974) 


City-pair  market 


Fare  (cents 
Distance        Coach  fare  per  mile) 


Boston-Washington 

San  Diego-San  Francisco '._ 

Chicago-Minneapolis 

Los  Angeles-San  Francisco' 

New  York-Washington 

Dallas-San  Antonio' 

Boston-New  York 

Washington-Philadelphia. . . 
Los  Angeles-San  Diego ' . .  - 


413 

$45. 00 

10.90 

449 

29.00 

6.46 

344 

42.00 

12.21 

355 

20.75 

5.84 

228 

2  29.00 

3  12.72 

253 

^25.00 

5  9.  88 

186 

26.00 

13.98 

133 

24.00 

18.05 

101 

10.75 

10.64 

'  Intrastate  markets  not  under  CAB  regulation. 
-  $25  off  peak  or  night  coach  fare. 
3  $10.96  off  peak  or  night  coach  fare. 
*  $15  off  peak  or  night  coach  fare. 
^  $5.93  off  peak  or  night  coach  fare. 


180 

$16.82 

$24.  00 

$20.  85 

1.24 

184 

20.63 

23.00 

19.97 

.97 

256 

18.67 

28.00 

24.23 

1.30 

675 

32.29 

55.00 

46.63 

1.44 

1,092 

44.65 

83.00 

69.95 

1.57 

1,627 

64.99 

113.00 

93.05 

1.43 

2,453 

86.88 

163. 00 

134.21 

1.54 

2  434 

92.10 

155. 00 

127.63 

1.39 

438 

TABLE  2.-ESTIMATES  OF  OPTIMAL  AIR  COACH  FARES  AND  ACTUAL  FARES,  SELECTED  MARKETS 
[In  19711 

Ratio  of 

Optimal  Coach  Adjusted     adjusted  yield 

City-pair  market  Distance  fare  fare  yield'    to  optimal  fare 

Baltimore-New  York 

Huntsville-Memphis 

Chicago-St.  Louis 

Chicago-Philadelphia 

New  York-Miami 

Denver-New  York 

Los  Angeles-New  York.. 

San  Francisco-Washington 

1  Adjusted  for  incidence  of  discount  fares  (see  CAB  docket  21866-9,  exhibit  BC-6006). 

Source:  George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C.  Miller,  III,  "Economic  Regulation  and  Domestic  Air  Transport,"  The  Brook- 
ings Institution,  Washington,  1974. 

The  ostrich-like  attitude  of  the  CAB  in  ipnoriug  the  lessons  of  tlae  California 
experience  and  in  not  seeking  the  manifest  henefits  which  could  he  obtained  for 
the  travelling  public  generally  can  only  be  regarded  as  scandalous.  This  attitude 
of  the  Board  was  not  based  on  ignorance ;  as  early  as  August  1965,  a  CAB  staff 
report  carefully  pointed  out  the  fares,  costs  and  profitability  in  the  California 
intrastate  markets.  (See  S.L.R.  Brown  and  Associates,  "Traffic.  Fares  and  Com- 
petition/ Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  Air  Travel  Corridor."  Staff  Research  report 
No.  4,  Research  and  Statistics  Division,  Bureau  of  Accounts  and  Statistics, 
August  1965). 

To  understand  how  these  cost  and  fare  differentials  arise  between  the  inter- 
state routes  under  CAB  regulation,  and  the  intrastate  routes,  which  are  not,  one 
must  look  to  the  nature  of  the  airline  markets  under  CAB  regulation.  The  prin- 
cipal aspects  of  CAB  regulation  which  have  brought  us  the  high  cost-high  fare 
markets  are  those  affecting  price  competition  and  entry.  Effective  price  compe- 
tition (where  it  in  fact  exists)  in  the  unregulated  industries  serves  an  im- 
portant role  in  both  keeping  prices  in  line  with  the  lowest  possible  costs  of  pro- 
duction of  goods  of  a  given  quality,  and  in  forcing  producers  to  produce  effi- 
ciently. On  examination  of  the  history  of  CAB  policy  in  this  area,  one  can  only 
conclude  that  its  principal  thrust  has  been  to  discourage  or  suppress  price  com- 
petition among  the  carriers.  Carriers  are  discouraged  from  comi)eting  with  price 
because  fare  changes  must  be  filed  with  the  Board,  and  are  subject  to  challenge 
by  their  rivals.  Having  observed  a  pattern  of  disapprovals,  they  understandably 
seek  other  avenues  of  rivalry. 

Complementing  the  discouragement  of  price  competition  is  the  Board's  con- 
sistent sheltering  of  the  industry  from  competition  by  new  firms.  Upon  the 
establishment  of  the  CAB  in  1938,  the  existing  carriers  were  given  certificates 
of  public  convenience  and  necessity  accorded  them  by  their  "grandfather"  rights. 
While  the  CAB  has  allowed  the  entry  of  a  new  class  of  "local  service"  carriers, 
it  has  not  allowed  the  entry  of  a  single  new  trunk  carrier  to  compete  in  the 
principal  markets  since  1938.  CAB  entry  protection  has  been  sufficient  to  enable 
the  grandfather  carriers  to  retain  about  nine  tenths  of  total  domestic  air  service, 
despite  a  250-fold  increase  in  total  traffic  since  193S.  Since  in  unregulated  indus- 
try the  absence  of  effective  price  competition  and  excessive  prices  brings  about 
new  entrants,  one  can  see  the  importance  of  the  foreclosure  of  entry  in  discourag- 
ing effective  competition.  While  the  Board  has  granted  the  entry  of  existing  firms 
Into  formerly  monopoly  markets  (i.e.,  between  two  cities)  so  that  monopoly  itself 
is  not  a  major  problem,  the  fact  that  each  firm  faces  the  same  rival  in  many 
markets  reduces  the  incidence  of  competition. 

It  should  be  pointed  out,  as  well,  that  a  monopoly  is  not  required  for  the  effi- 
cient operation  of  air  transportation.  Unlike  the  generation  and  distribution  of 
electric  power,  for  example,  econometric  studies  of  the  airline  industry's  costs 
are  virtually  unanimous  in  showing  tlie  lack  of  scale  economies.  That  is,  in  the 
former  case,  since  electric  power  can  be  produced  and  distributed  in  a  city  at 
less  cost  by  one  large  firm  than  four  smaller  firms,  it  is  in  the  public  interest  to 
establish  and  regulate  a  monopoly.  This  is  not  the  case  in  the  airline  industry. 

While  the  airlines  do  not  compete  with  prices,  they  do  compete  in  other  ways, 
such  as  advertising  and  the  provision  of  passenger  services  and  amenities.  This 
form  of  competition  is  beneficial  to  the  traveller,  and  can  be  most  noticed  in  its 
absence  in  those  markets  with  only  one  carrier  or  whether  there  is  no  effective 


439 

competition  for  some  other  reason.  But  of  far  greater  consequence  in  attracting 
passengers  is  the  frequency  of  flights.  The  carriers  have  discovered  that  the 
surest  way  to  increase  their  share  of  the  market  is  to  increase  their  flight 
frequencies. 

Thus,  even  though  the  fares  in  most  CAB-reguIated  markets  are  too  high,  this 
does  not  mean  that  the  carriers  earn  excessive  profit.  Rather,  the  result  of  the 
nonprice  comjjetition,  i>articularly  in  .scheduling,  is  to  increa.se  the  average  cost 
per  pa.ssenger  carried  up  to  the  level  of  the  price.  In  economic  terms,  we  would 
describe  this  market  as  one  in  which  the  costs  are  determined  by  the  price,  rather 
than  the  reverse,  which  Ls  the  usual  ca.se.  While  along  with  the  higher  price,  the 
travelling  public  does  benefit  from  the  convenience  of  more  frequent  departures 
(and  a  reduction  of  the  chance  that  a  seat  is  not  available  on  the  preferred 
flight  j,  the  additional  costs  are  well  out  of  proportion  to  any  po.ssible  value  that 
could  be  attributed  to  this  convenience.  In  short,  the  reason  why  the  costs  in  the 
regulated  indu-stry  are  high  and  the  number  of  wasted  .seats  is  large  and  the 
amount  of  wasted  fuel  is  high,  is  .simply  that  the  CAB-regulated  prices  have  been 
too  high.  They  are  particularly  .so  in  the  long  distance  routes  and  in  the  densely, 
heavily  travelled  route.s. 

By  contrast,  the  regtilatory  restraints  imposed  by  the  state  commissions  of 
Texas  and  California  have  not  had  the  .same  effect.  The  intrastate  c-arriers  have 
found  that  they  can  effectively  comijete  with  a  fair  profit  by  offering  .services  at 
a  considerably  lower  price,  doing  so  becau.se  they  have  found  ways  to  reduce 
.some  operating  costs,  but  more  importantly,  by  adjusting  schedules  "so  that  they 
fly  fewer  empty  .seats.  With  commensurately  lower  fares  in  interstate  routes,  the 
CAB-regulated  carriers  would  be  forced  to  do  the  .same. 

Since  the  relatively  high-fare  high-cost  equilibrium  which  obtains  in  the  inter- 
state markets  have  not  provided  the  economical  services  the  public  deserves,  nor 
provided  the  carriers  an  exceptional  profit,  why  does  such  a  condition  exist? 

My  own  interj^retation  of  the  regulatory  hLstory  is  that  the  CAB  has  failed  to 
understand  adwjuately  the  basic  economic  forces  in  the  industry  and  the  changes 
which  have  occurred  which  should  have  altered  its  fundamental  policies. 

The  legislative  "Declaration  of  Policy"  in  the  Federal  aviation  acts  by  which 
the  CAB  operates  admonishes  the  CAB  to  "promote"  the  industry  as  well  as  reg- 
ulate it.  In  its  formative  years  as  an  "infant"  industry  it  was  the  belief  of  Con- 
gress that  its  development  was  in  the  national  interest,  and  the  industry  was  for 
many  years  encouraged  in  its  growth  by  direct  sub.sidy.  In  addition  to  direct 
subsidy  the  CAB  attempted  to  further  promote  and  expand  the  industry  by  in- 
ternal cross  subsidy.  That  is.  the  carriers  would  be  required  to  fly  a  number  of 
routes  that  could  not  cover  costs.  To  compen.sate  the  carriers  for  the.se  losses  the 
carriers  were  allowed  to  earn  exce.ss  profits  in  the  viable  markets.  To  shelter 
these  profits  required  the  competitive  restraints  described  above :  barriers  to  new 
competition  and  discouragement  of  price  competition.  While  the.se  arrangements 
for  cross  subsidy  even  in  the  indastry's  formative  years  can  be  criticized  on  eco- 
nomic grounds,  they  nonethele.ss  had  some  logic  given  the  stated  goals  of  extend- 
ing air  tran.sport  .services  as  rapidly  and  extensively  as  rx».ssible. 

The  industry  has  grown  and  prospered,  and  is  now  the  dominant  commercial 
mode  of  intercity  traveL  The  trunklines  grew  out  of  their  needs  for  direct  sub- 
sidy in  the  fifties,  and  the  role  of  expanding  .services  in  small  markets  was  as- 
sumed by  the  local  .service  carriers.  Just  as  the  trunk  carriers  have  outgrown 
their  need  for  direct  subsidy,  they  have  al.so  outgrown  the  need  for  internal  cross- 
sub.sidy.  Reflecting  thLs  in  some  extent  is  the  Boards  action  in  the  last  10  years 
or  so  of  increasing  the  number  of  carriers  in  each  viable  market.  However,  the 
traditions  of  .sheltering  and  protection  from  competition  developed  in  the  indus- 
try's early  years  have  persisted,  although  the  need  for  them  has  pas.sed.  In  the 
milieu  of  nonprice  competition,  the  fare  levels  which  would  have  once  generated 
the  excess  profits  in  the  "lucrative'"  markets,  are  dissipated  in  higher  costs  to  the 
benefit  of  no  one. 

Lest  I  Ije  misinterpreted  as  suggesting  that  the  CAB  expand  its  regulation  to 
include  the  restraint  of  .scheduling  competition,  let  me  declare  directly  that  such 
a  move  is  unneces.sary  and  undesirable.  Were  the  CAB  to  take  a  policy  which 
would  encourage  more  effective  price  competition,  the  price  level  would  fall  and 
with  it  the  level  of  exce.ss  capacity  offered.  Currently  pending  before  the  Board 
IS  an  important  ca.se  in  this  regard,  in  which  the  Board  must  consider  the  d-^-sir- 
abiUty  of  mutual  agreements  by  the  carriers  to  restrain  capacity.  This  would  in 
effect,  perfect  the  cartel,  and  if  not  coupled  with  fare  reduction.s  ( which  are  not 
propo.sed;  would  generate  excessive  profits  in  tho.se  markets.  Travellers  in  those 
markets  would  be  paying  for  a  level  of  .service  which  would  be  denied  them  bv 
anticompetitive  agreement. 


440 

The  tradition  of  attempted  cross-subsidy  and  the  Board's  apparent  aversion 
of  efficient  low-cost  air  travel  is  nowhere  more  apparent  than  in  the  interna- 
ti(mal  markets.  The  CAB,  while  not  unilaterally  regulating  these  markets, 
has  a  contributing  role  which  has  seldom  advanced  the  consumers'  interest.  In 
this  case,  the  CAB  sets  rules  which  shelter  the  international  cartel  (The  Inter- 
national Air  Transport  Association)  from  effective  price  competition.  The  plainly 
excessive  lATA  fares  are  sheltered  by  CAB  policies  which  restrain  air  charters 
with  affinity  rules,  and  now  with  minimum  fare  floors.  Moreover,  the  occasional 
proposals  for  entry  of  a  new  carrier  promising  efficient,  low-cost  service  are  re- 
jected even  though  there  is  no  credible  evidence  that  the  service  would  be 
predatory  (i.e.,  below  cost). 

The  tradition  of  cross  subsidy  is  so  engrained  with  the  regulator  and  the  in- 
cumbent carriers  (one  can  predict  its  stout  defense  by  the  Air  Transport  As- 
sociation), that  even  a  statement  of  policy  contrary  to  the  same  by  the  Board 
in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  has  had  imperceptible  results  in 
actual  policy.  Let  me  state  some  frequent  criticisms  by  economists  of  the  practice : 

1)  If  the  policy  is  effective  (generating  profits  in  some  markets  which 
subsidize  losses  in  others),  there  is  a  net  loss  of  benefits;  the  additional 
benefits  received  by  those  consuming  the  subsidized  good  or  service  are  less 
than  the  additional  costs  borne  by  those  in  the  market  providing  the 
subsidy ; 

2)  There  is  no  presumption  that  the  implicit  transfer  of  benefits  is  equit- 
able. Particularly  it  should  not  be  assumed  that  the  traveller  in  the 
"large"  market  (e.g.  the  grandmother  flying  from  New  York  to  Los  Angeles) 
has  a  higher  income  than  the  traveller  in  the  "small"  market  (e.g.  the 
businessman  flying  from  Cedar  Rapids  to  Chicago) . 

3)  The  cross-subsidy  mechanism  is  seldom  effective.  As  in  the  airline 
industry,  to  provide  one  dollar  extra  profit  in  one  market  may  require  that 
the  consumers  pay  five  or  more  dollars  in  additional  fares. 

4)  The  amount  and  value  of  the  subsidy  is  invisible,  and  not  subject 
to  regular  review  by  the  agency  or  the  Congress.  Hence,  the  level  of  sub- 
sidized services  tends  to  grow  well  beyond  that  intended.  A  corollary  is 
that  the  nonremunerative  services  provide  an  attractive  legislative  pork 
barrel  whose  costs  are  not  revealed. 

I  should  like  to  take  this  opportunity  to  speculate  on  the  various  methods  of 
reform  that  might  influence  tlie  CAB  to  lie  more  responsive  to  the  needs  of 
the  public  in  developing  an  efficient  air  transport  system.  As  is  evident  from  my 
statement  today.  I  feel  that  current  Board  i>olicy  is  misfUrected  (or  at  best, 
without  direction).  To  this  I  might  offer  some  personal  observations. 

First,  upon  initiating  my  studies  of  the  airline  industry  in  15)68.  I  was  sup- 
posed to  find  that  the  CAB.  whose  mission  is  the  economic  regulation  of  the 
industry,  had  so  few  professional  economists  on  its  staff.  The  rare  exception 
of  a  very  capable  economist  of  whom  I  am  aware,  appears  to  be  an  embarrass- 
ment to  be  ignored.  By  the  same  token,  the  membership  of  the  Board  has  never 
included  an  economist,  and  to  my  knowledge  and  observation,  the  economic 
training  and  perception  of  the  administrative  law  judges  would  appear  most 
rudimentary.  I  am  not  suggesting  that  economic  expertise  would  ensure  con- 
sistently good  decisions,  or  insulate  a  member  of  the  Board,  for  example,  from 
the  pressures  he  faces,  but  one  cannot  help  but  believe  that  there  would  be 
fewer  policies  which  aid  no  one/or  are  futile. 

Second,  the  experience  of  the  permissive  regulation  in  California  and  Texas 
suggests  that  some  substantial,  phased  movement  toward  deregulation  should 
occur.  I  say  this  from  a  background  of  pragmatism,  rather  than  from  a  doctrin- 
aire "free  market"'  philosophy.  (I  am  a  Ph.  D.  from  Yale,  not  Chicago.)  In  fact, 
one  of  the  remarkable  things  about  the  study  of  regulation  of  transportation  is 
the  consensxis  of  almost  all  economists,  "liberal"  and  "conservative."  that  it  has 
in  large  measure  failed  its  intended  purpose  or  is  currently  obsolescent,  and  is 
desired  only  by  the  industries  regulated. 

Recognizing  tlie  improbability  of  a  phased  deregulation  of  the  industry,  I 
would  like  to  offer  some  proposals  that  would  cau!<e  airline  regulation  to  be  more 
efficient  and  resjionsive  to  tlie  public.  These  proposals  were  made  by  James  C. 
Miller  III  and  me  in  our  recent  study  of  the  industry  for  the  Brookings  Insti- 
tution.^ and  are  taken  directly  from  that  study  : 


1  Goorffe  W.   Doufilas  and  James   C.   Miller  III.   Economic  Rojrulation  of  Domestic  .Vir 
Transport :  Theory  and  Policy,  Brookings.  Washington.  1974. 


441 

KEFORMS    UNDER    EXISTING    LEGISLATION 

Under  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  the  Board  has  considerable  latitude  in  framing 
regulatory  policy.  We  shall  here  describe  a  number  of  recommendations  which 
are  possible  under  the  existing  statute.  First,  a  set  of  possible  actions  that 
should  not  be  attempted. 

1.  Do  n/it  attempt  to  regulate  return  on  investment. — As  described  in  chapter  4, 
carriers  will  employ  nonprice  competition  to  a  point  where  the  anticipated  return 
on  additional  investment  is  equal  to  the  carriers'  own  internal  required  rate  of 
return.  Board  attempts  to  regulate  this  return  precisely  as  a  predetermined 
reasonable  rate  will  prove  fruitless  and  will  lead  the  market  equilibrium  away 
from  the  efficient  combination  (see  figure  4-2). 

2.  Do  not  approve  eapacitij  agreements. — As  described  previously,  the  long- 
range  effect  of  capacity  agreements  is  carrier  inefficiency  in  matching  capacity 
with  demand.  Another  result  is  excess  profits  in  capacity-controlled  markets,  pro- 
vided fares  are  not  adjusted  downward  accordingly,  which  represent  an  alloca- 
tive  efficiency  cost. 

3.  Do  not  approve  fuel  reduction  and  rescheduling  agreements. — Restrictions  on 
fuel  supplies  to  airline  firms  obviously  limit  the  amount  of  capacity  they  can 
offer.  Competition  among  firms  in  planning  schedules  leads  generally  to  an  effi- 
cient ovei-i^ll  network,  that  is,  capacity  offerings  responsive  to  passenger  demand. 
Not  only  are  rescheduling  agreements  not  needed,  but  they  lead  to  inefficiencies 
and  create  excess  industry  profits. 

4.  Do  not  limit  entry  to  protect  incumbent  carriers. — As  described  in  chapter 
7,  entry  controls  insulate  existing  carriers  from  competition.  If  a  prospective 
entrant  appears  likely  to  succeed  in  the  market  to  the  detriment  of  an  incumber 
carrier,  then  this  may  be  an  indication  that  the  new  carrier  is  more  efficient.  Pro- 
tests from  incumbent  carriers  are  to  be  exi)ected,  but  to  give  them  great  weight 
is  to  encourage  technical  inefficiency. 

5.  Do  not  suspend  or  find  unlawful  fare  decreases  on  grounds  of  protecting 
competitive  carriers. — Understandably,  whenever  one  carrier  proposes  to  reduce 
a  fare  its  competitors  will  object,  preferring  instead  the  existing  fare  level.  Re- 
fusing to  approve  such  an  initiative  protects  less  efficient  carriers  and  con- 
strains differentiation  in  price-quality  options. 

6.  Do  not  limit  exit  from  service. — If  a  carrier  wishes  to  suspend  or  abandon 
a  market,  its  decision  is  an  indication  that  the  social  value  derived  from  the 
service  is  less  than  the  cost  of  providing  it.  To  constrain  exit  is  inefficient.  (How- 
ever, the  Board  should  be  liberal  in  certificating  a  new  carrier  in  any  abandoned 
market. ) 

7.  Do  not  regulate  commuter  carriers. — Continuing  the  exemption  for  com- 
muter carriers  is  a  good  way  of  testing  the  efficiency  of  trunk-  and  local-service 
carrier  service.  That  is,  if  a  commuter  carrier  can  provide  service  under  regu- 
lator-imposed cost  disadvantages,  then  this  is  a  market  test  of  the  inefficiency  of 
trunkliue  and  local  service  carrier  provision. 

8.  Do  not  further  restrict  (charter)  operations  of  the  supplemental  carriers. — 
The  supplemental  carriers  provide  a  vital  function  in  competing  with  the  sched- 
uled carriers.  Not  only  do  they  provide  benchmarks  of  technical  efficiency,  but 
they  reveal  the  need  for  lower  price-quality  options  in  scheduled  service.  With- 
out the  supplementals  the  inefficiencies  of  trunk  service  would  be  partially 
masked. 

FEASIBLE    PROPOSALS    OF    AN    AFFIRiIATI\-E    NATURE 

1.  Detemune  and  bring  about  the  optimum  level  and  structure  of  fare-quality 
options. — Hold  a  specific  hearing  in  which  the  trade-off  between  fare  level  and 
quality  is  brought  under  close  scrutiny  and  a  determination  is  made  concerning 
the  optimal  level  and  structure  of  fares  and  quality.  At  the  same  time,  explore 
the  feasibility  of  increasing  the  number  of  price-quality  options. 

2.  Hold  general  investigations  regarding  policies  toward  entry,  exit,  mergers, 
and  collusion. — At  present,  all  of  these  matters  are  treated  on  an  ad  hoc  basis. 
An  investigation  which  looked  at  the.se  issues  in  the  same  depth  as  the  Domestic 
Passenger  Fare  Investigation  looked  at  fares  would  be  appropriate  and  presum- 
ably would  lead  to  the  identification  of  more  si>ecific,  efficiency-inducing  policies. 

3.  Encourage  price  competition  and  market  tests  of  p7-ice-quality  options. — 
Conclude  that  under  .section  1002(d)  of  the  PYderal  Aviation  Act  a  zone  of  reason- 
ableness for  fares  is  in  the  public  interest.  Such  a  zone  might  work  either  in 
terms  of  per  se  reasonableness  (meaning  lawful  on  grounds  of  reasonableness 
whatever  the  ca.se),  or  prima  facie  reasonableness  (that  is,  presumed  to  be  law- 
ful on  grounds  of  reasonableness  unless  proven  otherwise).  This  might  also  be 


442 

coupled  with  a  stated  policy  of  giving  less  weight  to  questions  of  alleged  discrim- 
ination, preference,  or  prejudice.  The  zone  might  also  allow  for  broad  variations 
in  price-quality  options,  thereby  giving  market  tests  of  the  preferred  combinations. 

4.  Reform  the  decisionmaking  process.— It  would  enhance  economic  eflSciency 
if  in  the  adversary  process  more  emphasis  were  placed  on  substance  and  less  on 
form.  Also,  it  would  improve  the  quality  of  decisions  if  more  economics  expertise 
were  required  of  administrative  law  judges  and  Board  oppointees.  Finally,  in 
view  of  the  tendency  of  the  Board  to  minimize  squawk,  public  or  private  interest 
advocates  with  economic  efficiency  positions  should  be  encouraged  to  present 
their  case. 

While  the  above  reforms  do  not  exhaust  the  possibilities  feasible  under  exist- 
ing legislation,  they  include  some  of  the  more  important  ones,  and,  if  adopted, 
would  go  far  toward  increasing  the  efficiency  of  airline  markets. 

KEFORMS   REQUIRING   ADDITIONAL   LEGISLATION 

Even  more  substantive  reforms  are  possible  with  new  legislation.  Essentially, 
initial  legislation  setting  up  a  regulatory  agency  specifies  broad  objectives  for 
regulation  and  grants  powers  to  the  regulator  which  ultimately  take  the  form 
of  constraints  on  industry  behavior.  Reform  legislation  typically  can  take  one 
or  more  of  three  directions.  First,  it  might  change  or  identify  more  clearly 
regulatory  objectives ;  second,  it  might  specify  particular  restraints  on  the  in- 
dustry, thus  telling  the  Board  more  clearly  what  to  do ;  or  third,  it  might  prohibit 
certain  previously  imposed  restraints,  thus  telling  the  Board  what  not  to  do.  The 
reforms  described  below  contain  aspects  of  all  three. 

1.  Redefine  public  interest  to  mean  economic  efficiency. — As  described  in  the 
appendix,  the  legislative  "Declaration  of  Policy,"  which  essentially  defines  the 
term  "public  interest"  as  used  in  the  statute,  is  ambiguous  and  contains  mutually 
conflicting  goals,  some  of  which  are  inconsistent  with  economic  efficiency.  A 
simple  legislative  change  which  would  have  an  important  effort  is  replacing  the 
Declaration  of  Policy  with  a  policy  statement  admonishing  the  Board  to  foster 
efficiency  in  airline  markets. 

2.  Separate  promotion  activities  from  economic  regulation. — As  described 
above,  the  Board  has  attempted  to  promote  air  transportation  and  this  has  re- 
sulted in  efficiency  losses.  If  there  are  public-good  aspects  of  the  industry  which 
require  its  artificial  promotion,  then  this  is  better  accomplished  through  other 
means.  For  example,  as  the  Ash  Council  has  recommended,  transfer  the  promo- 
tional activities  of  the  Board  to  the  Department  of  Transportation.  Also,  promo- 
tion, if  it  is  to  exist,  should  be  designed  to  augment  efficiency  in  the  provision  of 
the  subsidized  service.  An  example  is  the  competitive  bidding  scheme  proposed  by 
the  Board  to  assure  service  at  low-density  points. 

3.  Alter  burden  of  proof. — Change  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  to  make  entry 
and  exit  merely  consistent  with  the  public  interest,  rather  than  required  by  it. 
Make  the  approval  of  collusive  agreements  required  by  the  public  interest,  instead 
of  being  "not  inconsistent  with  the  public  interest."  These  changes  arguably  would 
make  entry  and  exit  freer  and  would  restrain  Board  sanctioned  collusion. 

4.  Expand  regulatory  exemptions. — Broaden  the  class  of  exempt  carriers  which 
may  provide  schedule^l  air  service.  This  could  be  at^complished  in  a  number  of 
ways.  First,  grant  commuter  carriers  an  explicit  exemption  and  liberalized 
standards  of  aircraft  size.  Second,  allow  existing  charter  carriers  to  engage  in 
single-ticketed  scheduled  service.  Third,  totally  dereguljite  the  denser  city-pair 
markets.  The  instances  of  inefficiency  under  complete  deregulation  are  likely 
to  be  minimized  the  larger  the  market  size;  also,  the  greatest  efficiency  gains 
from  deregulation  are  likely  to  be  found  in  such  markets. 

5.  Withdraw  or  modify  CAB  power  to  approve  intcrcarrier  agreements. — 
Revise  section  412  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  to  eliminate  tlie  power  of  the 
Board  to  circumvent  Iho  antitrust  laws  and  approve  and  enforce  cartel  agree- 
ments. With  possibly  few  exceptions,  agreements  coming  imder  this  provision  for 
the  purpose  of  escaping  antitrust  liability  are  inconsistent  with  maximizing 
industry  performance. 

In  both  explaining  regulatory  behavior  and  in  assessing  the  probability  of 
reform,  discussions  of  economists  usually  touch  a  common  theme :  that  the  firms 
being  regulated,  being  few  in  number  and  having  such  a  large,  perceived  stake 
in  the  legislation  and  policies  of  regulation  carry  an  overwhelming  influence  when 
compared  with  the  consumers,  wliose  numbers  are  immense  but  whose  burdens 
are  ill  perceived  and  spread  thinly.  It  is  my  hope  that  the  hearings  of  this  com- 
mittee may  in  some  measure  redress  this  bias.  Thank  you. 


COMPARISON   OF   UNREGULATED   INTRASTATE   AIR- 
LINES WITH  REGULATED  INTERSTATE  AIRLINES 


FRIDAY,  FEBRUARY  14,  1975 

U.S.  Senate, 
Subcommittee  on  Administrate: 

Practice  and  Procedure  of  the 

Committee  on  the  Judiciary, 

Boston.,  Mass. 
The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  notice,  at  9:45  a.m.,  in  room 
2003A,  JFK  Federal  Building,  Senator  Edward  ^L  Kennedy,  chair- 
man of  the  subcommittee,  presiding. 
Present :  Senator  Kennedy. 

Also  present :  Stephen  Breyer,  special  counsel ;  Philip  Bakes,  as- 
sistant counsel;  Thomas  M.  Susman,  chief  counsel;  and  Stephen  L. 
Jones,  minority  counsel. 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  subcommittee  will  come  to  order. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  SENATOR  KENNEDY 

The  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure  is  to- 
day continuing  its  hearings  on  Federal  regulation  of  the  airlines  and 
its  effects  on  air  transportation.  The  subcommittee  began  these  hearings 
in  Washington  last  week,  with  representatives  from  various  Govern- 
ment agencies  and  independent  economists  arguing  that  Federal 
regulation  of  airlines  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  is  costly  and  in- 
efficient. As  one  witness  pointed  out,  while  the  traveler  may  be  pleased 
to  find  the  seat  next  to  him  empty  so  he  can  stretch  out,  he  might  not  be 
as  comfortable  if  he  knew  that  he  was  paying  for  that  empty  seat. 

The  airline  passenger  these  days  can  get  free  drinks  on  coach  or  a 
piano  bar  in  the  lounge.  He  can  fly  a  "yellowbird''  or  other  designer- 
colored  airplanes,  and  can  choose  menus  and  movies.  He  can  "fly  Carol 
to  Miami"  or  content  himself  in  someone  else's  "friendly  skies."  JBut  one 
thing  he  cannot  do  is  fly  cheaply.  He  may  choose  between  airlines,  but 
he  cannot  choose  between  air  fares.  A  lot  of  people  believe  that  the 
Federal  Government  is  responsible.  And  they  may  be  right. 

The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  regulates  air  fares.  These  have  been 
skyrocketing  in  recent  years  and  continue  upward.  Some  economists 
have  estimated  that  air  fares  presently  average  32— iT  percent,  and  in 
some  cases  100  percent,  higher  than  they  would  be  without  CAB 
regulation. 

For  Boston  residents,  that  could  mean  flights  to  Xew  York  for  $15 
instead  of  $28,  to  Washington  for  $21  instead  of  $45,  and  to  Los  Angeles 
for  $90  instead  of  $188. 

The  CAB  also  regulates  the  entry  of  new  airlines  into  the  market- 
place. But  the  CAB  often  delays  action  on  requests  by  existing  carriers 
to  serve  new  routes.  And  it  generally  discourages  or  refuses  to  act  on 
applications  by  new  airlines  to  begin  new  service.  As  a  result,  not  one 
new  trunk  airline  has  started  operation  since  1938,  while  the  number 
of  major  carriers  has  actually  decreased  because  of  mergers. 

(443) 


444 

The  people  of  Massachusetts  know  this.  Northeast  Airlines  merged 
with.  Delta  3  years  ago.  Service  has  been  cut  back  to  many  areas  of 
the  State.  We  are  especially  fortunate,  however,  to  be  in  one  of  the 
few  areas  of  the  country  receiving  new  service,  from  Air  New  Eng- 
land. In  the  current  climate  of  Federal  regulation,  though,  the  future 
holds  no  special  promise  for  a  bright  young  innovative  competitor  in 
the  airline  business.  For  competition  seems  to  be  a  word  missing  from 
the  CAB's  dictionary. 

We  will  also  ask  the  regulated  airlines  who  fly  the  Northeast 
whether  they  have  considered  this  question — whether  they  could  pro- 
vide the  kind  of  low-price  service  that  PSA  and  other  State  airlines 
provide  in  other  parts  of  the  country. 

This  subcommittee  began  its  investigation  of  the  CAB  as  a  first 
step  in  the  regulatory  reform  process.  I  was  pleased  to  see  that  in  our 
hearings  last  week,  the  administration  responded  to  our  efforts,  and 
has  promised  to  develop  and  support  a  legislative  reform  package.  We 
will  continue  these  efforts  in  future  hearings. 

The  difference  between  low  air  fares  and  high  air  fares  should  not 
be  the  difference  between  the  absence  and  presence  of  Federal  regula- 
tion. If  it  is,  then  we  must  be  prepared  to  overhaul  regulation  and 
make  it  more  responsive  to  the  citizens  it  is  intended  to  serve. 

Our  first  witnesses  this  morning  will  be  Kobert  W.  Clifford  and 
Lawrence  Guske. 

Mr.  Clifford  has  spent  over  25  years  of  his  career  experience  in 
airline  management,  and  he  is  now  president  of  Air  California. 

Mr.  Lawrence  Guske,  is  assistant  controller  of  Pacific  Southwest 
Airlines  and  has  appeared  as  witness  for  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines 
in  several  hearings  before  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission. 

STATEMENTS  OF  LAWRENCE  A.  GUSKE,  ASSISTANT  CONTROLLER, 
PACIFIC  SOUTHWEST  AIRLINES,  AND  ROBERT  W.  CLIFFORD, 
PRESIDENT,  AIR  CALIFORNIA 

IMr.  Guske.  Would  you  like  for  me  to  read  my  statement? 

Senator  Kennedy.  No,  maybe  just  highlight  it  in  2  or  3  minutes,  if 
you  could  do  that  for  us. 

Mr.  Guske.  Essentially  some  background  on  PSA,  we  serve  only 
in  the  State  of  California.  We  serve  the  Stat«  with  jet  aircraft.  We 
carry  approximately  6.4  million  passengers  a  year.  Our  current  fares 
in  our  primary  markets  average  approximately  5.68  cents  per  revenue 
passenger-mile.  AVe  have  currently  pending  before  the  Public  Utilities 
Commission,  by  which  we  are  regulated  as  to  fares  and  markets,  an 
increase  which  would  bring  those  primary  market  fares  up  to  approxi- 
mately 6.3  cents  per  mile.  We  currently  serve  32  city-pairs  in  the  State 
of  California. 

I  think  that  summarizes  who  PSA  is  and  the  type  of  service  we 
provide. 

psa's  "no-frills"  service 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  have  had  a  chance  to  review  the  rates  that  are 
charged  by  PSA  and  allowed  by  the  CAB.  Why  do  you  think  you 
are  able  to  charge  a  good  deal  less  than  regulated  air  service  carriers  ? 


445 

Mr.  GusKE.  Actually,  in  the  State  of  California,  the  CAB  carriers 
that  compete  with  us  have  the  same  fares  that  we  do.  But  as  far  as 
going  to  the  point  of  fares,  in  and  of  themselves,  I  think  it  can  be 
attributed  to  several  factors.  We  try  to  keep  our  overhead  as  low  as 
we  possibly  can.  The  type  of  service  we  offer  is  no-frills  type  service. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  do  you  mean  by  "no  frills?" 

]Mr.  GusKE.  We  do  not  have  food  service. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  people  not  demand  that? 

Mr.  GusKE.  No,  our  flights  are  generally  very  short,  approximately 
an  hour. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Sort  of  like  New  York  to  Washington  ? 

Mr.  GusKE.  I  think  it  would  be  somewhat  similar.  I  am  not  familiar 
with  that  market. 

We  have  no  free  alcoholic  beverages.  We  have  high-density  seating 
on  our  aircraft,  and  we  have  a  general  policy  of  no  discounting  of 
our  fares.  We  do  not  have  military  fares  or  excureion  fares  and  such 
like  that.  The  only  discount  fares  are  for  children  under  the  age  of 
12,  and  that  is  it. 

I  think  that  factor,  and  then  our  ability  to  generate  passengers  with 
a  friendly  type  of  service,  which  is,  the  more  passengers,  the  more 
you  can  hold  down  your  costs  to  the  extent  of  being  able  to  spread 
them  over  more  passengers  and  so  on. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  it  is  completely  coincidental,  that 
even  the  certified  carriers  operating  in  competition  with  you  in  the 
intrastate  market,  charge  about  close  to  half  of  what  the  CAB  formula 
is  and  just  about  what  yours  is?  They  do  that  in  California  and  in 
Texas,  hut  they  do  not  do  it  in  other  parts  of  the  countrv.  Why  do  you 
think  they  do  that  ? 

Mr.  GusKE.  I  really  could  not  speculate  on  other  parts  of  the  coun- 
try. As  far  as  the  State  of  California  is  concerned,  the  fares  are  regu- 
lated by  the  Public  Utilities  Commission  and  at  this  point  they  have 
designated  PSA  as  the  most  efficient  fare  setting  carrier  in  the  State, 
and  that  has  been  their  policy  that  whatever  fares  they  authorize  for 
PSA  they  will  also  grant  to  CAB  carriers.  Since  they  do  regulate  the 
fares,  that  has  a  controlling  interest  to  an  extent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  competition  has  anything  to  do 
with  these  lower  fares? 

Mr.  GusKE.  Again,  I  cannot  speak  for  those  carriers,  but  I  think 
that  would  be  a  definite  consideration  of  theirs  in  trying  to  meet 
competition. 

Senator  Kennedy.  AVhat  you  are  saying  then  is  that  you  provide 
more  seats  in  the  plane  and  no  food  or  beverages.  Besides  the  courteous 
services  that  you  extend,  you  are  able  to  charge  less  for  the  miles  that 
will  be  carried,  and  that  this  concept  or  idea  has  been  endorsed  by  the 
people  traveling  your  airline. 

Mr.  GusKE.  Yes,  sir. 

possible  EXPANSION  BY  PSA  OUTSIDE  CALIFORNIA 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  like  to  fly  outside  of  California  ? 

Mr.  GusKE.  Yes,  we  would.  We  currentlv  have  pretty  much  been 
serving  the  major  markets  in  California.  There  is  not  much  left  for 
us  to  expand  into.  As  far  as  our  future  goes,  we  would  be  very  inter- 
ested in  flying  outside  the  State. 


446 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  do  you  not  ? 

Mr.  GusKE.  We  have  no  application  on  file  currently  with  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board,  which  may  have  jurisdiction  in  that  matter,  and 
we  are  not  certificated  bv  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  at  this  point. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  would  like  to  fly  outside  California,  what 
are  the  reasons  you  are  not  making  application  to  do  so  ? 

Mr.  GusKE.  Well,  we  have  not  completed  the  necessary  studies  and 
so  forth,  which  would  be  a  prerequisite  to  filing  applications  or  seeking 
additional  routes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Has  there  ever  been  a  cost  study  done  in  an  effort 
to  find  out  why  you  provide  services  more  cheaply  thrai  we  do  in  the 
East? 

INIr.  Guske.  Not  that  I  am  aware  of. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  are  not  familiar  with  the  CAB  study  of 
1966? 

Mr.  Guske.  I  am  not. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  customers  prefer  the  no-frills  serv- 
ice you  provide  for  short  flights  more  than  the  C AB-type  of  service  ? 

Mr.  Guske.  Well,  all  I  can  say  is  that  our  passengers  appear  to 
accept  our  services  and  they  come  back,  and  we  have  shown  over  the 
years  considerable  growth  "in  our  passenger  total,  so  we  believe  our 
service  is  very  well  accepted. 

AIR  CALIFORNIA 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  Clifford  could  you  tell  us  a  little  about  the 
situation  in  California  ? 

INIr.  Clifford.  Senator,  our  situation  is  slightly  different  from 
PSA's.  Ours  is  a  California  carrier,  and  have  grown  extremely  fast. 
We  carried  1.4  million  customers  in  1974.  We  have  been  in  business 
since  1967. 

Our  primary  entry  into  the  business  was  not  in  a  competitive  nature 
rather  than  new  services  that  our  people  felt  were  necessary  in  survey- 
ing the  markets  Avithin  California. 

So  our  fares  are  slightly  higher  than  PSA's.  Our  average  fare  is  6.4 
cents  a  mile.  Twelve  of  our  19  markets  are  in  fact  noncompetitive  in 
nature,  if  you  will,  having  started  from  markets  that  were  not  previ- 
ously served. 

We  compete  in  five  markets,  and  the  fares  that  we  cliarge  are  com- 
parable to  the  other  scheduled  carriers  in  those  markets,  primarily, 
because  the  Public  Utilities  Commission  grants  fares  throughout  the 
State  of  California  on  all  intrastate  routes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  do  you  charge  to  fly  from  Orange  County 
to  San  Francisco,  or  San  Diego  to  Oakland  ? 

]Mr.  Clifford.  $24.30,  Senator. 

Senator  Kennedy.  And  the  flight  from  Boston  to  Washington  is  just 
about  as  far,  is  it  not  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  I  am  not  sure. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  many  miles  is  it  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  From  Orange  County  to  San  Francisco  it  is  344  miles. 

CX)NTRAST  between   AIR    CALIFORNIA'S   FARES   AND   CAB  FARES 

Senator  Kennedy.  Boston  to  Washington  is  399,  and  it  costs  almost 
twice  as  much.  How  can  you  fly  more  cheaply  ? 


447 

j\Ir.  Clifford.  Well.  I  believe  there  are  three  basic  reasons  why  Air 
California  flies  more  cheaply.  One,  Ave  are  blessed  in  California  with 
some  weather  circumstances  and  conditions  that  favor  us,  and  having 
been  an  east  coast  operator,  I  am  aware  of  the  weather  problems  that 
are  involved  and  would  require  higher  fares. 

We  are  a  younger  airline,  and  our  employees — although  we  pay 

standard  rates,  if  you  will 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  know  that  the  Boston-Washington  route 
completes  98.2  perceiit  of  their  flights  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  We  complete  99.8. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  there  much  difference  between  98.2  and  99.8 
percent  in  terms  of  real  cost  savings  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  I  would  not  have  a  judgment,  Senator.  We  fly  higher 
load  factors.  Our  break-even  load  factor  is  at  this  point  65  percent.  So 
we  gear  our  fares  for  what  we  believe  we  can  attain  in  load  factor,  and 
have  been  successful  in  that  degree. 

Senator  Kennedy.  In  other  words,  you  feel  that  by  charging  the 
loAver  prices,  you  can  get  more  people  on  a  flight  and  make  a  profit  on 
that  basis  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennp:dy.  Has  that  been  your  experience  ? 
INIr.  Clifford.  Yes,  sir,  we  try  to  gage  our  prices  to  a  break-even 
load  factor  that  is,  in  fact,  attainable. 
Senator  Kennedy  What  type  of  planes  does  PSA  fly  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  Boeing  737's. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  many  seats  do  you  have  in  the  plane  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  We  have  the  same  number  of  seats  as  the  Hawaiian 
carriers.  I  believe  more  seats  than  the  737  domestic  operators. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  you  could  provide  the  same  sort  of 
inexpensive  service  outside  of  California  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  Yes,  sir. 
Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  like  to  do  so  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  Yes,  sir. 

We  have  no  current  applications.  We  were  applicants  in  the  Pacific- 
Xorthwest  case  some  years  ago.  That  has  been  our  only  entry  into 
trying  to  fly  interstate. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  happened  in  that  case  ? 
Mr.  Clifford.  We  were  not  a  successful  applicant. 
Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  know  why  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Not  precisely,  but  t4iere  Avere  public  hearings,  and  the 
discussions  AA'ere  made  Avithout  us  being  successful. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  Avould  like  to  serA'e  other  places,  Avhat 
i-eally  stops  you  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  An  analysis  on  our  part  as  to  the  potential  success  of 
application  and  ability  to  serve  in  a  precise  market. 

Senator  Kennedy.  \Vould  you  elaborate  a  little  on  that? 
Mr.  Clifford.  Well,  prior  to  application  into  any  ncAV  market  Ave 
AA-ould  do  an  analysis  Avith  the  competiti\'e  services  that  were  then 
uA-ailable  and  Ave  Avould  apply  only  if,  in  our  judgment,  AA-e  saw  a  real 
need  and  requirenient  for  additional  services  Avithin  the  route. 

We  do  not  consider  ourseh-es  a  cutrate  airline,  and  it  Avould  not  be 
our  policy  and  philosophy  to  look  at  a  route  and  try  to  steal  passengers, 
if  you  Avill,  from  another  carrier,  but  rather  Ave  AAOuld  app>ly  for  the 


448 

route,  if  in  our  judgment,  additional  customers  were  potentially  avail- 
able in  that  route. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  understand  that  the  CAB  says  that  the  Cali- 
fornia routes  are  cheaper  because  one  of  the  reasons  is  they  are  denser, 
and  they  have  more  passengers.  There  are  about  2  million  passengers 
flying  between  Boston  and  Washington  each  year,  one  way.  How  many 
passengers  fly  between  Orange  County  and  San  Francisco  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  I  believe  a  million — I  think  I  have  a  figure— Orange 
County  to  San  Francisco  is  321,000  customers  in  1973.  Orange  County 
to  San  Jose  were  276,000,  approximately.  Orange  County 

Senator  Kennedy.  At  least  with  regards  to  the  issue  of  the  denser 
being  cheapei',  the  Boston-Washington  route  carrying  2  million  versus 
Orange  County  to  San  Francisco  or  San  Jose  with  approximately 
300.000,  that  does  not  seem  to  be  a  substantial  issue. 

Likewise,  the  98.2  percent  versus  99.8  percent  flight  completions 
seems  to  be  a  very  narrow  variable.  What  are  the  other  considerations  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Senator,  I  am  not  sure  whether  the  completion  factor 
really  tells  the  whole  story  on  the  weather  as  a  factor.  There  are  delays 
enroute  because  of  dense  traffic,  and  long  holds,  and  so  on,  that  cer- 
tainly would  be  a  cost  factor  in  this  regard. 

I  am  not  sure  what  services  are  offered  in  the  eai-n  sector  with  regard 
to  food  service  and  so  on. 

CAB    denial    of    authority    FOR    INTRASTATE    CARRIERS    TO 
INTERLINE    WITH    CAB    CARRIERS 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  want  to  fly  from  Boston  to  San  Francisco 
to  Orange  County,  could  you  buy  a  ticket  in  Boston  to  do  that  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  No,  sir;  you  cannot.  We  would  like  to  interline  bag- 
gage and  interline  passengers  for  truly  intrastate  operations  on  a  break 
of  your  trip,  if  you  will,  if  you  were  planning  on  spending  li/^  days  in 
San  Francisco,  and  traveling  to  Orange  County.  We  have  applied  for 
such  services  and  ai-e  not  able  to  oft'er  that. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  have  you  not  been  able  to  get  it  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Well,  there  is  the  question  of  inter--  versus  intra-state 
carriage,  common  carriage  of  customers. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  what  happened  to  the  applications? 

Mr.  Clifford.  The  application  was  denied. 

Senator  Kennedy.  By  whom  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  By  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

Senator  Kennedy.  For  what  reasons? 

Mr.  Clifford.  I  am  really  not  familiar  witli  that  portion  of  the  case, 
Senator. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  mentioned  a  little  earlier  that  you  would 
not  want  to  enter  a  market  at  a  cutrate  to  get  passengers  who  already 
fly  on  another  line.  Is  this  the  usual  businessman's  attitude  toward 
competition  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Xo,  but  it  is  a  very  straightforward  attitude  of 
making  sure  thei-e  is  enough  market  to  make  the  load  factor  that  is 
necessary  in  order  to  flv,  a  practical,  attainable  load  factor. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  would  happen  otherwise  ? 

Ml-.  Clifford.  Well,  if  we  needed  65  percent  to  break  even,  and  we 
got  55  percent  we  would  lose,  and  we  liave  no  place  to  go  except  as  a 
lost  venture.  Of  course,  we  want  to  avoid  that  prospect. 


449 

Senator  Kexxedy.  But  then  yon  wonld  not  be  reluctant  to  enter  this 
market  if  you  thought  you  could  maintain  a  65  percent  load  factor? 

Mr.  Clifp^ord.  No,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  enter  it  at  the  cutrate  ? 

Mr.  Clifford.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much.  I  appreciate  your  coming. 

Mr.  Clifford.  Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statements  of  Lawrence  Guske  and  Kobert  Cliflford 
follow :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Lawrence  A.  Guske,  Assistant  Controller, 
Pacific  Southwest  Airlines 

We  understand  the  focus  of  today's  session  to  be  on  costs  and  fares  in  rela- 
tively short-haul,  dense  airline  passenger  markets.  We  hope  that  PSA's  par- 
ticipation will  assist  the  subcommittee  in  pursuing  its  interest  in  this  important 
area. 

PSA  commenced  scheduled  airline  service  on  May  6,  1949,  between  San  Diego 
and  Oakland  via  Hollywood-Burbank,  utilizing  one  leased  DC-3  aircraft.  At 
present,  PSA  provides  single-plane  service  in  32  airport  pairs  using  three  Boeing 
737-200  aircraft  with  11.5  seat«,  twenty  Boeing  727-200  aircraft  with  159  seats, 
one  Boeing  727-100  with  128  seats  and  two  Lockheed  1011  aircraft  with  297 
seats. 

In  expanding  and  developing  from  1949  to  the  present,  PSA  has  consistently 
sought  to  provide  good  air  transportation  service  at  the  lowest  possible  fares. 
PSA  believes  that  the  air  passenger  market  is  price  elastic.  In  addition  to 
pioneering  in  the  area  of  fares,  PSA  has  concentrated  much  attention  on  develop- 
ment of  traffic  at  the  California  satellite  airports  of  Burbank,  Oakland,  San 
Jose,  Ontario  and  Long  Beach.  Without  the  satellite  operations,  airport  limita- 
tions and  congestion  would  have  posed  serious  constraints  to  the  expansion  of 
PSA's  low  fare  service  for  the  traveling  public. 

While  we  know  that  low  fares  increase  traffic,  PSA  has  not  been  able  to 
isolate  and  relate  particular  traffic  increases  to  particular  fare  offerings.  Ex- 
amples of  market  stimulation  which  can  be  attributed  in  part  to  PSA's  lower 
fares  are  as  follows  : 

1.  In  1965,  Pacific  Airlines,  the  only  carrier  providing  single-plane  service 
between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Jose,  carried  56,000  pasengers  in  that  market. 
In  May  1966,  PSA  commenced  lower-fare  service  between  Los  Angeles  and 
San  Jose  and  for  calendar  year  1967,  PSA  carried  556,919  passengers  for 
a  two-year  increase  of  nearly  1,000  iiercent. 

2.  In  196(),  only  Western  and  United  provided  jet  service  between  Los 
Angeles  and  Sacramento.  In  February  1967,  PSA  entered  the  market  with 
a  fare  level  approximately  25  percent  below  the  existing  fares.  In  1967, 
passenger  traffic  over  the  route  doubled,  and  Western  and  United  actually 
carried  more  passengers  than  in  1966,  despite  the  competition  from  PSA. 

PSA  has  historically  exercised  tight,  austere  controls  over  its  costs.  Four 
important  areas  where  this  has  been  done  are  : 

1.  Overhead.  PSA  employs  tight  expense  controls  and  efficient  flight  and 
ground  crew  practices.  It  has  only  five  top  corporate  officers. 

2.  Basic  transportation  service.  PSA  serves  no  food  or  free  alcoholic 
beverages. 

3.  High  seating  density.  PSA's  single-class  configurations  of  the  aircraft 
it  operates  are  about  20  percent  denser  than  those  of  interstate  airlines. 

4.  No  discounts.  PSA  has  offered  half -fa  re  for  children  2  to  12,  but  almost 
no  other  discounts.  As  a  result,  PSA's  system  fare  dilution  is  only  2  percent. 

Tight  cost  control  is  still  effective,  we  believe,  to  keep  PSA's  total  costs  below 
•those  of  other  carriers  on  a  passenger-mile  basis,  but  PSA's  costs  are  rising,  in 
common  with  those  of  the  entire  airline  industry,  at  an  alarming  rate.  PSA's 
fuel  costs  are  among  the  highest  in  the  nation.  From  14.4  cents  per  gallon  at 
the  end  of  1973.  PSA's  average  price  for  a  gallon  of  fuel  soared  to  31.2  cents  as 
of  November  1974,  and  we  anticipate  a  cost  of  46  cents  by  the  end  of  1975  under 
the  Administration's  crude  oil  program.  At  such  a  level,  1975  fuel  costs  would 
amount  to  $47  million  or  29.4  percent  of  PSA's  total  costs  of  airline  operation, 
compared  with  $14,396,000  and  14  percent  of  expenses  in  1973.  Although  fuel 


450 

prices  are  the  leading  factor  in  PSA's  cost  increases,  PSA  is  also  subject  to  the 
same  inflationary  pressures  that  afflict  the  entire  nation  over  the  entire  range 
of  its  costs. 

PSA  is  subject  to  competition  by  interstate  carriers  over  most  of  its  system. 
PSA's  primary  competitor,  United,  has  consistently  matched  PSA's  fares.  Until 
very  recently,  most  other  competing  airlines  published  fares  equal  to  PSA 
over  route  segments  served  in  common.  In  past  route  and  fare  proceedings  before 
the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission,  these  competing  airlines  have  intro- 
duced evidence  which  indicated  that  they  were  incurring  substantial  losses  charg- 
ing PSA's  fares  for  their  intra-Calif ornia  services. 

PSA's  services  have  over  the  years  yielded  a  profit,  but  a  return  on  investment 
of  only  1.06  percent  for  1973 — an  inadequate  return  even  under  California  PUC 
ratemaking  standards.  Substandard  profitability  for  PSA  along  with  losses  for 
all  competing  carriers  are,  unfortunately,  consistent  with  the  California  PUC's 
ratemaking  approach.  The  California  PUC  has  declared  PSA  to  be  the  rate- 
making  carrier  in  the  principal  California  intrastate  air  transportation  markets, 
on  the  ground  that  PSA  is  most  efficient.  As  a  result,  once  rate  increases  are 
granted  to  PSA  after  a  full  hearing,  such  increases  are  perfunctorily  awarded 
to  the  other  air  carriers  on  request,  on  the  basis  of  PSA's  relatively  low-unit 
costs  rather  than  market  or  industry  costs  or  the  particular  other  carrier's  costs. 
The  California  PUC  has  used  a  number  of  other  ratemaking  techniques  which 
we  at  PSA  have  opposed  as  unsound  and  as  calculated  to  prevent  PSA,  in  spite 
of  its  austere  cost  management  and  high  eflSciency,  from  earning  a  fair  return 
on  investment.  As  a  result  of  such  nearsighted  ratemaking  techniques,  PSA's 
public  shareholders  have  received  no  cash  dividends  from  1970  to  present. 

PSA's  present  fare  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  before  tax  is  $19.21, 
or  5.68  cents  per  mile.  We  have  pending  with  the  California  PUC  a  request  for 
increase  to  cover  general  cost  increases,  not  fuel,  which  would  increase  the  fare 
to  $21.30,  or  6.30  cents  per  mile. 

The  fact  that  we  are  asking  the  PUC  for  a  fare  of  6.30  cents  per  mile  does  not 
mean  that  PSA  has  stopped  being  a  low-fare  carrier.  We  still  are  dedicated  to  the 
lowest  compensatory  fares.  While  we  are  asking  for  0.30  cents,  the  Eastern  air- 
shuttle  fares  between  New  York,  on  the  one  hand,  and  Boston  and  Washington 
on  the  other,  are  14.02  cents  and  12.98  cents  per  mile  respectively,  and  the  lowest 
regular  Boston-Washington  fare  is  10.44  cents  per  mile. 

The  most  recent  development  in  the  California  intrastate  fare  arena  is  that 
several  interstate  carriers  now  offer  lower  fares  than  PSA  in  principal  markets. 
This  came  about  in  1974,  when  PSA  was  forced  to  raise  fares  on  all  its  routes  to 
compensate  for  the  increased  price  of  jet  fuel.  Although  in  the  past,  the  interstate 
carriers  have  normally  raised  their  intra-California  fares  to  match  those  of  PSA, 
some  carriers  did  not  do  so  in  this  instance.  As  a  result.  Delta  offers  the  lowest 
fare  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Diego ;  Hughes  Airwest  the  lowest  between 
Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco,  and  Continental  is  offering  a  lower  fare  between 
Burbank  and  San  Jose. 

PSA  continues  as  a  proponent  of  low  airline  fares.  Today,  however,  PSA  is 
faced  with  an  unprecedented  onslaught  of  deterrents  to  continuation  and  expan- 
sion of  the  availability  to  the  public  of  such  fares.  Rampant  inflation  led  by  fuel 
prices  unimaginable  two  years  ago,  a  slumping  economy,  an  inadequately  re- 
sponsive state  regulatory  agency,  and  competitors  who  for  the  first  time  are 
using  fares  as  an  offensive  weai)on  against  PSA,  have  all  converged  to  challenge 
the  continuation  of  PSA's  traditional  role  as  the  low  fare,  intrastate  airline. 
The.se  are  matters  PSA  feels  should  be  kept  in  mind  both  in  comparing  intra- 
California  airline  markets  and  fares  with  markets  and  fares  elsewhere  in  the 
country,  and  in  devi.sing  solutions  to  the  administrative  problems  faced  by  the 
carriers  and  the  traveling  public. 

Prepared  Statement  of  Robert  W.  Clifford,  President,  Air  California 

My  name  is  Robert  W.  Clifford.  I  am  the  president  of  Air  California,  and  we  are 
pleased  to  appear  before  you.  Air  California  is  a  scheduled  air  carrier  operating 
within  the  State  of  California  under  a  certificate  of  convenience  and  necessity 
issued  by  the  Public  Utilities  Commission,  the  agency  which  regulates  the  public 
utilities  and  transportation  services  within  Calf  ornia.  We  provide  passenger  and 
airfreight  services  to  eight  California  cities  constituting  19  city-pair  markets. 
Air  California  was  incorporated  in  1966  to  provide  initial  air  .service  between 
Orange  County  and  the  San  Francisco  bay  area.  The  company  has  grown  from 


451 

an  airline  operating  two  Lockheed  Electras  (Lr-188)  and  transporting  293.000 
annual  passengers  in  1967  to  the  operation  of  seven  Boeing  737-115  passenger 
jets  and  one  Electra  serving  1.4  million  customers  in  1974. 

The  corporate  mission  of  the  company  is  to  provide  low-cost  commuter-type  air 
.service  in  markets  that  do  not  have  required  service  or  receive  poor  and  inade- 
quate .service  from  interstate  airlines.  Of  the  19  markets  presently  served  by  Air 
California,  12  received  first  time  service  from  Air  California,  2  received  better 
service,  and  5  received  competitive  service.  The  State  of  California  is  to  be 
admired  for  its  foresight  in  recognizing  the  need  for  intrastate  air  transportation 
and  enacting  legislation  which  established  an  orderly  control  mechanism  for 
route  authorities,  tariffs,  and  financial  guidelines.  California,  if  it  were  a  nation, 
would  indeed  be  the  eighth  largest  economic  producer  (gross  national/state 
product)  in  the  world,  so  it  naturally  follows  that  communication  and  transporta- 
tion are  vital  and  dramatically  necessary  in  an  ever-changing  way. 

The  Public  Utilities  Commission  has  been  responsive  in  the  recognition  of  new 
service  route  needs,  and  has  been  able  to  meet  such  needs  through  tlie  avail- 
ability of  two  rather  large,  viable,  and  competent  transportation  companies.  Air 
California  and  PSA.  The  existence  and  growth  of  our  companies  is  adequate  and 
strong  testimony  as  to  the  need  for  services  of  the  type  offered  and  the  good  judg- 
ment of  our  regulators.  Tliere  is  no  question  in  my  mind  that  services  of  the 
type  we  provide  which  are  quickly  responsive  to  new  market  needs  and  priced  in 
innovative  packages  which  develop  markets  with  maximum  speed  would  not  be 
possible  in  the  framework  of  present  interstate  certification  processes. 

Our.s  is  an  operation  in  which  fares  are  priced  at  minimum  levels  which  can  be 
realistically  supported  by  expected  load  factors.  We.  like  all  other  air  carriers, 
are  currently  caught  in  a  pinch  because  of  fuel  prices.  Although  the  Commission 
has  been  attentive  to  the  fuel  price  increase,  the  additional  19  percent  in  our  fares 
has  somewhat  depressed  trafBc.  In  comparison  to  other  airlines,  intrastate  and 
interstate,  our  fares  are  in  some  instances  lower  and  in  some  instances  slightly 
higher.  Our  fares  are  lower  than  Hughes  Airwest,  however  slightly  higher  than 
Continental,  Western  and  PSA  in  our  Ontario  to  Sacramento  service.  In  order  to 
encourage  discretionary  travel.  Air  California  offers  and  is  highly  supportive  of 
reduced  rate  incentives.  We  offer  a  discounted  family  plan,  military  fare,  group 
rates,  and  a  standby  E-z  fare  (20  percent  reduction  on  certain  selected  low 
volume  flights). 

Our  operating  costs  are  somewhat  lower  than  the  interstate  carriers  since  we 
are  relatively  a  new  carrier  and  our  seniority  rates  are  not  as  mature  as  others. 
The  price  of  our  supplies,  including  fuel,  spare  parts,  miscellaneous  equipment, 
oflSce  supplies,  etc.,  are  probably  comparable  to  those  of  other  air  carriers. 

We  don't  look  upon  ourselves  as  a  cutrate  airline  for,  in  fact,  we  charge  fares 
that  permit  a  fair  level  of  profitability  potential  and  offer  services  which  are 
comparable  to  those  of  any  air  carrier  operating  .short  segment  flights  .similar 
to  ours.  We  require  a  relatively  high  load  factor  for  breakeven  and  we  maintain 
these  load  factors  by  effective  scheduling  of  individual  flights  on  daily  schedules 
which  match  peak  demand.  That  is,  we  schedule  more  trips  on  days  which  pro- 
vide higher  traffic  i>otential  (Fridays,  holidays,  etc.),  and  contract  .schedules  on 
days  of  expected  minimum  activity,  i.e.,  Saturdays,  day  after  holiday,  etc.  We  are 
able  to  control  capacity  through  the  use  of  our  modern,  computerized  reserva- 
tion .system  which  utilizes  the  data  bank  of  Continental  Air  Lines. 

Our  type  of  operation,  which  is  based  npon  high  frequency  on  short  flight  seg- 
ments, requires  close  adherence  to  published  flight  schedules.  The  maximum 
possible  completion  of  our  scheduled  trips  on  time  is  a  constant  concern.  Our 
completion  factor  for  the  year  1974  was  outstanding — 99.8  percent  with  89.2  per- 
cent of  the  flights  operating  on  time   (within  15  minutes). 

Although  our  intrastate  customers  enjoy  a  high  level  of  service  proficiency, 
we  are  not  able  to  offer  interline  ticketing  or  interline  baggage  exchange.  This 
deficiency  is  brought  about  by  the  possibility  of  our  being  con.sidered  an  inter- 
state carrier  if  such  service  was  offered.  On  two  occasions  we  have  requested 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board  is.suance  of  an  exemption  to  permit  interlining  of 
baggage  and  tickets  with  stated  restrictions  which  would  negate  the  possibility 
of  straight-through,  direct  interstate  commerce.  We  understand  the  technical 
regulatory  problems  involved  in  the  consideration  of  this  matter;  however,  we 
believe  that  the  traveling  public  would  be  best  served  through  the  adoption  of  a 
plan  which  would  offer  our  services  for  trips  which  were  not,  in  fact,  interstate 
in  nature. 

Transportation  services,  in  order  to  be  effective  and  of  value,  must  meet  the 
needs  of  the  people  they  serve.  These  needs  are  not  static,  but  rather  ever-chang- 


452 

ing.  We  believe  the  ingenuity  and  flexibility  brought  to  the  air  transportation 
industry  by  carriers  such  as  Air  California  should  be  recognized  as  beneficial  and 
that  the  continued  expansion  of  their  services  should  be  encouraged. 

We  are  proud  to  be  a  member  of  an  industry  which  provides  services  which 
are  so  vital  to  our  national  economy  and  well-being. 

We  thank  you  again  for  the  opportunity  to  appear  before  you  and  would  be 
pleased  to  answer  any  questions  which  would  be  of  benefit  in  your  consideration 
of  these  matters. 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  next  testimony  will  be  from  Dr.  William  A. 
Jordan,  professor  of  managerial  economics  at  York  University,  To- 
ronto, Canada ;  and  Dr.  John  R.  Summerfield,  president  of  Summer- 
field  Associates,  a  transportation  research  and  consulting  firm. 

During  the  past  27  years,  Dr.  Jordan  has  worked  for  Scandinavian 
Airlines  System,  Air  France,  Seaboard  World  Airlines,  and  Western 
Airlines.  Dr.  Jordan  has  consulted  on  airline  and  airport  matters.  He 
has  taught  graduate  courses  in  economics  and  government  regulation 
at  Columbia,  Stanford,  Northwestern,  U.S.  International,  and  York 
University,  and  he  is  a  colonel  in  the  Air  Force  Reserve.  Dr.  Jordan 
is  well  known  for  his  publications  on  airline  regulation  and  capacity 
agreements. 

Dr.  Summerfield  has  directed  transportation  research  at  the  RAND 
Corp.  and  has  served  as  corporate  economist  and  director  of  economic 
studies  at  Douglas  Aircraft  Co.  and  as  vice  president  of  economic 
planning  at  Western  Airlines  and  Pan  American  World  Airways. 

Dr.  Jordan,  do  you  want  to  start,  please  '^. 

STATEMENTS  OF  DR.  WILLIAM  A.  JORDAN,  PROFESSOR  OF  MAN- 
AGERIAL ECONOMICS,  YORK  UNIVERSITY  AND  DR.  JOHN  R. 
SUMMERFIELD,  PRESIDENT,   SUMMERFIELD  ASSOCIATES 

Dr.  Jordan.  Thank  you. 

My  presentation  today  is  based  on  research  for  the  past  10  years  on 
the  effects  of  CAB  regulation.  Rather  than  attempt  a  theoretical  study, 
I  decided  the  best  way  to  do  this  would  be  to  compare  the  actual  per- 
formance of  CAB-regulated  airlines  with  the  benchmark  of  the  actual 
performance  of  those  airlines  not  regulated  by  the  CAB. 

The  nonregulated  airlines  are  primarily  the  intrastate  airlines,  but 
not  entirely.  This  study  covers  the  post-World  War  II  period  with 
emphasis  on  the  years  since  1949. 

CONTROL   OF   INDUSTRY   ENTRY   IS    NECESSARY   FOR   REGULATION 

One  conclusion  of  this  study  is  that  a  necessary  condition  for  effec- 
tive regulation  is  the  control  of  entry.  It  is  necessary  to  control  entry 
to  prevent  rival  airlines  from  entering  should  regulation  cause  fares 
to  rise  above  average  costs,  and  it  is  necessary  to  prevent  entry  in  case 
costs  themselves  rise  above  the  minimum  average  achievable. 

The  CAB  has  effectively  closed  entry  into  U.S.  interstate  airline 
operations.  There  have  been  16  to  10  trunk  carriers,  decreasing  in  num- 
bers from  1938  to  the  present  time,  with  Pan  Am  being  another  large 
carrier,  but  primarily  international. 

There  have  been  21  to  8  local  service  carriers  from  1946  to  1950 
to  the  present  time  with  Air  New  England  being  the  latest  addition 
after  a  25-year  hiatus  in  the  authorization  of  such  carriers. 


453 

In  1973,  tlie  total  operating  revenues  of  all  U.S.  airlines  operating 
large  aircraft  were  approximately  $13  billion.  Of  this  $13  billion,  the 
10  trunks  plus  Pan  American  counted  for  81.2  percent,  and  each  of 
these  trunk  carriers  served  between  37  and  111  cities  with  60  to  390 
aircraft  each.  Local  service  carrier  share  was  8.2  percent  of  the  $13 
billion,  and  they  served  50  to  9,5  cities  per  carrier  with  33  to  133  air- 
craft. So  these  two  CAB-regulated  airline  groups  together  have 
accounted  for  92.4  percent  of  the  $13  billion  or  a  total  of  roughly  $12 
billion  of  this  $13  billion. 

All  other  airlines  in  the  United  States  accounted  for  the  remaining 
7.6  percent  or  roughly  $1  billion. 

DISECOXOMIES   OF   SCALE:    100    TO    2  00    AIRLINES    WITPIOUT  REGULATION 

The  conclusions  of  my  study  indicate  that  without  CAB  regula- 
tion there  would  be  between  100  to  200  or  more  airlines  in  the  United 
States  operating  large  aircraft  in  scheduled  service,  and  figure  No. 
1,  which  is  the  one  in  the  corner  there,  summarizes  this.  Twenty  CAB- 
regulated  trunk  and  local  service  carriers  plus  Pan  Am  as  opposed  to 
200  or  more  nonregulated  airlines  without  the  CAB. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  can  you  make  a  statement  like  that  when 
we  have  just  heard  from  two  operators,  one  of  whom  felt  that  unless 
you  were  very  sure  that  you  would  be  able  to  build  up  G5-per'cent 
passenger  capacity,  that  you  may  very  well  go  out  of  business?  Here 
we  have  20  with  regulation.  You  talk  about  100  to  200.  How  do  you 
draw  that  conclusion?  Would  it  not  oversaturate  the  market  and 
cause  finnncial  turmoil  and  disaster  among  carriers? 

Dr.  Jordan.  We  shoidd  recognize  that  the  nonregulated  airlines 
have  all  been  smaller  lines. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Does  that  mean  you  go  on  a  small  line  from 
Boston  to  Washington? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Yes,  it  would  operate  from  3  to  4  to  6  planes  as  opposed 
to  40  to  60  to  400  ail-planes.  The  point  is  there  is  enough  traffic  to  sup- 
port small  airlines  with  three  or  four  aircraft  and  make  them  liable. 
They  will  be  able  to  achieve  all  the  possible  efficiencies  with  that  small 
operation,  and  such  small  airlines  have  been  viable  in  the  California 
and  Texas  situation  without  regulation. 

What  I  am  saying  is  that  without  regulation  which  causes  airlines 
to  be  large,  you  would  have  a  large  number  of  small  airlines,  each  one 
specializing  in  a  certain  kind  of  operation. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Wliy  does  regulation  require  that  the  airlines 
be  large? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Because,  given  entry  control,  the  trunks  have  been 
limited  to  those  certified  in  1938  and  the  local  service  carriers  limited 
to  those  certificated  between  1946  and  1950.  and  these  ar-e  the  only  air- 
lines that  have  been  allowed  to  provide  interstate  seivice.  As  the  city- 
Dairs  haA'e  expanded  and  total  traffic  has  expanded,  these  airlines  have 
been  required  to  expand.  Also,  when  an  airline  makes  a  major  mistake, 
it  is  forced  to  merge  like  the  Capital-United  merger  of  some  years 
back  so  with  no  entry  the  size  of  the  remaining  airlines  increases. 
Closed  entry  is  the  cause  of  large  airlines. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  had  a  greater  number  of  airlines  sictually 
required  to  go  into  a  merger  situation,  as  you  pointed  out,  why  does 


454 

that  not  run  contrary  to  your  thesis  that  you  would  have  100  to  200, 
if  the  experience  has'^been  in  recent  times  that  the  total  numbers  have 
actually  reduced?  Why  do  you  not  believe  if  you  start  out  with  100, 
that  it  will  finally  contract  down  to  the  20  or  so  even  without  the 
regulation  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Because  without  regulation  we  find  that  airlines  can  be 
efficient,  low-cost  carriers  with  small  numbers  of  aircraft,  and  there- 
fore, as  airlines  become  larger  they  become  less  efficient,  and  we  will 
lose  business  to  the  small  airlines  that  will  enter. 

I  should  mention  that  one  very  striking  comparison — we  have  had 
merger  acquisitions  in  CAB  regulation.  There  has  not  been  a  single 
merger  application  in  a  nonregulated  environment. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  it  more  efficient  to  have  a  smaller  number  of 
planes  and  more  airlines,  or  a  larger  number  of  planes  and  fewer  air- 
lines? It  seems  to  me,  for  example,  in  the  terms  of  trucks  supplying 
the  planes  with  gasoline  or  handling  baggage  that  you  would  have 
regulated  lines.  Let  us  take,  for  example,  the  case  of  the  trucks  supply- 
ing planes  with  gasoline  or  handling  baggage  transfer.  On  the  one 
hand,  you  would  have  the  larger  regulated  airlines  using  one  gasoline 
truck  to  refuel  planes  all  day,  while,  on  the  other,  you  would  have  the 
smaller  airlines  using  one  gasoline  truck  to  refuel  four  or  five  planes. 

Dr.  Jordan.  In  response  to  that  question,  the  gasoline  truck  is 
usually  owned  by  the  fuel  company.  It  supplies  airlines  and  it  does 
not  have  to  supply  one  airline. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  that  true  of  all  these  other  services? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Yes ;  in  terms  of  overall  cost 

REGULATED   FARES    ARE    4  0-7  0    PERCENT   HIGHER    THAN    UNREGULATED 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let's  continue  with  your  other  testimony. 

Dr.  Jordan.  Fine. 

Given  closed  entry,  we  find  what  are  some  results  of  CAB  regula- 
tion. One  clear  result  has  been  higher  fares.  I  have  shown  in  figure  2, 
a  comparison  of  fares  Avith  regulation  as  opposed  to  fares  without 
regulation.  Those  in  red  are  with  regulation.  I  have  broken  them  down 
into  short-haul,  which  I  have  defined  as  0  to  250  miles,  more  or  less; 
medium-haul  from  251  to  1,000  miles;  and  long-haul  over  1,000  miles. 
I  have  shown  the  Boston-New  York,  Boston-Washington,  and  Boston- 
Los  Angeles  fares  as  examples  for  these  mileage  categories. 

In  the  case  of  a  short-haul,  the  California  analysis  implies  that  the 
fares  with  regulation  are  between  40-70  percent  higher  than  without 
regulation,  and  this  is  the  basis  for  the  difference  between  $25.93,  which 
is  the  actual  regulated  fare  between  Boston  and  New  York,  and  the 
$15  fare  without  regulation. 

In  terms  of  medium-haul,  we  find  that  the  fare  differences  are 
around  75  to  100  percent,  w^hich  is  a  difference  of  $41.67  with  regula- 
tion, versus  $21  without  regulation  for  the  Boston-Washington  fare. 

Finally,  for  the  long-haul,  we  find  fares  roughly  100  percent  larger 
with  regulation,  whicTi  gives  you  the  $187.04,  the  actual  fare  today, 
as  opposed  to  without  regulation,  approximately  $95. 

Now,  these  large  differences  are  in  city  fares  that  have  relatively 
high  traffic  density,  being  defined  as  over  100,000  passengers  per  year. 
The  same  analysis  applies  for  small  city-pairs  with  the  fare  differences 


455 

not  as  lai'^e,  but  witli  the  noiu'e^ulated  fares  still  lower  than  regu- 
lated fares.  This  analysis  is  based  upon  California,  but  supported  by 
similar  analyses  in  the  Texas  case,  in  the  military  airlift  case  where 
we  had  re^ilation  by  the  CAB,  imposed  in  1960,  and  it  is  supported 
by  a  comparison  with  reg:ulated  fares  in  Canada,  between  Montreal 
and  Toronto.  We  find  with  regulation  in  Canada,  their  fares  are  high, 
roughly  the  same  as  regulated  fares  in  the  United  States. 

So,  without  regulation  fares  are  lower.  With  regulation,  fares  are 
higher. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  ? 

REGULATION   INCREASES    COSTS SERVICE    COMPETITION 

Dr.  Jordan.  Well,  that  is  the  next  question.  If  prices  are  so  high 
why  are  there  not  large  profits,  for  example. 

Well,  it  appears  that  regulation  also  serves  to  increase  costs  of  opera- 
tion. Fares  go  up,  costs  also  go  up. 

This  is  a  major  area  of  work.  I  have  identified  three  important 
sources  of  these  difPerences  in  cost.  One  source  is  decreased  aircraft 
utilization.  The  second  source  is  lack  of  specialization  among  the  regu- 
lated airlines.  The  third  source  is  the  purchase  of  more  and  more  in- 
puts at  higher  prices,  that  is  labor  and  aircraft,  for  example. 

First,  the  matter  about  aircraft  utilization.  CAB  regulation  for  the 
last  86  years  has  been  asymmetric,  it  has  been  complete  in  entry  and 
exit,  it  has  been  very  effective  in  price,  but  it  has  been  ineffective  and 
almost  nonexistent  in  the  matter  of  service  quality.  Furthermore,  the 
CAB  has  failed  to  allocate  specific  market  shares  to  each  airline.  In- 
stead, it  has  certified  two  or  more  airlines  in  many  city-pairs  where- 
upon it  has  said  all  right,  fellows,  your  prices  are  fixed  but  you  are  in 
this  city-pair,  go  ahead  and  get  what  you  can  get.  The  airlines'  re- 
sponse has  been  well,  we  are  controlled  pricewase  but  not  service 
qualitywise,  let's  have  superior  service  quality.  The  way  to  do  that  is 
to  operate  brandnew  airplanes  at  high-schedule  frequencies.  They 
have  done  this.  Furthermore,  they  put  fewer  seats  in  their  aircraft, 
and  even  given  fewer  seats,  they  have  operated  enough  frequencies 
to  give  theui  lower  numbers  of  passengers  per  flight,  low-load  factors. 

Now,  I  have  on  figure  No.  3,  which  I  will  refer  to  very  shortly, 
an  explanation  of  what  this  means  in  terms  of  cost.  Looking  only  at 
aircraft  costs,  just  the  aircraft  from  the  viewpoint  of  the  airline  costs, 
if  we  increased  the  load  factor  from  the  current  56-percent  level, 
Avhicli  is  what  it  was  last  year,  1974.  to  70  percent,  a  25-percent  in- 
crease, and  by  the  way,  the  70  percent  load  factor  is  the  lowest  load 
factor  that  existed  between  1955  and  1964  in  California.  Quite  feasibly, 
it  has  occurred  regularly  without  regulation.  If  we  have  this  kind  of 
load  factor  in  all  U.S.  operations  we  would  decrease  the  fleet  size  by 
20  percent,  25  percent  increase  in  load  factor,  20  percent  decrease  iii 
passenger  flights. 

^  Such  a  decrease  in  the  fleet  would  reduce  the  value  of  the  aircraft 
fleet  from  the  present  $12.25  billion,  undepreciated  value,  for  the 
trunk  airlines,  to  about  $9.8  billion. 

A  second  factor  would  be  if  we  increased  the  average  life  of  each 
aircraft  by  25  percent,  going  from  sav  14  years,  which  is  an  average 
allowance  for  present  CAB  airlines,'  to  i7i/>  years,  you  would  de- 


456 

crease  the  average  annual  replacement  costs  from  $875  million  to 
$560  million  per  year,  or  a  saving  of  $315  million  per  year,  roughly 
$1.90  per  passenger  enplanement.  Now,  that  is  just  one  cost  factor 
which  results  in  an  appreciable  decrease  in  costs. 

Wlien  you  combine  this  with  a  decrease  in  operating  costs  associ- 
ated with  a  decrease  in  the  number  of  flights  by  20  percent,  you  can 
see  very  quickly  you  get  into  very  large  differences  in  cost. 

A  second  source  of  the  reason  that  the  intrastate  carriers  are  low- 
cost  is  their  ability  to  obtain  a  higher  output  per  employee.  Now,  they 
are  all  small,  the  intrastate  airlines.  They  have  usually  one  kind  of 
aircraft.  Each  provides  a  very  specialized  service  and  they  find  that 
the  result  of  this  has  been  employee  specialization  which  has  resulted 
in  large  outputs  per  employee. 

If  you  look  at  figure  No.  4  behind  you.  Senator,  these  are  fig- 
ures for  1965,  which  is  not  the  most  favorable  year  for  comparison, 
because  PSA  had  better  years,  but  it  is  a  good  average  year,  the  output 
per  employee  of  the  average  trunk  carriers  measured  on  available 
seat-miles  per  employee  was  603,000  available  seat-miles  per  employee. 
Compared  to  PSA's  1,270,000  available  seat-miles. 

Looking  at  the  next  two  columns,  revenue-passenger  miles,  the  aver- 
age trunk  carrier  had  333,000  revenue-passenger  miles,  PSA  had 
804,000.  It  is  a  difference  of  141  percent.  Senator. 

It  it  only  fair  to  point  out  these  figures  are  biased  against  the  trunk 
carriers.  They  do  not  include  cargo  production.  Yet  the  total  number 
of  employees  does  include  cargo. 

The  third  series  of  figures  attempts  to  correct  this  bias.  They  pro- 
vide figures  biased  against  PSA.  These  are  revenue  figures.  In  1965, 
the  average  yield  per  revenue-passenger  mile  for  PSA  was  3.85  cents, 
while  trunk  yield  was  5.93  cents,  roughly  50  percent  higher.  So  it  took 
PSA  half  again  as  many  passengers  to  get  the  same  revenues. 

PSA  had  revenues  per  employee  of  $32,500  versus  $22,200  for  the 
average  trunk.  Even  with  the  figures  biased  against  PSA,  it  is  still 
superior. 

Taking  these  three  comparisons  and  making  adjustments,  approxi- 
mating how  it  works  out  overall,  I  would  estimate  that  PSA  is  roughly 
100  percent  more  productive  per  employee  than  the  average  trunk  air- 
line. That  is  an  appreciable  difference.  This  is  an  important  cause  of 
the  lower  costs  of  the  intrastate  carriers. 

The  final  point  is  the  matter  of  increased  input  prices.  CAB  has 
closed  entry.  Therefore,  if  any  of  the  airlines  buy  their  inputs  from 
organizations  which  have  monopoly  power,  then  some  of  their  monop- 
oly gains,  some  of  the  airlines'  monopoly  gains  can  be  captured  by  their 
input  suppliers.  We  find  evidence  of  this  in  terms  of  the  labor  share 
per  total  cost. 

Here  we  find  in  figure  No.  5  that  for  1973  the  average  trunk  carrier 
had  44.3  percent  of  its  total  costs  accounted  for  by  labor  costs,  while 
three  intrastate  carriers  in  1974,  that  is,  for  10  or  11  months  in  1974, 
had  an  average  total  cost  of  26.1  to  34.0  percent — much  lower  than 
the  trunk  or  local  service  carriers.  This  is  evidence  that  there  are  higher 
costs,  higher  prices  paid  to  inputs  by  the  regulated  airlines. 

In  terms  of  your  aircraft,  the  other  major  input  into  airline  opera- 
tions which  the  airlines  must  purchase,  you  have  a  situation  where  the 
manufacturers  are  encouraged  to  produce,  to  modify  their  aircraft  and 


457 

give  variations.  A  number  of  modifications  are  bought  by  tlie  airlines 
so  that  manufacturers  make  a  large  number  of  different' kinds  of  air- 
craft, thereby  increasing  production  costs  and  aircraft  prices.  The 
demand  is  great  by  the  airlines  because  they  must  have  the  most  mod- 
ern aircraft  to  provide  high-quality  service. ' 

Those  are  three  major  sources  of  differences  in  airline  costs  with 
regulation  as  opposed  to  without  regulation. 

TOTAL   COST  OF  REGULATIOX 

Senator  Kennedy.  Have  you  figured  out  how  much  that  would  save  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  A  rough  estimate.  Senator  for  the  trunk  carriers  in 
1973,  total  operating  costs  were  about  $10.6  billion.  It  is  my  best  esti- 
mate that  without  the  regulation  it  would  be  reduced  down'to  approx- 
imately $7  billion,  a  saving  roughly  of  $3.5  billion,  an  appreciable 
difference. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  figure,  that  based  upon  these  variables, 
$31/^  billion  could  be  saved  by  consumers  with  deregulation? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Yes,  that  is  correct. 

EFFECT   OF   COMPETITION    ON    SAFETY 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  about  safety  ?  How  can  we  be  sure  that  if 
we  get  these  100  to  200  airlines  without  regulation  that  we  are  not 
going  to  have  people's  lives  endangered  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Well,  we  turn  again  to  the  evidence.  First  of  all,  all 
airlines,  whether  interstate  or  trastate,  are  controlled  by  the  Federal 
Aviation  Agency,  regardless  of  CAB  regulation.  So  they  have  that 
same  requirement  for  safety  as  controlled  by  the  FAA. 

Second,  within  California  there  have  been  two  fatal  accidents, 
one  a  DC-3  in  1949,  with  a  loss  of  nine  lives,  including  the  wife  and 
son  the  owner  of  the  airline,  which  was  a  painful  experience  for  him. 
In  1964  there  was  a  second  crash,  an  airline  operating  out  of  Lake 
Tahoe,  which  is  a  very  high  altitude  and  a  small  airport,  with  a  loss 
of  85  lives.  In  both  cases  the  airlines  went  out  of  business,  the  second 
case  because  the  FAA  rescinded  the  operating  license,  but  nevertheless 
they  went  out  of  business  which  gave  the  intrastate  carriers  the  sus- 
picion that  perhaps  if  they  are  unsafe  they  would  not  be  around  very 
long.  So  tliere  is  motivation  to  be  safe  in  that  very  real  sense. 

In  terms  of  deaths  per  revenue-passenger  miles,  those  two  accidents, 
given  the  low-traffic  base  for  the  period  from  1949  to  1965,  give  a 
relatively  high  average  of  number  of  deaths  per  100,000  of  revenue 
passenger  miles.  But  if  you  extend  those  same  number  of  fatalities  into 
the  present  time,  roughly  8  more  years,  it  goes  down  to  approximately 
that  of  the  trunk  carriers.  So  the  evidence  is  not  clear,  based  on  those 
two  crashes  for  the  shorter  time  period,  less  safety,  more  fatalities  per 
100,000  revenue-passenger  miles.  If  you  extend  the  period  you  find 
comparable  safety.  Again  the  key  point  is  if  you  are  unsafe,  if  you 
are  small,  you  are  going  out  of  business,  because  there  are  very  good 
substitutes  available  to  take  over  your  business. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  a  pretty  tough  test  for  100  or  200  car- 
riers. I  would  think  that  people  would  want  to  know  with  100  or  200 
carriers,  which  ones  ave  safe.  They  are  on  the  market  today  and  if  they 
have  a  fatality  they  are  out,  but  couldn't  they  come  back  under  some 


458 

other  name  ?  How  wil]  we  be  able  to  give  the  kind  of  assurances 
that  would  prevent  this  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  I  would  say  it  is  important  for  the  FAA,  who  must 
check  the  management  of  every  airline  and  its  operating  procedures, 
to  be  very  careful  about  that.  If  the  airline  has  a  crash  and  the  airline 
goes  out  of  business  because  they  are  negligent,  tlie  FAA  should  be 
responsible  to  make  sure  those  same  j)eople  did  not  go  back  into  busi- 
ness, would  suspect. 

Also,  once  you  do  have  a  crash  in  your  operation  it  is  harder  to  re- 
enter without  regulation. 

UXFAIR   COMPETITIOK    (PREDATORY   PRICING) 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  about  predatory  pricing  ?  Would  that  not 
bring  about  a  good  deal  of  chaos  for  the  consumer  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Well,  Senator,  I  have  just  finislied  a  study  of  predatory 
pricing  and  practices.  The  theoretical  background  provided  by  Pro- 
fessor McGee  years  ago  said  predatory  pricing  is  rare  because  it  is 
costly.  You  can  do  it  easier  by  merging,  buying  them  out. 

I  had  three  cases  where  it  was  alleged,  predatory  cases.  I  tested 
those  and  found  in  two  cases  there  was  great  doubt  as  to  any  predatory 
practices.  In  one  case  there  may  have  been,  but  again  not  sure.  This 
is  consistent  with  the  position  that  predatory  practices  are  rare.  I, 
therefore,  suspect  that  with  a  large  number  of  airlines  you  will  have 
relatively  little  predatory  practices.  If  you  can  get  new"  entry,  why  be  a 
predator  ?  The  guy  goes  out  of  business  if  you  take  him  over ;  other- 
wise, his  assets  remain  and  can  be  used  for  reentry.  Predation  is  very, 
very  costly  and  rare. 

PACIFIC    SOUTHWEST    AIRLINES— INCREASINGLY    RP^GULATED 

Senator  Kennedy.  Have  you  had  any  practical  experience  in  the 
airline  industry  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Yes.  I  started  working  with  the  airlines  in  December 
of  1947.  My  experience  spans  most  of  the  post-war  period.  As  you 
mentioned,  I  worked  four  airlines,  most  recently  from  1960  to  1964 
for  Western  Air  Lines  in  Los  Angeles,  and  I  worked  as  an  airport 
consultant  from  the  airport  viewpoint,  and  of  course,  I  have  my  mili- 
tary service  with  the  Military  Airlift  Command. 

Senator  Kennedy.  After  all  of  this  has  been  said  and  done,  could 
we  not  explain  it  that  perhaps  PSA  is  under  California  regulations 
and  this  is  just  sort  of  a  specialized  situation  in  California? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Well,  California  regulation  is  interesting.  Senator. 
They  are  starting  to  change.  Before  1965,  there  was  little  regulation. 
Open  entry,  no  regulation  of  price  decreases.  Anybody  could  come  in 
and  offer  their  initial  fares  with  no  questions  asked. 

Following  1965,  the  California  Public  ITtilities  Commission  was 
given  jurisdiction,  and  they  have  perhaj^s  since  1969  closed  entry. 
It  takes  awhile  for  these  adjustments  to  take  j)lace.  Things  do  not 
happen  overnight.  PSA  is  starting  to  act  like  a  regulated  airline.  We 
find  between  1969  and  January  1975,  this  last  fare  increase,  that  their 
]5ercentage  fare  increase  is  very  similar  to  the  percentage  increases  of 
the  airlines  regulated  by  the  CAB. 


459 

You  notice  on  that  figure  Xo.  5,  PSA  of  the  three  intrastate  carriers 
has  tlie  highest  labor  share  of  total  costs.  It  is  getting  out  towards  the 
level  of  total  trunk  carriers. 

My  hypothesis  is  that  10  years  from  now  when  I  do  a  restudy  of 
the  California  situation  that  if  the  present  PUC  situation  has  Ijeen 
maintained  we  will  be  finding  PSA  and  the  others  more  like  the  CAB 
airlines. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  is  that  ? 

Dr.  Jordan.  Because  California  regulation  has  become  very  similar 
to  CAB  regulation,  different  in  procedure  or  different  in  its  detail, 
but  the  economic  results  from  fragmentary  evidence  since  1969  indi- 
cate that  the  cases  are  becoming  very,  very  similar.  Closed  entry  in 
California  is  very  important. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  Summerfield. 

Mr.  Summerfield.  Thank  you.  Senator. 

My  testimony  does  not  differ  in  fact  very  much  from  Dr.  Jordon's. 
It  is"  a  fact  that  costs  are  different.  I  present  a  different  interpretation 
of  why  these  costs  are  different.  It  is  based  on  a  study  of  the  actual 
operating  environments  of  the  infra-California  carriers  versus  the 
trunk  and  local  service  carriers. 

COSTS  saved  by  PSA  BECAUSE  IT  DOES  NOT  FLY  INTERSTATE    (INTERLINING, 
TICKETING,    ACCOUNTING) 

To  summarize  briefly  what  is  contained  in  a  little  more  detail  in 
my  written  testimony,  a  number  of  differences  exist  because  of  the 
fact  that  PSA  and  Air  California  are  intrastate  carriers  operating  in 
restricted  geographical  areas.  In  the  first  place,  because  they  don't 
do  any  interline  work,  as  Mi\  Clifford  pointed  out,  the  reservations 
clerks  don't  need  to  know  anything  about  how  to  get  from  Santa  Ana 
to  Boston  because  they  are  not  allowed  to  route  you  that  way.  This 
means  you  don't  have  to  train  them,  a  major  saving  in  training  costs. 
But  the  big  saving  is  in  the  time  they  spend  on  the  telephone  when  you 
call  for  a  reservation.  They  simply' make  point-to-point  reservations. 
According  to  my  estimates,  the  average  length  of  call  for  reservations 
is  at  least  three"  times  as  long  for  a  trunk  carrier  as  for  an  intrastate 
carrier.  This  represents  about  a  3  to  1  difference  in  the  manpower 
required  to  man  the  reservation  system. 

A  second  way  in  which  this  carries  over  is  in  the  ticketing.  PSA 
uses  a  very  simple  cash  register  receipt  as  a  ticket.  They  don't  have 
to  figure  out  what  the  fare  is  between  Boston  and  iNIodesto,  Calif.,  a 
market  for  which  there  may  be  no  quoted  fare.  A  carrier  that  writes 
interline  tickets  must  add  up  fares  through  several  routes  to  be  sure 
they  have  the  lowest  fare.  Again,  there  are  substantial  economies 
because  intrastate  carriers  cannot  do  this. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  the  agents  did  have  interline  training  the  same 
as  other  carriers,  couldn't  that  mean  that  they  would  gain  more  rev- 
enues because  they  would  get  additional  kinds  of  services? 

Mr.  Summerfi?:ld.  That  is  possible,  that  they  would  gain 
additional 

Senator  Kennedy.  Isn't  it  likely?  Don't  you  suppose  they  would 
certainly  get  some? 


460 

As  I  understand,  if  you  want  to  go  from  Boston  to  San  Francisco 
to  Los  Angeles,  and  you  want  to  fly  that  San  Francisco  to  Los  An- 
geles leg  on  PSA,  which  is  cheaper,  you  can't  get  a  ticket  on  it. 

Mr,  SuMMERFiELD.  You  can  if  you  wait  till  you  get  to  San  Francisco 
to  buy  the  ticket. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  the  point.  If  people  wanted  to  fly,  and 
knew  PSA  was  cheaper,  wouldn't  they  take  PSA  ?  And  would  not  that 
help  to  offset  additional  training  costs  for  reservation  clerks? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  It  might.  It  would  expand  the  whole  system. 
Senator,  so  they  would  end  up  having  more  airplanes  and  more  flights. 
Whether  the  cost  would  go  up  proportionately  or  not,  I  do  not  know. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Maybe  load  capacity  would  change  from  65 
percent  full  up  to  75  percent. 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  I  dou't  kuow,  Senator.  That  is  speculation.  What 
I  have  tried  to  do  is  limit  myself  to  the  areas  in  which  there  are  data 
to  support  the  analyses. 

Revenue  accounting  is  a  third  way  in  which  this  lack  of  interlining 
saA'es  the  intrastate  carrier  a  good  deal  of  money. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  the  cost  for  interlining,  have  you  figured 
that  out? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  ]\Iv  estimate  for  those  three  functions  for  PSA, 
for  reservations  for  ticketing  and  for  revenue  accounting,  is  on  the 
order  of  $11  million  a  year  difference  for  the  size  of  operation  that 
PSA  now  has.  This  is  based  on  data  on  the  cost  per  passenger  of  these 
services  and  some  estimates  based  on  my  experience. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  much  does  that  work  out  to  per  passenger  ? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiEiJ).  A  little  under  $2  a  passenger.  PSA  said  they 
carry  about  a  little  less  than  61/0  million  passengers  a  year. 

Senator  Kennedy.  So  it  is  about  $1.50. 

Mr.  SUMMERFIELD.  $1.50,  $1.70. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Even  with  a  $1.60  additional  charge,  it  is  difficult 
to  explain,  the  sizable  difference  in  the  fare  between  PSA  and  the  CAB- 
regulated  airlines. 

INIr.  SuMMERFiELD.  That  is  right,  but  there  are  other  factors,  some 
of  which  have  been  mentioned,  but  let  me  try  to  put  some  on  dollar 
amounts  on  some  of  these  other  factors,  also. 

COST  SAVED  BY  PSA  BECAUSE  IT  DOES  NOT  SERVE  FOOD 

They  don't  have  food  service.  If  food  service  were  at  the  relatively 
simple  level  of  local  service  carriers,  in  other  words,  and  if  they  had 
longer  routes  on  Avhich  some  food  service  was  required  or  they  felt  it 
was  necessary  to  give  the  kind  of  food  service  that,  for  example,  local 
service  carriers  do,  that  might  add  another  $3  million.  That  is  based 
on 

Senator  Kennedy.  But,  they  don't  have  that,  do  they  ? 

]Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  Xo,  they  do  not  have  the  kind  of  route  structure 
that  operates  over  longer  distances;  typically  they  have  about  1-hour 
flights.  On  1-hour  flights,  liardly  anybody  serves  food. 

If  they  had  a  longer  loute  structiire  and  operated  like  the  trunk  or 
local  service  carrier,  then  in  all  likelihood  they  would  liave  food  service. 

One  of  tlie  main  ways  they  benefit  from  this  is  that,  because  they 
don't  liave  food  service,  thev  don't  need  aallovs,  and  there  is  room  for 


461 

additional  seats.  This  provides  them  room  for  extra  passengers  on 
flights  that  woukl  othei-wise  be  sokl  out  and  not  avaihible. 

Senator  Kexnedy.  From  the  consumer's  point  of  view,  there  is  no 
real  problem  with  that,  is  tliere?  If  they  want  to  give  up  lunch,  for 
that  hours  ride  either  from  Los  Angeles  to  San  Francisco,  or,  from 
Boston  to  Washington,  can't  they  ? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  No,  I  am  merely  trying.  Senator,  to  explain  the 
differences  in  cost  structure  between  two  different  types  of  operation, 
and  trying  to  explain  why  these  costs  actually  exist.  It  has  really  noth- 
ing to  do  with  the  regulatory  process  is  what  I  am  saying.  The  differ- 
ences result  from  the  natui'e  of  the  I'oute  structure  in  some  cases  or  the 
nature  of  the  geograjihical  confinement  of  the  system.  In  fact,  if  you 
had  100  to  200  different  airlines,  as  Dr.  Jordan  suggested,  many  of 
them  would  have  these  short  segments  and  some  of  these  differences 
would  appear. 

INTERLINING 

One  of  the  problems,  however,  with  these  self-contained  units  like 
PSA  and  Air  California  is  that,  if  they  existed  for  the  whole  country, 
it  would  be  terribly  difficult  to  get  around  because  of  the  point  you 
brought  out  a  minute  ago.  You  can't  make  a  reservation — you  can  make 
a  reservation  if  you  mnke  a  long-distance  telephone  call.  You  can't  get 
a  ticket  here. 

If  we  had  many  of  these  small  intrastate  operations  the  whole  inte- 
grated system  we  depend  on,  not  to  get  from  here  to  Los  Angeles  or 
Washington,  but  from  here  to  Podunk  would  fall  apart.  We  would 
have  a  difficult  time  getting  all  these  connecting  services  tied  into  the 
different  carriers. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  there  any  reason  this  couldn't  be  computerized 
in  some  kind  of  central  agency  ?  As  I  understand,  in  less  than  a  minute, 
a  Chicago  policeman  can  call  in  an  automobile  license  plate  and  find 
out  wlio  owns  it. 

INIr.  SuMMERFiELD.  That  is  correct. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  it  so  difficult  then  to  computerize  ticket  inter- 
lining? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  Of  tile  58,000  city-pairs  that  are  now  served, 
many  don't  have  fares  quoted  between  them.  For  those  with  fares 
listed  in  the  OAG  there  could  be  a  retrieval  process,  though  it  might 
be  expensive.  Rut  for  the  person  who  wants  to  go  from  here  to  Chicago, 
to  Des  ]Moines,  and  then  down  to  Dallas  and  so  on,  the  airlines  have 
spent  a  lot  of  money  trying  to  computerize  this  and  they  have  found  it 
really  can't  be  economically  done  except  for  the  relatively  simple 
itineraries. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  mean  everybody  who  is  traveling  from 
Boston  to  Washington  is  paying  for  compiiterized  fare  construction 
for  the  person  flying  from  Fargo  to  Podunk,  and  if  they  are,  we  ought 
to  know  about  it,  shouldn't  we  ?  We  are  already  paying  too  much  in 
terms  of  energy  underwriting  for  other  areas  of  the  country,  and  now 
we  find  that  when  M-e  go  fi-om  Boston  to  Washington  Ave  are  paying 
for  that  integrated  system  as  well. 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  But  that  part  is  not  in  the  computer  because  it 
was  just  too  expensive  to  do  it.  It  is  really  the  very  simple  routings 
that  are  in  the  computerized  systems  of  the  airlines.  If  you  want  to 


462 

ask  these  questions  of  representatives  who  operate  these  computer 
systems 

Senator  I^nnedy.  Let  me  get  back  to  another  point,  when  you  were 
talking  about  the  route  structure  and  about  how  it  really  wasn't  the 
CAB,  but  it  was  tlie  route  structure  that  determined  such  considera- 
tions as  food  service.  Isn't  it  really  the  CAB  that  develops  those 
route  structures  ?  Couldn't  they,  by  regulation,  provide  that  there  be  a 
more  efficient  or  lower  cost  service,  in  these  particular  areas? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  Well,  the  CAB  has,  of  course,  no  authority  to 
set  fares.  Fares  are  recommended  or  applied  for  by  the  carriers  based 
on  their  need  to  get  a  return  on  their  investment.  What  I  am  trying 
to  point  out  is  that  there  are  differences  in  the  cost  structure  of  the 
trunk  and  local-service  carriers  from  the  cost  structure  that  exists  in 
a  small  intrastate  carrier.  These  differences  make  it  difficult,  impossible 
in  many  cases,  to  operate  at  lower  fares  for  a  larger  system.  There 
are  other  costs,  and  I  am  trying  to  review  with  you  basically  what 
those  costs  are. 

Some  of  them  are  the  result  of  having  an  integrated  system,  which 
makes  it  more  convenient  for  the  public, 

LABOR    COSTS    SAVED    BY   PSA 

There  are  some  costs  related  to  unionization,  that  is,  the  union  rules. 
One  of  these  has  to  do  with  productivity.  The  one  reason  that  cost 
differences  are  narrowing  is  that  as  airlines  get  older,  the  unions 
organize  the  workers  and  get  stronger.  Although  PSA  pays  its  pilots 
about  the  same  amount  per  hour  as  its  com|>etitors  do,  they  have  a 
different  set  of  operating  rules  that  enable  PSA  pilots  to  get  maybe 
20  hours  a  month  more  flying  time  within  the  same  maximum  time 
than  trunk  carrier  pilots  do.  This  is  a  matter  of  union  regulations,  not 
of  the  management  of  the  airline.  Dr.  Jordan's  speculation  that  PSA 
labor  rates  are  going  up  is  probably  a  reflection  that  the  unions  get 
stronger  as  the  airline  gets  stronger  and  as  the  airline  is  older. 

Mr.  Guske  pointed  out  that  younger  airlines  have  lower  seniority 
structure  and  hence  a  lower  wage-cost. 

On  the  basis  of  the  numbers  that  I  was  able  to  get  from  the  rela- 
tively sparse  data  that  was  published  with  the  public  Utilities  Com- 
mission, my  estimates.  Senator,  are  that  if  PSA  operated  in  the  same 
operating  environment  and  with  the  same  kind  of  route  structure  as 
the  trunk  and  local-service  carriers,  their  pretax  profits  would  have 
been  reduced  on  the  order  of  $20  million. 

Senator  Kennedy.  As  I  understand  this,  PSA  has  about  6i/^  million 
passengers  so  that  $20  million  in  increased  costs  would  mean  about 
$8  additional  fare  per  passenger.  Yet  PSA's  fare  from  San  Francisco 
to  Los  Angeles  is  $6  lower  than  the  CAB  carriers'  intrastate  fare  and 
$18  lower  than  their  interstate  fare.  Even  taking  the  lower  figure  for 
the  moment,  how  can  you  account  for  the  other  $8  ? 

Mr.  SuMMERFiELD.  I  dou't  liave  a  complete  answer  to  where  the  dif- 
ferences are.  Senator,  and  there  are  other  differences  that  I  have  not 
been  able  to  get  any  data  on.  I  have,  for  example,  not  been  able  to 
make  any  estimates  of  differences  in  the  training  costs  that  I  alluded 
to  earlier,  or  some  of  the  other  differences.  The  $20  million  is  based  on 


463 

those  things  for  which  I  was  able  to  get  data  from  the  rather  sparse 
amount  of  data  available  for  the  Public  Utility  Commission  filings 
and  PSA  applications  for  fare  increases. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Fine.  Thank  you. 

Mr.  Jordan,  do  you  have  any  comments  you  want  to  make  on  any 
of  these  points  that  have  been  raised  ? 

Mr.  Jordan.  I  agree  with  Dr.  Summerfield  that  if  PSA  were 
allowed  to  operate  in  the  manner  of  trunk  carriers  they  would  indeed 
have  higher  costs.  My  position  is  that  trunk  carriers  operate  the  way 
they  do — not  because  they  are  bad  people — but  because  they  are  regu- 
lated and  they  have  certain  rules  they  follow  and  this  kind  of  game 
results  in  these  kinds  of  outputs.  PSA  or  nonregulated  airlines  do  not 
operate  in  this  manner.  This  is  the  whole  point.  They  would  operate 
efficiently  in  long-haul  services  as  well  as  short-haul  services.  The  only 
reason  why  PSA  is  a  short-haul  carrier  is  because  it  can't  be  a  longer- 
haul  carrier,  it  is  limited  to  California.  Part  of  the  folklore  of  the  air- 
line industry  is  that  long-hauls  are  good,  not  bad,  yet  intrastate  car- 
riers have  been  efficient  even  in  short-haul  operations. 

In  terms  of  the  decreased  profits,  I  would  argue  he  is  talking  about 
increased  costs,  not  decreased  profits,  because  as  you  pointed  out  he  is 
ignoring  the  revenue  side  of  the  interlining  operation.  But  given  his 
cost  estimates,  which  I  don't  agree  with,  but  they  have  given  them,  the 
difference  is  only  $3  per  passenger.  I  would  assert  that  in  the  case  of 
reservations,  for  example,  even  if  PSA  did  have  interlining  reserva- 
tions the  person  who  called  in  Los  Angeles  for  a  ticket  to  San  Fran- 
cisco would  say,  hello,  when  is  your  next  flight  to  San  Francisco, 
fine,  reservations  for  so  and  so,  telephone  number  893-1808,  and  hang 
up,  that  is  a  minute  call.  There  would  be  no  long  3-minute  telephone 
conversations,  I  have  things  to  do  with  my  time  and  they  have  things 
to  do  with  their  time.  It  wouldn't  change  for  those  simple  kinds  of 
passenger  trips.  I  see  no  reason  why  the  cost  would  be  inflated  by  a 
large  degree. 

The  point  is  that  without  regulation  you  have  specialization.  You 
have  carriers  operating  some  type  of  aircraft  in  a  very  simplified  man- 
ner. There  are  no  excessive  aircraft  purchases  or  excessive  aircraft 
operations.  This  saves  a  large  am.ount  of  money.  A  747  now  costs  $30 
million;  that  is  roughly  the  cost  of  this  building,  I  would  guess,  and 
when  you  start  talking'about  100,  or  200,  or  300  large  aircraft  we  have 
important  differences  in  cost.  If  you  talk  about  differences  in  employee 
output  as  I  mentioned  in  figure  5,  differences  in  costs  are  very  impor- 
tant, and  this  is  due  to  regulation. 

Senator  Keiv  nedy.  Thank  you  very  much. 

[The  prepared  statements  "of  Dr.  Jordan  and  Dr.  Summerfield  fol- 
low. During  the  hearing  of  February  18,  1975,  the  chairman  of  the 
subcommittee  asked  Continental  Airlines  to  respond  to  Dr.  Jordan's 
testimony.  The  response  by  James  L.  Mitchell  of  Continental  Airlines, 
a  reply  by  Dr.  Jordan,  and  further  remarks  by  Continental  Airlines 
are  all  printed  after  the  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Harvey  Wexler 
of  Continental  Airlines,  which  follows  the  testimony  of  the  panel  of 
airlines  on  February  18,  1975,  pp.  587  ff.,  below.  Dr.  Summerfield's 
written  responses  to  Dr.  Jordan's  testimony  and  to  a  subcommittee  staff 
memo  are  included  after  his  prepared  statement.] 


464 

Prepared  Statement  of  Dr.  William  A.  Jordan 

QUALIFICATIONS 

My  name  is  Willian  A.  Jordan,  I  am  a  professor  of  managerial  economics 
at  York  University,  Toronto,  Canada.  During  the  past  27  years  I  have  been 
employed  in  traffic,  sales,  and  research  positions  by  four  airlines  (the  Scan- 
dinavian Airlines  System,  Air  France,  Seaboard  World  Airlines,  and  Western 
Air  Lines),  have  consulted  on  airline  and  airport  matters,  and  have  taught 
graduate  courses  and/or  done  research  in  economics  and  government  regulation 
at  Columbia  University,  Northwestern  University,  Stanford  University,  U.S. 
International  University  and  York  University.  My  Ph.  D.  in  managerial  eco- 
nomics is  from  the  University  of  California,  Los  Angeles,  and  my  research 
publications  include  the  following :  Airline  Regulation  in  America :  Effects  and 
Imperfections,  1970 ;  Producers  Protection,  Pi-ior  Market  Structure,  and  the 
Effects  of  Government  Regulation,  1.5  Journal  of  Law  and  Economics,  April 
1972 :  Airline  Capacity  Agreements :  Correcting  a  Regulatory  Imjierfection,  39 
Journal  of  Air  Law  and  Commerce,  Spring  1973;  If  We're  Going  to  Regulate 
the  Airlines,  Let's  Do  it  Right,  in  James  C.  Miller  III,  ed.,  Perspectives  in 
Federal  Transportation  Policy,  1975. 

I  am  a  colonel  in  the  U.S.  Air  Force  Reserve  and  since  1959  have  been  as- 
signed to  Headquarters,  Military  Airlift  Command.  I  was  a  member  of  the 
American  Statistical  Associaiton  Advisory  Committee  for  Statistical  Research 
to  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  from  1967  until  it  was  disbanded  this  past  year. 
My  current  professional  memberships  include  the  American  Economic  Associa- 
tion, Western  Economic  Association,  Canadian  Economic  Association  and  Cana- 
dian Transportation  Research  Forum.  Individually,  or  jointly,  my  wife  and  I 
own  stock  in  the  following  airlines :  Air  California,  Airlift  International,  Braniff 
International,  Capitol  International,  Continental,  Xordair,  North  Central,  Pacific 
Southwest,  Sedalia-Marshall-Boonville,  Southwest,  United. 

INTRODUCTION 

A  useful  way  to  investigate  the  actual  results  of  the  activities  of  independent 
regulatory  commissions  is  to  compare  the  performances  of  firms  regulated  by 
such  commissions  with  those  of  other  similar  firms  operating  beyond  the  com- 
missions' jurisdictions.  It  is  possible  to  make  such  cross-sectional  studies  of 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board  (CAB)  regulations  because  the  CAB  does  not  regulate 
all  parts  of  the  U.S.  airline  industry.  The  intrastate  airlines  operating  entirely 
within  California,  and  recently,  within  Texas  provide  the  best  examples  of 
airlines  not  regulated  by  the  CAB.  Also,  the  CAB  has  exempted  third-level/ 
commuter  carriers  from  most  of  its  regulatory  control  so  long  as  they  operate 
only  small  aircraft.  Furthermore,  comparisons  with  Canadian  airline  perform- 
ance can  be  useful  because,  while  Canada  is  a  different  country,  it  shares  many 
geographical,  demographic  and  social  characteristics  with  the  U.S. 

Another  way  to  measure  the  effects  of  regulation  is  to  compare  industry 
performance  before  and  after  a  major  change  in  regulatory  policy.  Time-.series 
studies  such  as  these  provide  less  reliable  results  than  cross-sectional  studies, 
however,  because  considerable  time  often  is  required  for  the  effects  of  specific 
actions  to  come  to  full  fruition.  In  the  meantime,  other  developments  may 
impinge  on  or  otherwise  obscure  the  effects  of  the  policy  action  under  study. 
Occasionally,  though,  time-series  evidence  can  be  quite  useful,  especially  when 
it  corroborates  evidence  obtained  from  cross-sectional  analyses. 

A  fundamental  problem  in  using  time-series  data  is  estimating  the  effects  of 
government  regulation  is  that  a  change  in  a  regulatory  policy  merely  results 
in  a  relative  change  in  performance  under  regulation.  Unless  the  action  to  be 
studied  results  in  a  change  from  where  regulation  did  not  exist  to  one  where 
it  was  implemented,  there  is  no  benchmark  or  baseline  with  which  to  deter- 
mine the  absolute  effects  of  regulation  per  se.  Without  the  benchmark  of  non- 
regulated  performance,  it  is  difficult,  if  not  impossible,  to  determine  whether 
some  regulatory  policy  results  in  an  additional  deviation  from  non-regulated 
performance  by  10  percent,  or  20  percent  or  whatever.  For  example,  a  CAB 
action  may  cause  the  regulated  trunk  and  local  service  carriers  to  raise  their 
fares  by  only  five  rather  than  7  or  8  percent.  Tlius,  it  might  be  argued  that 
CAB  regulation  decreases  the  relative  level  or  regulated  airline  fares.  This 
may  be  true,  but  without  knowing  what  fares  would  have  been  without  CAB 
regulation  one  can  not  conclude  from  this  that  such  regulation  reduces  absolute 


465 

fare  levels.  It  may  well  be  that  the  existence  of  CAB  regulation  since  1938 
has  resulted  in  fares  that  are  substantially  higher  than  what  would  have 
developed  in  its  absence.  If  so,  then  any  impediment  the  CAB  now  introduces 
to  fare  increases  merely  serves  to  reduce  the  degree  to  which  regulated  fares 
exceed  non-regulated  fares. 

This  testimony  will  present  evidence  from  various  cross-sectional  and  time- 
series  studies  regarding  the  effects  of  CAB  regulatory  practices  on  the  economic 
performance  of  the  regulated  airlines.  Emphasis  will  be  placed  on  entry  and 
the  number  of  airlines  in  existence,  fares,  and  productive  efficiency,  with  some 
mention  also  being  made  of  safety  and  profits.  The  primary  source  of  this 
evidence  will  be  a  comparative  study  of  the  California  intrastate  carriers  and 
the  CAB-regulated  airlines,  supplemented  by  additional  evidence  concerning  the 
Texas  intrastate  carrier,  Canadian  airlines,  third-level  carriers,  and  the  results 
of  extending  CAB  regulation  over  military  charter  operations. 

CAB   REGULATION    HAS   DECREASED   THE   NUMBER  OF   AIRLINES 

One  result  of  CAB  regulation  has  been  the  effective  restriction  of  entry  into 
airline  oi>erations.  The  only  airlines  so  far  authorized  to  provide  trunk  service 
were  those  who  obtained  their  certificates  of  public  convenience  and  necessity 
under  the  "grandfather"  provisions  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938  (52  Stat. 
988).  Today,  10  of  the  original  16  trunk  carriers  remain — the  others  having  been 
acquired  by  or  merged  with  surviving  trunk  carriers.'  The  same  is  true  for  the 
local  service  carriers.  With  the  single  recent  exception  of  Air  New  England,  all 
of  the  existing  local  service  carriers  were  among  the  21  airlines  the  CAB  al- 
lowed to  enter  the  industry  during  the  "local  feeder"  experiment  between  the 
end  of  World  War  II  and  October  1950.  Again,  acquisition  by  or  merger  with 
other  certificated  carriers  characterized  the  means  by  which  failing  local  serv- 
ice carriers  have  left  the  industry,  and  now  only  eight  of  the  original  21  remain.^ 

The  extent  to  which  CAB  regulation  has  effectively  restricted  new  airlines 
from  impinging  upon  the  activities  of  the  original  trunk  and  the  local  service 
carriers  can  be  seen  by  comparing  the  relative  shares  of  the  almost  $13  billion 
of  overall  operating  revenues  earned  systemwide  in  1973  by  all  U.S.  airlines 
operating  large  aircraft.^  The  trunk  carriers,  plus  Pan  American,  accounted  for 
84.2  percent  of  this  total  revenue  while  the  local  service  carriers  earned  another 
8.2  percent.  Thus,  these  two  groups  consisting  of  19  scheduled  passenger/cargo 
carriers  accounted  for  92.4  percent  of  the  $13  billion,  leaving  the  remaining  7.6 
percent  for  the  Alaskan,  Hawaiian,  territorial,  helicopter,  intrastate,  all-cargo, 
supplemental  and  other  carriers  (31  in  all)  that  operated  in  1973.* 

This  means  that,  combined,  these  31  other  carriers  earned  fewer  operating 
revenues  than  the  local  service  carriers  and  less  than  one-tenth  the  revenues  of 
the  trunk  carriers  and  Pan  American.  One  would  think  that  the  managers  and 
employees  of  the  trunk  and  local  service  carriers  would  be  quite  pleased  with 
this  situation  and  would  feel  that  CAB  regulation  had  been  good  to  them  during 
these  past  36  years.  Indeed,  had  the  early  airline  pioneers  been  told  back  in  1938 
that  CAB  regulation  would  result  in  this  allocation  of  such  large  oi>erating  rev- 
enues one  would  exi>ect  they  would  have  been  quite  pleased  with  the  prospect. 
But  present-day  industrj'  leaders  appear  to  be  dissatisfied  with  this  situation  and 
are  endeavoring  to  increase  their  present  dominant  share.  It  should  be  recog- 
nized, however,  that  none  of  these  leaders  proposes  the  abolition  of  CAB  regula- 
tion, merely  its  improvement. 

In  California,  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission  (PUC)  did  not  have 
power  over  airline  entry  within  the  state  until  September  1965.  During  the  years 
from  1946  to  1965,  at  least  sixteen  airlines  inaugurated  scheduled  service  with 
large  aircraft  within  the  confined  area  of  California,  and  entry  occurred  through- 
out these  years  rather  than  being  concentrated  in  a  single  time  period  (as  was 
the  case  under  CAB  regulation).  Fourteen  of  these  airlines  subsequently  termi- 
nated service  after  operating  from  only  a  few  weeks  to  over  six  years.  In  not 
one  of  the.se  ca.ses,  however,  was  a  failing  airline  acquired  by  or  merged  with 


1  William  A.  Jordan.  Airline  Regulation  in  America  :  Effects  and  Imperfections,  15-17 
(1970).  ALSO,  a\B  Handbook  of  Airline  Statistics.  568-69  (1973  ed.). 

2  Id. 

SCAB,  Air  Carrier  Financial  Statistics.  1-14.  98  (December  1973);  Air  California, 
Annual  Report  (1973)  ;  PSA  Annual  Report  (1973)  ;  and  Southwest  Airlines  Annual 
ReDort  (1973). 

*  The  only  carriers  excluded  from  this  compilation  are  the  few  third-level  carriers  who 
have  CAB  exceptions  to  operate  large  two-engine  propeller  aircraft. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  31 


466 

another  carrier.  This  is  in  marked  contrast  to  the  consistent  usage  of  these  meth- 
ods of  exit  by  the  CAB-reguIated  airlines.  This  implies  "that  the  asset  of  an  air- 
line that  is  of  unique  value  to  other  airlines  is  its  CAB  certificate  of  public 
convenience  and  necessity,  not  its  aircraft,  facilities,  or  good  will,  .  .  ."  ^ 

Not  only  does  the  California  experience  demonstrate  that  CAB  regulation  has 
effectively  impeded  entry  into  the  interstate  airline  industry  and  has  promoted 
exit  via  merger  and  acquisition,  but  it  also  indicates  that  this  regulation  has 
served  to  limit  the  number  of  airlines  in  existence  at  any  point  in  time.  Based 
on  the  system  sizes  and  traffic  volumes  of  the  California  intrastate  carriers,  it 
appears  that  without  CAB  regulation  from  100  to  over  200  airlines  operating 
large  aircraft  would  have  existed  at  any  one  time  in  the  48  contiguous  states 
from  1949  through  1965.  This  is  in  sharp  contrast  to  the  35  to  24  trunk  and 
local  service  carriers  that  the  CAB  actually  allowed  to  operate  during  that  pe- 
riod." Should  this  range  seem  unrealistioally  large,  one  should  note  that  a  total 
of  201  commuter  air  carriers  Oii>erated  under  very  constrained  conditions  during 
fiscal  year  1973,  and  that  126  of  these  small  airlines  operated  for  the  entire 
year.'  Implicit  in  the  conclusion  that  CAB  regulation  serves  to  limit  greatly  the 
number  of  airlines  in  existence  is  the  finding  that  there  are  no  appreciable 
economies  of  scale  in  nonregulated  airline  operations,  and  that  a  high  degree  of 
specialization  by  airlines  would  occur  without  regulation.* 

Effective  entry  control  is  a  crucially  important  factor  in  protecting  established 
airlines,  their  employees  and  their  suppliers.  Not  only  does  it  insulate  the  air- 
lines from  the  results  of  honest  errors  in  judgment  and  from  possible  managerial 
inefficiencies,  but  it  also  allows  monopolistic  or  oligopolistic  suppliers  of  inputs 
(such  as  labor,  aircraft,  petroleum  products  and  airports)  to  charge  ever  higher 
prices  for  their  products  and  services.  All  of  these  factors  increase  the  operat- 
ing costs  of  regulated  airlines.  Furthermore,  market  protection  enhances  the 
viability  of  charging  higher  prices  so  that  the  regulated  airlines  can  seek  to  cap- 
ture monopoly  profits.  Given  entry  control,  cost  increases  and  higher  fares  can 
persist  because  new,  more  eflScient  carriers  paying  lower  prices  for  their  inputs 
are  prohibited  by  CAB  regulation  from  entering  the  industry,  offering  lower  fares 
for  their  services  and,  eventually,  replacing  or  reducing  the  sizes  of  the  existing 
airlines.  Evidence  on  fare  levels  and  operating  costs  will  be  presented  in  the 
following  sections. 

CAB  REGULATION  HAS  INCREASED  AIRLINE  FARES 

Evidence  from   California 

Article  XII  of  the  California  State  Constitution  has  long  empowered  the 
PUC  to  regulate  the  intrastate  rates  and  fares  of  all  transportation  companies, 
including  the  airlines.  In  practice,  the  PUC  has  controlled  airline  fare  increases, 
but  not  decreases."  Effective  September  17, 1965,  the  PUC  received  authority  from 
the  legislature  to  regulate  entry  and  exit  to  and  from  scheduled  airline  passenger 
service.^"  It  has  exercised  this  power  over  entry  with  an  enthusiasm  comparable 
to  that  of  the  CAB.  To  date,  it  has  issued  to  just  five  airlines  certificates  of  public 
convenience  and  necessity  to  operate  large  aircraft  (those  carrying  over  30 
passengers)  in  scheduled  passenger  service.  Four  of  these,  including  three  "grand- 
father" certificates,  were  issued  in  the  fall  of  1966,"  while  the  fifth,  and  last, 
certificate  was   issued  in  early   1969  and   then   reissued  in    September  1971." 

All  other  applications  for  certificates  have  been  denied." 


^  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  17-14,  esp.  pp.  23-24. 

«  Id.  at  24-32. 

•CAB,  Commuter  Air  Carrier  Traffic  Statistics,  Year  Ended  June  .30,  1!)73,  3  (June 
1974). 

^  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  191-94. 

»Id.  at  2-4. 

"  Id.  Also,  State  of  California,  Statutes  and  Amendments  to  the  Codes,  196.5  Chapters, 
A-3,  214.")  (196.')). 

It  PUC  decision  71310  (September  20,  1966)  for  Air  California:  rUC  decision  71393 
(October  11,  1966)  for  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  (PSA)  :  PUC  decision  71490  (November 
1,  1966)  for  :Mercer  Enterprises,  and  PUC  decisions  71648  (December  6,  1966)  and  72.')60 
(April  IS.  1967)  for  Holiday  Airlines. 

1- PUC  decision  7.")373  (Februar.v  25,  1969)  issued  a  certificate  to  California  Sierra  Air- 
lines which  was  revoked  by  PUC  decision  7S6S2  (May  18.  1971)  when  this  carrier  failed 
to  inaugurate  service.  Essentially  the  same  route  to  the  Mammoth  Lakes  ski  resort  area 
was  then  awarded  to  Sierra  Pacific  .\irlines  in  I'UC  decision  79166   (September  21.  1971). 

"For  example,  the  applications  of  .\ir  Metrooolitan  and  Pacific  Air  Transport  to 
operate  between  points  in  the  Los  .\n>,'eles  and  San  Francisco  metropolitan  areas  were 
denied   in   PUC   decisions   74S37    (October   15,   196S).  and   76110    (September  3,   1969). 


467 

This  change  in  California  regulation  provides  some  interesting  comparisons 
with  which  to  evaluate  the  effects  of  entry  control  on  fares.  Prior  to  19G5, 
it  is  possible  to  make  a  cross-sectional  comparison  between  the  fares  of  air- 
lines operating  within  California  without  entry  protection  and  the  fares  of 
CAB-regulated  airlines  who  were  protected  from  entry  into  their  interstate 
city-pairs.  Then  a  comparison  can  be  made  between  the  fares  of  the  intrastate 
and  CAB-regulated  carriers  after  1965  when  both  enjoyed  closed  entry.  Finally,  a 
time-series  comparison  can  be  made  for  iiercentage  fare  changes  by  the  two 
types  of  carriers  following  the  PUC's  effective  closure  of  entry  after  1965.  First 
the  pre-19()5  comiJarison. 

One  important  aspect  of  PUC  rate  regulation  was  that  the  initial  tariff  of 
a  new  carrier  had  to  be  accepted  providing  it  conformed  to  basic  technical  and 
publication  requirements.  "  Thus,  there  was  no  regulation  of  the  fares  introduced 
by  new  carriers.  The  first  ma.ior  period  of  entry  by  intrastate  carriers  occurred 
in  1949  when  seven  airlines  (including  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines)  inaugurated 
coach  service  between  the  larger  city-pairs  and,  in  the  process,  introduced  new 
low  fares.  Of  these  seven  airlines,  only  PSA  has  survived  so  its  fares  will  be 
used  here,  both  because  they  are  representative  of  those  adopted  by  other  intra- 
state can-iers  at  the  specified  times  and  because  they  provide  a  continuous  fare 
history  for  the  entire  period. 

TABLE  l.-PSA'S  COACH    FARES   COMPARED  WITH    CAB-AUTHORIZED    IST-CLASS    FARES  FOR    THREE    MAJOR 
CALIFORNIA  CITY-PAIRS,  1949 


CAB-authorized  percent 


CAB-authorized2  greater  than  PSA 


City-pairs 

One-way 

Round  trip 

One-way   Round  trip  ' 

One-way 

Round  trip 

LAX/BUR-SFO/OAK 

_ _            $9.95 

$19.90 
11.30 
31.20 

$21.05           $40.00 
6.75             12.82 
27.80             52.82 

111.6 
19.5 
78.2 

101.0 

LAX/BUR'SAN 

5.65 

13.4 

SAN-SFO/OAK 

15  60 

69.3 

•  Coach  fares  effective  May  23, 1949  to  Mar.  27,  1951. 

2  Ist-class  fares  effective  Sept.  1,  1948  to  Apr.  29,  1952.  From  Feb.  1  to  Oct.  14,  1949,  the  CAB  authorized  Western  to 
offer  a  "no-meal"  tariff  which  gave  a  5-percent  discount  on  all  fares.  Thus,  during  this  9)-^-month  period,  Western's 
one-way  fares  were  equal  to  1/2  the  regular  round  trip  fares. 

3  A  10-percent  discount  was  given  on  the  return  portion  of  round  trip  journeys  by  CAB-regulated  airlines. 

Source:  William  A.  Jordan,  "Airline  Regulation  in  America,"  276-78,  284-87  (1970). 

Table  1  compares  the  1!)49  coach  fares  of  I'SA  in  the  three  major  California 
city-pairs  with  the  first-class  fares  authorized  by  the  CAB  and  utilized  by  United 
and  Western  airlines  who  were  the  CAB-regulated  airlines  serving  all  three  of 
these  city-pairs.  It  is  necessary  to  compare  coach  with  first-class  fares  in  1949 
because  CAB-regulated  carriers  did  not  offer  coach  service  in  short-haul  city- 
pairs  at  that  time,  making  first-class  their  lowest  available  fare. 

Table  1  shows  that  the  CAB-authorized  one-way  fares  ranged  from  19  to  111 
percent  higher  than  the  fares  of  PSA  (and  other  intrastate  carriers).  The 
greatest  difference  was  in  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  city-pair  where  a  medi- 
um stage  length  (340  miles)  combined  with  high  traffic  density  resulted  in  low 
operating  costs  for  the  intrastate  carriers.  The  smallest  difference  was  for  Los 
Angeles-San  Diego  where  a  short  stage  length  (109  miles)  and  much  lower 
traffic  density  yielded  higher  operating  costs  and,  therefore,  higher  fares  per 
mile.'''  The  lower  fares  introduced  by  the  intrastate  carrier  greatly  benefited 
pas.sengers  who  preferred  somewhat  inferior  service  quality  and  low  fares  to 
high-quality,  high-price  service.  These  passengers,  in  turn,  benefited  the  intra- 
state carriers  by  utilizing  their  services.  In  1949,  total  traffic  in  these  three 
city-pairs  increased  34  percent  and  almost  one-third  of  all  pas.sengers  utilized 
the  low-fare  coach  service  of  the  intrastate  carriers.  At  the  same  time,  the  CAB- 
regulated  airlines'  first-class  traffic  fell  9.4  i)ercent  from  its  1948  level.'" 

As  shown  in  table  2,  this  same  fundamental  fare  relationship  still  existed  in 
1965  after  over  16  years  of  open  entry  within  California. 


'<  William  A.  .Tordan.  supra,  note  1,  at  114.  .      ..,      x,, 

i"' 194!»  total  on  linp  oricin  and  df'stination  nassencer  traffic  on  all  carriers  '"  tJiejnrPe 

major  California  citv-pairs  were:  LAX/P.TJR/LGR-SFO/OAK  =  459,400' ;  LAX/BUR/LGB- 

SAX  =  81,700  ;  and  SAX-SF0/OAK  =  29,200.  Id.  at  307,  311,  315.  ^^^  ^^^   . 

« Total   on-line  O&D   passpncer   traffic   for  these  three  city-pairs  grew  from  426.000   in 

1948  to  570,000  in  1949.  Of  the  1949  total,  the  intrastate  carriers  accounted  for  184,300 

passengers  and   the  CAB-regulated  airlines  386,000.   Id. 


468 

TABLE   2.-PSA'S    COACH    FARES    COMPARED    WITH    CAB-AUTHORIZED    COACH    FARES    FOR     THREE    MAJOR 
CALIFORNIA  CITY-PAIRS,  1965 

One-way  coach  fares ' 

CAB-authorized,  percent 


CAB-authorized  3  greater  than  PSA 


City-pairs 

Propeller 

Jet 

Propeller 

Jet 

Propeller 

Jet 

LAX/BUR-SFO/OAK 

$11.43 

$13.  50 
6.35 
19.85 

$21.  70 
9.45 
27.15 

$23. 70 
10.90 
29.25 

89.9 
48.8 
52.7 

75.6 

LAX/BUR-SAN __._ 

:::::::       6.35 

71.6 

SAN-SFO/OAK 

17.78 

47.4 

1  Round-trip  fares  equal  twice  the  one-way  fares  for  ail  carriers. 

2  Effective  Apr.  20,  1965  to  Aug.  2,  1969. 

3  Effective  Feb.  1,  1962  to  Feb.  1,  1968.  Applicable  to  interstate  passengers  making  stopovers  in  these  cities  on  journeys 
originating  and/or  terminating  outside  California.  Also,  the  jet  coach  fares  were  approved  by  the  PUC  in  April  1962  for 
intrastate  passengers  utilizing  interstate  jet  flights. 

Source:  William  A.  Jordan,  "Airline  Regulation  in  America,"  111,  279-87  (1970). 

The  lowest  CAB-authorized  coach  fares  for  1965  were  47  to  90  percent  greater 
than  PSA's  coach  fares.  This  somewhat  decreased  range  in  fare  differences, 
compared  with  1949,  resulted  from  two  developments.  First,  starting  on  May  14, 
1950,  the  CAB  allowed  the  interstate  airlines  to  provide  coach  service  and  fares 
in  California  city-pairs  so  this  1965  comparison  is  based  on  coach  fares  for  both 
categories  of  carriers."  Second,  since  1952  the  CAB  has  promoted  the  adoption 
of  an  ever  larger  fare  taper  whereby  short-haul  fares  per  mile  (such  as  for  Los 
Angeles-San  Diego)  have  been  increased  more  than  the  fares  per  mile  for 
longer-haul  city-pairs.^^  Generally  speaking,  given  these  developments,  it  can  be 
concluded  that  had  CAB  regulation  kept  the  California  intrastate  carriers  from 
inaugurating  service  the  coach  fares  in  these  three  major  California  city-pairs 
would  have  been  those  authorized  by  the  CAB  and,  therefore,  would  have  been 
from  47  to  90  percent  higher  than  they  actually  were. 

Since  the  PUC  has  had  the  power  to  close  entry  since  1965,  it  would  seem 
reasonable  to  predict  that  differences  between  CAB-authorized  fares  and  those  of 
PSA  should  now  be  less  than  before.  To  the  contrary,  as  shown  in  table  3,  even 
following  the  PUC's  most  recent  fare  authorization  (effective  January  29.  1975), 
the  percentage  differences  between  PSA's  fares  and  those  authorized  by  the  CAB 
(effective  November  15,  1974)  have  increased  to  a  range  of  from  70  to  108  per- 
cent compared  with  the  1965  range  of  47  to  90  percent. 

The  above  findings  are  surprising,  but  it  should  be  remembered  that  they 
reflect  the  effects  of  accumulated  fare  changes  since  1949.  Actually,  since  the 
PUC's  decision  to  prevent  new  carriers  from  entering  the  major  California  city- 
pairs   was    not   fully   implemented   nor   apparent    until    late    1969,    it    may    be 

TABLE    3.— PSA'S  COACH  FARES  COMPARED  WITH   CAB-AUTHORIZED  COACH  FARES,  FOR  THREE  MAJOR 
CALIFORNIA  CITY-PAIRS,  JAN.  29,  1975 

CAB- 
authorized 
One-way  jet  coach  fares  i  percent 

City-pairs  J'^i^^l 

than  PSA 


LAX/BUR  SFO/OAK 

$19.21 

$39.  23 
20.71 
45.71 

104.2 

._                 9.95 

108.1 

SAN-SFO/OAK 

_.     ..               26.85 

70.2 

•  Round-trip  fares  equal  twice  the  one-way  fares  for  all  carriers. 

2  Effective  Jan.  29,  1975.  „     . 

3  Effective  Nov.  15,  1974.  The  CAB  has  authorized  an  additional  fare  increase  and  restructuring  to  become  effective 
Apr.  29,  1975. 

Sources:  CAB  orders  74-11-62  (Nov.  14,  1974)  and  74-12-109  (Dec.  27,  1974).  PUC  decisions  83814  (Dec.  10,  1974), 
83918  (Dec.  30,  1974)  and  83939  (Dec.  30,  1974).  Norman  Richards,  Asst.  Chief,  CAB  domestic  passenger  fare  section, 
telephone  conversation  (Jan.  14,  1975). 


I''  Id.  at  78. 

i«  Id.   at   64-65.   Also,   CAB  Orders  74-3-82    (March  IS,   1974)    and  74-12-109    (Decem- 
ber 27,  1974). 


469 

more  meaningful  to  look  for  possible  effects  on  fares  from  this  action  by 
comparing  fare  increases  between  1969  and  early  1975  than  by  comparing  fare 
levels  in  1975.  It  happens  that  the  CAB-authorized  two-fare  increases  in  1969 — 
the  first  significant  increases  since  February  1,  1962 — with  the  second  resulting 
in  a  major  increase  and  restructuring  of  coach  fares  that  became  effective  on 
October  1,  1969.'°  Similarly,  the  PUC  also  authorized  PSA  to  increase  its  fares 
twice  in  1969  with  the  second  becoming  effective  on  December  3 ;  and  it  happens 
that  these  increases  were  the  first  implemented  by  PSA  since  December  12,  1960.-" 
Thus,  the  fares  in  effect  at  the  end  of  1969  provide  like  bases  for  a  time-series 
comparison  of  the  effects  of  CAB  and  PUC  regulation  under  closed  entry.  This 
comparison  is  presented  in  table  4,  and  it  indicates  how  PSA  and  the  PUC,  on 
the  one  hand,  and  the  interstate  airlines  and  the  CAB,  on  the  other  hand, 
responded  to  such  factors  as  inflation,  airport  security  expenses  and  increases 
in  petroleum  prices,  all  under  similar  regulatory  conditions. 

TABLE  4.-INCREASES  IN  COACH  FARES  FROM  LATE  1969  TO  EARLY  1975:  PSA  COMPARED  WITH  CAB-AUTHORIZED 
FARES  FOR  THREE  MAJOR  CALIFORNIA  CITY-PAIRS 


One-way  jet  coach  faresi 


CAB-authorized 


Percent  increase 


City-pairs 

Dec.  3, 
1969 

Jan.  29, 
1975 

Oct.  1, 
1969 

Nov.  15, 
1974 

PSA 

CAB- 
authorized 

LAX/BUR-SFO/OAK 

$15.00 

$19.21 
9.95 
26.85 

$30.  00 
15.00 
36.00 

$39.23 
20.71 
45.71 

28.1 
34.8 
28.2 

LAX/BUR-SAN 

7.38 

SAN-SFO/OAK 

20.95 

27.0 

1  Round-trip  fares  equal  twice  the  one-way  fares  for  all  carriers. 

Sources:  Table  3.  CAB  order  69-9-68  (Sept.  12, 1969).  PUC  decision  76447  (Nov.  18, 1969). 

The  similarities  between  the  percentage  increases  for  the  two  categories  of 
carriers  in  these  three  city-pairs  are  indeed  remarkable.  For  the  first  time  since 
1949,  percentage  increases  in  PSA's  fares  have  been  almost  the  same  as  those 
for  CAB-authorized  coach  fares.  This  is  certainly  not  conclusive  evidence  that 
PSA's  pricing  practices  under  the  new  PUC  regulator  environment  will  be  about 
the  same  as  that  of  the  CAB-regulated  airlines,  but  it  is  consistent  with  the 
hypothesis  that  similar  regulation  does  have  similar  effects  on  airline  fares. 
Actually,  it  is  much  too  soon  to  draw  firm  conclusions  on  this  matter.  It  takes 
many  years  for  the  effects  of  an  important  change  such  as  the  imposition  of 
entry  control  to  work  its  way  through  the  economy,  but  there  appears  to  be 
a  start  in  this  direction. 

Overall,  the  California  experience  provides  strong  evidence  that  one  major 
accomplishment  of  CAB  regulation  has  been  to  increase  airline  fares  by  large 
amounts.  Since  the  CAB  establishes  fares  on  a  nationwide  basis,  the  sizes  of 
these  increases  would  vary  with  conditions  in  individual  city-pairs.  For  short- 
haul  city-pairs,  present  coach  fares  are  probably  between  40  to  70  percent  higher 
than  they  would  be  without  CAB  regulation — with  the  larger  differences  oc- 
curring in  those  city-pairs  with  the  higher  traflSc  densities."'  Thus,  without  CAB- 
regulation,  current  Boston-New  York  and.  New  York-Washington  one-way  coach 
fares  would  probably  be  around  $15  and  $17  vs.  the  actual  fares  of  $25.93  and 
$27.78."  In  medium-haul  city-pairs  (between,  say,  250  and  1,000  miles),  it  appears 
that  CAB-authorized  coach  fares  range  from  75  to  over  100  percent  higher  than 
non-regulated  fares.  This  means,  for  example,  that  absent  regulation  the  Boston- 
Washington  coach  fare  would  be  around  $21  instead  of  the  current  $41.67."^ 


«Id.  Also,  CAB  orders  69-2-98  (February  19.  1969)  and  69-9-68  (September  12,  1969). 
The  first  of  these  orders  increased  coach  fares  by  $2  in  city-pairs  oOO  miles  or  less  apart, 
and  by  .$1  in  city-pairs  between  iiOl  and  1,800  miles  apart.  The  second  order  established 
a  fare  structure  based  on  a  .$9  terminal  charge  and  various  line-haul  charges  starting  at 
60  per  mile  for  the  first  500  miles. 

20  Id.  at  285.  Also,  PUC  decisions  75899  (July  S,  1969)  and  76447  (November  18. 
1969).  Together,  these  two  decisions  yielded  fare  increases  of  11.1,  16.2  and  5.5  percent 
in  the  three  major  city-pairs. 

^  In  addition  to  the  Los  -Vngeles-San  Diego  data,  the  fare  experience  in  eight  minor 
California  city-pairs  from  1951  to  1965  also  support  this  conclusion.  Id.  at  115-3.3. 

22  1  Official  Airline  Guide  14.3,  150,  716  (North  American  Edition,  .Tanuary  1,  1975). 
The  distances  between  these  two  city-pairs  are:  B0S-NYC  =  191  miles,  NYC-DCA  =  215 
miles.  CAB,  supra,  note  1,  at  4.33. 

23  Id.  Boston  and  Washington  are  406  miles  apart. 


470 

Finally,  extrapolating  the  California  evidence  in  conjunction  with  our  knowledge 
that  average  costs  of  airline  operations  decrease  with  distance,  leads  to  the 
conclusion  that  CAB-authorized  fares  in  the  transcontinental  city-pairs  are  also 
around  100  percent  higher  than  they  would  be  without  regulation.  That  is, 
rather  than  paying  ,$187.04  (plus  tax)  to  Hy  from  Boston  to  Los  Angeles,  one 
would  pay  only  $D0  to  $100  for  unregulated  service."^ 

Differences  of  these  magnitudes  are  startling  to  say  the  least,  and  they  lead 
to  the  question  of  whether  or  not  the  California  experience  may  be  due  to  unique 
factors  other  than  regulation.  For  example,  it  is  correctly  pointed  out  that  Cali- 
fornia weather  is  milder  than  other  parts  of  the  country  and  that  the  three  major 
city-pairs  have  extremely  heavy  traffic  volumes.  These  arguments  overlook  the 
fact  that  the  weather  is  also  good  in  both  Los  Angeles  and,  say,  I'hoenix  (358 
miles  apart)  yet  the  high,  allegedly  cost-based,  CAB-authorized  coach  fares  have 
applied  in  that  city  pair  rather  than  the  lower  California-type  fares.  Indeed,  the 
Los  Angeles-Phoenix  coach  fares  have  been  identical  to  those  in  the  Chicagio- 
Minneapolis/St.  Paul  city -pair  (344  miles  apart)  despite  the  differences  in 
weather  conditions  in  these  two  city-pairs.^  Similarly,  if  weather  is  so  important, 
why  isn't  a  lower  fare  formula  applied  to  Los  Angeles-Miami  service  than  to  Los 
Angeles-Boston  service  V 

Regarding  traffic  density,  it  should  be  noted  that  in  1948,  the  year  before  the 
intrastate  carriers  inaugurated  low-fare  service,  Boston-Xew  York/Xewark  was 
the  largest  city  pair  in  the  LLS.,  with  Los  Angeles/Burbank-San  Francisco/Oak- 
land being  a  poor  second  accounting  for  about  35  i)ercent  fewer  true  O&D  pas- 
sengers."'" Yet,  as  indicated  in  table  1.  efficient  intrastate  carriers  were  able  to 
survive  in  the  then  lower-density  California  city-pairs  at  much  lower  fares  per 
mile  than  the  CAB  authorized  for  the  major  East  Coast  city-pairs  and,  remem- 
ber, this  was  well  before  the  days  of  airport  congestion.  True,  due  in  part  to  the 
availability  of  low  fares,  by  1972  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  "area"  pair 
accounted  for  5.6  million  on-line  O&D  passengers  compai-ed  with  2.1  million  true 
()&D  passengers  in  the  Boston-Xew  York  "area"  pair.-'  It  should  be  recognized, 
however,  that  the  5.6  million  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  passengers  were  ac- 
commodated through  eight  airports  and  13  separate  airport  pairs,  compared  with 
only  four  airports  and  three  airport  pairs  for  Boston-Xew  York,  and  that  low 
intrastate  fares  were  available  in  all  of  the  Los  Angeles-San  Franci.seo  airport 
pairs  even  though  four  of  them  each  accounted  for  less  than  200,000  O&D  pas- 
sengers in  1972.^  Xo.  possible  cost  differences  due  to  weather  and  traffic  densities 
come  nowhere  near  accounting  for  the  differences  of  100  percent  or  more  that 
have  exi.sted  between  PSA's  fares  and  those  authorized  by  the  CAB. 

Fortunately,  supplementary  evidence  regarding  the  effects  of  regulation  on 
airline  fares  is  available  from  the  Texas  intrastate  experience,  Canadian  regu- 
lation, and  from  U.S.  military  airlift  procurement.  Brief  summaries  of  some  of 
this  evidence  are  presented  in  the  following  sections. 

Evidence  from  Texas 

On  February  20,  1968,  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission  (TAC)  issued  a 
certificate  of  public  convenience  and  necessity  to  Southwest  Airlines  authorizing 
it  to  provide  scheduled  intrastate  service  l)etween  Dallas/Ft.  Worth,  Houston 
and  San  Antonio.^  Immediately  thereafter,  Braniff  Airways  and  Texas  Interna- 
tional Airlines  began  over  three  years  of  litigation  in  the  Texas  and  U.S.  Federal 
courts,  the  CAB  and  the  TAC  to  prevent  Southwest  from  inaugurating  service. 


"In  April  1967.  World  Airways  (a  supplemental  carrier)  applied  to  the  C\B  for 
authority  to  operate  scheduled  nonstop  service  between  California  and  the  East  Coast  at 
a  "thrift  service"  fare  of  .$79.50  compared  with  the  then  existing  coach  fare  of  .?145.10.  Sfi 
Aviation  Week  and  Space  Technology  27  (May  1,  1967).  Similarly,  applying  the  CAB's 
recently  approved  low-season  seat-mile  rate  for  charter  operations  with  aircraft  having 
more  than  229  seats  (2.40  per  seat-mile)  and  assuming  a  6.")-percent  load  factor,  yields 
a  $96.00  one-way  fare  between  Boston  and  Los  Angeles  (2,600  miles  apart).  CAB  regula- 
tion PS-.57  (October  18.  1974)  at  17. 

-•■''  See,  for  example,  supra,  note  22,  at  201.  r)42.  Note  that  the  difference  between  origin 
and  destination  traffic  for  these  two  citv-pairs  is  not  great.  In  1972,  ORD-MSP  =  -:  "6,000 
passeneers  while  LAX-PHX  =  .S4.S.000.  CAB,  sunra,  note  1,  at  43.3. 

=«BOS-lSrYC/EWR  =  .-)50,.500  passengers,  LAX/BUR/LGB-SFO/OAK  =  297,600.  CAB,  Air- 
line Traffic  Survey  (March  and  September  194S). 

2"  CAB,  supra,  note  1,  at  4.3.S  ;  and  PTTC,  Intrastate  Origin-Destination  Passengers  of 
Scheduled  Air  Carriers.  Quarter  and  Twelve  Months  Ended  December  .31,  1971  and  1972, 
2  (Renort  1511.33,  1974). 

^  PT'C.  sunra,  note  27,  at  4-6.  Also,  see  appendix  B. 

-"Thomson  &  INIcKinnon  Auchincloss,  Inc.,  Prospectus,  Southwest  Airlines  Co.,  8  (.Tune  8, 
1971).  Southwest  was  incorporated  on  :\Iarch  9,  1967  (Southwest  Airlines  annual  report, 
note  1,  1971). 


471 

As  a  result  of  this.  Southwest  was  luiable  to  inaugurate  service  until  June  18, 
1971,  and  it  was  forced  to  incur  legal  expenses  ()f  well  over  $500,000  before  it 
even  began  operations.'"  While  it  is  not  known  whether  TAC  regulation  will 
effectively  close  entry  within  Texas,  the  problems  Southwest  had  makes  it  ap- 
pear that  future  entry  will  be  restricted.  Thus,  the  regulatory  structure  within 
Texas  is  probably  more  like  the  current  I'UC  and  CAB  situations  than  the  open- 
entry  environment  of  California  prior  to  1965. 

Initially,  Southwest  offered  a  .$20  one-way  price  (fare  plus  8  percent  trans- 
portation tax)  between  IMllas-Houston  (222  miles)  and  Dallas-San  Antonio 
(253  miles)  compared  with  the  CAB-authorized  .jet  cdach  prices  of  .$27  and  $28, 
respectively.''^  Branift"  and  Texas  International  immediately  matched  these  prices 
for  their  intrastate  passengers,  but  not  for  iiassengers  originating  or  terminating 
outside  of  Texas  and  thus  subject  to  CAB  regulation.  The  full  price  histories 
for  these  two  city-pairs  through  December  1974  are  given  in  appendix  A.  This 
appendix  .shows  that,  .starting  on  .Tuly  9.  1972,  Southwest  raised  its  day-coach 
price  to  $26  (almo.st  back  to  the  earlier  CAB-authorized  level).  Braniff  and 
Texas  International  quickly  matched  this  higher  price  and,  subsequently,  re- 
adopted  CAB-authorized  fares  which  resulted  in  the  three  $1  to  $2  price  in- 
creases shown  in  the  appendix.  The  most  interesting  developments  during  this 
period  were  Southwest's  introduction  of  a  $13  one-way,  day-coach  price  between 
Dallas  and  San  Antonio  on  .lanuary  22,  1973,  followed  by  Braniff's  introduction 
of  a  retaliatory  $13  price  between  Dallas  and  Hou.ston's  Hobby  Airport  for  a  60- 
day  period  starting  February  1,  1973. 

It  is  clear  that  the  entry  of  an  intrastate  carrier  did  serve  to  lower  prices  paid 
by  passengers  in  these  city-pairs.  This  was  especially  true  between  Dallas  and 
San  Antonio  where  Southwest  relied  on  its  lower  price  to  make  up  for  its  in- 
frequent service  (it  scheduled  48  to  66  weekly  one-way  trips  compared  with 
Braniff's  210  to  260  weekly  trips)."-  In  this  city-pair,  Braniff's  regular  day-coach 
prices  were  93  to  115  percent  higher  than  Southwest's — cpiite  similar  to  the  Cali- 
fornia experience.  In  the  Dallas-Houston  city-pair,  in  contrast.  Southwest  pro- 
vided much  moie  fre<pient  service  and  operated  to  and  from  convenient  Love 
Field  in  Dallas  and  Hobby  Airport  in  Houston.  As  a  result,  it  was  able  to  attract 
passengers  at  relatively  high  weekday  prices  that  were  almost  equal  to  the  CAB- 
authorized  prices.  It  did,  however,  initiate  low  weekend  and  night-coach  prices 
of  $13  and  $15  which  resulted  in  CAB-authorize<l  coach  fares  being  87  to  108 
percent  higher  during  evenings  and  weekends. 

On  October  1,  1974,  Southwest  modified  its  Dallas-Houston  price  structure  by 
decreasing  the  day-coach  price  from  $28  to  ,$25,  and  it  then  extended  this  price 
stnicture  to  its  other  two  city  pairs.  Table  5  summarizes  these  new  prices  and 
compares  them  with  those  of  the  CAB-regulated  airlines  following  the  CAB- 
authorized  fare  increase  of  November  15,  1974. 

TABLE    5.-S0UTHWEST'S    COACH    FARES    COMPARED    WITH    CAB-AUTHORIZED    COACH    FARES    FOR   THREE 
MAJOR  TEXAS  CITY-PAIRS,  NOV.  15,  1974 


One-way  coach  prices' 


CAB-authorized  percent 
greater  than  southwest 


Night/  CAB- 

City-pairs  Day         weekend  2       authorized  3  Day 


DAL-HOU 

$25 

$15 
15 
15 

$31.  37 
32.37 
29.37 

25.5 
29.5 
17.5 

109.1 

DAL-SAT 

25 

115  8 

HOU-SAT 

25 

95.8 

1  Fare  plus  8  percent  Federal  transportation  tax. 

2  Effective  after  7  p.m.  on  weekdays  and  all  day  on  Saturdays  and  Sundays. 

2  Includes  the  37  cents  airport  security  surcharge.  Southwest  does  not  assess  a  security  surcharge. 

Sources:  1  "Official  Airline  G;iide"  7,  280,  28P,  469  (North  American  Edition,  Dec.  1,  1974).  Richard  Robertson,  Sales 
Representative,  Southwest  Airlines,  telephone  conversation  (Jan.  23,  1975) 


™  William  A.  Jordan.  Some  Predatory  Practices  Under  Government  Regulation?,  22-24 
(processed.   .January   107.">).    Southwest  Airlines,  supra,   note  29. 

"^  See  appendix  A.  Prices  (fare.s  plus  S-percent  transportation  tax)  are  used  in  this 
analysis  hecause  the  practice  of  rounding  prices  to  the  nearest  whole  dollar  simpli^^es  the 
data.  Pares  were  used  in  the  California  analysis  because  the  transportation  tax  changed 
from  !.■)  to  10  to  5  percent  at  various  times  after  1949  before  being  set  at  the  current 
S-percent  rate  on  Julv  1,  1970. 

==-'  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  28,  at  31-32. 


472 

Day-coach  price  differeuces  of  17.5  to  29.5  percent  are  not  as  spectacular  as 
the  differences  of  over  100  percent  tliat  were  available  between  Dallas  and  San 
Antonio  during  most  of  1973  and  1974,  but  it  should  be  noted  that  the  most 
iiuiiorraut  city-pairs  had  the  largest  differences  and  savings  of  $6.37  and  $7.37 
per  4.1-  (ir  .".(l-minute  trip  are  significant  to  many  individuals.  Travelers  on  evenings 
and  weekends  are,  of  course,  benefited  by  an  additional  $10,  and  the  price 
differences  are  again  around  100  percent. 

Certainly,  by  simply  allowing  this  single  intrastate  carrier  to  enter  and  pro- 
vide service,  the  TAC  has  benefited  many  Texas  travelers,  as  well  as  Southwest,'^ 
at  the  expense  of  the  CAB-regulated  airlines.  Again,  tbe  key  factor  was  entry. 
The  most  effective  way  for  a  new  firm  to  carve  out  a  viable  share  of  a  market 
is  to  offer  comparable  service  at  lower  prices.  Only  if  more  efficient  or  innovative 
firms  are  allowed  to  enter  does  such  economically  useful  rivalry  occur.  It  remains 
to  be  seen  whether  or  not  the  TAC  will  allow  still  other  new  airlines  to  test  their 
mettle  in  this  manner.  If  it  does,  one  can  predict  a  continuation  or  an  increase 
in  the  price  differences  shown  in  table  5.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  TAC  closes 
entry  to  potential  Texas  intrastate  carriers,  one  can  predict  that  at  most  the 
present  differences  will  persist,  and  it  seems  more  likely  that  the  percentage 
differences  will  decrease.  In  any  case,  by  allowing  Sonthwest  to  inaugurate 
service,  the  TAC  has  provided  additional  evidence  that  CAB  regulation  does 
serve  to  increase  airline  fares. 
Evidence  from  Canada 

While  there  have  been  dift'erenees  in  administrative  procedures  and  in  relative 
independence  from  various  branches  of  government,  the  regulatory  powers  of  the 
Air  Transport  Committee  (ATC)  of  the  Canadian  Transport  Commission  (and  its 
predecessor,  the  Air  Transport  Board)  have  been  quite  similar  to  those  of  the 
CAB.^*  Since  1938,  all  Canadian  airlines  (including  intra  provincial  and  the 
smallest  of  fixed-base  or  bush  operators)  have  been  subject  to  regulatory  con- 
trol over  entry  and  exit,  prices  and  service  quality.'"'  Furthermore,  the  largest 
Canadian  airfine,  Air  Canada,  is  a  Cro\^'n  (government-owned)  corporation 
\\hieh  has  received  special  consideration  and  protection  from  both  the  Canadian 
I'arliament  and  the  regulatory  Cdiiimissions.'"' 

Montreal-Toronto  is  the  city-pair  witliin  Canada  most  like  the  major  East 
Coast  and  West  Coast  city-pairs  in  the  U.S.  Montreal  and  Toronto  are  322  mile" 
apart  and  in  1972  a  total  of  758,520  origin  and  destination  passengers  flew  between 
them."'  This  traflic  volume  resulted  in  it  being  ranked  about  eleventh  in  total 
size  on  the  North  American  continent  in  1972  and,  overall,  it  is  clear  that 
Montreal-Toronto  is  a  high-volume,  medium-haul  city-pair.'*'  Among  U.S.  airport 
pairs  of  about  the  same  traflic  density  and  distance  are  Los  Angeles-Oakland 
(712,720  O&D  passengers  in  1972  and  a  distance  of  339  miles),  Los  Angeles-San 
Jose  (666,312  passengers  and  309  miles),  and  Boston- Washington  (570,000 
passengers  and  399  miles).®  A  common  fare  has  long  been  in  effect  between  Los 
Angeles/Burbank  and  San  Francisco/Oakland/San  Jose,  and  it  happens  that  the 
simple  average  of  the  resulting  six  airport-to-airport  mileages  is  322  miles — the 
same  as  the  Montreal-Toronto  mileage."'  Tliis  mih'u.m'  similarity  facilitates  direct 
comparisons  between  fares  available  in  these  two  (■ity-i»airs. 

If  relatively  complete  regulation  (including  entry  control)  has  similar  effects 
on  increasing  fares,  one  would  expect  the  regulated  coach  fares  between  Montreal 
and  Toronto  in  1965  to  be  about  the  same  as  the  CAB-authorized  coach  fares 
between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  and,  to  be  much  higher  than  PSA's  fares 
which  had  developed  in  a  relatively  unregulated  environment.  Furthermore,  one 


•"  DnrinfT  the  twelve  iiiiiiitlis  ended  September  .>().  1974.  Southwest  earned  a  net  income 
of  .i;2.1  million  on  total  revenues  of  .$l.S.l  million.  Southwest  Airlines,  Annual  Keport 
(107.S)  :  and   Third  (Quarter  Uejiort   (O-months  ended  September  .-Ml.   i;»74). 

■-'William  A.  .Jordan,  Comparisons  of  American  and  Canadian  Airline  Keffulation  2-10 
(a  paper  presented  at  tbe  Societ.v  of  Government  Economists  sessions.  Allied  Social 
Sciences  Association  National  Convention,  December  I'S,  1!)72). 

-Id.  at:!-4. 

■"■■Id.  at  4.  Trans  Canada   Airlines  Act.  Stat,  Can.  c  4:!   (19;!7). 

■■^  Statistics  C.inida.  .\viation  Statistics  C.'ii  tr.'-Servicc  Imlletin  1-lL'  (April  197;^).  Also, 
1   Official   Airline   (Jni.le  s    (.Xorth   .\nierican   lOdition.   October  If),   1974). 

•''' Comi);ire  the  ,."is.,-,iii)  .Montr.MJ-Toronto  (i&I)  ii.isseuKcrs  with  those  listed  in  appendix 
B.   Note,   interairport  niileapres  differ  sliirlitlv  from  intercitv  mileages. 

^  rue,  supra,  note  27,  at  4.  Also.  CAB,  .supra,  note  1,  at  4:>;!. 

^o  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  305. 


473 


would  expect  that  increases  in  regulated  Montreal-Toronto  coach  fares  from 
1965  to  early  1975  would  be  similar  to  the  increases  in  CAB-authorized  fares  in 
the  California  city-pair.  In  contrast,  PSA's  fare  increase  for  this  period  should  be 
somewhat  less  since  it  was  not  clear  until  1969  that  entry  into  major  California 
city-pairs  had  been  closed  by  PUC  regulation.  Table  6  presents  the  fare  data  that 
test  these  hypotheses. 

TABLE  6.-C01V1PARIS0N  OF  PSA,  CAB-AUTHORIZED  AND  CANADIAN  COACH  FARES  i 

LOS  ANGELES-SAN  FRANCISCO  VS.  MONTREAL-TORONTO 

JUNE  1965  AND  JAN.  29,  1975 


Coach  fares  i 

Percent  increase  June 
Jan.  1975 

1965- 

June  1965 

Jan.  29, 1975 
(Jet) 

Propeller- 
Jet 

City-pair  and  fare  source 

Propeller 

Jet 

Jet-Jet 

LAX/BUR-SFO/OAK/SJC: 

PSA .__ 

CAB-authorized 

$11.43 
21.70 

23.00 
21.30 

$13.50 
23.70 

23.00 
21.30 

$19.21 
39.23 

37.00 
37.37 

68.1 
80.8 

60.9 
75.4 

42.3 
65.5 

Montreal-Toronto  ATC/ATB-authorized : 
(Can$).... 

(US$)2 

60.9 
75.4 

1  Fares  are  used  rather  than  prices  (fares  plus  taxes)  because  of  the  different  transportation  taxes  in  the  2  countries. 
-'  In  1965,  the  official  exchange  rate  was  $0,925  U.S.=$1  Canadian.  In  January  1975,  it  was  about  $1.01  U.S.=$1 
Canadian. 

Sources:  Tables  2  and  3,  Official  Airline  Guide(quick  reference  North  American  edition,  June  1, 1965,  and  North  American 
edition,  Jan.  15,  1975). 

Comparisons  of  these  data  are  complicated  somewhat  by  the  fact  that  Canada 
has  never  had  a  higher  fare  for  jet  service  than  for  service  provided  on  propeller 
aircraft,  and  by  fluctuations  in  the  exchange  rates  between  the  two  currencies. 
Regardless  of  these  factors,  it  is  clear  that  regulated  Canadian  fares  have  been 
very  similar  to  the  CAB-authorized  fares  and  have  been  much  higher  than  PSA's 
fares  both  in  1965  and  1975.  In  1965,  about  three  quarters  of  all  nonstop  flights 
between  Montreal  and  Toronto  were  provided  by  propeller  aircraft  (Viscounts 
and  Vanguards)"  and  the  U.S.  dollar  fare  (paid  by  residents  of  the  U.S.)  was 
almost  identical  to  the  CAB-authorized  propeller  fare  in  Los  Angeles-San 
Francisco.  In  January  1975.  when  only  jet  service  was  available  in  both  city- 
pairs,  a  U.S.  resident  paid  just  $1.86  (4.7  percent)  less  to  fly  between  Montreal 
and  Toronto  than  he  paid  for  interstate  coach  service  over  the  same  distance  in 
the  U.S. 

In  terms  of  fare  increases,  PSA's  very  low  propeller  fare  resulted  in  an  increase 
from  its  propeller  fare  in  1965  to  jet  fares  effective  January  29,  1975  that  is 
similar  to  the  Canadian  experience  and  somewhat  lower  than  the  CAB-authorized 
fare  increase.  However,  when  comparing  fares  for  jet  service  in  both  1965  and 
1975,  PSA's  fare  increase  is  much  smaller  than  both  the  CAB-authorized  fare 
increase  and  the  Canadian  experience  (whether  based  on  Canadian  or  U  S 
dollars).  Indeed,  in  this  case  CAB  and  ATC/ATB  regulation  had  very  similar 
effects.  Once  more  the  evidence  indicates  that  CAB-type  regulation  results  in 
higher  fares. 

Evidence  from  military  airlift 

Prior  to  1960,  the  Military  Air  Transport  Service  (now  the  Military  Airlift 
Command)  contracted  for  planeload  movements  of  passengers  and  cargo  on  a 
competitive  bid  basis  open  to  any  carrier  meeting  the  safetv  and  operational 
standards  established  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Agencv  (now  the  Federal  Aviation 
Administration).  These  carriers  included  the  CAB-certificated  airlines  (trunk, 
international,  local  service,  territorial,  all-cargo  and  supplemental)  plus  the  so- 
called  'part  i.y  carriers  composed  of  operators  of  large  aircraft  who  contracted 
their  services  to  a  single  purchaser  and  thus  did  not  engage  in  common  carriage. 
As  defined  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  195,S,  these  part  45  carriers  were 
operating  in  air  commerce  rather  than  air  transportation.  As  a  result,  they  did 

"21   Official  Airline  Guide  C-9  to  C-IS    (Nortli  American  edition,  June  1965). 


474 

not  have  to  have  CAB-issued  certificates  of  public  convenience  and  necessity  and 
the  CAB  had  no  control  over  their  activities  so  long  as  they  limited  their  activities 
to  air  commerce,  including  military  airlift  charters/" 

Because  part  45  carriers  could  participate  on  Military  Air  Transport  Service 
(MATS)  contract  operations  without  having  to  file  tariffs  or  otherwise  comply 
with  CAB  regulations,  the  CAB  found  it  infeasible  to  control  entry  by  certificated 
airlines  into  the  military  procurement  market  and  to  regulate  rates.  Thus,  it  gave 
blanket  exemptions  to  all  certificated  airlines  to  participate  in  this  activity  at 
rates  through  the  competitive  bidding  process/'  This  resulted  in  a  monopsonistic 
market  structure  with  one  large  buyer  (MATS)  and  many  independent  sellers. 
Not  surprisingly,  military  charter  rates  fell  to  low  levels. 

The  certificated  airlines  and  the  CAB  found  this  situation  to  be  undesirable 
and  in  1958,  when  the  annual  growth  rate  of  scheduled  passenger  traffic  abruptly 
fell  from  15  to  zero  percent,"  they  prevailed  upon  I'resident  Eisenhower  to  direct 
Department  of  Defense  to  undertake  a  study  of  the  military  role  performed  by 
MATS.  This  study  resulted  in  a  report  completed  in  early  1900  entitled,  "The  Role 
of  Military  Air  Transport  Service  in  Peace  and  War."  ^^  This  report  recommended 
nine  courses  of  action,  including  action  number  five  which  proposed  the  procure- 
ment of  commercial  airlift  be  changed  from  competitive  bidding  by  all  FAA  quali- 
fied carriers  to  the  use  of  only  CAB-certificated  airlines  thereby  excluding  part  45 
carriers)  under  tariff  rates  or  through  negotiated  contracts.*®  The  courses  of 
action  were  approved  by  the  President  on  February  9,  I960,*'  and  the  DOD,  the 
Air  Force  and  MATS  moved  to  implement  action  number  five  during  the  following 
months.  Interim  procurement  procedures  consistent  with  action  number  five  were 
adopted  for  airlift  contracts  for  the  three-month  period  starting  October  1, 
I960.*' 

The  DOD's  exclusion  of  part  45  carriers  gave  the  CAB  substantial  power  over 
military  airlift  procurement  and  the  Board  was  quick  to  implement  its  new 
power.  On  June  24,  1960,  the  CAB  Chairman  advised  the  DOD  that  blanket  exemp- 
tions would  no  longer  be  issued  to  certificated  airlines  allowing  them  to  partici- 
pate in  military  contracts.  Instead,  only  individual  exemptions  would  be  given 
to  each  airline  whose  contract  complied  with  CAB  policies.*"  Thus,  between 
August  1959  (when  the  last  competitive-bid  contracts  were  signed  for  service 
from  October  1,  1959  to  September  30,  1960)  and  mid-1960,  entry  into  military 
airlift  operations  was  abruptly  closed  to  all  except  those  CAB-regulated  airlines 
complying  with  CAB  policies.  The  effects  on  contract  rates  of  this  fundamental 
change  soon  became  ai)parent. 

On  August  5,  1960.  the  CAB  Chairman  advised  the  DOD  that  exemptions  would 
not  be  granted  to  CAB-regulated  carriers  if  round-trip  contract  rates  were  less 
than  2.9  cents  per  passenger-mile  on  a  year  round  basis  "[f]or  plane  load  traffic 
in  transatlantic  and  transpacific  operations  equivalent  to  economy  type  serv- 
ice. .  .  ."  °°  Since  only  passenger  contracts  were  planned  at  that  time,  this  single 
rate  was  suflficient.  There  followed  considerable  discussion  and  correspondence 
between  the  DOD  and  CAB  concerning  rates,  and  it  was  not  until  February  10, 
1961,  that  final  rates  were  established  for  the  remaining  categories  of  inter- 
national traffic — to  become  effective  no  later  than  May  1,  1961.  These  initial 
CAB-authorized  rates  are  summarized  in  table  7  and  compared  with  tlie  success- 
ful competitive-bid  rates  of  August  4,  1959 — the  last  nonregulated  rates  utilized 
by  MATS. 


«Spc.  101(3).  (4).  (10).  (20).  (21),  (.".2),  and  (.33).  72  Stat  737.  Also,  72  Stat  7o4, 
72  Stnt  758.  and  72  Stat  760.  ^  _  ^ 

"Whitney  Gillilland.  CAB  Chairman,  letter  to  Thomas  S.  Gates,  Jr.,  Secretary  of  Defense 
(June  24,  1960). 

*'^  CAB,  supra,  note  1,  at  24.  ^    ^^ 

*5DOD.  The  Role  of  Military  Air  Transport  Service  in  Peace  and  War,  February  1960. 

4«  Id.  at  .5-6. 

«■  Robert  IT.  Charles,  Assistant  Secretary  of  the  -\ir  Force,  Address  before  the  Aero 
Clnb  of  Washinston,  March  26,  196S. 

^MIATS,  Histoiv  of  the  Implementation  of  Course  of  Action  No.  5:  The  Role  of  MATS 
in  Peace  and  War,  Jan.  1,  1960-June  30,  1961  173-76,  March  1962. 

*»  \Vhitnev  Gi'lilland.  snnra.  note  43. 

BO  Whitney  Gillilland,  CAB  Chairman,  letter  to  Thomas  S.  Gates,  Jr.,  Secretary  of  Defense 
(August  5,  1960). 


475 

TABLE  7.-C0MPARIS0N    OF  COMPETITIVE-BID    RATES   WITH   CAB-AUTHORIZED    RATES, 
CATEGORY   B,    INTERNATIONAL  OPERATIONS 
AUG.  4,  1959  VS.  FEB.  10,  1961 

Rate.<;  CAB- 

— — ■ authorized 

percent 
greater  than 
competitive- 
Service  and  area  Competitive-bid  Aug.  4,  1959     CAB-authorized  Feb.  10,  1961  bid 

Round-trip  passenger; 

Atlantic 2.08  cents  per  pax-mile  ' 2.9  cents  per  pax-mile...  39  4 

Pacific 1.89' 2.9  2 53  4 

One-way  passenger: 

Atlantic 4.2  cents  per  pax-mile  s 

Pacific 4.2  2,3 

Round-trip  cargo: 

Atlantic 13.75  cents  per  ton-mile' 

Pacific 13.752,3 

One-way  cargo: 

Atlantic 21.89  cents  per  ton-mile  ■ 22.5  cents  per  ton-mile  3 2.8 

Pacific 21.351 22.52,3 5.4 

Round-trip  convertible:  < 
Atlantic: 

Passenger 1.70  cents  per  pax-mile  ' 2.9  cents  per  pax-mile 70.6 

Cargo 15.11  cents  per  ton-mile' 16.5  cents  per  ton-mile  s 9.2 

Pacific: 

Passenger 2.24 .    2.9^  29.5 

Cargo 16.54 16.52,3 -.5 

'  Calculated  on  a  weighted  average  of  mileages  and  traffic  for  multiple  origins  and  destinations  as  specified  in  the  invita- 
tion for  bid. 

■  Rates  applied  to  Central  Pacific  mileages  even  though  flights  might  actually  be  operated  via  North  Pacific  routings 
which  were  approximately  !,000  miles  shorter. 

3  By  letter  oated  Dec.  5,  1960,  the  CAB  set  the  following  rates  to  be  a  basis,  effective  Mar.  1,  1961,  for  issuing  military 
charter  exemptions: 

Cents 
per 
pax- 
mile 

One-way  passenger _ 5.2 

Round-trip  cargo 14.  5 

One-way  cargo .    27.5 

Convertible  cargo 19.0 

On  Feb.  10,  1961,  these  rates  were  superseded  by  those  specified  in  the  table  to  be  effective  no  later  than  May  1,  1961. 
^  Passengers  carried  one  way  and  cargo  the  other  on  a  round-trip  flight. 

Sources:  Alan  S.  Boyd,  CAB  Chairman,  letter  to  P.  B.  Taylor,  Assistant  Secretary  of  the  Air  Force  (Feb.  10, 1961).  Whitney 
Gillilland,  CAB  Chairman,  letters  to  Thomas  S.  Gates,  Secretary  of  Defense  (Aug.  5,  12,  1960,  and  Dec.  5,  1S60).  MAC, 
CAB-approved  mileage  as  of  Oct.  20,  1967  (n.d.)  MAiS,  Invitation  for  Bids  11-626-59-11  and  11-626-59-12  (July  8,  1959), 
and  Abstract  of  bids  tor  these  IFBs  (Aug.  1,  1959). 

Again,  the  now  familiar  pattern  emerges.  The  CAB-regulated  rates  for  round- 
trip  passenger  service  were  39  and  53  percent  higher  than  the  earlier  nonregulated 
rates  for  such  service,  while  the  regulated  rates  for  passenger  legs  of  convertible 
flights  were  30  and  71  percent  higher  than  the  nonregulated  rates.  At  the  same 
time,  however,  the  differences  in  cargo  rates  were  small  or  nonexistent.  One 
possible  reason  for  this  could  have  been  that  about  four  times  the  ton-miles  of 
cargo  were  moved  in  fiscal  year  1962  than  in  fiscal  year  1960.'^^  Thus,  a  relatively 
low  trafllic  volume  in  fiscal  year  1960,  divided  between  both  the  Atlantic  and 
Pacific,  could  have  resulted  in  high  average  costs  and  thus  high  comi>etitive-bid 
rates.  Another  rea.son,  of  course,  could  have  been  that  MATS  and  DOD  were  able 
to  convince  the  CAB  to  adopt  relatively  low  cargo  rates.  The  fact  that  the  CAB 
originally  set  the  one-way  cargo  rate  at  27.5  cents  per  ton-mile  (about  28  percent 
higher  than  the  competitive-bid  rates)   lends  credence  to  that  possibility.^-  But, 


=1  In  fiscal  year  1960,  cargo  accounted  for  about  $12. .3  million  (21. .3  percent)  of  category 
B  passenger  and  cargo  revenues  totaling  .$.58.7  million.  In  fiscal  year  1962,  cargo  com- 
prised .$55.4  million  (48.5  percent)  of  the  $114.2  million  total.  Since  cargo  rates  were 
about  the  same  in  these  two  periods,  changes  in  cargo  revenues  approximate  changes  in 
ton-miles  of  traffic.  (MATS,  Historical  Background  of  MATS'  Commercial  Airlift  Opera- 
tions, fiscal  years  1960-64  12,  14  (n.d.).) 

=2  Whitney  Gillilland,  CAB  Chairman,  letter  to  Thomas  S.  Gates,  Secretary  of  Defense 
(Dec.  5,  1960). 


476 

then,  both  these  and  other  reasons  may  be  applicable. 

It  is  only  proper  to  point  out  that  the  CAB  lowered  its  approved  rates  starting 
in  1962  and  continuing  to  1967-68,  before  inflationary  pressures  reversed  the 
trend.  Round-trip  passenger  rates,  for  example,  fell  to  1.75  cents  per  passenger- 
mile  for  standard  jets  and  1.66  cents  per  passenger-mile  for  stretched  jets.°''  AVith 
some  adjustments  for  the  relatively  low  inflation  of  that  S-year  period,  it  can  be 
seen  that  these  rates  are  significantly  lower  than  the  competitive-bid  rates  of 
1959.  It  should  also  be  recognized,  however,  that  these  rates  were  achieved  with 
unusually  high  trafiic  flows  over  extremely  long-hauls  to  Vietnam  and  other 
points  in  the  Pacific,  and  that  jet  aircraft  have  experienced  substantially  lower 
operating  costs  than  the  piston  aircraft  that  provided  most  contract  services  prior 
to  the  early  1960's.  With  regards  to  this  latter  point,  it  should  also  be  noted  that 
CAB-approved  rates  for  round-trip  passenger  service  on  piston  aircraft  have  never 
fallen  below  2.55  cents  per  passenger-mile.^* 

Summary 

It  is  remarkable  how  consistent  the  evidence  from  these  four  cases  has  been. 
The  large  amount  of  cross-sectional  evidence  from  the  California  experience  is 
supported  by  similar  evidence  from  Texas  and  Canada,  as  well  as  by  time-series 
evidence  from  the  most  recent  years  in  California,  from  Canada,  and  from  mili- 
tary airlift  procurement.  Where  entry  has  been  possible  and  airlines  have  been 
able  to  introduce  new  or  lower  fares  without  regulatory  constraint,  airline  fares 
have  been  low.  Where  regulation  has  served  to  close  entry  and  fares  have  been 
controlled,  fares  have  been  much  higher.  Indeed,  in  most  cases  regulated  fares 
have  been  50  percent  or  more  above  nonregulated  fares,  and  differences  of  over 
100  percent  have  been  common. 

These  consistently  large  fare  differences  are  not  explained  by  factors  such  as 
whether,  airport  congestion,  trafiic  density,  and  so  forth.  Of  course,  cold  and  snow 
for  5  months  or  so  each  year  increase  the  resources  required  for  ground  handling ; 
and  fog,  snow  and  rain  delay  flights  at  various  times,  as  does  aii-port  congestion. 
The.se  factors  all  increase  costs  somewhat,  but  not  by  50  to  100  percent  over  costs 
in  nonregulated  city -pairs  which  also  experience  weather  and  congestion  prob- 
lems. However,  should  weather  and  airport  congestion  influence  costs  appreciably 
in  particular  interstate  city-pairs,  and  if  CAB-authorized  fares  are  supposed  to 
lie  cost  based,  why  aren't  CAB-authorized  fares  lower  for  city-pairs  where 
weather  is  generally  good  and  airports  are  free  of  congestion?  The  fact  is  that 
these  cost  differences  are  relatively  small  and  thus  it  is  infeasible  to  adjust  the 
present  rigid  fare  structure  to  reflect  them. 

Tratfic  density  is  certainly  a  relevant  factor  in  average  costs  per  passenger- 
mile  and  thus  fares.  This  was  reflected  in  the  higher  fares  charged  by  the  intra- 
state carriers  in  minor  California  city-pairs  as  opposed  to  the  major  city-pairs. 
But  beyond  a  certain  threshold  level  of,  say,  100,000  true  O&D  passengers  per 
year,  differences  in  costs  per  passenger-mile  are  sniall.^"  Here  again,  it  should 
be  noted  that  the  CAB  makes  no  allowances  for  trafiic  density  in  its  basic  fare 
formula. 

In  the  new  cost-based  coach-fare  formula  to  be  implemented  on  April  29,  1975, 
the  CAB  has  established  a  terminal  charge  of  $13.85  and  various  line-haul  charges 
starting  at  7.79  cents  per  passenger-mile  for  the  first  500  miles.'"'  Implicit  in  this 
"cost-based"  formula  is  the  belief  that  it  costs  the  average  CAB-regulated  airline 
$13.85  merely  to  attract  a  passenger,  process  his  reservation  and  issue  a  ticket, 
enplane  him,  takeoff  and  then  immediately  land  at  the  same  or  an  adjacent  air- 
port, and  then  deplane  the  passenger.  All  this  regardless  of  whether  the  airport 
is  large,  small,  congested,  has  bad  weather,  or  whatever.  In  sharp  contrast  PSA 
will  do  all  this  plus  fly  a  passenger  159  miles  (Fresno-San  Francisco)  for  $12.73, 
that  is,  for  $1.12  less  than  the  CAB's  terminal  charge.^"  Similarly,  in  Texas,  South- 


^^  CAB,  supra,  note  1,  at  597-99. 

■'■■'Id.  The  current  round-trip  passenger  rate  for  jet  aircraft  is  2.84S  cents  per  passenger- 
mile.  CAB  press  release  7.5-1.")   (.Tan.  17,  197.5). 

■"•"The  threshold  traffic  level  for  a  city-nair  depends  on  many  related  factors  such  as 
distance,  aircraft  size  required  to  operate  efficiently  over  that  distance,  existence  of  alterna- 
tive transportation  services,  the  nuniher  of  other  fiisihts  servinp:  each  airport  in  the  city- 
pair,  the  amount  of  complementary  conneetin?  traffic,  and  so  on.  100,000  true  O&D 
passengers  ner  year  would  yield  an  average  of  274  per  day  which,  alone,  would  provide  a 
fiO-percent  load  factor  for  four  one-way  flights  provided  with  115-seat  aircraft.  In  1972, 
the  100th  largest  city-pair  was  New  York-Norfolk  with  186,000  true  O&I)  passengers 
(annendix  B). 

^  CAB  order  74-12-109  (Dec.  27,  1974>. 

S'PUC  decisions  83814  (Dec.  10,  1973),  83918  (Dec.  30,  1974)  and  83939  (Dec.  30, 
1974). 


477 

west  Airlines  will  provide  terminal  services  and  then  fly  a  weekend  or  night- 
coach  passenger  from  19.:  to  253  miles  for  ,$13.W)  ($15.00  including  tax),  almost 
identical  to  the  alleged  cost  of  a  CAB-regulated  airline's  brief  "sightseeing"  flight. 
There  are  indeed  fundamental  differences  between  CAB-regulated  airlines  and 
the  successful  intrastate  carriers ;  and  these  difl'erences  stem  from  regulation 
which  serves  to  close  entry,  provide  a  mechanism  through  which  agreements  can 
be  reached  regarding  fares  and  other  matters,  and  facilitate  the  low-cost  (to 
the  airlines)  enforcement  of  such  agreements. 

CAB    REGULATION    HAS    DECREASED    AIRLINE    EFFICIENCY 

If  the  fares  and  rates  of  the  certified  airlines  have  been  increased  so  much 
by  CAB  regulation,  why  haven't  these  airlines  made  consistently  large  profits? 
Of  course,  at  various  times  since  1938,  most  of  the  trunk  carriers  have  enjoyed 
substantial  profits  and  a  few  of  them,  such  as  Delta,  Northwest  and  Western, 
have  had  quite  good  and  relatively  consistent  profit  records.'^  On  the  whole, 
however,  the  profits  of  the  entire  regulated  industry  have  been  less  than  spec- 
tacular and  certainly  lower  than  would  be  expected  from  the  higher  fares  re- 
sulting from  regulation. 

The  fundamental  reason  for  the  surprisingly  poor  profit  performance  of  the 
certificated  airlines  is  that,  while  increasing  airline  prices,  CAB  regulation  has 
also  greatly  increased  airline  costs.  Three  of  the  major  sources  of  these  higher 
costs  appear  to  be:  1)  imperfections  in  CAB  regulation  which  promote  intense 
service-quality  (rather  than  price)  rivalry  among  the  airlines;  2)  regulatory 
entry  restrictions  which  require  each  of  the  relatively  few  certificated  airlines  to 
provide  a  diversity  of  services  ini3tead  of  being  able  to  specialize  in  an  opera- 
tionally homogeneous  service  pattern;  and  3)  the  assistance  that  entry  restric- 
tions give  monopolistic  or  oligopolistic  airline  suppliers  in  capturing  larger 
portions  of  the  airlines'  gains  by  increasing  the  prices  the  airlines  must  pay  for 
their  inputs  (especially  labor).  These  three  factors — carrier  rivalry,  decreased 
specialization,  and  increased  input  prices — will  be  examined  below. 

Candler  rivalry 

While  the  CAB  has  full  discretionary  power  over  entry  and  exit,  under  the 
Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958  (as  well  "as  the  earlier  1938  act)  it  has  had  only 
limited  direct  power  over  the  quality  of  service  provided  by  the  airlines.^."  In 
addition,  it  has  been  slow  to  influence  service  quality  through  indirect  means 
such  as  promoting  capacity  agreements  and  conditioning  its  approval  of  fares 
on  modifications  of  service  qualitj^.™  Thus,  CAB  regulation  has  been  asymmetric 
or  "imperfect,"  with  complete  control  in  some  areas  and  little  control  in  other 
areas. 

The  effects  of  this  asymmetric  regulation  have  been  amplified  by  the  Board's 
failure  to  allocate  predetermined  shares  of  industry  revenues  and  profits  to  each 
carrier.  Speciticnlly,  it  has  authorized  two  or  more  airlines  to  operate  over 
cA-ery  major  interstate  route  and  between  every  major  city-pair  without  assign- 
ing traffic  shares  in  each  city-pair.  Therefore,  great  rivalry  has  developed  between 
the  certificated  carriers  as  they  seek  to  retain  or  increase  their  traffic  shares.*^ 
Since  CAB  regulation  requires  cooperation  and  agreement  in  setting  prices,  this 
rivalry  has  long  been  channeled  toward  the  area  of  service  quality.  Operationally, 
this  has  meant  that  each  carrier  in  a  miilti-carrier  city-pair  has  endeavored  to 
operate  more  frequent  flights  with  the  fastest,  most  modern  and  comfortable 
aircraft,  while  providing  elaborate  in-flight  services  and  superior  ground  services. 
The  following  analysis  indicates  some  of  the  effects  that  such  service-quality 
rivalry  can  have  on  the  costs  of  regulated  airlines. 

An  airline's  most  important  physical  asset  is  its  aircraft  and  related  equip- 
ment. As  of  June  30,  1974,  flight  equipment  accounted  for  over  84  percent  of  the 
nondepreciated  value  of  the  total  operating  property  and  equipment  of  all  CAB- 
certificated  route  air  carriers."-  Obviously,  if  CAB-induced  service-quality  rivalry 


^''  CAB,  supra,  note  1.  at  411. 

^"William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  2-4. 

""■William  A.  Jordan.  Airline  Capacity  Agreements:  Correcting  a  Regulatory  Imper- 
fection. .39  Journal  of  Air  Law  and  Commerce  19.3-205   (snrinR  197.3). 

"1  In  addition  to  the  effects  of  multi-carrier  authorizations  on  service-quality  rivalry, 
there  is  no  indication  that  the  CAB  has  made  route  awards  to  the  carrierfs)  able  to 
provide  the  optimal  level  and  quality  of  service  at  the  lowest  marginal  cost.  Unless  low- 
cost  carriers  are  authorized  to  provide  new  services,  the  total  and  average  costs  of  air- 
line onerations  are  increased  over  minimum  attainable  levels. 

«=CAB,  Air  Carrier  Financial  Statistics  53  (June  1974). 


478 

results  in  excessive  numbers  of  aircraft  being  purcliased  and  then  being  under- 
utilized, the  costs  of  regulated  airline  operations  will  be  increased.  Evidence  on 
this  point  can  be  obtained  by  comparing  the  aircraft  utilization  by  the  CAB- 
regulated  trunk  carriers  with  that  of  the  California  intrastate  carriers  between 
1949  and  19G5.  The  California  carriers  could,  of  course,  undertake  rivalry  both 
by  reducing  fares  and  by  increasing  service  quality,  while  the  regulated  trunk 
carriers  were  largely  constrained  to  service-quality  rivalry.  Not  surprisingly,  the 
record  of  this  period  demonstrates  that  price  rivalry  was  indeed  very  important 
within  California  in  sharp  contrast  to  the  emphasis  on  service-quality  rivalry 
by  the  CAB-regulated  airlines."'' 

The  following  four  measures  can  be  used  to  determine  the  overall  intensity 
with  which  aircraft  are  utilized  : 

1.  The  average  number  of  revenue  hours  per  day  that  each  aircraft  is  operated 
(a  measure  of  airframe  utilization). 

2.  The  number  of  seats  installed  in  each  aircraft  type  for  a  given  class  of 
service    (indicating  the  extent  to  which  the  aircraft's  interior  is  utilized). 

3.  The  average  passenger  load  factor  (which  measures  the  degree  to  which 
the  installed  seats  are  utilized). 

4.  The  total  number  of  years  each  aircraft  is  operated  (measuring  the  length 
of  time  this  resource  is  utilized,  as  well  as  indicating  the  flow  of  resources  re- 
quired to  maintain  some  given  stock  of  aircraft  over  time). 

It  happens  that  the  successful  California  intrastate  carriers  operated  their 
aircraft  about  the  same  number  of  hours  per  day  as  the  trunk  carriers  (and  some- 
what more  than  the  local  service  carriers),  so  there  is  little  difference  in  effi- 
ciency in  this  respect,  unless  detailed  adjustments  are  made  to  compensate  for  the 
intrastate  carriers'  shorter  stage  lengths."*  yigniflcant  differences  did  exist,  how- 
ever, in  the  number  of  seats  installed  per  aircraft,  in  passenger  load  factors,  and 
in  aircraft  life. 

Two  factors  are  relevant  with  regard  to  numbers  of  seats  installed.  First,  no 
intrastate  carrier  operated  first-class  service  from  1949  to  1965  and,  therefore, 
never  provided  the  low-density  seating  associated  with  that  high-(iuality  si'rvice. 
Second,  when  comparing  identical  aircraft  types  in  all-coach  coiifi.mirations,  one 
finds  that  the  intrastate  carriers  generally  managed  to  install  more  seats.  I'sually 
the  differences  were  in  the  order  of  5  to  10  percent,  but  there  was  one  case  of  a 
24  percent  increase  and  a  few  others  with  differences  of  only  1,  2  or  3  percent.""' 
Combined,  these  two  factors  have  resulted  in  the  intrastate  carriers  utilizing 
their  aircraft  appreciably  more  than  the  CAB-regulated  airlines,  simply  by  put- 
ting more  seats  in  each  aircraft. 

Even  with  more  seats  per  aircraft,  the  California  intrastate  carriers  usually 
managed  to  fill  an  appreciably  larger  percentage  of  them  and  thus  have  higher 
coach  load  factors  than  the  certificated  airlines.  The  exceptions  all  occurred 
between  1949  and  19.53  when  the  trunk  carriers'  coach  service  was  very  limited 
and  was  mainly  provided  in  long-haul  city-pairs  while,  the  intrastate  carriers 
operated  only  in  short-haul  city-pairs  and  were  experiencing  their  initial  period 
of  extensive  entry  and  exit  (with  failing  carriers  having  low-load  factors).  For 
that  five-year  period  the  trunk  carriers'  average  coach  load  factor  was  73.9 
percent  compared  with  69.8  percent  for  the  intrastate  carriers.  In  every  .subse- 
quent year,  howevei-,  the  California  intrastate  carriers'  annual  average  load 
factor  exceeded  the  coach  load  factor  of  the  trunk  carriers  by  amounts  ranging 
from  1.0  percentage  point  in  1954  to  17.9  percentage  points  in  1963.  From  1955 
through  1964.  the  annual  average  load  factor  for  all  intrastate  carriers  com- 
bined never  fell  below  70  percent  and  it  reached  a  high  of  80.6  iiercent  in  1957. 
Their  12-year  weighted  average  load  factor  was  71.2  percent  compared  with 
only  59.1  percent  for  the  trunk  carriers'  coach  operation.""  Some  might  argue 
that  these  differences  resulted  from  the  high  tratfic  densities  in  the  three  major 
California  city  pairs.  But  a  detailed  comparison  of  the  scheduling  practices  of 
the  two  carrier  groups  in  those  city  pairs  demonstrates  that  the  successful 
intrastate  carriers'  higher  load  factors  were  due  to  management  decisions. 
Specifically,  the  intrastate  carriers'  adjusted  their  .schedules  to  conform  more 
closely  with  traffic  fluctuations  than  did  the  trunk  carriers."'^ 


«3  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  .34-72. 
«*  Tfl.  at  197-99. 
^^  Tfl.  at  199-201. 
««  Id.  at  200-.'?. 
67  Id.  at  203-9. 


479 

Finally,  during  much  of  this  period  the  California  intrastate  carriers  mainly 
operated  older,  obsolescent  aircraft  that  they  purchased  from  the  trunk  car- 
riers or  from  governments  surplus  stocks.  Thus,  they  served  to  extend  the  pro- 
ductive lives  of  these  aircraft,  thereby  increasing  their  utilization  and  economic 
efficiency.  This  increased  efficiency  was  reflected  in  the  low  prices  the  intrastate 
carriers  paid  for  their  aircraft  which,  in  turn,  served  to  lower  their  costs.  Had 
the  CAB-regulated  airlines  been  allowed  to  adopt  prices  lower  than  those 
authorized  by  the  CAB,  they  too  could  have  used  such  aircraft  in  low-fare  serv- 
ice, but  so  long  as  price  rivalry  was  prevented  by  regulation  it  was  desirable 
for  the  trunk  carriers  to  concentrate  on  high-quality  service  and  thus  retire  their 
aircraft  relatively  early.^ 

The  above  experience  is  what  happened  with  piston-powered  aircraft  through 
the  1950s  and  into  the  early  1960s.  The  turbine-powered  aircraft  innovation  was 
different  in  that  these  aircraft  provided  a  happy  combination  of  lower  operating 
costs  and  superior  service  quality.  This  indicates  that  such  aircraft  would  have 
been  adopted  quite  early  by  all  airlines  regardless  of  regulation.  Not  surpris- 
ingly, PSA  inaugurated  turbine-powered  Electra  service  less  than  eleven  months 
after  the  first  trunk  carrier,  and  it  adopted  the  medium-range  Boeing  727-100 
fifteen  months  after  that  aircraft  first  flew  in  scheduled  service.^"  It  was  those 
aircraft  that  provided  somewhat  higher  service  quality  at  higher  costs  (such  as 
the  DC-7,  the  L-1649)  that  were  fathered  by  CAB-regulation  and  which  would 
probably  not  have  been  developed  without  such  regulation. 

The  implications  of  these  differences  in  aircraft  utilization  can  be  illustrated 
by  the  following  example.  The  trunk  carriers'  1973  system  load  factor  was  52.4 
percent  and,  with  the  operational  adjustments  related  to  the  fuel  crisis,  it  rose 
to  about  56  percent  in  1974.™  Also,  the  service  life  of  a  turbojet  aircraft  is  com- 
monly thought  to  be  around  14  years.  Now,  the  California  exiierience  indicates 
70  percent  load  factors  are  feasible  without  regulation  and  that  aircraft  with 
low  operating  costs  would  have  longer  lives  without  regulation  than  with  regu- 
lation. A  70-percent  load  factor  is  25  percent  higher  than  the  56-percent  load 
factor  of  1974  (and  34  percent  above  the  52.4-percent  load  factor  in  1973),  and 
applying  a  similar  25-percent  extension  to  a  14-year  aircraft  service  life  would 
bring  it  to  17.5  years.  Increasing  the  average  load  factor  by  25  percent  means 
that  the  trunk  carriers'  present  traffic  volume  could  be  carried  by  SO  percent  of 
their  existing  fleet,  that  is,  by  about  $9.8  billion  worth  of  aircraft  rather  than 
the  $12.25  billion  (undepreciated  value)  in  existence  as  of  June  30,  1974.'^ 
17.5  years,  the  annual  replacement  rate  would  be  in  the  order  of  $560  million 
($9.8  billion-=-17.5)  rather  than  the  $875  million  rate  required  to  replace  the 
current  fleet  every  14  years  ($12.25  billion-^14).  This  would  be  a  saving  of 
roughly  $315  million  per  year,  or  about  $1.90  per  passenger  enplanement.''- 

The  above  calculations  are  quite  rough  and  ignore  the  fact  that  increased 
seat  density  without  regulation  would  result  in  further  reductions  in  the  fleet 
size  required  to  carry  existing  traffic.  Furthermore,  while  important,  aircraft  are 
just  one  item  of  airline  costs.  A  25-i>ercent  increase  in  load  factor  also  implies 
a  20-percent  decrease  in  the  number  of  flights  which  means  fewer  flight  per- 
sonnel, less  fuel  consumption,  lower  maintenance  costs,  smaller  landing  fees, 
and  so  forth.  Clearly  the  cost  differences  would  be  large.  One  can  begin  to  see 
how  emphasizing  service-quality  rivalry  increases  the  costs  of  the  CAB-regulated 
airlines.  One  can  also  begin  to  see  why  the  successful  intrastate  carriers  have 
been  able  to  survive  and  profit  under  fa-res  much  lower  than  those  authorized 
by  the  CAB. 
Decreased  specialization 

When  relatively  unregulated,  the  intrastate  carriers  have  been  characterized 
by  operational  simplicity  and  homogeneity.  Generally  speaking,  each  carrier 
has  operated  only  one  aircraft  type  at  any  point  in  time  (except  for  brief  tran- 
sitional periods),  offered  only  one  class  of  .service  (coach),  and  operated  be- 
tween cit.v-pairs  that  provided  traffic  flows  and  stage  lengths  compatible  with 
the  chosen  aircraft  type.  Some  of  the  carriers,  such  as  Mercer  Enterpri-ses  and 
Holiday  Airlines,  have  served  recreational  communities  or  activities  where  low 


"« Id.  at  209-10. 

o"  Id.  at  40-44,  .5.5-.56.  Also.  CAB.  supra,  note  1.  nt  3.52. 

•"  CAB,  Air  Carrier  Traffle  Rtati.'^tics  1  (Dec  lOT.S),  and  2  (Sept.  1974). 

"  CAB.  snnra.  note  fi2.  at  •">."). 
Furthermore,  if  this  smaller  number   (value)    of  aircraft  were  replaced  every 

"2  Total  system  tnrnk  revenue  passenjrpr  enplanements  for  the  year  ended  September  .30. 
1974,  was  166,7.30,000.  CAB,  supra,  note  70,  at  2. 


480 

trafl5c  densities  exist.  Others,  like  PSA  and  Southwest,  have  operated  between 
large  cities  having  high  traffic  densities.  To  this  day,  PSA,  the  largest  of  the 
intrastate  carriers,  serves  only  11  airports  while,  prior  to  1965,  it  never  served 
more  than  five  airports  at  one  time.  Similarly,  Air  California  now  serves 
eight  airports.  Holiday  seven,  and  Southwest  three."  Overall,  the  intra- 
state carriers  have  customarily  been  quite  small.  Only  one  (PSA)  has 
ever  operated  more  than  a  dozen  aircraft  at  one  time  (three  to  six  aircraft  has 
been  the  usual  fleet  size),  and  they  have  consistently  had  very  simple  fare 
structures  and  procedures.  All  this  has  allowed  each  employee  to  become  inti- 
mately familiar  with  his  work.  Pilots,  for  example,  spend  large  parts  of  their 
professional  lives  flying  only  one  aircraft  type  between  just  a  few  airports.  In 
the  same  way,  the  work  of  employees  engaged  in  maintenance,  engineering,  sched- 
uling, reservations,  accounting,  etc.,  are  all  simplified,  and  managers  can  become 
intimately  acquainted  with  the  carrier's  traffic  and  operational  features. 

Contrast  this  to  the  trunk  carriers  at  the  end  of  1972.  The  smallest  number 
of  U.S.  and  foreign  cities  served  by  any  carrier  was  37  (Western)  while  the 
largest  number  was  89  (United).  The  number  of  certificated  route  miles  ranged 
from  10,821  (Western)  to  38,968  (TWA),  and  the  trunk  fleets  ranged  from 
60  aircraft  (Continental)  to  388  (United)  with  each  carrier  operating  several 
different  types  of  aircraft.'*  Even  the  local  service  carriers  were  geographically 
large  and  diverse  in  comparison  with  the  intrastate  carriers.  In  December  1972 
each  of  them  between  50  and  95  cities  connected  by  3,660  to  8,295  certificated 
route  miles,  and  each  operated  33  to  133  aircraft."  Even  brandnew  Air  New 
England  has  been  authorized  to  serve  14  cities  located  throughout  New  Eng- 
land." The  operational  problems  and  complexities  faced  by  these  certificated  air- 
lines are  much  greater  than  those  of  the  intrastate  carriers,  and  the  associated 
decrease  in  specialization  translates  into  less  output  per  employee. 

Rough  indications  of  the  effects  of  specialization  on  airline  productivity  may 
be  obtained  by  comparing  the  1965  average  annual  output  per  employee  of  the 
total  trunk  carriers  as  a  group  and  of  Western  Air  Lines  (one  of  the  more 
productive  of  these  carriers)  with  that  of  PSA.  1965  was,  of  course,  the  last  year 
of  relatively  unregulated  operations  in  California,  and  it  was  also  the  year  that 
PSA  introduced  jet  aircraft  and  thus  operated  a  fleet  whose  composition  was 
very  similar  to  that  of  the  trunk  carriers."  Two  of  the  productivity  measures 
will  be  available  seat-miles  (ASM)  per  employee  and  revenue  passenger-miles 
(RPM)  per  employee.  It  happens  that  these  two  measures  are  biased  against 
the  certificated  carriers  because  they  provided  relatively  more  cargo  service 
than  PSA  which  served  to  inflate  their  number  of  employees  without  increasing 
their  ASM  and  RPM  figures.  Therefore,  to  provide  balance,  operating  revenues 
per  employee  will  also  be  given  with  the  recognition  that  this  measure  is  biased 
against  PSA  since  its  lower  fares  required  more  physical  output  per  dollar  of 
revenue.  The  data  for  Western  Air  Lines  are  particularly  useful,  both  because 
they  indicate  the  range  of  trunk  carrier  productivity  and  because  a  substantial 
portion  of  its  total  operations  were  entirely  or  partially  within  California  which 
may  yield  increased  comparability  with  PSA's  data.  The  comparisons  are  given 
in  table  8. 

TABLE  8.-AVERAGE  ANNUAL  OUTPUT  PER  EMPLOYEE  (PSA  COMPARED  WITH  TOTAL  TRUNK  CARRIERS  AND 
WESTERN  AIR  LINES),  1965 


Output  per  employee 

PSA  percent  gre 
Total  trunks 

ater  than 

Output  measure 

Total  trunks 

Western 

PSA 

Western 

603,000 

769, 000 
431,  000 
$26, 100 

1,  270,  000 
804,  000 
$32,  500 

111 
141 
46 

65 

.     ...            333,000 

87 

Operating  revenues 

$22,  200 

25 

Source:  William  A.  Jordan,  Airline  Regulations  in  America),  215,  217,  219  (1970). 


"PUC.  Present  and  Pronosed  Route  Structures  of  California  Certificated  Air  Carriers 
and  Routes  Onerated  bv  CAB  Certifleated  Air  Carriers  as  of  July  1,  1974.  lA.  10.  15A 
(n.d. ).  .Vise,  Southwest  Airlines,  Third  Quarter  Report  (nine  months  ended  Sept.  30, 
1974). 

"!*  CAB,  supra,  note  1,  at  1-2. 

'5  Id. 

7«  CAB  press  release  75-18  (.Tan.  23,  1975).  .  ,   ,.       ^     .^ 

"1965  was  neither  the  hest  nor  the  worst  year  for  PSA's  productivity  re'ative  to  the 
certificated  airlines.  While  its  jet  operations  increased  total  output,  between  April  and 
AuKust  its  total  number  of  employees  increased  from  575  to  740  persons.  William  A. 
Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  339-40. 


481 

Again,  large  differences  can  be  seen  to  have  existed  between  the  performances 
of  the  certificated  trunk  carriers  and  PSA.  After  talcing  account  of  the  biases  in 
the  measures,  it  appears  that  in  1965  PSA's  output  per  employee  was  about  100 
percent  larger  than  the  average  for  all  trunk  carriers,  and  almost  60  percent 
larger  than  Western's  output  per  employee.  Of  course,  the  certificated  airlines 
provided  higher  quality  service  (including  first-class  service),  operated  many 
conveniently  located  ticket  offices,  were  engaged  in  regulatory  activities,  and  .so 
forth,  all  of  which  would  decrease  employee  output  as  measured  in  table  8.  At  the 
same  time,  their  much  larger  and  diverse  route  structures  added  complexity  to 
their  operations.  Combined,  these  factors  decreased  employee  productivity  in 
terms  of  fundamental  output  measures.  Here  is  yet  another  reason  why  the  suc- 
cessful intrastate  carriers  v.-ere  able  to  survive  while  charging  appreciably  lower 
fares  than  the  CAB-regulated  airlines — their  specialized  operations  simply 
yielded  more  output  per  employee. 

Increased  input  prices 

The  earlier  analysis  of  carrier  rivalry  has  shown  that  the  regulation-promoted 
emphasis  on  service-quality  rivalry  has  served  both  to  increase  the  total  .stock  of 
aircraft  operated  by  the  airlines  and  to  decrease  their  utilization  by  installing 
fewer  seats,  operating  at  lower  load  factors,  and  retiring  them  at  relatively  early 
ages.  Since  the  end  of  World  War  II  there  have  been  three  major  reequipment 
cycles — starting  in  1946  with  pressurized  aircraft,  then  turbine-powered  aircraft 
in  1958  and,  finally,  wide-bodied  aircraft  in  1970 — each  with  several  phases  in 
which  improved  versions  of  the  basic  innovation  were  developed.  Given  the 
emphasis  on  service-quality  rivalry,  it  has  been  essential  that  each  CAB-regulated 
airline  operate  the  mo.st  modern  equipment,  and  thus  each  new  aircraft  type  has 
been  adopted  quickly  and  extensively  by  the  regulated  airlines  with  a  concurrent 
replacement  of  existing  aircraft.™ 

Clearly,  the  above  .situation  has  resulted  in  greatly  increased  demand  for  new 
aircraft  and  this  has  benefited  the  aircraft  and  engine  manufacturers  over  what 
they  would  have  experienced  without  CAB  regulation.  At  the  same  time,  the 
increased  variety  of  airci-aft  produced  has  re.sulted  in  higher  costs  of  production. 
Economic  theory  (and  common  sense)  predicts  that  increased  demand  for  a  good 
combined  with  increased  costs  of  producing  that  good  will  result  in  higher  equi- 
librium prices  regardless  of  whether  the  market  structure  is  competitive,  oligop- 
olistic or  monopolistic.  Thus,  there  is  every  theoretical  reason  to  expect  aircraft 
prices  have  been  increased  as  a  result  of  CAB-regulation.  Actually,  it  is  difficult 
to  imagine  how  the  1938  and  1958  acts  could  have  been  written  and  implemented 
to  promote  greater  demand  for  the  products  of  the  aircraft  and  engine  manufac- 
turers at  the  expense  of  the  airlines  and,  through  them,  those  consumers  of  air- 
line services  who  value  lower  prices  relatively  more  than  very  high  service- 
quality.™ 

By  prohibiting  the  entry  of  new  airlines,  CAB  regulation  has  also  greatly  bene- 
fited airline  employees.  The  employees  of  CAB-regulated  airlines  know  that  they 
can  obtain  higher  wages  or  more  co.stly  work  rules  without  fear  of  having  some 
new  or  existing  airline  enter  and  destroy  their  company  and  their  jobs  through 
price  rivalry  supported  by  lower  labor  costs.  They  also  know  that  should  their 
company  happen  to  fail  it  would  be  merged  with  another  CAB-regulated  airline 
whereupon  the  CAB's  labor-protective  policies  would  result  in  their  obtaining 
similar  jobs  in  the  merged  company  or  "receiving  sub.stantial  termination  pay- 
ments.'" Furthermore,  where  a  union  provides  the  only  source  of  labor  of  a  certain 
category  for  most  of  the  industry  (pilots,  for  example),  or  where  labor  can  other- 
wise act  industry-wide,  they  know  that  the  airlines  can  transfer  a  large  portion 
of  above-market  wage  demands  to  airline  customers  simply  by  agreeing  on  price 
increases  with  their  fellow  carriers  through  CAB  procedures.  The  overall  result 
of  these  factors  appears  to  be  ever  higher  labor  costs  for  the  regulated  airlines. 
Evidence  pertaining  to  the.se  factors  is  fragmentary,  but  significant.  In  recent 
studies  of  the  trunk  and  local  service  carriers,  the  CAB  found  that  total  labor 
costs  in  1973  comprised  45.7  percent  of  total  operating  expenses  for  the  trunk 
carriers  and  48.9  percent  for  the  local  service  carriers."  In  contrast,  in  informa- 


™  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  36-44.  .\lso.  William  A.  Jordan,  exhibit  DJ-RT-1, 
13-21  (testimony  submitted  in  the  American-Western  merger  case,  CAB  docket  22916, 
June  25.  1971). 

■^  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  230-33. 

so  CAB  order  72-4-31/32  (March  28,  1972),  at  18-33. 

"1  CAB,  Productivity  and  Cost  of  Employment,  System  Trunks,  Calendar  Years  1972  and 

73,  8  (Sept.  1973).  Also,  CAB  press  release  75-13  (Jan.  16,  1975). 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  32 


482 

tion  submitted  to  this  subcommittee,  Air  California  advises  that  for  the  eleven 
months  ended  November  30,  1974,  wages  and  executive  salaries  totaled  just  26.1 
percent  of  its  total  costs.**"  Similarly,  Southwest  reports  these  labor  categories 
accounted  for  only  28.37  percent  of  its  total  costs  for  the  10-month  period  ended 
October  30,  1974.'' 

Factors  other  than  regulation  probably  influenced  the  above  percentages.  For 
example,  it  appears  that  the  two  intrastate  carriers  included  interest  expenses 
in  their  total  costs  while  these  are  not  part  of  the  CAB-defined  operating  expenses. 
However,  adding  interest  expenses  to  the  certificated  carriers'  operating  expenses 
merely  brings  their  labor  costs  to  44.3  percent  (trunk)  and  47.2  percent  (local 
service)  of  the  expanded  total.**  Another  possible  cause  of  these  differences  in 
labor's  share  of  total  costs  is  that  both  Air  California  and  Southwest  are  young 
companies  with  relatively  low  seniority  costs.  Actually,  the  percentage  differences 
are  too  large  to  be  accounted  for  by  such  adjustments.  Instead,  they  are  consist- 
ent with  the  prior  evidence  that  the  employees  of  small,  specialized  airlines  are 
more  productive  than  the  employees  of  CAB-regulated  airlines,  and  with  the  hy- 
pothesis that  regulation  allows  employees  of  certificated  airlines  to  obtain  higher 
wages  for  all  categories  of  workers. 

The  only  California  intrastate  carrier  to  be  unionized  prior  to  1965  was  Cali- 
fornia Central — the  largest  and  most  important  of  the  California  airlines  from 
January  1949  until  it  was  adjudged  bankrupt  in  February  1955.  Both  its  pilots 
and  mechanics  were  unionized,  and  a  37-day  strike  by  the  mechanics  occurred  in 
July  and  early  August  1953.  It  appears  that  this  strike  and  the  subsequent  wage 
increase  reduced  California  Central's  ability  to  operate  effectively  against  its 
low-fare  rivals  (including  PSA).  In  January  1954,  just  six  months  after  the 
strike,  it  initiated  the  bankruptcy  proceeding  that  eventually  resulted  in  its 
demise.^ 

It  also  appears  relevant  that  PSA  was  never  unionized  until  early  1971  when 
its  station  personnel  voted  to  be  represented  by  the  Teamsters  Union.®"  While 
initially  voting  against  union  representation,  PSA's  mechanics  eventually  also 
joined  the  Teamsters  and  in  November  1973  carried  out  the  first  strike  ever  insti- 
gated against  PSA.^  While  far  from  conclusive,  it  should  be  noted  that  these 
actions  followed  the  PUC's  effective  closure  of  entry  into  the  major  California 
city -pairs  during  the  period  ending  in  late  1969. 

The  above  analyses  pertain  to  the  airlines'  two  most  important  types  of  in- 
puts— aircraft  and  labor.  Similar  analyses  could  be  made  regarding  suppliers 
of  other  inputs  such  as  airports,  petroleum  products,  supplies  used  in  in-flight 
services,  etc.  Enough  has  been  said,  however,  to  indicate  how  regulation  can  act 
to  increase  the  prices  and  quantities  of  inputs  utilized  by  the  CAB-regulated  air- 
lines in  providing  their  high-quality  services. 

Summary 

CAB  regulation  has  served  to  decrease  airline  eflSciency  and.  thus,  increase 
airline  costs.  It  has  done  so  by  closing  entry  and  then  by  providing  an  environ- 
ment which  encourages  the  certificated  airlines  to  undertake  extensive  service- 
quality  rivalry  among  themselves  for  larger  shares  of  traflic,  revenues  and,  hope- 
fully, profits.  As  a  result,  the  CAB-regulated  airlines  purchase  excessive  numbers 
of  very  costly  aircraft  and  then  under-utilize  them ;  they  operate  over  large  and 
diverse  route  structures  which  decrease  specialization  and  increase  operational 
complexities,  and  which  are  associated  with  significantly  lower  employee  produc- 
tivity ;  and,  finally,  they  pay  higher  prices  for  the  larger  quantities  of  inouts 
that  are  required  for  their  high-quality  services. 


All  U.S.  airlines  must  comply  with  the  safety  and  operational  regulations  of 
the  Federal  Aviation  Administration.  Thus,  the  question  is,  given  FAA  regulation, 
does  the  economic  regulation  of  the  CAB  significantly  influence  airline  safety? 
The  evidence  on  this  point  is  unclear. 


»-  R.  W.  Clifford,  president,  Air  California,  Letter  to  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
attachment   (Dec.   19,  1974). 

'*•''  M.  Lamar  Muse,  president,  Southwest  Airlines,  Letter  to  Senator  Edward  >L  Kennedy. 
20  (Jan.  3,  1975). 

^  CAB,  Air  Carrier  Financial  Statistics,  1,  4  (Dec.  1973). 

ss  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  183-S4. 

88  PSA,  First  Quarter  Report  (ending  Mar.  31,  1971). 

87  The  Wall  Street  Journal,  16  (Midwest  edition,  Nov.  19,  1973). 


483 

The  California  intrastate  carriers  have  experienced  two  fatal  accidents.  On 
December  7,  1949,  a  California  Arrow  DC-3  crashed  near  Vallejo,  California, 
killing  six  passengers  (including  the  wife  and  son  of  the  airline's  owner)  and 
three  crew  members."  Then,  14  years  later  on  March  1,  1964,  a  Constellation  L-049 
of  Paradise  Airlines  crashed  near  Lake  Tahoe,  killing  81  passengers  and  foui 
crew  members.*'*  These  two  crashes  resulted  in  a  passenger  fatality  rate  of  2.67 
passengers  per  100  million  revenue  passenger-miles  for  the  California  intrastate 
carriers  from  1949  through  1965,  compared  with  a  rate  ot  only  0.45  fatalities  per 
100  million  revenue  passenger-miles  for  the  trunk  carriers  and  a  rate  of  0.92  for 
the  local  .service  carriers  for  these  same  years.'"  Proponents  of  CAB  regulation 
could  well  use  these  results  to  conclude  that  CAB  regulation  has  indeed  increased 
airline  safety. 

In  opposition  to  this  position,  proponents  of  decreased  CAB  regulation  could 
point  out  that,  because  of  the  relatively  small  number  of  revenue  passenger-miles 
provided  by  the  intrastate  carriers,  the  Paradise  crash  had  an  inordinate  and 
statistically  nonpredictive  effect  on  the  data ; "'  that  the  short  stage  lengths  of 
intrastate  operations  increa.se  the  probability  of  crashes  aue  to  the  high  exposure 
resulting  from  frequent  takeoffs  and  landings  (note  the  local  service  carriers' 
higher  fatality  rate)  ;  and  that  there  have  been  no  other  crashes  of  intrastate 
carriers  (either  in  California  or  Texas)  so  that  the  1949-74  fatality  rate  would 
be  very  much  lower  than  the  1949-65  rate. 

It  happened  that  both  California  Arrow  and  Paradise  terminated  intrastate 
operations  shortly  after  their  crashes.  California  Arrow  transferred  its  remaining 
aircraft  to  irregular  interstate  service,  while  the  FAA  suspended  and  then  refused 
to  renew  Paradise's  operating  certificate.  Thus,  in  each  case  a  fatal  accident 
imposed  substantial  economic  penalties  on  the  intrastate  carrier.  No  CAB- 
regulated  airline  has  borne  similar  penalties  following  a  crash.  In  fact,  the  CAB's 
economic  regulation  may  even  prevent  the  full  application  of  sanctions  otherwise 
applicable  under  federal  .safety  regulations  or  available  to  consumers.  With 
respect  to  service  termination,  if  a  carrier  ix»ssesses  a  CAB  certificate  of  public 
convenience  and  necessity,  does  the  FAA  really  have  the  power  to  suspend  its 
operating  certificate  following  one  or  more  fatal  accidents,  or  are  the  FAA's 
corrective  powers  actually  limited  to  fines,  increased  surveillance  of  operations, 
etc.?  In  terms  of  consumer  choice,  .since  carriers  with  low  passenger  fatality  rates 
are  prohibited  by  the  CAB  from  quickly  extending  operations  over  the  routes  of 
a  carrier  having  a  relatively  high  fatality  rate,  do  air  travelers  have  as  many 
opportunities  under  CAB  regulation  to  express  their  concern  over  a  carrier's 
poor  safety  record  by  using  other  carriers  having  superior  records? 

Regardless  of  one's  opinion  on  this  matter,  the  complete  absence  of  fatal  acci- 
dents by  PSA  during  16  years  of  unregulated  operations  (and  continued  now 
under  increased  regulation),  and  by  California  Central  during  .six  years  of  opera- 
tions, does  indicate  that  economic  regulation  is  not  a  necessary  condition  for 
airline  safety.  At  the  same  time,  the  varying  experiences  of  individual  certificated 
airlines  .show  that  such  regulation  is  not  a  sufficient  condition  for  superior  safety 
performance. 

CONCLUSION 

There  is  strong  evidence  that  CAB  regulation  has  reduced  entry  into  the 
airline  industry,  resulted  in  exit  occurring  only  through  acquisition  and  merger, 
and  has  caused  fares  to  be  much  higher  than  they  would  be  without  regulation. 
One  would  think  this  would  have  been  very  beneficial  to  the  regulated  airlines 
and  that  they  would  have  enjoyed  consistently  high  profits.  Unfortunately,  the 
recurrent  crises  and  low  profits  of  most  regulated  airlines  demonstrate  that  such 
has  not  been  the  case,  and  the  reason  for  the  airlines'  problems  can  also  be 
attributed  to  the  CAB's  regulatory  policies  and  procedures.  By  motivating  air- 
lines to  purcha.se  excessive  numbers  of  aircraft  and  then  underutilize  them  by 
requiring  them  to  operate  diverse  services  thereby  reducing  specialization  and 
lowering  employee  productivity,  and  by  providing  an  environment  where  larger 
amounts  of  inputs  are  purchased  at  higher  prices,  CAB  regulation  has  increased 

The£i''.^n'|Jles"'limeJ:\''(D;Y.t^  ^'""'"''"  ^'^"  '''^^>'  "^   ^-^"^-  ^^^l)'  ^'^»' 

^  wnn'nm '"a^'V"  A^'""'^*'"*  Report.  1-2   (SA-.378,  file  1-002,  July  12,  1965,  proces.sed ) . 
""  WlUlam  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  1,  at  49-.53  -^        <  >  i-  i 

carried'"  hv^^th'rPnWf^'^  •'^''^ '?'  V'"!"  ""e-half  of  1  percent  of  all  revenue  passenser-mlles 

l^r^^ntlUZ\:tll%7i'^.^'^^^^^^  ''''   *°   l^^^'   ">-'  -^<^ounte6  for  93 


484 

airline  costs  as  much  as  it  has  increased  fares.  Indeed,  regulated  fares  50  to  100 
percent  higher  than  nonregulated  fares  have  been  accompanied  by  emp  oyee 
productivity  40  to  50  percent  lower  than  the  most  successful  of  the  nonregulated 
intrastate  carriers.  This,  of  course,  indicates  a  fundamental  fallacy  in  the  Board  s 
policy  of  basing  fares  on  regulated  airline  costs. 

Rather  than  the  airlines  themselves  (or  their  stockholders)  being  the  prime 
beneficiaries  of  CAB  regulation,  the  major  beneficiaries  appear  to  have  been 
airline  employees,  aircraft  and  engine  manufacturers  (and  their  stockholders 
and  employees),  and  suppliers  of  all  the  other  inputs  utilized  by  the  regulated  air- 
lines Passengers  who  value  high-quality  airline  service  relatively  more  than 
other  goods  and  passengers  who  do  not  pay  for  their  air  travel,  have  also 
benefited  from  the  high-quality  service  flowing  from  CAB  regulation.  Passengers 
who,  in  contrast,  prefer  low-price  and  somewhat  lower-quality  service  have  been 
harmed,  either  by  having  to  pay  higher  prices  for  airline  services  or  by  using  less 
preferred  means  of  travel,  or  by  not  traveling  at  all.  Also  harmed  through  having 
to  pay  higher  prices  or  higher  taxes  are  the  many  consumers  of  goods  and  services 
produced  by  firms  or  government  agencies  utilizing  air  transportation  in  their 
production  and/or  distribution  activities. 

Clearly,  the  present  type  of  airline  operation  flowing  from  CAB-regulation  is 
very  inefficient,  including  substantial  inefficiencies  in  fuel  consumption.  Assuming 
economic  efficiency  in  a  world  of  scarcity  is  desirable,  this  inefficiency  may  be 
rectified  in  one  of  at  least  two  ways.  The  first  way  is  to  eliminate  the  imperfec- 
tions of  current  CAB  regulation  by  placing  every  aspect  of  airline  operations 
under  the  direct  control  of  the  CAB.  The  aim  would  be  to  increase  efficiency  by 
eliminating  service-quality  rivalry.  It  would  be  a  pure  cartel  attempting  to 
maximize  airline  profits,  or  other  goals,  in  a  world  of  uncertainty.  Of  course, 
some  individuals  would  be  harmed  by  this  alternative.  The  elimination  of  service- 
quality  rivalry  would  result  in  decreased  demand  for  personnel,  aircraft  and 
other  inputs,  and  would  reduce  service-quality  with  little  or  no  reduction  in 
general  fares.  This  alternative  may  be  attractive  to  many  airline  stockholders 
and  managers,  but  it  has  drawbacks  over  the  long-run  (say,  10  to  20  years).  First 
of  all,  those  employees  still  working  for  the  airlines  (and  other  airline  suppliers) 
would  endeavor  to  capture  ever  larger  shares  of  the  higher  profits  and,  given 
their  own  monopoly  powers,  would  be  successful  in  so  doing.  Second,  higher 
fares  and  decreased  service  quality  would  provide  great  motivation  and  many 
opportunities  for  innovators  to  develop  new  substitute  services  to  attract  the 
airlines'  traffic  from  them.  An  historical  example  of  such  an  occurrence  is  the 
way  the  motor  carriers  have  been  able  to  divert  large  amounts  of  traffic  from  the 
railroads.  Third,  the  administration  of  this  cartel  would  doubtless  be  cumbersome 
and  slow  to  adjust  to  changes.  So  long  as  airline  demand  continues  to  grow,  this 
first  alternative  will  remain  viable.  It  will,  however,  be  very  vulnerable  to 
innovations  or  to  a  secular  decline  in  demand. 

The  second  way  to  eliminate  airline  inefficiency  stemming  from  CAB  regulation 
is  to  abolish  entry  control  and  to  allow  any  airline  to  lower  its  fares  without 
regulatory  restraint,  that  is,  to  adopt  the  essentially  nonregulated  environment 
that  existed  within  California  prior  to  1965.  This  too  would  be  undesirable  to 
the  aircraft  and  engine  manufacturers  (unless  they  quickly  develop  aircraft 
having  appreciably  lower  operating  costs)  because  large  numbers  of  excess  air- 
craft would  have  to  be  absorbed  into  a  revamped  industry  emphasizing  low-cost, 
high-load  factor  operations.  High-paid  and/or  relatively  unproductive  employees 
would  find  them.selves  unemployed  as  their  companies  went  bankrupt  or  radically 
decreased  their  .sizes  of  operation,  but  many  of  these  same  employees  would  find 
themselves  working  for  the  large  numbers  of  new  or  expanded  airlines  that  would 
purchase  existing  aircraft  and  inaugurate  service.  Airline  passengers  preferring 
low-prices  would  find  themselves  better  off  as  would  the  consumers  of  goods 
utilizing  air  transportation  as  a  productive  input.  The  period  of  adjustment 
would  probably  be  in  the  order  of  ten  years  (the  effective  lives  of  some  of  our 
older  jet  aircraft),  but  upon  its  conclusion  the  U.S.  would  have  an  efficient,  low- 
price  air  transportation  system  better  able  to  adjust  to  economic  fluctuations 
and  operating  in  a  way  that  would  make  the  emergence  of  substitute  services 
more  difficult.  The  short-run  "medicine"  would  taste  terrible,  but  the  long-run 
prognosis  would  be  good. 

Congress  has  to  choose  between  the  status  quo  or  variations  of  one  of  these 
two  alternatives.  The  choice  will  not  be  easy  because  many  indiwduals  will 
be  harmed  and  many  others  benefited  regardless  of  the  choice. 


485 


ONE-WAY  COACH   PRICES  '   FOR  DALLAS-HOUSTON   AND  DALLAS-SAN  ANTONIO  SERVICE 

SOUTHWEST  AIRLINES,  BRANIFF  AIRWAYS,  AND  TEXAS  INTERNATIONAL  AIRLINES 

JUNE  1971-DECEMBER  1974 


One-way  coach  price 

Dallas-Houston  (222  mil 

es) 

Dallas-San  Antonio  (253  miles) 

Day 

Night 

Day 

Night 

Effective  date 

SW 

BNTT 

SW 

BNTT 

SW 

BN 

SW               BN 

1971: 

Junel 

June  18. 

---- 

$27  __. 
=  20  ... 

20 
20 
26 
26 

»27 
27 
■0  27/13 
12  27/13 
27/13 
•6  27/13 
17  28/15 

.30/15 

31 

3  $10 
10 
10 

8  13 

13 
13 
13 
13 
13 
13 

8  15 

15 

=3  15  . 

15  . 

""Vio.'oo' 

""13.00" 

13.00 

13.00 

18  14.  99 

14.99 

$20"           2  20'. 

20              20 

5  26              20 

26               26 

7  26/13               26 

26/13            »  28 
13               28 
13               28 
13               28 
13      H  28/13 
13          28/13 
15      i»  29/15 

15      21  31/15 

22  25/15               31 

25/15               32 

1972: 
May  (na) 

20 

4  $10 

10 
10 

July9.. 

July  17/21 

526 
26 

Oct.  30 

1973: 

Jan.  5 

Jan.  22 _.. 

Feb.  1 

Apr.2 

May  21 

....      '26/13 

26/13 

....        26/13 

13 

....     7 26/13 

26/13 

8  13 

13 
13 
13 
13 
13 

Sept.  24 

Dec.  1. 

.-_        26/13 
'9  28/15 

13 

1974: 

Apr.  16 

Oct.  1 

Nov.  15 

....        28/15 
....     "25/15 
....        25/15 

15 

23  15 

15 

1  Jet  coach/economy/1-class  fare  plus  8  percent  Federal  transportation  tax. 

2  This  and  the  subsequent  prices  in  this  column  to  Oct.  30, 1972,  were  available  to  intrastate  passengers  only.  Interstate 
passengers  continued  to  pay  the  price  specified  above.  Effective  Oct.  30,  the  highest  price  listed  in  each  entry  applied  to 
interstate  as  well  as  intrastate  passengers. 

3  Applicable  to  1  northbound  and  1  southbound  flight  departing  after  9  p.m.  on  weekdays  and  Sundays. 

<  Applicable  to  1  northbound  flight  departing  after  9  p.m.  on  Fridays  and  1  southbound  flight  departing  after  9  p.m.  on 
weekdays  and  Sundays. 

s  $50  round-trip  price.  $225  commuter  club  card  introduced  providing  unlimited  transportation  for  a  30-day  period. 

'  Available  to  intrastate  passengers  on  a  daily  Braniff  weekday  flight  departing  Dallas  at  7 :30  p.m.  and  returning  from 
Hobby  Airport  in  Houston  at  9  p.m. 

'$26  on  weekday  flights  prior  to  8  p.m.  $13  on  Saturday  and  Sunday  flights  with  a  $25  round-trip  price. 

8  Applicable  to  flights  departing  on  or  after  8  p.m. 

'  The  CAB  authorized  a  2.7  percent  across-the-board  fare  Increase  effective  Sept.  5,  1972,  and  this  price  was  a  delayed 
response  to  that  action.  Texas  International  adopted  this  price  for  Intrastate  passengers  on  Jan.  11,  1973. 

1°  Braniff:  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  Airport  $27,  to/from  Hobby  Airport  $13  with  $25  round-trip  price.  Texas 
International;  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  $13  effective  Feb.  20,  1973. 

11  Footnote  deleted. 

12  Braniff:  weekdays  $27,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  $27,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Hobby 
Airport  $13.  Texas  International:  $20. 

'3  Available  to  Intrastate  passengers  on  one  Braniff  flight  departing  Hobby  Airport  at  9  p.m.  daily. 

i«  $28  for  intrastate  passengers  utilizing  approximately  10  daily  flights.  $13  for  intrastate  passengers  utilizing  another 
5  or  so  designated  flights. 

15  Braniff:  weekdays  $27,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  $27,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Hobby 
Airport  $13.  Texas  International:  weekdays  $27,  Saturday-Sunday  through  Sept.  30,  $20;  effective  Oct.  1,  $27  on  all  days. 

i«  $28  on  weekday  flights  prior  to  8  p.m.  $15  on  Saturday  and  Sunday  flights. 

1'  Braniff:  weekdays  $28,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  $28,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Hobby 
Airport  $14.99.  Texas  International:  $28. 

■^  Available  to  intrastate  passengers  on  Braniff  flights  departing  on  or  after  7  p.m.  to/from  Hobby  Airport. 

'«  $29  for  intrastate  passengers  utilizing  approximately  10  daily  flights.  $14.99  for  intrastate  passengers  utilizing  another 
5  or  so  designated  flights.  Effective  Jan.  13,  1974:  $29  for  all  flights  to/from  Dallas-Fort  Worth  Regional  Airport,  $15 
for  all  flights  to/from  Love  Field. 

20  Braniff:  weekdays  $30,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Houston  Intercontinental  $30,  Saturday-Sunday  to/from  Hobby 
Airport  $14.99.  Texas  International:  $30. 

21  $31  for  all  flights  to/from  Dallas-Fort  Worth  Regional  Airport,  $15  for  approximately  3  daily  flights  to/from  Dallas 
Love  Field.  Braniff  terminated  all  service  at  Love  Field  effective  Sept,  1,  1974. 

22  $25  on  weekday  flights  prior  to  7  p.m.  $15  on  Saturday  and  Sunday  flights. 

23  Applicable  to  flights  departing  on  or  after  7  p.m. 

Source:  Braniff  Airways,  letter  from  T.  P.  Robertson  (Jan,  29,  1975);  Southwest  Airlines  annual  report  (1971,  1972,  and 
1973).  Also  quarterly  report  (3  months  ended  Mar.  31,  1972-74,  June  30,  1972-73,  and  Sept.  30,  1971-73).  Texas  Inter- 
national Airlmes,  letter  from  V.R.Shelley  (July  16, 1974).  Official  Airline  Guide  (North  American  edition,  Apr.  15,  June  1, 
Sept.  14,  Oct.  15,  Nov.  1,  and  Dec.  1,  1972;  Apr.  1,  May  15,  June  15,  July  15,  and  Nov.  15,  1973;  Jan.  15,  Feb.  1,  May  1, 
Aug.  1,  Oct.  15,  and  Dec.  1,  1974).  Aviation  Week  and  Space  Technology  43  (Apr.  30,  1973),  and  37  (June  4,  19^^  The 
Houston  Post  5/A  (Jan.  31,  1973). 


486 


APPENDIX  B 
TOP  100  ORIGIN-DESTINATION  CITY-PAIRS  ^  IN  ORDER  OF  PASSENGER  RANK,  CAB-CERTIFICATED  AND 
CALIFORNIA/TEXAS  INTRASTATE  AIRLINES  (SCHEDULED  DOMESTIC  SERVICE,  1972) 


Rank  and  City-pair  1 


Number  of 

airport 

pairs 


Number  of 

origin-desti- 

Intercity  nation 

mileage «         passengers 


1  Boston-New  York/Newark 

2  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco 

3  Miami-New  York/Newark 

4  Chicago-New  York/Newark 

5  New  York/Newaik-Washington 

6  Los  Angeles-New  York/Newark.. 

7  Fort  Lauderdale-New  York/Newark 

8  Los  Angeles-San  Diego 

9  Detroit/Ann  Arbot-New  York/Newark 

in  New  York/Newark-San  Francisco 

n  Los  Angeles-Oakland-   

12  Los  Angeles-San  Jose.. 

13  Chicago-Los  Angeles 

14  Cleveland-New  York/Newark 

15  New  York/Newark-Pittsburgh 

16  Los  Angeles-Sacramento 

17  Dallas/Fort  Worth-Houston 

18  Las  Vegas-Los  Angeles 

19  Boston-Washington - 

20  Chicago-Detroit/Ann  Arbor 

21  Atlanta-New  York/Newark ---- 

22  Buffalo/Niagara  Falls-New  York/Newark... 

23  Chicago-Minneapolis/St.  Paul 

24  Chicago-Washington - 

25  Honolulu-Los  Angeles - 

26  Burbank-San  Francisco 

27  Chicago-Miami ■ 

28  Chicago-St.  Louis 

29  Hrlo-Honolulu 

30  New  York/Newark-Rochester 

31  Honolulu-Lihue 

32  New  York/Newark-Tampa - 

33  San  Diego-San  Francisco 

34  Boston- Philadelphia 

35  Chicago-Philadelphia 

36  Boston-Chicago 

37  Chicago- San  Frr.ncisco 

38  Los  Angeles-Phoenix 

39  Honolulu-Kahului 

40  Chicago-Cleveland 

41  Denver-Los  Angeles.. - 

42  Dallas/Fort  Worth-New  York/Newark 

43  San  Francisco-Seattle. 

44  New  York/Newark-St.  Louis 

45  Los  Angeles-Seattle - - 

46  Boston-Miami 

47  New  York/Newark-Syracuse 

48  Miami-Philadelphia 

49  Philadelphia-Pittsburgh 

50  Los  Angeles-Washington 

51  Chicago-Denver.   

52  Houston-New  York/Newark 

53  Chicago-Kansas  City 

54  Honolulu-San  Francisco... 

55  Dallas/Fort  Worth-Los  Angeles 

56  Burbank-San  Jose.... 

57  New  York/Newark-West  Palm  Beach 

58  San  Francisco-Santa  Ana. 

59  Denver-New  York/Newark.. 

60  New  York/Newark-Orlando... --■ 

61  Minneapolis/St.  Paul-New  York/NevKark. 

62  Cincinnati-New  York/Newark 

63  Miami-Washington 

64  Chicago-Pittsburgh 

65  Atl anta- M iami 

66  San  Francisco-Washington 

67  Boston-Los  Angeles 

68  Columbus-New  York/Newark 

69  Chicago-Dallas/Fort  Worth 

70  Ontario-San  Francisco 

71  Dallas /Fort  Worth-San  Antonio 

72  Baltimore-New  York/Newark 

73  Detroit/Ann  Arbor-Los  Angeles 

74  Miami-Tampa 

See  footnotes  at  end  of  table. 


3 

1 

3 

6 

6 

3 

3 

1 

3 

3 

1 

1 

2 

3 

3 

1 

4 

I 

2 

2 

3 

3 

2 

4 

1 

1 

2 

2 

1 

3 

1 

3 

1 

1 

2 

2 

2 

1 

1 

2 

1 

6 

1 

3 

1 

1 

3 

1 

1 

2 

2 

6 

2 

1 

2 

1 

3 

1 

3 

3 

3 

3 

2 

2 

1 

2 

1 

3 

4 

1 

2 

3 

1 

I 


191 

355 
1,092 
721 
215 
2,453 
1,071 
101 
489 
2,574 
3  354 
3  324 
1,740 
410 
329 
8  379 
222 
227 
406 
238 
755 
289 
344 
591 
2,556 
3  342 
1,188 
256 
216 
252 
102 
1,003 
456 
274 
675 
860 
1,853 
358 
100 
312 
839 
1,363 
671 
882 
959 
1,258 
197 
1,017 
273 
2,288 
907 
1,416 
407 
2,399 
1,246 

3  311 

1,030 

3  389 

1,627 

941 

1,016 

579 

920 

404 

595 

2,430 

2,600 

472 

790 

S377 

253 

179 

I  988 

Iw 


2,  077,  000 
1,984,000 
1,930,000 
1,  785,  000 
1,738,000 
1,  092,  000 
871,000 
855,  000 
782,  000 
779,  000 
713,000 
666,  000 
653,  000 
623,  000 
619,  000 
588,  000 
580,  000 
575,  000 
570,  000 
565,  000 
549,  000 
517,  000 
476,  000 
458,  000 
454,  000 
454,  000 
436,  000 
429, 000 
424,  000 
401,  000 
397,  000 
396,  000 
394,  000 
393, 000 
376, 000 
376,  000 
374,  000 
373,000 
355,000 
353, 000 
348, 000 
347, 000 
340,  000 
339,  000 
327,000 
326, 000 
319,  000 
319, 000 
312,000 
309,  000 
305,  000 
300,  000 
294,  000 
294,  000 
292, 000 
286, 000 
283, 000 
281, 000 
277,  000 
270,  000 
269,  000 
267,  000 
265,  000 
263,  000 
256,  000 
255,000 
252,000 
250, 000 
244,000 
244,000 
240,000 
238,000 
235,000 
231.  00  C 


487 


APPENDIX  B 

TOP   100  ORIGIN-DESTINATION  CITY-PAIRS  i  IN  ORDER  OF  PASSENGER  RANK,  CAB-CERTIFICATED  AND 

CALIFORNIA/TEXAS    INTRASTATE  AIRLINES  (SCHEDULED   DOMESTIC  SERVICE,    1972)— Continued 


Rank  and  City-pair' 

Number  of 

airport 

pairs 

Intercity 
mileage  3 

Number  of 
origin- 
destination 
passengers 

303 

1,151 

597 

3  358 

3  J41 

S40 

1,906 

1,521 

1,177 

537 

540 

654 

956 

3  115 

i,172 

391 

254 

2,396 

1,445 

1,372 

132 

3  370 

1,5?6 

2,703 

150 

291 

231,  000 

76  Detroit/Ann  Arbor-Miami 

229,  000 

229,  000 

78  San  Jose-Santa  Ana                 .     

228,  000 

79  Burbank-Oakland 

227,  000 

80  Atlanta-Washington 

81  Chicago-Tampa 

226, 000 
225,  000 

82  Chicago-Las  Vegas 

223,  000 

83  New  Orleans-New  York/Newark 

84  Charlotte-New  York/iNewark 

223,  000 
222, 000 

208,  000 

86  Indianapolis-New  York/Newark 

87  Denver-San  Francisco 

208,  000 
206,  000 
200,  000 

89  Chicago-Fort  Lauderdale                                   

200, 000 

90  Detroit/Ann  Arbor-Washington 

200,  000 
19?,  000 

92  Los  Angeles-Philadelphia 

198,  000 

196, 000 

94  Houston-Los  Angeles                          

195,000 

95  Portland-Seattle 

195,  000 

193, 000 

97  Los  Angeles-Minneapolis/St.  Paul 

98  Boston-San  Francisco.. 

193,000 
191,000 
189,  000 

100  <  New  York/Newark-Norfolk 

186,  000 

'  As  defined  in  the  CAB  origin  and  destination  survay.  In  some  cases  the  CAB  combines  two  or  more  airports 
Origin-Destination  serving  one  city.  In  those  cases,  as  shown  above,  each  city-pair  includes  two  or  more  airport  pairs. 

■  As  specified  by  the  CAB.  In  some  cases  intercity  mileages  differ  slightly  from  inter-airport  mileages. 

3  Estimated  using  inter-airport  mileages. 

<  The  following  larger  intrastate  city-pairs  are  not  among  the  top  100  city-pairs:  Oakland-San  Diego  =  178,000;  Oakland- 
Santa  Ana  =  158,000;  Sacramento-San  Francisco  =  152,000;  San  Diego-San  Jose  =  139,000;  Sacramento-Santa  Ana  = 
92,000;  Ontario-San  Jose=91,000;  Houston-San  Antonio=89,000;  Ontario-Sacramento  =  79,000;  Burbank-Sacramento  = 
71,000;  Oakland-Ontario  =  65,000. 

Sources:    CAB,  "Handbook  of  Airline  Statistics,"  433  (1973  ed.). 

PUC,  "Form  1511    report"  number  33     (12   mos.  ended  Dec.  31,  1971   and  1972),   and    for    SANSFO/ 
OAK/SJC;  number  34  (12  mos.  ended  June  30,  1972  and  1973). 

Prepared  Statement  ob^  Dr.  John  R.  Summerfield 

My  name  is  John  R.  Summerfleld.  I  am  president  of  Summerfield  Associates, 
a  transportation  research  and  consulting  company. 

I  welcome  an  opportunity  to  discuss  with  this  subcommittee  a  topic  that  has 
interested  and  confused  politicians,  academicians  and  businessmen  alike:  namely, 
differences  l)etween  interstate  and  intrastate  airline  costs  and,  hence,  fare  levels. 
I  plan  to  demonstrate  the  low-cost  operation  of  the  California  intrastate  air 
carriers  is  a  disiippearin.s;  phenomenon.  Rcnuiiuits  of  the  aiiparent  low  cost  are 
attributable  to  isolation  from  the  integrated  f.S.  air  t  nuisportation  system,  not  to 
lack  of  regulation.  If  PSA  wen>  part  of  the  integrated  interstate  airline  system 
of  the  United  States,  the  airline  would  have  reported  a  loss  of  about  $8M.  million 
1974  instead  of  the  profit  of  $].<;  million  reported  earlier  this  week  (assuming 
48  percent  Federal  income  tax).  Despite  intra-California  fare  increases  that  have 
exceeded  those  approved  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Roard,  PSA's  profit  have  been 
declining  and  just  this  month  the  airline  has  begun  furloughing  employees  in  an 
attempt  to  offset  losses  in  the  last  half  of  1974. 

My  testimony  is  liased  on  a  study  I  conducted  to  determine  in  what  specific 
way.s  the  co.st  structures  of  the  two  California  intrastate  air  carriers— PSA  and 
Air  California— differ  from  cost  structures  of  tnmk  and  local  service  air  c-arriers. 

Regulation  is  not  the  issue.  Fares  of  Air  California  and  I'SA  are  regulated  ))y 
the  California  I'ublic  Itility  Commissirm  (Pl'C)  instead  of  by  the  CAR.  Pas- 
sengers purciiasing  tickets  within  California  for  travel  wholly  within  the  State 
pav  the  pre  fare.  Passengers  purchasing  tickets  outside  California  pay  the 
CAR  fare.  The  recr)rd  of  recent  years  clearly  demonstrates  that  the  PUC  is  as 
sensitive  to  carriers'  rising  costs  as  is  the  CAR  ;  in  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco 
market,  for  example,  the  PUC  has  granted  fare  increases  amounting  to  30.7  per- 


488 

cent  since  1969,  compared  with  CAB  authorized  increases  of  only  26.7  percent  in 
the  same  period.  The  PUC  also  controls  route  authority  within  California. 

If  not  regulation,  what  factors  do  account  for  the  apparent  lower  cost  structure 
of  an  intrastate  carrier?  To  answer  this  question,  it  is  useful  to  examine  the 
operation  of  the  two  California  intrastate  air  carriers.  Because  tJiey  are  intra- 
state carriers,  they  cannot  sell  tickets  to  passengers  traveling  outside  California. 
That  fact  alone  means  that  their  reservations  clerks  do  not  need  to  become 
involved  in  routing  a  passenger  to  remote  points,  in  computing  fares  on  trips 
connecting  to  other  carriers,  or  in  any  of  the  other  information  a  trunk  or  local 
service  carrier's  reservations  clerks  must  become  involved  in.  Because  of  these 
differences  the  average  reservation  call  to  an  interstate  carrier,  even  with  massive 
assistance  from  a  computer,  lasts  about  3  minutes,  compared  with  less  than  1 
minute  for  a  reseration  call  to  an  intrastate  carrier.  PSA  has  estimated  that  its 
reservation  service  costs  77  cents  per  passenger.  This  year  PSA  will  carry  about 
61/^  million  passengers.  If  it  had  to  handle  typical  reservation  loads  of  an  inter- 
state carrier  (3  minutes  vs.  1  minute  per  call),  its  costs  would  probably  be  at 
least  $1.50  per  passenger  higher,  or  an  extra  $9%  million  a  year.  In  1974,  PSA's 
profit  was  $1.6  million. 

Ticketing  economies  of  the  PSA  system  exist  for  the  same  reasons.  No  multiple 
stop  tickets  with  complex  routing  and  joint  fares  are  written.  Each  transaction 
is  a  point-to-point  trip  for  which  the  passenger  receives  a  cash  register  receipt 
that  serves  as  his  ticket.  Although  many  trunk  and  local  service  airline  tickets 
are  now  printed  by  computer,  the  multi-stop  tickets,  the  complex  ones  that  take 
so  long  when  you  are  standing  in  line  behind  a  traveller  with  a  long  itinerary,  are 
handwritten  and  fares  are  hand-computed.  If  PSA  had  to  sell  interline  tickets, 
its  average  cost  per  ticket  written  would  increase  substantially  because  of 
increased  complexity.  No  published  data  exist  to  enable  me  to  compute  the  size 
of  the  increase.  It  could  well  cost  an  extra  million  dollars  a  year  in  added 
administrative  costs. 

Trunk  and  local  service  airlines  must  provide  extensive  training  for  both 
reservations  clerks  and  ticket  agents.  Because  the  public  interest  requires  that 
the  air  transportation  system  be  integrated  and  interrelated,  trunk  and  local 
service  employees  must  be  able  to  route  a  traveller  to  any  designation  in  the 
world  and  be  able  to  find  the  correct  fare.  This  is  no  simple  task.  To  impart  and 
update  this  knowledge  and  skill,  trunk  and  local  service  carriers  spend  sub- 
stantial sums  for  training.  By  comparison,  intrastate  carriers'  training  costs  for 
these  categories  of  employees  are  very  much  lower. 

Revenue  accounting  is  a  third  function  in  which  PSA  saves  money  because 
it  does  not  sell  interline  tickets.  Trunk  and  local  service  carriers  employ  large 
staffs  of  revenue  accountants,  often  aided  by  computers,  to  determine,  among 
other  things,  how  much  their  airline  owes  other  airlines  for  interline  sales 
and  how  much  other  airlines  owe  them.  By  comparison,  PSA  needs  only  to  add 
the  cash  register  receipt  tickets  it  collects.  Here  again,  published  data  do  not 
enable  me  to  determine  how  much  more  it  would  cost  PSA  if  its  revenue  account- 
ing office  had  to  deal  with  interline  accounts.  It  would  probably  run  well  over 
$200,000  a  year. 

Because  it  doesn't  sell  interline  space,  therefore,  PSA  saves  about  $11  million 
a  year  compared  with  its  interstate  counterpart  airlines. 

It  cost  local  service  airlines  7.2  cents  per  passenger  to  file  and  publish  tariffs, 
schedules,  and  timetables  in  1973.  The  intrastate  carriers,  with  their  simpler 
route  structures  and  tariff,  structures,  were  able  to  accomplish  these  functions 
within  California  at  about  half  that  cost,  or  3.5  cents  per  passenger.  Faced  with 
the  complexity  of  interstate  operations,  PSA  would  have  to  spend  an  added  3.7 
cents  per  passenger,  or  nearly  $250,000  extra  a  year,  to  file  and  publish  its 
tariffs,  schedules  and  timetables. 

A  number  of  other  differences  between  the  cost  structure  of  inlrautate  carrier 
and  that  of  a  trunk  or  local  service  carrier  can  be  attributed  to  the  fact  that 
intrastate  carriers  serve  smaller  geographical  regions.  Since  the  longest  PSA 
flight  is  less  than  2  hours  and  nearly  all  are  less  than  1  hour,  PSA  serves  no  food. 
It  sells  cocktails  and  serves  complimentary  soft  drinks.  Profits  on  the  sale  of 
cocktails  cover  the  cost  of  soft  drinks.  By  contrast,  local  service  carriers  spend 
over  50  cents  per  passenger  on  food.  If  PSA  operated  a  route  structure  comparable 
to  that  of  a  typical  local  service  carrier,  its  food  service  would  cost  over  $3 
million. 


489 

Lack  of  food  service  provides  other  benefits  for  PSA  and  Air  California. 
Because  there  are  no  galleys  in  their  aircraft,  there  is  room  for  more  seats  and, 
therefore,  an  opportunity  to  increase  revenues  per  flight  at  very  little  extra 
operating  cost.  PSA's  Boeing  727-200  aircraft  have  158  seats;  and  interstate 
competitor  has  124  seats  in  the  same  aircraft  model.  That  27  percent  extra 
revenue  on  PSA's  busy  flights  in  the  heavily-traveled  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles 
market,  for  example,  can  contribute  as  much  as  $650,000  per  year  in  added 
revenue  on  PSA's  busy  flights  in  the  heavily-traveled  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles 
way  between  the  two  cities  (plus  eighteen  L-1011  weekly  flights  each  way).  Even 
if  the  extra  727-200  seats  are  sold  only  10  percent  of  the  time,  the  extra  capacity 
resulting  from  elimination  of  food  service  adds  more  than  $650,000  a  year  to 
PSA's  revenues  on  the  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles  run  alone.  Although  United 
can  refrain  from  serving  food  on  these  short  runs,  it  uses  its  aircraft  also  on 
longer  runs  that  require  food  service.  Hence,  it  must  forego  the  revenue  that 
galley  space  might  otherwise  provide. 

Another  attribute  of  the  geographically  limited  route  structure  of  PSA  and 
Air  California  is  that  very  few  crews  spend  their  nights  in  hotels  away  from 
home  base.  Because  flights  are  short,  scheduling  makes  it  possible  for  most  crews 
to  return  to  home  base  each  night.  For  safety  reasons  the  Federal  Aviation 
Administration  (FAA)  requires  that  crews  rest  after  long-crew  duty-time. 
Accordingly  carriers  with  long  route  segments  pay  hotel  and  meal  costs  for  a 
large  number  of  crews  each  night.  Much  more  costly,  however,  is  the  provision 
in  typical  union  contracts  that  flight  crews  receive  flight  pay  for  a  portion  of 
hours  on  the  ground  away  from  home  base.  Since  the  FAA  and  union  contracts 
both  specify  a  maximum  number  of  duty  hours,  crew  productivity  is  lower  for 
the  long-haul  carrier.  That  is,  becau.se  of  these  so-called  duty  rigs  and  trip  rigs 
in  union  contracts  and  more  crews  away  from  home  base,  trunk  and  local 
service  airline  pilots  fly  fewer  hours  within  the  same  maximum  duty  hour  limits. 
Cost  per  hour  of  actual  flying,  therefore,  is  much  higher  for  the  trunk  and  local 
service  carriers  than  for  the  intrastate  carriers.  Trunk  carriers  typically  pay 
pilots  about  20  hours  of  flight  pay  a  month  for  nonflying  activities,  thus  reducing 
their  actual  flying  time  to  about  50-55  hours  a  month.  If  PSA  were  to  lose  as 
much  flying  time  per  pilot  because  of  duty  and  trip  rigs  of  the  trunk  and  local 
service  carriers,  its  annual  flight  crew  costs  would  be  about  $3  million  higher. 

Differences  in  flight  crew  requirements  for  the  Boeing  737-200  account  for 
yet  another  saving  for  PSA  and  Air  California.  Trunk  carriers'  contracts  with 
the  Air  Line  Pilots  Association  require  a  three-man  flight  crew  despite  the  fact 
that  the  FAA  certificated  the  aircraft  for  a  two-man  flight  crew.  PSA  and 
Air  California  use  two-man  flights  crews.  If  PSA  required  the  third  man  in  the 
cockpit  of  its  four  Boeing  737's  it  would  incur  added  costs  of  about  $450,000 
per  year.  For  Air  California's  seven  Boeing  737's,  the  added  costs  would  amount 
to  about  $800,000  per  year. 

The  commuter  nature  of  the  intra-California  air  carriers  results  in  consider- 
ably less  baggage  per  flight  than  trunks  and  local-service  airlines  carry.  It  has 
been  observed,  for  example,  that  interstate  competitors  carry  more  than  twice  as 
much  baggage  per  727  flight  as  does  PSA.  For  the  same  speed  of  baggage  han- 
dling per  flight,  therefore,  PSA  needs  fewer  baggage  handlers.  PSA  also  carries 
little  freight.  Neither  baggage  nor  freight  are  transferred  from  PSA  .^o  another 
airline.  Reported  data  indicate  that  traffic  servicing  costs,  which  encompass 
passenger  and  baggage  handling  at  airports,  are  about  twice  as  higli  per  pas- 
senger on  both  trunk  and  local  service  airlines  as  on  the  California  intrastate 
airlines.  Excluding  the  economies  of  ticketing,  discussed  earlier,  and  allowing 
for  PSA's  greater  flexibility  in  crossing  union  jurisdictions,  it  is  estimated  that, 
if  PSA  operated  a  route  structure  more  nearly  like  those  of  either  trunk  or  local 
service  airlines,  PSA's  traffic  servicing  costs  would  increa.se  as  much  as  $2  million 
a  year. 

PSA's  low  cost  operation  is  rapidly  vanishing.  Its  earlier  non-union  status  is 
gone.  Unions  have  brought  pay  scales  in  line  with  those  of  the  rest  of  the  indus- 
try. A  few  years  ago.  PSA  operated  only  in  the  very  bu.sy  high  density  markets 
of  San  Diego,  three  Los  Angeles  airports,  three  San  Francisco  Bay  area  airports, 
and  the  State  capital  at  Sacramento.  Recently  PSA  began  service  at  The  less 
active  cities  of  Long  Beach.  Stockton  and  Fresno.  At  these  airports,  lower  traffic 
means  fewer  flights  and  more  idle  time  for  ground  crews  between  flights,  hence 
higher  unit  costs.  So  far,  these  low  density,  high  cost  stations  represent  only  a 
small  part  of  PSA's  operations.  If.  like  trunk  and  local-service  carriers,  PSA 
begins  to  serve  more  small  communities,  its  cost  will  increase  even  more. 


490 

PSA's  costs  have  been  rising :  Its  profits  fell  from  a  high  of  $6.9  million  in 
1972  to  $600,000  in  1973.  Fare  increases,  however,  produced  earnings  of  $2.7 
million  for  the  first  half  of  1974,  follo\ve<l  by  a  loss  of  $1.1  million  for  the  last 
half  of  the  year.  Intrastate  fares  increased  again  2  weeks  ago. 

The  following  quotation  from  a  September  1974,  PSA  application  to  the  PUC 
for  a  fare  increase  indicates  how  PSA  now  feels  about  fares  lower  than  those 
set  by  the  CAB:  "In  the  context  of  competition  between  interstate  and  intra- 
state carriers,  adequate  consideration  by  the  Commission  of  the  ratemaking 
principles  set  forth  by  the  CAB  will  contribute  to  the  policy  of  alleviating  .in- 
just  fare  discrimination  and  preferential  fares  inherent  in  a  dual  regulatory 
system.  .  .  .  Furthermore,  the  methodology  .  .  .  (used  in  the  CAB's  Domestic 
Passenger  Fare  Investigation)  will  assists  in  assuring  that  California  intra- 
state carriers  do  not  experience  disproportionately  low  or  confiscatory  rates 
of  return  in  relation  to  interstate  carriers  with  which  they  compete."  That  state- 
ment does  not  sound  like  a  confident  low  cost  carrier. 

Late  last  month  PSA  announced  indefinite  furloughs  for  100  stewardesses  and 
about  50  ramp  personnel  to  become  effective  February  1.  The  carrier  also  stated 
that  it  was  talking  with  representatives  of  the  pilots  about  possible  furloughs. 

In  summary,  Mr.  Chairman,  the  low-cost  operation  of  the  California  intra- 
state air  carriers  is  a  thing  of  the  past  except  for  that  portion  of  the  cost  struc- 
ture attributable  to  isolation  from  the  integrated  U.S.  air  transportation  .system. 

I  have  identified  and  quantified  the  following  factors  in  the  operating  environ- 
ment of  the  California  intrastate  air  carriers  that  differ  from  factors  in  the 
operating  environment  of  interstate  airlines. 

Annual  cost 

difference 

Factor :  [In  millions] 

Reservations   $9-  ^5 

Ticketing    1-  0 

Revenue  accounting 0.  2 

Tariffs,   schedules,   timetables .25 

Food  service 3.  0 

Additional  seats  in  aircraft -65 

Pilot  duty  and  flight  rigs 3.  0 

Extra  crew  member  in  737 •  45 

Trafiic  servicing 2.  0 

Total  identified 20.  30 

If  PSA  operated  interstate  routes  comparable  to  those  of  its  interstate  com- 
petitors, its  pre-tax  profits  would  be  diminished  by  about  $20  million  per  year 
and  it  would  be  seeking  an  even  larger  fare  increase  than  is  now  pending. 

SUMMERFIELD    ASSOCIATES,    INC. 

February  28,  1975. 
Mr.  Stephen  Breyer,  Special  Counsel, 
Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure, 
U.S.  Senate, 
Washington,  B.C. 

Dear  Mr.  Breyee  :  I  am  responding  to  your  invitation  at  the  conclusion  of  the 
February  14  hearings  in  Boston  to  send  comments  and  further  information  that 
might  assist  the  subcommittee  in  its  understanding  of  the  impact  of  air  carrier 
regulation.  Attached  are  two  short  papers.  Attachment  no.  1  addresses  several 
issues  embodied  in  Dr.  Jordan's  testimony.  Attachment  no.  2  addresses  the  10 
points  you  raised  in  Boston,  i.e.,  the  10  rpasons  advanced  to  explain  the  apparent 
lower  costs  of  PSA  vis-a-vis  trunk  and  local-sei-vice  carriers. 
If  I  can  be  of  further  assistance,  please  do  not  hesitate  to  ask. 
Sincerely  yours, 

John  R.  Summerfield. 
Attachment  1. 

Response  to  Testimony  of  Dr.  William  A.  Jordan 

This  memorandum  challenges  conclusions  that  Dr.  Jordan  stated  in  his  testi- 
mony before  the  subcommittee.  Most  misleading  is  his  allegation  tliat  regulation 
causes  high  labor  costs,  \^hereas  in  reality  labor  costs  are  high  or  not  as  a  result 
of  employee  seniority,  unionization,  and  productivity.  Productivity,  in  turn,  de- 


491 

pends  in  part  on  union  contract  clauses  and  in  part  of  characteristics  of  the  air- 
line as  outlined  in  my  testimony  (Is  it  geographically  limited?  Does  it  sell 
interline  space?). 

Other  points  I  wish  to  make  are  that  free  entry  has  resulted  in  high  bank- 
ruptcy rates  and  instability  ;  that  70  percent  average  load  factors  are  possible 
only  in  very  special  markets ;  and  that  longer  aircraft  life  is  not  determined  by 
Ihe  presejice  or  absence  of  regulation.  The  following  paragraphs  discuss  each  of 
these  4  points. 

/.  Costs  of  free  entry 

On  pages  5  and  G  of  his  testimony,  Dr.  Jordan  attempts  to  demonstrate  that, 
absent  regulation,  100  to  200  airlines  would  have  existed  during  the  period 
covered  by  his  earlier  study.  In  support  of  this  hypothesis,  Dr.  Jordan  points  out 
that  "two  hundred  and  one  commuter  air  carriers  operated  .  .  .  during  fiscal 
year  1973,  and  that  126  of  these  small  airlines  operated  for  the  entire  year."  With 
that  high  a  mortality  rate  (37  percent  in  one  year),  free  entry  would  result  in  a 
chaotic  industry.  Travellers  would  not  know  from  day-to-day  which  carrier  would 
still  be  in  business.  Dr.  Jordan  draws  the  wrong  conclusion  from  the  fact  that  no 
airline  bought  the  defunct  commuters.  Mergers  have  helped  trunk  and  local 
service  carriers  provide  a  continuity  of  service  to  the  public.  Experience  of  the 
largely  unregulated  sector  of  the  industry  has  shown  that  instability  may  well 
be  a  very  substantial  cost  of  deregulation. 

2.  Load  factors 

On  pages  o3  and  34  of  his  testimony,  Dr.  Jordan  alleges  that  70  percent 
passenger  load  factors  are  feasible  because  California  intrastate  airlines 
operated  at  or  above  70  percent  for  many  years.  It  is  important  to  understand, 
however,  that  average  load  factors  of  70  percent  are  feasible  only  under  special 
conditions.  The  intra-California  market  is  considerably  less  seasonal  than  are 
most  airline  markets.  In  most  markets,  when  time-of-day  peaking  is  super- 
imposed on  day-of-week  and  seasonal  peaking,  80  to  100  i>ercent  load  factor  flights 
are  not  enough  to  compensate  for  the  many  flights  with  load  factors  in  the  20  to 
50  percent  bracket.  Scheduling  alone  cannot  make  up  for  the  peaking  character- 
istics of  the  market.  Many  costs  are  fixed ;  hence  grounding  of  aircraft  in  olT- 
peak  periods  often  results  in  revenue  losses  that  exceed  those  costs  that  are 
saved  by  not  flying.  My  experience  both  at  Western  Airlines  and  at  Pan  Am 
has  convinced  me  that,  on  a  system  basis,  airlines  with  extensive  route  systems 
cannot  economically  operate  at  70  percent  system  load  factors  and  still  provide 
adequate  serAice  to  the  public. 

3.  Aircraft  life 

On  pages  33  and  34,  Dr.  Jordan  argues  that  regulation  causes  airlines  to  retire 
aircraft  too  early.  Quantitative  evidence  on  this  point  is  lacking.  In  the  California 
market,  however,  it  is  instructive  to  recall  that,  after  PSA's  introduction  of  the 
Lockheed  Electra  in  the  early  1060's,  Western  tried  to  comi)ete  in  the  Los 
Angeles-SanFrancisco  market  using  DC-6  aircraft  at  a  fare  of  $11.43  (several) 
dollars  less  than  PSA's  fare).  The  experiment  failed  to  attract  enough  passengers 
to  the  older  aircraft,  despite  the  lower  fare. 

A  further  point  on  failure  to  adopt  new  aircraft  types  is  the  cost  of  airport 
and  airways  congestion.  Were  it  not  for  the  (possibly  premature)  introduction 
of  wide  bodied  aircraft,  the  high  delay  rates  of  1D70  would  still  plague  airlines 
and  their  customers.  Largely  because  of  the.se  larger  aircraft  and  accompanying 
reduced  scliedules,  delay  rates  at  JFK  dropi>ed  from  42.6  per  thousand  operations 
in  1970  to  18.1  in  1971 ;  at  Los  Angeles  International  Aii-port,  from  8.0  to  0.7. 
(These  rates  are  those  recorded  by  FAA  and  measure  only  delays  of  30  minutes 
or  more  at  the  departure  or  arrival  trafiic  control  center.  Hence  absolute 
numbers  are  deceptively  low  as  measures  of  delay.) 

Finally,  new  aircraft  types  are  introduced  because  they  offer  economies  of 
operation  and  other  improvements,  such  as  better  fuel  economy  and  reduced 
noise  levels.  An  air  transport  system  that  discourages  modernization  of  the  fleet 
would  result  in  aggravated  pollution,  especially  in  the  vicinity  of  airports. 

4.  Labor  costs 

On  pages  40  to  42  of  his  testimony.  Dr.  Jordan  attempts  to  .show  that  regulation 
causes  high  labor  costs.  To  address  this  issue,  it  is  helpful  to  consider  both 
wage  rates  and  productivity.  Wage  scales  dei)end  on  management  philosophy 
and  employee  bargaining  strength,   tempered  occasionally  by   consideration   of 


492 

the  company's  financial  situation.  New  airlines  may  not  be  unionized  at  first; 
but  if  they  survive  the  initial  years,  most  become  unionized  and  wage  scales  within 
the  industry  tend  to  become  identical.  I  have  determined,  for  example,  that 
PSA  and  Western  now  pay  pilots  at  approximately  the  same  hourly  rate  for  the 
.same  seniority.  PSA's  wage  costs,  however,  are  lower  because,  as  a  younger  air- 
line, average  seniority  is  lower.  In  the  case  of  pilots,  however,  the  main  differ- 
ence in  wage  costs  comes  from  productivity.  As  I  stated  in  my  written  testimony  : 

".  .  .  because  of  these  so-called  duty  rigs  and  trip  rigs  in  union  contracts 
and  more  crews  away  from  home  base,  trunk  and  local-service  airline  pilots 
fly  lewer  hours  within  the  same  maximum  duty  hour  limits.  Cost  per  hour  of 
actual  flying,  therefore,  is  much  higher  for  the  trunk  and  local-service  carriers 
than  for  the  intrastate  carriers.  Trunk  carriers  typically  pay  pilots  about  20 
hours  of  flight  pay  a  month  for  non-flying  activities,  thus  reducing  their  actual 
flying  time  to  about  50-55  hours  a  month." 

In  that  testimony,  I  also  identifietl  many  other  elements  of  productivity  dif- 
ferences attributable  to  the  nature  of  an  intrastate  carrier.  Specifically,  I 
identified  a  3-to-l  difference  in  productivity  of  reservations  clerks  because  intra- 
state carriers  do  not  handle  interline  business.  Similar  productivity  differences 
were  established  in  my  testimony  for  ticketing,  revenue  accoimting,  food  service, 
aircraft  seating  configuration,  extra  pilots  in  737  aircraft,  baggage  and  freight 
handling,  ti-aining  of  reservation  and  ticketing  personnel,  and  service  at  low- 
density  airports. 

To  achieve  the  low  labor  costs  that  Dr.  Jordan  believes  it  is  possible  to  achieve, 
we  must  envisage  a  series  of  new  airlines,  each  of  which  ceases  oi>eration  before 
its  employees  attain  either  seniority  or  union  representation.  That  pattern  of  in- 
stability is  lUilikely  to  benefit  the  traveling  public. 

In  summary,  although  I  have  no  major  quarrel  with  the  data  presented  by 
Dr.  Jordan,  I  disagree  with  many  of  the  conclusions  he  draws  from  the  data. 

Specifically,  I  conclude  that : 

1.  Free  entry  and  exit  would  cause  major  instability  in  airline  service ; 

2.  Seventy  per  cent  load  factors  are  not  feasible  for  the  industry  as  a  whole  on 
a  year-around  basis ; 

3.  Regulation  is  not  a  determining  factor  in  aircraft  life ;  and 

4.  Labor  costs  are  high  or  low  because  of  airline  age,  unionization,  and  route 
characteristics,  not  because  of  regulation  or  its  absence. 

[The  memorandum  referred  to  in  the  following  attachment  is 
printed  on  pp.  515-17,  below.] 

Attachment  2 

Reasons  Advanced  by  Mr.  Breyeb  To  Explain  Apparent  Low  Cost  of  PSA 
Operations 

This  memorandum  contains  comments  on  10  reasons  for  PSA's  lower  costs,  as 
listed  by  Mr.  Stephen  Breyer  at  the  Boston  hearings  of  the  Subcommittee  on 
Administrative   Practice   and   Procedure  on  February  14,  1975. 

Questions  1  and  7.  Weather  and  airport  congestion. — Citing  minor  differences 
in  flights  not  completed.  Mr.  Breyer  concluded  that  neither  weather  nor  airport 
congestion  contributed  substantially  to  cost  differences.  High  completion  rates, 
however,  cost  more  in  regions  with  higher  delay  rates.  At  the  hearings,  American 
Airlines  stated  that  50  percent  of  its  flights  encountered  ground  or  air  traffic 
delays  at  LaGuardia  compared  with  20  percent  at  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco. 
Official  delay  statistics  collected  by  FAA  indicate  that  only  12.7  flights  per 
thousand  suffered  delays  at  LaGuardia  in  1974.  However,  the  reported  data  in- 
clude only  delays  of  30  minutes  or  more  at  the  departure  or  arrival  air  traffic 
control  center.  If  American's  experience  at  LaGuardia  is  typical,  more  than 
160,000  flights  were  delayed  at  LaGuardia  in  1974.  If  average  delays  were  as 
little  as  10  minutes,  delays  cost  airlines  about  $25  million  in  direct  operating 
costs  last  year  at  LaGuardia  alone.  Officially  reported  delay  rates  at  Los  Angeles 
last  year  were  one-seventh  as  high  as  at  LaGuardia. 

I  have  sought  to  reconcile  these  data  with  the  block-to-block  statistics  to  which 
Mr.  Breyer  referred  at  the  Boston  hearings.  I  believe  that  the  discrepancy  may 
be  a  result  of  the  practice  of  airlines,  following  the  fuel  crisis,  of  waiting  to  leave 
gate  positions  until  cleared  for  take-off.  This  practice  conceals  departure  delays 
in  the  block-to-block  statistics.  When  these  delays  exceed  30  minutes,  however, 
they  do  appear  in  FAA's  delay  statistics.  American's  data  presumably  consider 
all  ground  and  air  traffic  delays  regardless  of  whether  engines  have  been  started 
or  not. 


493 

Question  2.  Traffic  density. — It  was  stated  that  traffic  densities  between  city- 
pairs  did  not  account  for  major  differences  for  markets  carrying  at  least  100,000 
yearly  passengers.  Trunk  and  local  service  airlines  serve  many  markets  of  lower 
density  than  100,000  a  year.  As  pointed  out  on  page  5  of  my  testimony,  further- 
more, airport  costs  are  very  sensitive  to  volume  at  the  low  volume  end  of  the 
scale.  If  few  flights  serve  an  airport,  airline  personnel  and  equipment  are  under- 
utilized and  units  costs  are  therefore  high. 

By  contrast,  at  airports  like  LaGuardia,  Washington  National  and  Los  Angeles, 
to  name  just  a  few,  ground  crews  and  equipment  are  busy  most  of  the  time  for 
14  to  16  hours  a  day.  PSA  only  recently  added  low-utilization  stations  to  its 
route  structure.  Its  rising  unit  costs  are  in  part  a  result  of  the  change. 

Question.  3.  Seasonality  patterns. — The  intra-California  markets  are  more 
heavily  business  markets  than  most  other  U.S.  markets  and  hence  not  as  subject 
to  vacation  peaking.  Hour-of-day  and  day-of-week  peaking  are  not  readily  meas- 
urable from  published  data.  My  experience  in  the  California  and  other  markets 
leads  me  to  the  conclusion  that  the  intra-California  markets  are  less  peaked  than 
other  markets.  Hence  it  is  possible  to  operate  at  higher  average  load  factors 
within  California.  This  point  is  clearly  not  related  to  the  regulation  issue. 

Question  4.  Extra  interline  costs. — These  are  the  costs  covered  in  the  first  part 
of  my  February  14  testimony.  Dr.  Jordan  challenged  my  comparison  by  stating 
that  an  intrastate  traveller  would  still  make  a  brief  call  for  reservations  even  if 
PSA  could  accept  interline  business.  He  missed  the  point  that  the  mix  of  calls 
would  change  and  would  be  similar  to  Western's  or  United's  with  more  short  calls 
and  some  long  calls.  The  argument  that  the  added  costs  would  be  offset  by  added 
revenue  also  misses  the  point.  I  cited  the  differences  only  to  explain  why  a  self- 
contained  system  is  cheaper  to  run.  But  if  the  entire  air  transport  system 
operated  that  way  there  would  be  no  system.  Interline  connections  would  be 
virtually  impossible  and  the  public  would  be  greatly  inconvenienced. 

Question  5.   Other  costs  identified   hy  Dr.   Summcrfield. — Actually  there  are 
cost  differences  I  did  not  attempt  to  quantify  that  might,  if  measureable,  add  up 
to  a  considerable  amount.  My  testimony  mentioned  low-density  airports,  training 
for  interline  traffic  handling,  and  overnight  expenses  of  crews. 
Question  6.  Different  aircraft. — No  further  comments. 
Question  7.  Airport  congestion. — See  No.  1. 

Question  8.  Regulatory  co.^ts.— These  are  hard  to  define.  CAB  form  41  reports 
do  not  require  separation  of  regulatory  costs.  Airlines  I  have  queried  do  not  keep 
separate  records  of  the  costs  of  dealing  with  CAB  versus  PUC  or  even  the  total 
costs  of  regulatory  activities.  CAB  regulatory  proceedings  tend  to  be  more  pro- 
tracted, principally  because  more  parties  are  involved  and  more  issues  are  raised. 
Question  9.  Cross  subsidy. — Profitable  routes  do  subsidize  unprofitable  routes 
for  most  airlines.  The  chart  accompanying  Dr.  Ehrlich's  testimony  of  February  14 
indicates  that  the  CAB  expects  to  continue  the  practice  of  long-haul  routes  sub- 
sidizing short-haul  routes.  In  addition,  high-density  routes  subsidize  low-densitv 
routes,  though  no  formula  exists  to  recognize  this  fact.  My  personal  experience 
makes  it  clear  that  cross-subsidy  is  a  fact  of  airline  life!  If  exit  were  free,  I 
have  no  doubt  that  many  communities  would  find  themselves  without  service 
from  trunk  or  local  service  air  carriers. 

A  special  form  of  cross-subsidy  exists  when,  for  example,  American  Airlines 
extends  its  New  York-Los  Angeles  fiight  to  San  Diego.  The  Los  Angeles-San 
Diego  flight  may  lose  money  on  a  fully  allocated  cost  basis,  but  marginal  costs 
may  well  be  less  than  marginal  revenue.  American  has  a  better  chance  of  moving 
a  New  York-San  Diego  passenger  on  its  own  long-haul  leg  if  the  passenger  can 
continue  to  his  final  destination  without  change  of  plane.  In  this  case  (and  there 
are  hundreds  like  it)  the  long-haul  passenger  may  be  subsidizing  the  short-haul 
passenger  on  the  same  fiight.  But  the  added  convenience  of  a  through  fiight  makes 
this  arrangement  highly  beneficial  to  the  travelling  public. 

At  the  Boston  hearings,  it  was  stated  that  DOT  claims  there  is  no  cross 
subsidy  in  the  present  system.  I  believe  that  this  is  a  mistaken  impression  and 
that  DOT  is  on  record  only  as  opposing  cross  subsidy.  You  will  no  doubt  wish 
to  check  this  point. 

Question  10.  Load  factor  and  number  of  seats.— My  testimonv  confirms  dif- 
ferences in  number  of  seats  and  provides  an  explanation  for  the  differences.  Load 
factor  differences  are  not  easy  to  document  since  PSA  has  not  published  load 
factors  for  some  years.  Air  California,  however,  did  report  a  1974  system  average 
load  factor  of  70.8  percent.  As  mentioned  in  No.  3  above,  California  markets 


494 

are  not  typical.  Peaks  and  troughs  are  not  as  pronounced.  In  addition,  the  Cali- 
fornia intrastate  carriers  do  not  operate  any  routes  with  very  low-load  factors. 
Most  trunk  and  local  service  airlines  still  serve  cities  whose  traffic  needs  were 
well  served  by  DC-3  aircraft  but  whose  traffic  has  not  grown  over  the  years.  Even 
minimum  service  to  these  communities  results  in  very  low-load  factors  with  to- 
day's aircraft — load  factors  that  intrastate  carriers  never  experience. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  would  next  like  to  welcome  Mr.  Richard  J. 
O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  Mr. 
O'Melia  has  been  a  member  of  the  CAB  staff  since  1957.  He  served  as 
Assistant  to  the  Office  of  General  Counsel,  Deputy  Director  of  the 
Bureau  of  International  Affairs  and  Director  of  the  Board's  Bureau 
of  Enforcement. 

Appearino;  witli  Mr.  O'Melia  are  Thomas  J.  Heye,  Administrative 
Assistant  to  the  Chairman ;  Arthur  H.  Sims,  Acting  Deputy  Director 
of  the  Bureau  of  Economics;  and  William  B.  Caldwell,  Jr.,  Director 
of  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights. 

STATEMENT  OF  RICHARD  J.  O'MELIA,  ACTING  CHAIRMAN,  CIVIL 
AERONAUTICS  BOARD,  ACCOMPANIED  BY  THOMAS  J.  HEYE, 
ADMINISTRATIVE  ASSISTANT  TO  THE  CHAIRMAN;  ARTHUR  H. 
SIMMS,  ACTING  DEPUTY  DIRECTOR  OF  THE  BUREAU  OF  ECO- 
NOMICS; AND  WILLIAM  B.  CALDWELL,  JR.,  DIRECTOR  OF  THE 
BUREAU  OF  OPERATING  RIGHTS 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  have  heard  a  lot  of 
mention  of  the  CAB  sitting  in  the  back  of  the  room,  and  just  being 
appointed  Chairman  of  the  CAB,  I  certainly  welcome  these  hearings, 
because  if  there  is  a  better  way  to  operate  the  CAB,  I  certainly  welcome 
it. 

I  will  cut  my  prej^ared  remarks  down  to  about  2  minutes. 

cab's  new  fare  formula 

To  begin  with,  let  me  explain  briefly  the  w^ords  "basic  ratemaking 
approach."  This  involves  the  establishment  of  fares  for  a  large  number 
of  airlines  which  operate  over  a  competitive  and  interlining  system 
involving  short-haul  and  long-haul  markets,  big  cities  and  small  com- 
munities, markets  which  have  many  passengers  and  markets  which 
have  only  a  few  passengers.  Airline  costs  vary  from  market  to  market 
as  you  have  heard  this  morning  and  within  markets  compared  to  the 
carrier. 

The  competitive  markets,  of  course  the  economics  are  such  that  all 
airlines  must  operate  at  the  same  fare  irres2:)ective  of  their  own  partic- 
ular cost.  As  a  result  there  is  no  practical  way  for  the  Board  to  tailor 
fares  so  as  to  meet  each  airline's  own  revenue  requirement  and  reflect 
the  distinct  operational  characteristics.  Instead,  the  Board  established 
a  uniform  fare  fornnila,  which  means  that  the  fares  are  based  on  the 
revenue  requirements  of  the  trunkline  industry  as  a  group  and  fares 
with  comparable  mileages  are  the  same.  The  system  isn't  perfect,  but 
nonetheless  represents  what  the  Board  has  considered  to  be  a  reason- 
able balance  of  all  the  equities. 

I  direct  the  subcommittee's  attention  to  my  prepai'ed  testimony 
which  includes  a  more  detailed  discussion  of  the  industrywide 
ratemakine;. 


495 

DIFFERENCES   BETWEEN   INTRASTATE  AND   INTERSTATE   SERVICE 

Operations  by  a  large  intrastate  airline  such  as  PSA  or  Southwest 
Airlines  involve  exactly  the  opposite  considerations.  Service  by  these 
airlines  is  performed  in  markets  which  have  nearly  optimum  opera- 
tional characteristics.  These  intrastate  operators  serve  only  a  few 
points,  almost  all  of  them  large  cities,  and  generally  j^rovide  com- 
muter-type service  in  markets  which  generate  a  large  volume  of  traf- 
fic. As  a  result,  these  intrastate  operators  have  less  need  for  different 
aircraft  types  to  cope  with  differing  traffic  densities  or  stage  lengths, 
and  have  little  problem  with  respect  to  positioning  of  aircraft.  On 
the  contrary,  they  can  successfully  employ  wide-bodied  aircraft,  which 
are  extremely  efficient,  they  can  configure  their  aircraft  for  high  den- 
sity operation,  and  operate  at  extremely  high  load  factors. 

In  other  words,  the  intrastate  operators  can  fine  tune  their  opera- 
tion to  the  special  needs  of  the  new  markets  they  serve,  and  there  is 
no  doubt  that  they  can  hold  down  the  costs  of  operating  and  as  a 
result  offer  service  at  a  very  attractive  fare. 

Clearly,  PSA  has  been  able  to  achieve  efficiencies  in  its  Los  Angeles- 
San  Francisco  service  which  the  intrastate  Texas  airline,  Southwest. 
for  example,  is  unable  to  match  over  its  routes,  and  which,  in  fact,  PSA 
itself  cannot  duplicate  in  its  other  markets. 

I  would  call  the  subcommittee's  attention  to  the  chart  attached  to 
my  prepared  testimony  with  details  of  comparisons  between  interstate 
operations  for  a  selected  month. 

CAB    POLICY    ON    FARE    COMPETITION 

Let  me  turn,  for  just  a  moment,  to  the  question  of  competitive  pric- 
ing. A  proposal  for  competitive  price  often  referred  to  as  a  flexible 
fare  formula  was  presented  to  the  Board  in  the  recent  passenger  fare 
investigation.  I  have  included  with  my  testimony  the  Board's  rather 
extensive  disposition  of  that  question.  I  did  not  participate  in  the 
Board's  decisions  on  that  issue,  but  it  seems  to  me  the  Board  was  say- 
ing that  a  flexible  fare  formula  just  won't  work  as  long  as  Congress 
wishes  to  continue  to  have  a  regulated  system  with  limited  entry. 

Let  me  make  one  final  observation  with  respect  to  a  regulatory  sys- 
tem. The  Congress  has  given  the  Board  what  I  think  sliould  properly 
be  described  as  a  balanced  mandate,  a  mandate,  in  other  Avords,  to  pro- 
vide good  service  to  the  traveler  and  shipper  at  a  reasonable  price 
and  with  profits  to  the  airlines  such  to  permit  their  continued  growth 
and  development.  The  Board's  job  is  always  more  difficult  in  times 
of  economic  downturn  when  airlines  seek  to  reduce  service  to  save 
money  or  raise  fares  to  cover  increased  costs.  But  the  traveling  public 
would  like  to  continue  the  same  quality  of  service  and  the  same  fares 
that  prevailed  in  better  economic  times. 

The  current  economic  circumstances  brought  about  in  large  part  by 
the  unprecedented  rise  of  fuel  prices  is  virtually  without  parallel  in 
aviation  history. 

I  want  to  assure  this  subcommittee  that  the  Board  has  taken  a  long 
hard  look  at  its  regulatory  responsibility  in  light  of  the  drastic  change 
in  economic  conditions. 

If  you  have  any  questions.  Senator,  we  will  try  and  answer  them. 


496 

CAB   STATF   STUDY   OF   PSA -TYPE   SERVICE 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  you  familiar  with  the  1965  staff  study  on 
PSA  ?  This  study  concluded  that  while  using  low  fares  PSA  attracted 
the  traffic  of  competitors,  reduced  their  fares,  brought  down  average 
fares,  and  expanded  total  revenue  far  above  what  it  would  have  been ; 
and,  as  I  understand,  during  that  time  PSA  made  healthy  profits. 
Are  you  familiar  with  that? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  am  familiar  with  it,  but  when  I  don't  know  an 
answer  I  would  like  to  address  it  to 

Senator  Kennedy.  Given  that  kind  of  result,  what  takes  place  in 
the  Board  when  you  receive  a  study  like  that  ?  What  kind  of  f ollowup 
is  there  when  you  see  something  that  appears  to  be  working  effec- 
tively ?  It  seems  that  there  was  a  favorable  report  submitted. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  am  not  sure  what  happened  to  it  because  I  wasn't 
there,  but  that  was  an  intrastate  study,  Senator,  wdiich  the  Board  had 
no  regulatory  control  over  the  operation  of  an  intrastate  air  carrier. 
So  I  presume  it  was  a  study  that  was  given  for  information  for  the 
Board  members  to  look  at.  What  they  did  with  it,  I  have  no  knowledge. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  think  that  it  has  any  lessons  for  in- 
terstate carriers?  Or,  is  it  dismissed  out  of  hand,  as  something  that 
works  well  for  intrastate  but  not  interstate? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  As  far  as  I  am  concerned,  if  it  were  brought  up  to 
date  now,  and  I  am  sure  these  hearings  will  bring  it  up  to  date,  and 
as  far  as  I  am  personally  concerned  as  one  Board  member,  I  am  very 
interested  in  having  that. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  does  that  really  mean,  besides  interest? 
Will  you  be  a  little  bit  more  specific? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Yes,  I  will.  If  the  ratemaking  system  which  the  Board 
has  evolved  over  the  years  has  some  defects  in  it  based  on  the  cost 
studies  that  you  are  finding  here  today  are  what  PSA  has,  certainly 
the  airlines  might  find  a  way  to  cut  costs  and  save  fuel  and  if  they 
can  do  that  the  Board  as  Avell  Avill  certainly  benefit  by  it. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  do  have  some  influence  over  these  kinds  of 
efficiencies,  don't  you  ?  You  could  encourage  development  of  a  similar 
service  or  give  direction  to  a  carrier  who  wants  to  duplicate  that  serv- 
ice from  Boston  to  Washington.  You  could  do  that,  could  you  not,  if 
the  Board  wanted  to  do  it  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Yes. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Then  you  can  do  something  about  it. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Oh,  yes,  the  Board  can  consider  any  applications. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Given  at  least  some  of  these  figures,  if  they  hold 
up,  would  you  consider  it  if  some  other  grou^)  wanted  to  come  in,  not 
one  of  the  major  trunk  carriers,  and  wanted  to  provide  this  kind  of 
service  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Absolutely. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  hold  a  hearing  on  that  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  a  PSA-type  service  work  along  the  east 
coast,  do  you  think  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Mr.  Caldwell,  do  you  have  any  thoughts  on  this 
question  ? 


497 

Mr.  Caldwell.  Well,  I  think  one  of  the  problems  is,  Senator,  if  you 
look  at  the  California  situation,  particularly  since  it  is  older,  you 
have — it  isn't  a  question  of  reo;ulations  versus  no  regulations.  It  is 
i-eally  the  type  of  regulation.  The  California  PUC,  as  I  understand 
their  policies,  certificate  air  carriers  much  like  public  utilities.  You 
have  one  light  company,  you  have  one  air  carrier  in  each  of  the  major 
markets  in  California.  You  do  not  have  competitive  intrastate  laws. 
The  comeptition  that  PSA  has  is  furnished  by  the  CAB  certificated 
carriers  as  far  as  the  flights  go. 

I  think  the  occasion  for  the  possibility  of  duplicating  the  number 
of  points  and  the  distances  the  PSA  operates  are  very  remote,  indeed, 
to  find  that  type  of  situation  in  other  areas  of  the  United  States.  You 
have,  as  I  think  they  are  representative  of  one  of  the  two  carriers 
indicated,  they  are  blessed  with  much  better  flying  weather  than  we 
find  on  the  east  coast  or  probably  in  most  other  portions  of  the  country 
except  possibly  Florida;  therefore,  they  are  less  apt  to  spend  costly 
time  in  the  air  between  their  points,  and  obviously  their  costs  are 
lower.  They  are  not  burdened  with  providing  service.  They  are  not 
required  to  have  the  burden  by  the  PUC  of  providing  service  to  the 
less  dense  city  fares  in  California. 

Now,  obviously  if  you  could  design  a  system  in  the  United  States 
that  had  an  average  density  that  PSA  has  in  California,  then,  one, 
I  think  its  cost  structure  would  be  entirely  different  than  what  we 
see  out  there  today  and  I  think  the  fares  would  be  different  than  what 
we  see  today. 

CROSS-SUBSIDY   AND   SMALL   TOWN   SERVICE 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  am  going  to  have  to  leave  at  half  past  12,  but 
I  want  to  give  the  carriers  a  chance  to  present  their  testimony.  I  won't 
be  able  to  finish,  but  counsel  will  have  additional  questions. 

As  I  understand  it.  DOT  has  told  us  there  is  no  cross  subsidy.  The 
ATA  indicated  they  are  doing  a  study.  Can  we  find  that  out  ? 

Mr.  SiMMS.  Well,  I  can't  speak  for  the  Board,  Senator. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  one  be  done?  ATA  thinks  so. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  Well,  I  think  we  certainly  can  do  a  study.  A  lot  depends 
upon  the  time  parameter 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  bet  if  you  did  it,  it  would  be  a  good  one. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  A  lot  depends  on  the  amount  of  resources  we  have  to 
go  into. 

Could  I  finish  my  last  point  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes,  fine. 

Mr.  Si^iMS.  That  is  this.  That  at  the  present  time  the  Board 
subsidized  local  carriers,  ineligible  service  carriers  operate  routes 
given  to  them  for  the  purpose  of  enabling  them  to  make  profits  which 
can  be  used  to  cross-subsidize  their  eligible  services.  At  the  present 
time,  according  to  the  latest  figures,  the  carriers  are  making  excess 
earnings  on  profitable  segments  that  amount  to  something  like  $29  mil- 
lion. That  compares  to  the  overall  subsidv  need,  computed  before  that, 
of  something  in  the  areas  of  $70-$80  million.  So  that  there  is  some 
hard  evidence  right  there  that  cross-subsidization  does  exist,  and  th«t 
it  can — and  that  cross-subsidization  is  a  fact. 


51-146  O  -  76  -  pt. 


498 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  could  do  a  study  of  that,  I  think  it  would 
be  extremely  helpful. 

I  would  like  to  make  a  final  point  about  the  differences  between- 
intrastate  and  interstate  fares.  We  have  mentioned  many  thinp:s  ex- 
cept one,  which  I  think  is  a  very  important  factor.  When  you  come 
ri^ht  down  to  it,  the  significant  difference  is  that  the  consumer  is 
offered  a  low  fare  without  all  the  frills.  More  seats  and  no  food  and 
beverages  result  in  a  lower-cost  operation  ;  that  cost  is  passed  on  to  the 
consumer,  and  it  has  been  welcomed  by  him.  They  don't  seem  to  com- 
plain that  there  are  no  first-class  seats,  or  that  they  are  not  getting  a 
variety  of  services.  I  can't  understand  why  consumers  in  other  parts  of 
the  country  aren't  entitled  at  least  to  that  choice. 

We  can  talk  about  all  these  other  facts,  about  Avhether  the  weather 
variations  result  in  higher  costs,  or  the  time  in  the  air.  or  density 
factors. 

We  find  out  less-dense  areas  out  in  California  are  making  a  profit. 
We  find  that  the  kinds  of  planes  the  airlines  use  are  just  about  the 
same,  that  neither  the  time  in  the  air,  nor  the  weather  make  a  great 
deal  of  difference.  But  there  is  a  significant  difference  in  the  number 
of  seats,  the  elimination  of  hrst  class  and  all  the  frills,  and  it  does 
show  up  in  terms  of  price  to  the  consumer.  The  public  is  not  offered 
that  choice  in  other  parts  of  the  country,  and  the  real  question  is  what 
can  be  done. 

One  alternative  is  to  go  completely  without  any  regulations.  Another 
is  to  move  toward  permitting  the  development  of  alternative  services. 

I  appreciate  your  presence  here,  and  I  apologize  that  we  are  not 
able  to  continue  at  this  time. 

If  you  want  to  make  any  comments  or  responses  I  will  be  glad  to 
hear  them. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  want  to  sav  we  will  he.  glad  to  work  with  vour 
staff. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  It  is  kind  of  you  to  be 
with  us  this  morning. 

Commissioner  Murphy,  I  Avant  to  thank  you  very  much  for  coming 
up  in  response  to  these  questions. 

[The  statement  of  Richard  O'Melia  follows:] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Richard  J.  O'Melia 

Senator  Kennedy,  this  is  my  first  appearance  before  this  subcommittee  as  the 
Acting  Chairman  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  The  hearings  you  have  con- 
vened are  exploring  a  number  of  facets  of  cardinal  importance  to  the  work  of  the 
Board.  I  am  pleased  to  be  here  to  contribute  to  the  efforts  of  this  subcommittee 
to  conduct  an  incisive  and  productive  examination  of  the  Board  and  its  processes, 
and  can  assure  you  that  we  will  study  with  great  attention  the  views  expressed 
in  these  hearings  and  the  report  that  your  subcommittee  will  issue  as  a  result 
of  these  hearings. 

We  have  been  advised  by  your  staff  that  the  topic  for  this  session  of  the 
hearings  is  a  comparison  of  state  and  Federal  regulation  of  air  transport  and 
a  comparison  of  interstate  air  fares  and  intrastate  air  fares.  I  would  like  to 
offer  a  few  preliminary  observations  of  a  general  nature  concerning  this  topic 
before  entering  into  a  more  detailed  look  at  the  question  of  intrastate  and 
interstate  fares. 

As  this  subcommittee  is  aware,  I  was  appointed  a  member  of  the  Board  in 
November  1973,  and  was  designated  by  the  President  as  Vice  Chairman,  and 
accordingly  Acting  Chairman,  effective  at  the  beginning  of  last  month.  As  a 


499 

result  I  have  not  had  personal  experience  of  long  duration  with  some  of  the 
Board's  actions  affecting  this  subject.  In  particular,  I  was  not  a  member  of  the 
Board  at  the  time  the  basic  decisions  were  made  in  the  Board's  Domestic  Pas- 
senger Fare  Investigation,  which  have  great  pertinence  to  our  topic.  Neverthe- 
less, I  want  to  try  to  set  forth  the  problem  and  issues  involved  in  the  most  direct 
manner  possible. 

Before  entering  into  the  question  of  intrastate  and  interstate  fares,  which 
is  the  specific  subject  under  discussion,  let  me  mention  briefly  the  authority 
which  Congress  has  given  the  Board  in  the  Federal  Aviation  Act.  In  that  Act, 
Congress  charged  the  Board  with  tlae  taslc  of  encouraging  the  development  of 
an  economically  sound  air  transportation  system  designed  to  meet  the  needs  of 
the  domestic  and  foreign  commerce,  of  the  Postal  Service,  and  of  the  national 
defense.  However,  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  does  not,  by  its  terms,  give  the 
Board  comprehensive  authority  over  all  air  transport  regulation.  Instead, 
Congress  has  left,  to  use  a  phrase  often  quoted,  "a  residuum  of  power  in  the 
states  to  mal<;e   laws  governing  matters  of  local  concern  *  *  *." 

Now,  although  the  Board's  authority  is  limited  by  statute,  its  responsibilities 
and  objectives  are  nonetheless  nationwide  in  scope.  The  states,  on  the  other  hand, 
have  responsibilities  and  objectives  which  are  much  more  limited.  Therefore, 
Mr.  Chairman,  in  examining  the  question  of  why  intrastate  fares  are  lower 
than  interstate  fares,  we  must  remember  that  the  regulatory  responsibility 
established  for  the  Board  by  the  Congress  involves  the  nation  as  a  whole,  and 
is  not  necessarily  the  j-ame  as  a  state  may  establish  within  its  own  borders. 
Furthermore,  and  even  more  important,  I  believe  that  the  basic  economic  charac- 
teristics affecting  intra.state  operations  by  carriers  like  PSA  or  Southwest  are 
quite  different  from  those  affecting  interstate  operations  by  carriers  regulated 
by  the  Board.  With  these  general  considerations  in  mind,  let  me  now  discuss 
briefly  the  pricing  considerations  with  respect  to  airlines  subject  to  the  Board's 
jurisdiction  and  then  contrast  them  with  pricing  considerations  affecting  the 
intrastate  operators. 

Pricing  considerations  of  interstate  carriers 

To  begin  with,  let  me  explain  briefly  the  Board's  basic  ratemaking  approach. 
That  approach  necessarily  involves  the  establishment  of  faires  for  a  large  number 
of  airlines  which  operate  over  a  competitive  and  interlacing  route  system.  That 
route  system  comprises  short-haul  and  long-haul  markets ;  big  cities  and  small 
communities ;  markets  which  have  many  passengers ;  and  markets  which  have 
very  few  passengers.  Since  the  certificated  airlines  Serve  basically  a  linear  route 
system,  and  often  connect  more  than  two  points  on  a  single  flight,  their  equipment 
cannot  be  tailored  to  the  needs  of  each  individual  market  on  a  route.  Airline  costs 
also  vary  from  market  to  market,  and  within  markets  from  carrier  to  carrier.  In 
competitive  market,  of  course,  the  economics  are  such  that  all  carriers  must 
operate  at  the  same  fare  irrespective  of  their  own  particular  costs.  As  a  result, 
there  simply  is  no  practical  way  for  the  Board  to  tailor  fares  so  as  to  meet  each 
carrier's  own  revenue  requirements  and  reflect  the  distinct  braflBc  and  operational 
characteristics  of  each  city-pair  market.  On  the  other  hand,  under  the  Board's 
statutory  mandate  from  Congress — particularly  section  1002(e)(5) — the  Board 
is  required  to  take  into  account  the  need  of  each  carrier  for  revenue  sufficient  to 
operate  adequate  and  efficient  air  service  under  what  the  statutes  describes  as 
"honest,  economical,  and  efficient  management  *  *  *  ."  Faced  with  the  problem 
of  how  to  reconcile  the  statutory  mandate  to  consider  the  need  of  each  carrier 
with  the  hard  fact  that  fares  cannot  be  regulated  on  an  individual  basis,  the 
Board  has  concluded  that  an  industry-wide  approach  to  ratemaking  reflects  a 
reasonably  good  balance  between  the  needs  of  all  of  the  airlines  on  the  one  hand, 
and  the  Board's  obligations  to  insure  satisfactory,  low-cost  air  transportation  to 
the  nation  on  the  other.  As  a  result,  the  Board's  ratemaking  approach  is  based 
on  the  need  of  the  industry  as  a  group,  rather  than  any  individual  carrier,  and  is 
also  based  on  mileage  rather  than  the  unique  characteristics  of  particular  mar- 
kets. The  system  isn't  perfect,  but  nonetheless  represents  what  the  Board  has  con- 
sidered to  be  a  reasonable  balance  of  all  the  equities.  This  general  industry-wide 
approach  to  ratemaking,  I  might  add,  was  established  by  the  Board  in  the  Gen- 
eral Passenger  Fare  Investigation  in  1960  and  was  not  challenged  in  the  recent 
Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  in  1970.  I  am  submitting  for  the  subcom- 
mittee's information  those  sections  of  those  two  decisions  which  explain  industry- 
wide ratemaking  in  somewhat  greater  detail  (see  appendixes  1,  2  and  3  herewith) . 


500 

Pricing  considerations  of  intrastate  carriers 

Operations  by  a  large  intrastate  airline  such  as  PSA  or  Southwest  Airlines 
involve  exactly  the  opposite  considerations.  Service  by  these  airlines  is  performed 
in  markets  which  have  nearly  optimum  operational  characteristics.  These  intra- 
state operators  serve  only  a  few  points,  almost  all  of  them  large  cities,  and  gen- 
erally provide  commuter-type  service  in  markets  which  generate  a  large  volume 
of  traffic.  As  a  result,  these  intrastate  operators  have  less  need  for  different  air- 
craft types  to  cope  with  differing  traffic  densities  or  stage  lengths,  and  have 
little  problem  with  respect  to  positioning  of  aircraft.  On  the  contrary,  they  can 
successfully  employ  wide-bodied  aircraft,  which  are  extremely  efficient,  they  can 
configure  their  aircraft  for  high  density  operation,  operate  at  extremely  high- 
load  factors  and  achieve  a  high  degree  of  aircraft  utilization.  Let  me  give  you 
two  comparisons  in  this  regard,  one  dealing  with  load  factors,  the  other  dealing 
with  station  utilization.  In  1973,  the  certificated  industry  had  a  coach  load  factor 
of  52.4  percent.  By  way  of  comparison,  a  decision  issued  by  the  California  Public 
Utilities  Commission  in  April  1974  indicated  that  Air  California,  another  intra- 
California  operator,  had  load  factors  in  1973  averaging  67  percent — or  almost  15 
points  above  the  certificated  industry  average.  Similarly,  the  trunkline  industry 
in  1972  averaged  about  262,000  passenger  enplanements  per  station,  and  Ameri- 
can Airlines,  which  had  the  most  passengers  per  station,  had  just  under  400,000. 
PSA,  on  the  other  hand,  averaged  545,000  passengers  per  station  in  1972.  Now  that 
translates  into  a  highly  efficient  operation.  Undoubtedly,  the  lack  of  Federal  regu- 
latory requirements,  including  reporting  requirements,  and  the  lack  of  expenses 
associated  with  interline  ticketing  and  reservations  involved  in  the  many  two- 
carrier  services  provided  over  the  interstate  system,  also  reduce  the  cost  of  op- 
erations by  the  intrastate  carrier  to  some  degree.  And  I  am  inclined  to  believe 
that  it  is  easier  to  manage  a  small,  reasonably  self-contained  system  than  it  is  to 
manage  a  nationwide  route  system.  All  of  these  factors  help  to  hold  down  the 
cost  of  operating  and  permit  airlines  like  PSA  or  Southwest  to  offer  very  attrac- 
tive fares. 

Having  said  all  of  that,  I  would  like  to  make  one  point  which  I  think  is  often 
overlooked.  The  table  below  (table  1)  shows  that  the  intrastate  carriers,  in  these 
higher  density  markets,  operate  at  generally  lower  fares  than  the  carriers  regu- 
lated by  the  Board.  However,  there  are  differences  even  among  intrastate  car- 
riers. For  example,  PSA,  on  the  West  Coast,  operates  in  the  3.38  mile  Los  Angeles- 
San  Francisco  market — which  is  the  largest  in  the  world  in  terms  of  passengers — 
at  a  per-mile  fare  of  about  HVo  cents.  The  per-mile  fare  increases  to  8.6  cents  in 
the  209  mile  Los  Angeles-Fresno  market,  which  is  shorter  and  has  less  traffic.  On 
the  other  hand.  Southwest  Airlines  operates  between  Houston  and  San  Antonio 
at  a  regular,  daytime  per-mile  fare  of  over  12  cents.  Clearly  PSA  has  been  able 
to  achieve  efficiencies  in  its  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  operation  which  the  intra- 
state Texas  airline  is  unable  to  match  and  which,  in  fact,  PSA  itself  cannot  dupli- 
cate in  other  of  its  markets.  It  is  also  likely  that  a  carrier  like  PSA  could  not 
duplicate  its  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles  success  in  the  northeast  corridor 
markets. 

Nevertheless,  I  think  that  everyone  is  willing  to  agree  that  passengers  in  high 
density  markets  regulated  by  the  Board — such  as  Boston-New  York  or  Boston- 
Washington,  for  example — may  pay  a  little  more  than  they  would  if  these  mar- 
kets were  served  only  by  airlines  which  could  tailor  their  operations  more  closely 
to  the  special  requirements  of  these  routes.  One  of  the  results  of  the  current  sys- 
tem of  regulation,  after  all,  is  that  fares  of  comparable  mileages  are  the  same 
notwithstanding  the  particular  economic  characteristics  of  the  markets  involved, 
including  the  number  of  passengers  in  the  markets.  However,  any  attempt  to 
adjust  the  uniform  fare  formula  so  as  to  account  for  market  characteristics 
could  produce  some  highly  anomalous  results.  For  example,  a  particular  low-cost 
market  may  have  several  intermediate  points  not  sharing  the  low-cost  character- 
istics. If  the  fare  in  the  low-cost  market  were  adjusted  downward,  passengers 
traveling  to  the  intermediate  points  could  well  be  required  to  pay  a  higher  fare 
than  passengers  traveling  to  the  more  distant  point  in  the  low-cost  market.  Simi- 
larly, while  passengers  in  low-cost  markets  would  probably  continue  to  get  multi- 
frequency  competitive  service,  with  modern  jet  equipment,  at  a  somewhat  lower 
fare,  travelers  to  smaller  communities — places  like  Worcester  or  Hartford — 
might  well  get  higher  fares,  or  perhaps  smaller  or  non-jet  equipment.  Although 
that  might  be  more  efficient  if  looked  at  only  from  the  perspective  of  air  transpor- 
tation economics,  the  effect  on  the  overall  economic  health  of  these  smaller  com- 


501 

munities  is  not  as  easy  to  predict.  The  potential  problems  are  legion,  but  I  think  it 
is  fair  to  say  that  it  is  not  feasible  to  consider  a  particular  market  in  isolation  in 
view  of  the  extensive  route  system  now  being  operated. 

Board  policies  affecting  fare  levels 

Let  me  point  out,  in  this  regard,  Mr.  Chairman,  that  the  Board  has  specifically 
considered  the  possibility  of  establishing  fares  on  a  flexible  basis  in  order  to 
allow  carriers  to  match  fares  to  the  costs  in  particular  markets.  That  proposal 
was  recently  presented  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation  by  the 
Departments  of  Justice  and  Transportation,  among  others.  Basically,  it  was 
argued  that  the  Board  should  allow  airlines  the  flexibility  to  set  fares  within 
a  zone  ranging  above  and  below  the  fares  found  reasonable  by  the  Board.  The 
adoption  of  such  a  procedure,  it  was  contended,  would  inject  a  measure  of  price 
competition  into  the  setting  of  air  fares  and  would  permit  individual  airlines 
the  opportunity  to  tailor  their  fares  to  the  specific  needs  of  particular  markets. 
The  Board  rejected  the  proposal,  and  I  have  included  among  the  materials  sub- 
mitted to  the  subcommittee  that  portion  of  the  Board's  decision  which  deals 
with  that  subject.  Let  me  outline  the  Board's  conclusions  briefly. 

The  Board  observed,  in  the  first  place,  that  for  over  thirty  years  prior  to  its 
decision  in  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investigation,  it  had  never  established 
a  general  passenger  fare  level  or  structure.  As  a  result,  between  1938  and  1970, 
the  airlines  had  been  free  to  file  tariffs  proposing  changes  in  their  normal  fares, 
either  upward  or  downward.  However,  as  a  factual  matter,  the  only  proposals 
submitted  by  the  airlines  during  the  entire  period  were  increases  in  fares.  Price 
competition  in  normal  fares,  in  other  words,  has  been  virtually  nonexistent.  And 
this  is  really  not  surprising.  Carriers  do  not  engage  in  price  competition  because 
they  ordinarily  cannot  expect  any  significant  advantage  from  such  action.  Com- 
petitors, after  all,  are  always  free  to  match  any  reduction  in  fares  and,  as  a 
result,  a  carrier  cannot  expect  that  a  fare  reduction  will  increase  its  competitive 
position  or  generate  sufficient  additional  trafl3c  to  offset  the  decline  in  overall 
yield.  This  result  flows  inevitably  from  the  character  of  the  airline  industry. 
Congress  has  subjected  to  regulation  and  control  both  entry  into  the  industry 
and  entry  into  individual  markets,  with  the  result  that  the  number  of  competitors 
over  individual  routes  is  necessarily  limited.  As  long  as  Congress  wishes  to  retain 
a  regulated  system,  with  limited  entry,  and  designed  to  provide  air  service  across 
the  nation  and  not  merely  to  big  cities  or  in  heavily  traveled  markets,  it  is  simply 
not  realistic  to  expect  pricing  behavior  representative  of  a  truly  competitive 
market  structure.  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  virtually  certain  that  the  so-called 
flexible  fare  approach  would  inevitably  lead  to  an  overall  fare  level  in  excess  of 
that  found  reasonable  by  the  Board.  The  flexible  fare  proposal,  in  short,  would 
be  simply  a  license  for  the  carriers  to  raise  their  fares  to  the  traveling  public 
without  submitting  those  fare  increases  to  the  Board  and  there  would  be  no 
incentive  to  keep  fares  below  the  maximum  level  permitted.  The  Board's  use  of 
average  industry  costs  at  least  gives  each  airline  the  incentive  to  keep  its  own 
costs  as  low  as  possible.  The  bigger  the  difference,  after  all,  between  an  individual 
carrier's  co.sts,  on  the  one  hand,  and  industry  average  costs,  on  the  other,  the 
greater  the  profits  for  the  individual  airline.  That  is  a  pretty  powerful  incentive. 

Let  me  make  one  final  observation  about  the  regulated  system.  The  Congress 
has  given  the  Board  what  I  think  should  properly  be  described  as  a  balanced 
mandate — a  mandate,  in  other  words,  to  provide  good  service  to  the  traveler 
and  shipper,  at  a  reasonable  price,  and  with  reasonable  profits  to  the  industry. 
When  that  mandate  gets  out  of  balance,  I  think  it  is  up  to  the  Board  to  bring 
it  back  into  balance.  The  Board's  job  is  always  more  difficult  in  times  of  eco- 
nomic downturn,  when  airlines  want  to  reduce  service  to  save  fuel  or  money, 
and  increase  fares  to  cover  increased  costs,  but  the  traveling  public  would  like 
to  continue  the  same  quality  of  service  and  the  same  fares  that  prevailed  in 
better  economic  times. 

The  current  economic  circumstances,  brought  about  in  large  part  by  the 
unprecedented  rise  in  fuel  prices,  is  virtually  without  parallel  in  aviation  history. 
But  I  want  to  assure  this  subcommittee  that  the  Board  is  taking  a  long  hard 
look  at  its  regulatory  responsibilities  in  light  of  the  drastically  changing  eco- 
nomic circumstances.  In  this  connection,  you  may  be  interested  to  know,  Mr. 
Chairman,  that  the  Board  has  established  a  special,  independent  staff  to  study 
the  effectiveness  of  Federal  economic  regulation  with  respect  to  air  transporta- 
tion.  Dr.   Lucile  Keyes,   a  distinguished  economist,  has  accepted  the  Board's 


502 

invitation  to  serve  as  an  economic  consultant  to  the  staff.  And  we  shall  also 
take  a  long  hard  look  at  our  responsibilities  in  light  of  the  information  that 
comes  out  of  these  subcommittee  hearings.  My  experience  on  the  Board's  staff, 
and  most  recently  as  one  of  the  Board's  members,  convinces  me  that  the  Board 
can  respond  creatively  to  the  challenges  and  responsibilities  which  the  Congress 
has  placed  upon  our  shoulders. 

TABLE  l.-COMPARISON  OF  FARE  RATES  FOR  CAB-REGULATED  AND  NON-CAB-REGULATED  CARRIERS  IN  SELECTED 

MARKETS 


Fare  per 

Fare  per 

Coach 

Elapsed 

mile 

minute 

Carrier 

fare 

Mileage 

time ' 

(In  cents)  (in  cents) 

Comments 

Northeast  corridor 

interstate 
markets: 
BOS-NYC(LGA)-. 

.  EA,AA,  NA,  NE... 

$25. 93 

185 

:49 

14.02 

52.91 

DL 

24.07 

185 

:49 

13.01 

49.12 

EA - 

20.37 

185 

:49 

11.01 

41.57 

Night  coach. 

NYC-WAS(DCA)- 

.  EA.AA -. 

27.78 

214 

:54 

12.98 

51.44 

BOS-WAS  (DCA). 
Selected  Intrastate 

EA,  AA 

41.67 

399 

1:07 

10.44 

60.19 

markets : 

California 

LAX-SFO 

.  PS ..— 

18.75 

338 

:55 

5.55 

34.09 

LAX-FAT 

_  PS - 

18.01 

209 

.45 

8.62 

40.02 

LAX-SMF  

.  PS 

20.47 

373 

1:00 

5.49 

34.12 

SFO-SMF 

.  PS.. 

9.73 

86 

•,30 

11.31 

32.43 

SMF-SJC 

.  OC 

11.48 

94 

:25 

12.21 

45.92 

DAL-HOU..— 

.  WN-.. 

13.89 

241 

:50 

5.76 

27.78 

Weekends  and 

evenings. 
Weekdays. 

WN 

2.^.  15 

241 

:50 

9.61 

46.30 

DAL-SAT 

.  WN 

13.  89 

250 

:50 

5.56 

27.78 

Weekends  and 
evenings. 

WN 

23.15 

250 

:50 

9.26 

46.30 

Weekdays. 

HOU-SAT 

-  WN.... 

13.89 

191 

:40 

7.27 

34.73 

Weekdays  and 
evenings. 

WN... 

23.15 

191 

:40 

12.12 

57.87 

Weekdays. 

>  Fastest  block  time  between  1700  and  1900  hours,  unless  otherwise  appropriate. 

Key:  AA=American;  DL=Delta;  EA=Eastern;  OC=Air  California;  WN=Southwest  Airlines;  PS  =  Pacific  Southwest 
Airlines;  BOS=Boston;  DAL=Dallas  Fort  Worth;  FAT=Fresno;  HOU  =  Houston;  LAX=Los  Angeles;  NYC=New  York; 
SAT=San  Antonio;  SFO=San  Francisco;  SJC=San  Jose;  SMF=Sacramento;  OAG=QRE,  January  1975. 

[Appendix  1] 

Before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  Washington,  D.C. 

[Docket  2186&-7] 
(71-4-59) 
(71-4-60) 

Domestic   Passenger  Fare  Investigation— Phase  7 

(Pages  70-72) 

Decided  April  9,  1971 


general  conclusions 

Unit  of  ratemaking. — In  determining  the  reasonableness  of  the  overall  fare 
level  in  any  given  point  of  time,  we  are  faced  with  the  fact  that  we  are  deal- 
ing with  a  large  number  of  carriers  who  operate  in  a  highly  competitive  in- 
terlacing route  system  and  that  fares  cannot  be  individually  tailored  to  meet 
each  carrier's  own  revenue  requirements.  In  its  1960  decision  in  docket  8008,^"" 
the  Board  noted  that  while  section  1002(e)  (5)  enjoined  it  to  take  into  considera- 
tion "each"  carrier's  need,  a  large  part  of  the  domestic  route  structure  is  served 
by  two  or  more  carriers  in  competition  and  that  fares  inevitably  will  be  uniform 


102  General  Passenger  Fare  Investigation,  32  CAB  291  (1960). 


503 

as  between  them,  notwithstanding  that  one  carrier's  revenue  need  may  be  less 
than  another's."^  In  considering  what  it  deemed  the  vexing  problem  of  how  to 
reconcile  the  statutory  mandate  to  consider  the  need  of  "each"  carrier  and  the 
hard  fact  that  fares  cannot  be  regulated  on  an  individual  basis,  the  Board  re- 
jected the  concept  that  the  fares  should  be  established  at  levels  to  meet  the 
need  of  the  most  poorly-situated  carriers.  Such  a  standard  was  held  to  be  in- 
consistent with  the  standards  of  section  1002(e)  (1)  (the  effect  of  rates  on  move- 
ment of  traffic)  and  section  1002(e)(2)  (the  need  for  transportation  at  the 
lowest  cost).  The  Board  also  considered  that  such  a  standard  would  be  con- 
trary to  the  mandate  of  section  1002(e)  (5)  in  that  to  use  the  most  poorly  sit- 
uated carrier  as  the  unit  of  ratemaking  would  result  in  the  va.st  majority  of 
the  public  paying  rates  in  excess  of  the  cost  of  furnishing  the  transportation. 
By  the  same  token,  the  Board  noted  that  it  cannot  fix  fare  levels  at  the  need 
of  the  most  favorably-situated  carrier,  since  such  a  standard  would  have  a  dis- 
astrous impact  upon  the  bulk  of  the  carriers  and  upon  the  development  of  air 
transportation  generally. 

Accordingly,  in  consideration  of  the  foregoing,  the  Board  concluded  that  in  the 
absence  of  special  circumstances,  fares  which  meet  the  needs  of  the  domestic 
trunkline  industry  as  a  whole  would  reflect  a  balancing  of  the  needs  of  the 
high-  and  low-cost  carriers,  and  that  where  the  bulk  of  the  carriers  fall  within 
a  reasonable  range  of  the  standard  rate  of  return  and  the  industry  figures  are 
not  distorted  by  the  results  of  unrepresentative  carriers,  fare  adjustments  should 
normally  be  based  upon  the  results  of  the  industry  as  a  group.  This  standard 
does  not  appear  to  be  challenged  in  this  proceeding,  is  found  reasonable,  and  is 
employed  herein  in  our  determination  of  the  reasonable  fare  levels. 

A  special  problem  involves  the  extent  to  which  local  service  carriers  should 
be  considered  in  fixing  the  overall  fare  level.  Generally,  these  carriers  operate 
predominantly  short-haul  services  in  the  less-dense  trafl5c  markets.  As  a  class, 
these  carriers  have  never  been  able  to  realize  a  sufficient  level  of  passenger 
revenues  to  meet  the  costs  of  passenger  services  and  they  require  government 
support  in  the  form  of  subsidy  in  order  to  furnish  their  services.^*^  Our  de- 
termination as  to  the  required  adjustments  does  not  take  into  account  the  needs 
of  the  local  service  carriers.  The  local  service  carriers  accounted  for  only  6.6 
percent  of  the  total  revenue  passenger  miles  in  scheduled  domestic  air  trans- 
portation in  1969,  and  their  revenue  requirements  are  not  representative  of  the 
industry  as  a  whole.  To  include  them  in  the  industry  results  would  have  a  dis- 
tortionary  effect  on  the  fare  level  since,  in  the  absence  of  an  adjustment  in  the 
fare  structure  or  in  the  divisions  of  joint  fares,  the  bulk  of  the  need  of  the 
local  service  carriers  would  be  reflected  in  the  trunkline  passenger  fares.  Ac- 
cordingly, while  we  have  set  forth  in  the  appendixes  the  impact  on  the  local  serv- 
ice carriers  of  the  fare  adjustments  found  reasonable  herein,  the  adjustments 
have  been  based  solely  upon  the  requirements  of  the  trunklines. 

[Appendix  2] 
Before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  Washington,  D.C. 

[Docket  21866-9] 
(74-3-82) 

Domestic   Passenger  Fare   Investigation — Phase  9 

(Pages   108-22) 

Decided  March  18,  1974 

FARE   FLEXIBILITY 

A  number  of  proposals  have  been  put  forward  to  allow  carriers  flexibility  to 
set  fares  within  a  zone  ranging  both  above  and  below  the  fares  found  reasonable 
in  this  proceeding,  and  for  fares  within  this  zone  to  be  deemed  reasonable  per 
se.  The  principal  proponents  of  such  a  zone  are  DOJ,  DOT,  and  American.  These 
parties  advocate  a  zone  of  15  percent  above  to  15  percent  below  the  formula- 


W3  32  CAB  329. 

10*  The  estimated  level  of  subsidy  for  fiscal  1971  Is  $58.6  million.   See  order  71-1-143, 
January  29,  1971. 


504 

determined  fares.  Other  proposals  are  advanced  by  Delta,  Continential  MOC, 
and  the  Bureau.  Delta  and  Continental  support  flexibility  within  a  range  of 
plus  or  minus  5  percent  of  formula-determined  fares.^"  MOC  supports  establish- 
ment of  a  minimum  fare  level  15  percent  below  its  formula  fare.  The  Bureau 
supports  a  range  of  plus  or  minus  5  percent ;  however,  unlike  the  other  zone 
proposals,  fares  filed  within  the  Bureau's  zone  would  be  only  prima  facie  reason- 
able.^^ Adoption  of  a  fare  zone  is  opposed  by  United,  Eastern,  Northwest,  TWA, 
NARUC,  and  the  State  of  Wisconsin.  Judge  Johnson  found  that  none  of  the 
zone  proposals  should  be  adopted. 

Upon  consideration,  we  find  we  are  in  agreement  with  Judge  Johnson's  rejec- 
tion of  these  proposals,  although  for  somewhat  different  reasons. 

DOJ  supports  adoption  of  maximum  and  minimum  fare  levels  as  a  means  of 
stimulating  price  competition  in  the  domestic  air  transportation  industry.  The 
Department  believes  that  increasing  managements'  pricing  discretion  will  en- 
courage eflScient  operations,  and  lessen  disparities  in  carrier  earnings  resulting 
from  differences  in  route  structure  and  other  factors  beyond  management  control. 
DOJ  also  believes  that  the  availability  of  price  competition  will  reduce  the  indus- 
try's present  tendency  to  channel  competitive  forces  into  expensive  service  rivalry. 
Additionally,  the  Department  expects  carriers  to  utilize  increased  pricing  free- 
dom to  experiment  with  fares  in  order  to  build  traffic,  and  to  adjust  fares  without 
regulatory  lag  to  rapid  changes  in  supply  and  demand.  Lastly,  the  Department 
argues  that  giving  carriers  more  pricing  latitude  will  reduce  the  regulatory  bur- 
den on  the  Board,  and  enable  the  Board  to  better  carry  out  its  statutory  mandate. 

DOJ's  support  of  the  zone  concept  is  predicated  on  its  belief  that  fares  in  the 
past  have  been  set  by  a  process  which  results  in  a  uniform  Board-established  and 
enforced  fare  structure.  The  Department  believes  that  this  system  of  uniform 
pricing  has  forced  competition  into  nonprice  areas,  e.g.,  fiight  frequencies,  equip- 
ment types,  seating  configurations,  and  other  service  amenities,  resulting  in  a 
constantly  improving  quality  of  service,  but  at  significantly  increasing  cost."' 
The  Department  believes  that  the  public,  if  free  to  choose,  would  prefer  a  lesser 
quality  of  service  at  prices  reflecting  its  lower  cost.  Competitive  pricing,  it 
argues,  would  permit  carriers  to  experiment  with  fares  and  service  to  deter- 
mine what  combination  of  price  and  service  is  most  preferred  in  particular 
markets. 

The  DOT  supports  fare  flexibility  because,  in  its  view,  a  simple  fare-taper 
formula  is  inadequate  to  provide  the  optimal  fare  for  all  city-pair  markets.  The 
record  in  this  proceeding  shows  that  costs  vary  considerably  from  market  to 
market,  and  within  markets  from  carrier  to  carrier.  A  simple  fare-taper  formula 
cannot,  however,  accommodate  these  variations.  The  Department  believes,  there- 
fore, that  carriers  should  be  free  to  vary  fares  in  individual  markets  based  upon 
perceived  costs,  and  upon  marketing  judgments  as  to  what  quality  of  service  the 
public  desires.  Market  response  to  carrier  decisions  would  then  guide  fares.  The 
Department  argues  that  fares  which  do  not  reflect  costs  in  each  market  are  unfair 
either  to  the  public  or  to  the  carrier.  If  the  fare  is  below  cost  at  the  optimum 
level  of  service,  either  the  carrier  will  be  denied  revenue  to  which  it  is  entitled, 
or  the  quality  of  service  will  be  reduced  so  that  costs  may  be  recovered.  If  the 
fare  exceeds  cost  at  the  appropriate  level  of  service,  the  public  is  denied  a  fare 
at  the  lowest  cost  consistent  with  furnishing  the  service.  In  the  Department's 


1"  North  Central,  in  its  brief,  in3ic.ited  tliat  it  does  not  except  to  the  adoption  of  a 
5-percent  range  above  and  below  tie  fare  curve  within  which  fare  filings  would  be  con- 
sidered prima  facie  reasonable,  pnvided  the  flexibility  afforded  by  the  range  is  closely 
monitored  to  prevent  predatory  pra  :tices. 

155  The  Bureau  indicates  that  its  zone  proposal  is  intended  to  give  carriers  flexibility  to 
file  fares  within  a  narrow  range  both  above  and  below  formula-determined  fares  without 
those  fares  being  subject  to  rejection  under  the  final  order  in  this  Investigation.  Such  fares 
would,  however,  remain  subject  to  suspension  and  investigation.  In  view  of  the  fact  that, 
as  discussed  elsewhere  herein,  we  have  determined  not  to  adopt  an  order  which  prescribes 
specific  fares  for  the  future,  with  exceptions  not  here  material,  carriers  will  not  need  to 
seek  modification  or  an  outstanding  rate  order  before  filing  certain  "nonconforming" 
tariffs.  Accordingly,  we  find  the  Bureau's  proposal  moot,  and  it  is  not  further  considered 
therein. 

isflThe  Department  further  argues  that  Board-imposed  uniform  fares  have  contributed 
to  the  economic  disparities  that  exist  between  carriers.  The  Department  believes  that  a 
uniformly-applied  fare  formula  cannot  take  into  account  cost  differences  that  exist  between 
markets,  and  therefore,  tends  permanently  to  relegate  some  carriers  to  below-average 
earnings  and  others  to  above-average  earnings. 

Factors  cited  by  the  Department  as  affecting  the  comparative  cost  of  service  between 
markets  but  not  easily  accommodated  in  a  simple  fare-taper  formula  include  route  density, 
congestion,  traffic  peaks,  and  equipment  types.  The  Department  concludes  that  where  a 
uniform  fare  formula  is  utilized,  the  most  important  determinant  of  a  carrier's  profit- 
ability is  its  route  structure. 


505 

view,  a  single  industry-wide  fare  formula  cannot  avoid  these  problems.  However, 
rather  than  have  the  Board  attempt  to  set  fares  on  a  market-by-market  basis,  or 
examine  individually  the  numerous  cost- justified  deviations  from  formula-deter- 
mined fares,  the  Department  believes  the  Board  should  give  the  carriers  broad 
flexibility  to  adjust  fares  to  costs  on  a  market-by-market  basis.  In  this  way,  the 
Board  would  be  spared  the  necessity  of  passing  on  the  reasonableness  of  numerous 
individual  fare  filings,  and  carriers  could  avoid  regulatory  lag  in  changing  or 
modifying  fares  to  track  with  movements  in  the  level  and  structure  of  costs. 
Finally,  DOT  advocates  fare  flexibility  as  a  means  of  enabling  carriers  to  deter- 
mine the  optimal  price/quality  relationship  in  each  market.  In  the  Department's 
view,  there  are  considerable  variations  in  desirable  service  quality  between  mar- 
kets of  similar  distance.^"  Use  of  an  industry-wide  fare  formula,  however,  pro- 
duces the  same  quality  of  service  in  markets  of  similar  distance  regardless  of  the 
inherent  differences  in  the  market's  service  needs. 

American  supports  fare  flexibility  because  it  believes  that  a  fare  structure  based 
upon  approximations  of  industry  average  costs  is  inadequate  for  determining  the 
^appropriate  fare  in  particular  markets.  American,  like  DOT,  contends  that  since 
costs  vary  considerably  from  market  to  market,  equitable  treatment  for  pas- 
sengers and  carriers  requires  that  carriers  be  given  meaningful  pricing  flexibility 
in  order  that  these  cost  variations  may  be  reflected  in  the  fare  structure."* 
American  also  argues  that  far^  flexibility  will  permit  carriers  to  test  fares  in  the 
marketplace  and  thereby  determine  their  effect  on  trafllc.^" 

Continental  supports  fare  flexibility  as  a  means  of  enabling  carriers  more 
easily  to  adjust  fares  in  individual  markets  to  reflect  marketing  considerations, 
and  to  encourage  price  competition.  Continental  believes  that  price  elasticity 
varies  from  market  to  market,  and  that  carriers  need  increased  pricing  discre- 
tion to  react  to  marketing  realities.""  Continental  argues  that  under  the  statute 
fares  are  supposed  to  reflect  not  only  costs,  but  value  of  service  principles  as 
well.  Strict  adherence  to  a  uniform  fare  formula,  however,  inhibits  manage- 
ments' ability  to  reflect  value  of  service  considerations  in  the  fare  structure. 
Continental  supports  increased  opportunities  for  price  competition  so  carriers 
will  not  have  to  come  to  the  Board  every  time  they  want  to  introduce  a  fare 
reduction. 

Delta  supports  fare  flexibility  limited  to  plus  or  minus  5  percent  of  formula 
fares  because  it  believes  that  such  a  range  more  nearly  corresponds  to  costs 
than  does  a  single  formula-determined  fare.  Delta  argues  that,  in  view  of  the 
numerous  judgmental  factors  involved  in  mileage  block  costing,  the  best  that 
can  be  expected  with  reasonable  assurance  of  accuracy  is  development  of  a  cost 
band  or  profile.  Delta  believes  that  after  an  initial  stabilizing  period,"^  carriers 
should  be  free  to  adjust  fares  within  this  band  without  the  fares  being  subject 
to  suspension  on  reasonableness  grounds. 


1S7  D0T-T-.3.  The  variations  are  the  result  of  difference  in  passenger  density  and  type  of 
traffic.  The  Department  believes  that  In  dense  markets  passengers  would  prefer  lower- 
than-average  fares  and  higher  load  factors,  and  the  converse  in  less-dense  markets.  Like- 
wise, the  Department  believes  business  passengers  would  be  willing  to  pay  higher  fares 
for  more  frequent  service,  and  vacation  travelers  would  accept  higher  load  factors  in 
return  for  a  lower  fare. 

^S8  American's  contention  is  that  the  Bureau's  costing  methodology  produces  only  esti- 
mates of  average  trunkline  costs,  which,  like  all  averages,  tend  to  mask  the  wide  cost 
variations  that  exist  between  markets.  American  concedes  that  the  inherent  limitations 
of  the  regulatory  process  make  it  unrealistic  ^o  attempt  to  determine  the  cost  of  domestic 
air  transportation  on  a  market-by-market  basis.  However,  rather  than  ignore  the  cost 
variation,  as  American  alleges  an  industry-wide  fare  formula  does,  the  carrier  contends 
that  the  practical  way  to  reflect  cost  variations  in  the  fare  structure  is  by  giving  carriers 
sufficient  flexibility  to  adjust  fares  to  perceived  costs  on  a  market-by -market  basis. 

1^  In  conjunction  with  this  expectation,  American  refers  to  the  oft-repeated  argument 
in  this  proceeding  that  short-haul  fares  cannot  be  raised  to  the  level  of  short-haul  costs 
without  adversely  affecting  traffic  in  those  markets.  American  contends  that  this  generaliza- 
tion is  deceptive  and  without  convincing  support  in  the  record.  American  believes  Instead 
that  elasticity  varies  from  market  to  market,  and  supports  fare  flexibility  as  a  means  of 
permitting  carriers  to  increase  fares  in  those  short-haul  markets  where  to  do  so  would 
not  significantly  aflfect  trafltic. 

160  por  example.  Continental  points  out  that  in  some  markets  carriers  compete  against 
ground  transportation.  In  such  markets,  Continental  believes  carriers  would  utilize  fare 
flexibility  to  lower  fares  to  attract  more  traflic.  Likewise,  flexibility  would  permit  fare 
decreases  in  vacation-oriented  markets  in  order  to  attract  added  traffic.  On  the  other  hand, 
in  business  markets,  carriers  could  increase  fares  to  compen:-.ate  for  the  lower  fares  in 
more  price-sensitive  markets. 

^«i  Delta  proposes  that  formula-determined  coach  fares  and  other  basic  fares  based 
upon  percentage  relationships  to  the  coach  fare  remain  in  effect  without  change  for  a 
period  of  6  months  following  the  final  order  in  this  investigation. 


506 

In  general,  the  parties  which  oppose  fare  flexibility  argue  that  the  proposals 
in  effect  constitute  a  deregulation  of  air  transiportation  and  are  inconsistent  with 
the  policies  of  the  Act.  Some  express  concern  that  the  adoption  of  such  a  pro- 
posal could  result  in  discrimination  between  passengers  traveling  in  different 
markets.  Finally,  the  carriers  opposing  flexibility  argue  that  it  could  result  in 
economically  destructive  competition.  They  are  concerned  that  in  competitive 
markets  fares  will  necessarily  fall  to  the  bottom  of  the  zone  resulting  in  inade- 
quate earnings  for  the  industry. 

Upon  consideration  of  the  foregoing,  the  Board  has  determined  to  afl5rm 
Judge  Johnson's  rejection  of  the  various  zone  proposals. 

In  general,  the  proposals  rest  on  an  erroneous  understanding  of  the  Board's 
past  practices  with  respect  to  fare  policy,  and  on  unrealistic  assumptions  as  to 
how  the  industry  would  respond  to  a  policy  of  partial  deregulation  of  fares.  In 
our  opinion,  adoption  of  any  of  these  propsals  would  be  tantamount  to  abdicat- 
ing our  statutory  responsibility  to  protect  the  public  interest  in  reasonable  fares. 
Moreover,  we  believe  that  the  proposals  would  inevitably  lead  to  an  irrational 
and  inequitable  fare  structure  and  to  an  unwarranted  escalation  of  the  fare 
level. 

As  previously  noted,  DOJ's  position  rests  on  its  contention  that  the  historic 
absence  of  price  competition  in  the  domestic  air  transportation  industry  is 
largely  the  result  of  a  uniform  Board-established  and  enforced  fare  structure. 
Eliminate  the  Board-enforced  rigidity,  says  DOJ,  and  the  carriers  will  engage 
in  price  competition  rather  than  costly  service  competition.  However,  the  facts 
do  not  fit  the  theory.  The  facts  are  that  until  this  proceeding,  the  Board  had 
never  prescribed  a  general  domestic  passenger-fare  level,  or  minimum  or  maxi- 
mum levels.  Under  section  1002(d)  of  the  Act,  although  the  Board  is  empowered 
to  establish  reasonable  fares,  it  may  do  so  only  after  finding  the  existing  fare 
level  unlawful.  While  the  Board  has  adjudicated  the  reasonableness  of  numerous 
individual  fare  proposals,  prior  to  the  issuance  of  the  opinion  and  order  in  Phase 
7  of  this  DPFI,^*"  it  had  never  before  found  the  existing  general  passenger-fare 
level  unlawful.^"^  Consequently,  until  this  proceeding,  it  has  never  had  occasion 
to  prescribe  a  general  domestic  passenger-fare  level  or  structure. 

Thus,  for  over  thirty  years  the  carriers  have  been  free  to  file  tariffs  proposing 
changes  in  their  normal  fares,  either  upward  or  downward,  subject  to  the 
Board's  power  to  suspend  and  investigate.  The  history  of  carrier-initiated  fares 
under  this  regime  inspires  little  confidence  in  the  likely  end-results  of  the  zone 
proposals.  For,  aside  from  the  patchwork  fare  structure  which  evolved,  the 
fact  is  that,  for  all  practical  purposes,  the  only  proposals  to  adjust  normal  fares 
during  this  entire  period  involved  increases.^"  Price  competition  in  normal  fares 
has  been  virtually  nonexistent.^^ 

Indeed,  even  in  Phase  7  of  this  proceeding,  when  the  Board  for  the  first  time 
established  a  general  constraint  on  future  domestic  fare  filings,  we  imposed  a 
maximum  fare  level  only,^*^  in  an  effort  to  afford  managerial  discretion  in  im- 
plementing fare  changes.  The  carriers'  response  to  this  pricing  discretion,  how- 
ever, was  to  raise  virtually  all  basic  fares  to  the  maximum  level  permitted,  and 
to  continue  their  intensive  nonprice  competition,  as  well  as  price  competition 
in  the  form  of  discount  fares. 

It  is  clear,  therefore,  that  the  general  absence  of  price  competition  in  normal 
fares  is  not,  as  alleged,  the  result  of  a  Board-imposed  fare  structure.  Rather, 
it  is  directly  attributable  to  the  economic  structu'-e  of  the  industry.  Carriers 
have  demonstrated  little  inclination  to  engage  in  su'i'h  price  competition  because 
they  normally  can  expect  no  significant  advantage  from  such  action.  Competitors 
are  always  free  to  match  any  fare  reduction,  and  as  a  result,  a  carrier  cannot 


i«2  Order  71-4-60  dated  April  9.  1971.  ,       ^„ 

lo^in  the  Suspended  Passenger-Fare  Increase  case,  25  CAB  .511  (1957),  the  Board,  while 
not  finding  the  existing  fare  level  unlawful,  did  find  that  tariffs  proposing  Increases  in 
substantially  all  domestic  fare  levels  were  uniust  and  unreasonable.  The  decision  did 
not  result  in  a  Board  prescription  of  fares  for  future  application,  but  only  in  the  cancel- 
lation of  the  proposed  increases. 

i«*  Exceptions  to  the  rule  are  three  across-the-board  fare  decreases  implemented  during 
World  War  II.  These  reductions  were  not,  however,  the  result  of  intercarrier  price  com- 
petition, but  were  in  response  to  orders  to  show  cause  why  passenger  fares  should  not  be 
reduced.  See  e.g.,  order  2164,  adopted  February  27,  194,3.  Also,  it  should  be  emphasized 
that  the  above  discussion  is  concerned  with  standard-class  fares,  and  does  not  consider 
carrier  proposals  for  introduction  of  new  lower-cost  forms  of  service  at  fare  levels  below 
existing  fares,  e.g.,  the  introduction  of  coach  service  by  Capitol  Airlines  in  1948  at  a  level 
approximately  2  cents  below  first-class  passenger-mile  rates. 

16.5  In  recent  years,  the  curriers  have,  however,  engaged  in  extensive  discount  fare  com- 
petition which  was  the  subject  of  our  exhaustive  opinion  in  Phase  5  of  this  investigation, 
and  is  not  further  considered  herein. 

i««  Orders  71-4-59  and  -60,  p.  80. 


507 

expect  a  fare  decrease  to  improve  its  market  share  and  consequently  its  com- 
petitive position.  As  a  consequence,  reductions  in  normal  fares  can  only  lead  to 
a  reduced  passenger-mile  yield  and,  unless  traffic  expands  substantially,  to  reduc- 
tions in  carrier  earnings.  And,  as  the  evidence  in  Phase  7  indicates,  normal-tare 
traffic  appears  to  be  relatively  inelastic  with  the  result  that  general  fare  reduc- 
tions do  not  generate  sufficient  additional  traffic  to  offset  the  decline  in  overall 
yield. 

Also  of  significance  in  explaining  the  absence  of  normal-fare  price  competition 
between  air  carriers,  and  a  fact  with  which  the  proponents  of  fare  flexibility 
not  come  to  grips,  is  the  character  of  the  industry.  Congress  has  subjected  to 
regulation  and  control  both  entry  into  the  industry  and  entry  into  individual 
markets,  with  the  result  that  the  number  of  competitors  over  individual  routes 
is  necessarily  limited.  The  Congressional  purpose  was  to  enable  the  Board  to 
prevent  excessive  competition  which,  because  it  is  uneconomic,  would  inevitably 
drive  up  fares.  As  a  consequence,  effective  competition  on  all  but  a  few  individ- 
ual city-pair  markets  is  confined  to  a  relatively  limited  number  of  carriers — and 
many  markets  are  served  by  only  one  carrier.^"^  Under  these  circumstances,  to 
expect  pricing  behavior  representative  of  a  truly  competitive  market  structure 
is  ingenuous  at  best,  and  it  is  therefore  not  surprising  that  competition  in  basic 
fares  has  been  virtually  nonexistent. 

The  second  failing  of  the  zone  proposals  is  that  they  are  premised  on  unrealistic 
assumptions  as  to  how  carrier  managements  are  likely  to  respond.  In  general, 
two  different  types  of  pricing  responses  are  predicted  by  the  zones  proponents. 
First,  they  expect  that  the  deregulation  of  fares  within  a  zone  of  plus  or 
minus  15  percent  of  the  formula  fares  will  encourage  price  competition ;  and 
second,  they  support  fare  flexibility  as  a  means  of  permitting  carriers  to  adjust 
fares  to  the  level  of  costs  on  a  market  basis. 

Although  the  proponents  of  fare  flexibility  anticipate  it  will  encourage  price 
competition,  for  the  reasons  outlined  above,  we  believe  instead  that  carrier 
managements  will  react  to  this  form  of  pricing  flexibility  in  the  same  manner 
they  have  always  reacte<l  to  the  extensive  flexibility  which  they  have  historically 
been  afforded,  and  that  is  to  compete  on  the  basis  of  service  rather  than  price, 
on  the  other  hand,  a  policy  which  automatically  permits  carriers  to  adjust  fares 
to  levels  15  percent  above  the  formula  will  enable  the  carriers  to  increase  fares 
to  levels  far  in  excess  of  cost  plus  a  fair  return.  There  is  no  reason  to  believe 
that  the  carriers  will  not  avail  themselves  of  this  opportunity,  the  resultant 
excessive  earnings  inevitably  being  used  to  finance  additional  service  competition. 
In  any  event,  insofar  as  the  different  price-service  levels  predicted  to  result 
from  increased  price  competition  merely  represent  introduction  of  lower  cost 
forms  of  service — such  as  with  more  densely  configured  aircraft — nothing  pre- 
vents carriers  from  introducing  such  services  at  appropriate  fares.  The  fare 
structure  we  are  adopting  herein  is  applicable  only  to  existing  forms  of  service. 
However,  to  the  extent  the  price-service  differentials  envisioned  by  DOJ  and 
DOT  contemplate  carriers  competing  over  the  same  routes  on  the  basis  of  high- 
load  factor/low-price  service  versus  low-load  factor/high-price  service,  there  is 
no  evidence  that  such  competition  would  take  place.  Without  further  belaboring 
the  point,  it  may  again  be  noted  that  for  over  thirty  years  the  carriers  have 
been  free  to  offer  prices  different  from  those  of  their  competitors,  but  with 
insignificant  exceptions,  airline  fares  have  always  been  uniform.  Again,  this 
phenomenon  is  hardly  surprising.  Assuming  that  a  particular  carrier  were  to 
reduce  its  fares  predicated  on  achieving  a  higher-load  factor,  other  competing 
carriers  would  be  compelled  to  reduce  their  fares,  the  result  being  that  all  car- 
riers would  have  to  achieve  a  higher  load  factor  if  earnings  were  not  to  be  ad- 
versely affected.  Thus,  the  public  would  not  have  a  choice  of  different  prices,  but 
would  be  forced  to  pay  for  whatever  level  of  service  could  be  economically  pro- 
vided at  the  established  fare.  We  are  at  a  loss  to  perceive  how  this  result  squares 
with  our  obligation  under  section  1002(e)  (2)  to  take  into  account  "the  need  in 
the  public  interest  of  adequate  and  efficient  transportation  of  persons  and  prop- 
erty *  *  *  at  the  lowest  cost  consistent  with  the  furnishing  of  such  service." 

American,  on  the  other  hand,  indicates  that  it  would  not  expect  price  compe- 
tition to  result  in  carriers  competing  in  the  same  market  by  offering  different 
fares.  Rather,  American  anticipates  that  price  competition,  while  producing 
uniform  fares,  will  result  in  a  greater  emphasis  on  efficiency.  However,  why  a 
carrier  would  reduce  its  fares,  and  concurrently  its  yield  per  passenger-mile,  when 
to  do  so  would  not  increase  its  market  .share,  is  not  all  clear,  since  the  result  of 
such  action  would  be  that  the  carrier  earns  less  money  than  it  did  prior  to  the 


See  exhibit  TW-9-T-B. 


508 

fare  decrease.  American  concedes  this  point,  but  fails  to  adequately  explain  why 
a  carrier  would  still  act  in  a  manner  likely  to  decrease  its  revenues. 

Nor  is  there  any  likelihood  that  under  fare  flexibility  carriers  will  adjust  fares 
to  the  level  of  actual  costs  on  a  market-by-market  basis,  that  fare  reductions 
would  be  made  in  those  markets  in  which  actual  costs  are  below  industry  average 
cost  for  the  stage  length  involved,  or  that  fares  would  be  raised  only  in  markets 
where  costs  or  other  justification  exists.  Managements'  basic  incentive  is  the 
maximization  of  revenues,  and  not  adjusting  fares  to  costs.  Accordingly,  in  mar- 
kets where  the  value  of  service  exceeds  the  formula  fare,  carriers  would  seek  to 
raise  fares  to  the  maximum  amount  permitted  resulting  in  fares  based  upon 
whatever  the  traffic  will  bear,  irrespective  of  the  cost  of  service. 

In  sum,  we  are  forced  to  conclude  that  the  zone  proposals  essentially  constitute 
thinly-veiled  efforts  to  eliminate  meaningful  regulation  of  passenger  fares.  The 
proposals  themselves  contain  no  safeguards  to  prevent  unreasonable  increases  in 
the  overall  fare  level.  Moreover,  adoption  of  a  fare  zone  would  nullify  our 
laborious  efforts  to  achieve  a  rational,  equitable  and  cost-oriented  fare  structure. 

Finally,  much  of  the  concern  of  the  proponents  of  a  zone  concept  of  regulation 
is  related  to  the  fear  that  a  detailed  Board  prescription  of  the  specific  fares  to  be 
charged  in  the  future  would  create  intolerable  rigidities.  Such  an  order  woulu, 
until  amended,  preclude  the  filing  of  fare  changes,  and  amendments  could,  in  many 
instances,  necessitate  evidentiary  hearings.  A  fare  prescription  order  which  per- 
mitted deviations  within  a  zone  would  permit  a  degree  of  carrier-initiated  fare 
change  without  procedural  impediments.  However,  as  detailetl  elsewhere  in  this 
opinion,  our  order,  for  the  most  part,  will  not  contain  a  prescription  of  specific 
fares  to  be  charged  for  an  indefinite  future  period.  Instead,  we  have  determined 
not  to  restrict  the  carriers'  freedom  to  file  tariffs  proposing  fare  level  changes, 
or  to  propose  structural  changes  that  have  the  effect  of  bringing  the  fare  curve 
closer  to  the  cost  curve  at  all  distances.  We  will,  however,  restrict  the  carriers' 
discretion  to  propose  structural  changes  which  have  the  effect  of  moving  the 
fare  curve  farther  from  the  cost  line  at  any  distance  than  the  fare  curve  we  have 
adopted  herein.  Throughout  the  various  phases  of  this  investigation,  one  of  the 
Board's  overriding  concerns  has  been  the  development  of  a  fare  structure  as 
closely  cost-based  as  possible.  For  this  reason,  we  believe  it  essential  that  the 
Board  prescribe  the  parameters  of  the  fare  structure  if  our  efforts  are  not  to 
prove  an  exercise  in  futility.  Within  these  limited  constraints,  carriers  will  re- 
main free  to  initiate  fare  changes  by  filing  tariffs  subject  to  our  powers  to  suspend 
and  investigate. 

In  sum,  a  denial  of  fare  flexibility  as  here  proposed  will  not  prevent  carriers 
from  establishing  changed  fare  levels  consistent  with  the  provisions  of  the  Act. 
Nor  does  our  decision  in  any  manner  prevent  carriers  from  offering  new  types 
of  service  at  fares  commensurate  with  costs.  Thus,  fare  flexibility  is  already 
possible  whenever  factors  justifying  its  existence  are  present.  However,  con- 
sidering the  pricing  history  of  this  industry  and  the  true  economic  incentives 
associated  with  increases  or  decreases  in  fares,  we  continue  to  believe  that  a 
close  monitoring  of  propo.sals  for  fare  changes  is  necessary  if  the  public  is  to 
be  protected  from  unreasonable  fares  and  the  economic  viability  of  the  industry 
maintained. 

[Appendix  3] 

Before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  Washington,  D.C. 

[Docket  8008  et  al.] 
(E-16068) 

General  Passenger  Fare   Investigation 

(32  CAB  291,  328-31) 

Decided  November  25,  1960 

KATE    LEVEL 

As  noted  earlier,  the  unreliability  of  the  expense  and  revenue  forecasts  in 
the  record  makes  it  impossible  to  determine  the  proper  fare  level  in  this  pro- 
ceeding. We  have  therefore  confined  ourselves  in  this  opinion  to  the  fixing  of 


509 

the  standards  which  will  be  employed  in  regulating  future  fare  levels.  There 
remains  for  consideration  the  question  of  the  method  of  employing  these  stand- 
ards in  future  cases. 

Essentially,  the  major  problems  of  application  of  the  standards  fall  into  two 
categories:  a)  the  extent  to  which  the  fare  level  should  be  based  upon  results 
to  be  auticiijated  over  an  extended  period,  and  b)  the  extent  to  which  fares 
should  be  regulated  on  an  industrywide  basis. 

a)  No  party  has  suggested  that  we  attempt  to  regulate  fares  so  as  to  produce 
a  particular  rate  of  return  for  every  12-month  period.  It  is  manifest  that  in 
an  industry  in  which  costs  and  revenue  factors  tend  to  fluctuate  and  are  difficult 
to  forecast  precisely  for  any  short-term  period,  any  attempt  to  maintain  a 
constant  rate  of  return  would  be  futile.  There  is  thus  general  agreement  among 
the  parties  that  the  fare  levels  must  be  regulated  to  produce  a  reasonable  return 
over  an  extended  period  of  time. 

This  is  not  to  say  that  short-term  considerations  need  always  be  ignored.  For 
example,  if  fare  relief  is  necessary  to  prevent  financial  ruin  to  the  bulk  of 
the  industry,  we  would  clearly  not  be  justified  in  refusing  such  relief  on  the 
ground  that  the  adverse  factors  responsible  for  the  industry's  condition  were 
merely  of  a  temporary  nature.  Thus,  the  extent  to  which  short-term  factors 
would  be  influential  in  affecting  the  fare  level  must  depend  on  the  length  of 
time  those  factors  are  expected  to  remain  operative  and  the  magnitude  of  their 
impact  on  the  carriers'  operating  results. 

From  the  foregoing  it  is  apparent  that  the  problem  of  determining  when  and 
for  what  periotls  fare  adjustments  should  be  made  cannot  be  relegated  for  solution 
to  any  mechanical  device.  For  this  reason  we  do  not  believe  that  the  5-year  mov- 
ing average  formula  proposed  in  the  initial  decision  is  practicable.^  Rather,  the 
determination  of  when  to  permit  fare  adjustments  and  the  length  of  the  future 
period  which  should  be  considered  in  making  these  adjustments  can  be  resolved 
only  on  a  case-by-case  basis,  applying  informed  judgment  to  the  task  of  balancing 
the  relevant  factors. 

(b)  The  second  major  problem  in  the  application  of  standards  relates  to  the 
so-called  unit  of  ratemaking.  Section  1002(e)  (5)  sets  forth,  as  one  of  the  factors 
to  be  considered  in  ratemaking,  "the  need  of  each  air  carrier  for  revenue  sufficient 
to  enable  such  air  carrier  under  honest,  economical,  and  efficient  management,  to 
provide  adequate  and  efficient  air  service."  While  we  are  thus  enjoined  to  take 
into  consideration  "each"  carrier's  need,  we  are  also  faced  with  the  facts  that 
a  large  part  of  the  domestic  route  structure  is  served  by  two  or  more  carriers 
in  competition,  and  that  fares  must  be  wniform  as  between  them,  notwithstanding 
that  one  carrier's  revenue  need  may  be  less  than  another's.  In  short,  we  must 
reckon  with  the  vexing  problem  of  how  to  reconcile  the  statutory  mandate  to 
consider  the  need  of  "each"  carrier  with  the  hard  fact  that  fares  cannot  be 
regulated  on  an  individual  basis.  Specifically,  shall  fares  be  fixed  to  meet  the 
needs  of  the  carriers  as  a  group,  of  the  smaller  trunks,  of  the  poorest  situated 
carrier  or  possibly  even  of  the  most  favorably  situated  ? 

The  initial  decision  concluded  that  fares  should  be  set  at  levels  which  would 
meet  the  average  of  the  costs,  including  return,  of  the  bulk  of  the  industry.  In 
effect,  the  entire  domestic  trunkline  industry  would  be  treated  as  a  single  unit  and 
would  be  regulated  so  as  to  produce  an  overall  rate  of  return  to  the  industry  equal 
to  10.6  percent,  the  weighted  average  of  the  returns  which  were  found  reasonable 
in  the  initial  decision  for  the  "Big  Four"  and  "Medium  Eight"  carriers,  respec- 
tively. The  parties  disagree  among  themselves  as  to  the  propriety  of  this  "bulk- 
line"  approach.  Some  of  the  carriers  and  bureau  counsel  agree  that  the  nature  of 
the  industry  requires  that  fare  levels  be  set  on  the  basis  of  the  industry  as  a 
whole,  whereas  other  carriers  and  the  GSA  argue  that  the  initial  decision  method 
violates  the  requirement  of  section  1002(e)(5)  that  we  consider  the  need  of 
"each"  carrier.  We  agree  in  general  with  the  result,  although  we  reach  that  result 
by  somewhat  different  means  and  would  subject  it  to  some  qualifications. 


21  The  Initial  decision  found  that  rates  should  be  set  by  a  formula  under  which  aver- 
age earnings  would  be  fair  and  reasonable  over  a  reasonably  extended  oeriod,  yearly 
and  5-year  averages  being  given  special  consideration.  Under  this  formula,  yearly  and 
5-year  earnings  of  the  industry  would  be  allowed  to  fluctuate  between  an  average  of 
10  and  12  percent  on  investment.  Carriers  would  be  allowed  fairly  high  rates  in  an 
individual  year  if  the  5-year  average  is  low,  and  consideration  would  be  given  to  rais- 
ing the  fare  level  if  the  earnings  for  a  particular  year  fall  below  10  percent,  and  to 
lowering  the  fare  level  if  the  5-year  average  rate  is  above  12  percent. 

We  note  that  the  formula  would  have  the  effect,  at  least  partially,  of  adiusting  fu- 
ture rates  to  compensate  for  past  earnings  deficiencies  or  excesses,  a  result  which  appears 
at  war  with  the  doctrine  of  T.W.A.  v.  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  336  U.S.  601  (D.C.  Cir. 
1949). 


510 

The  initial  decision  is  based  in  large  part  on  the  theory  that  regulation  should 
strive  toward  achieving  the  same  kind  of  results  that  would  obtain  in  the  oi>en 
marketplace,  and  upon  the  belief  that  fixing  fares  at  the  level  proposed  in  the 
initial  decision  would  substantially  achieve  that  result.  But  conformance  with 
results  under  hypothetical  free  competitive  conditions  is  not  one  of  the  stated 
policy  objectives  of  the  Act,  nor  is  it  one  of  the  statutory  ratemaking  standards. 
We  would  not  be  justified  in  refusing  to  consider  the  need  of  each  individual 
carrier  merely  because  a  "bulkline"  concept  may  more  nearly  approach  the  results 
under  free  competition.  Nor  can  we  read  section  1002(e)  as  authorizing  the  Board 
to  ignore  the  need  of  each  carrier  in  favor  of  the  need  of  the  carriers  as  a  group. 
As  the  excepting  parties  have  pointed  out,  the  statute  does  not  speak  in  terms  of 
groups  of  carriers  but  rather  of  individual  carriers.  The  fact  that  we  cannot 
regulate  fares  so  as  to  provide  precisely  for  the  need  of  each  individual  carrier 
does  not  authorize  us  to  refuse  to  take  such  need  into  consideration. 

On  the  other  hand,  we  clearly  are  not  required  to  establish  fare  levels  to  meet 
the  need  of  the  most  poorly  situated  carrier  as  Eastern  contends  we  must.  The 
statutory  requirements  that  we  "consider"  the  need  of  each  carrier  is  only  one  of 
five  ratemaking  factors  which  we  are  required  to  weigh.  Consideration  of  the 
other  ratemaking  standards  of  section  1002(e),  particularly  the  effect  of  rates  on 
movement  of  traffic  (section  1002(e)  (1) )  and  the  need  in  the  public  interest  for 
transportation  at  the  lowest  cost  (section  1002(e)(2))  militates  against  the 
adoption  of  the  least  profitable  carrier  as  the  standard  for  fixing  rates.  Moreover, 
the  standard  pressed  upon  us  by  Eastern  would  be  inconsistent  with  the  need 
factor  itself.  Thus,  were  we  to  base  fares  on  the  results  of  the  poorest  situated 
carrier  we  would  of  necessity  be  ignoring  the  need  of  every  other  carrier,  contrary 
to  the  mandate  that  we  consider  the  need  of  each  of  them.  Finally,  to  use  the 
most  poorly  situated  carrier  as  the  unit  of  ratemaking  would  result  in  the  vast 
majority  of  the  public  paying  rates  greatly  in  excess  of  the  cost  of  furnishing  the 
transportation  and  would  unjustly  enrich  the  great  majority  of  the  air  carriers. 

By  the  same  token,  we  obviously  cannot  fix  fare  levels  on  the  basis  of  the  need 
of  the  most  favorably  situated  carrier.  Such  a  standard  could  have  a  disastrous 
impact  upon  many  of  the  other  carriers  and  upon  the  development  of  transpor- 
tation generally.  It  is  thus  clear  that  the  proper  fare  level  must  be  found  at  some 
point  between  the  needs  of  the  most  profitable  and  least  profitable  carriers  and  the 
determination  of  the  unit  to  which  the  standards  shall  be  applied  must  be  based 
upon  informed  judgment.  Insofar  as  the  need  standard  is  concerned,  this  deter- 
mination can  only  be  made  after  testing  any  fare  proposal  against  the  needs  of 
the  industry  as  a  whole,  smaller  groups  of  carriers,  and  each  individual  carrier. 

The  approach  recommended  by  bureau  counsel  appears  to  us  to  accommodate 
reasonably  the  practical  problems  of  industrywide  regulation  with  the  require- 
ments of  the  statute.  The  Bureau  would  first  examine  the  results  of  the  carriers 
as  a  group  by  taking  the  weighted  average  of  the  relationship  of  yield  per  pas- 
senger-mile to  cost  per  passenger-mile  (including  return  on  investment ).^^  This 
industry  average,  although  not  controlling,  is  entitled  to  great  weight.  It  indicates 
the  extent  of  the  general  fare  adjustment  needed  to  produce  a  reasonable  return 
for  the  industry  as  a  whole.  The  Bureau  would  then  test  the  resulting  fare  level 
against  the  needs  of  the  individual  carriers  and  of  groups  of  carriers.  Thus, 
consideration  is  given  to  the  extent  to  which  the  fare  level  meets  the  costs  of  the 
Big  Four  and  the  Medium  Eight  carriers ;  the  relative  number  of  passenger-miles 
accounted  for  by  the  various  carriers ;  the  extent  by  which  each  carrier  deviates 
from  the  norm ;  the  effect  of  such  deviation  on  the  group  and  industry  averages, 
etc. 

In  the  absence  of  special  circumstances,  the  record  indicates  that  rates  which 
meet  the  needs  of  the  domestic  trunkline  industry  as  a  whole  would  reflect  a  bal- 
ancing of  the  needs  of  the  high-cost  and  low-cost  carriers.  Where  the  bulk  of  the 
carriers  fall  within  a  reasonable  range  of  the  rates  of  return  found  herein  to  be 
proper,  and  industry  figures  are  not  distorted  by  the  unrepresentative  results  of 
carriers  who  are  in  extremely  poor  or  extremely  favorable  situations,  fare  adjust- 
ments should  normally  be  based  upon  the  results  for  the  industry  as  a  group. 


=2  The  Bureau   would  weight  the  average  on  the  basis  of  revenue  passenger-miles  per- 
formed by  each  carrier. 


511 

Inevitably,  under  an  industrywide  system  of  regulation  some  carriers  may  fall 
below  the  standard  rate  of  return.  That  a  given  carrier  may  earn  less  than  the 
standard  during  a  particular  period  is  not  by  itself  a  cause  for  concern  since,  as  we 
have  previously  discussed,  the  reasonableness  of  earnings  must  be  Judged  over  an 
extended  period  of  time.  On  the  other  hand,  even  failure  to  earn  the  standard 
return  for  an  extended  period  does  not  necessarily  mean  that  the  particular 
carrier  will  be  unable  to  compete,  grow,  and  prosper.  Our  findings  on  rate  of 
return  demonstrate  that  the  rates  of  10.25  and  11.125  which  we  have  adopted  as 
standards  are  not  miniraum  returns  below  which  confiscation  would  result. 
Rather,  we  have  deliberately  adopted  rates  of  return  which  are  above  the  mini- 
mum returns  but  within  the  broad  range  of  reasonableness.  In  arriving  at  these 
rates,  we  have  taken  into  consideration  the  circumstances,  that  fares  cannot  be 
fixed  on  an  individual-carrier  basis  because  of  the  competitive  nature  of  our 
domestic  rate  structure  and  that  some  carriers  will  of  necessity  earn  less  than  the 
average  standard  of  return.  Thus,  in  view  of  the  level  of  the  rate-of-return 
standards  established,  we  would  not  regard  a  carrier's  earnings  to  be  deficient 
unless  those  earnings  fell  significantly  below  the  standards  for  an  extended 
period. 

The  problem  of  accommodating  the  requirements  of  the  weak  and  strong  car- 
riers is,  of  course,  one  of  the  most  difficult  to  be  found  in  regulation.  Clearly, 
general  fare  increases  cannot  be  regarded  as  the  panacea  capable  of  solving  the 
problem.  There  are  other  tools  which  are  more  appropriate  for  use  in  dealing  with 
the  less  profitable  carriers.  First,  an  overall  examination  of  the  general  passenger- 
fare  structure,  an  issue  excluded  from  this  proceeding,  might  well  result  in 
bringing  the  costs  and  revenues  of  the  individual  carriers  into  closer  alinement. 
Second,  as  the  examiner  pointed  out,  carriers  whose  needs  are  not  met  by  general 
fare-level  adjustments  can  seek  higher  fares,  although  competitive  aspects  would 
preclude  them  from  charging  such  fares  except  on  some  few  noncompetitive  seg- 
ments (assuming,  of  course,  that  such  fares  are  otherwise  lawful).  A  third  tool  is 
that  of  route  realinements  designed  to  produce  a  more  balanced  competitive 
structure.  Finally,  we  are  authorized  by  section  406  of  the  Act  to  grant  subsidy 
payments  where  we  find  that  such  compensation  is  required  in  the  interests  of 
commerce,  the  postal  service,  and  national  defense.  Whether,  and  to  what  extent, 
any  of  these  approaches  should  be  used  will,  of  course,  depend  on  all  surrounding 
circumstances.  Suflice  it  to  say,  however,  that  the  Board  has  available  to  it  a 
number  of  techniques  for  dealing  with  problems  not  amenable  to  solution  by  regu- 
lation of  the  general  level  of  commercial  fares. 

We  have  considered  all  the  exceptions  to  the  initial  decision,  and  we  find 
that,  except  to  the  extent  indicated,  they  should  not  alter  our  decision  herein. 

An  appropriate  order  will  be  entered. 

Chairman  Gillilland,  Vice  Chairman  Gurney,  and  Member  of  the  Board  Boyd, 
concurred  in  the  above  opinion.  Member  Minetti  filed  the  following  concurring 
and  dissenting  opinion.  Member  Bradgon,  did  not  take  part  in  the  decision. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Our  next  witnesses  represent  Eastern,  Delta, 
and  American  Airlines:  Mr.  Morton  Ehrlich,  of  Eastern  Airlines, 
Mr.  Randall  ^Malin  of  American  and  Mr.  Morris  Shipley  of  Delta 
Air  Lines. 

Dr.  Ehrlich  is  vice  president  of  planning  and  chief  economist  for 
Eastern.  In  addition  to  serving  on  various  committees  of  the  Air 
Transport  Association  of  America,  Dr.  Ehrlich  is  an  adviser  to  the 
U.S.  Department  of  Labor. 

Mr.  Eandall  Mai  in,  vice  president  of  market  planning,  has  worked 
for  American  Airlines  since  1961  and  has  had  the  positions  of  director 
of  economic  research,  assistant  to  the  president,  director  of  marketing 
plans  and  assistant  vice  president  of  market  planning. 

Mr.  Morris  Shipley  is  vice  president  of  government  affairs  for 
Delta  Airlines  and  has  been  employed  by  Delta  since  1962. 

I  welcome  you  to  our  hearings  today.  As  you  know,  I  am  going 
to  have  to  leave,  but  we  have  some  questions. 


512 

STATEMENTS  OF  DR.  MORTON  EHRLICH,  VICE  PRESIDENT  FOR 
PLANNING  AND  CHIEF  ECONOMIST,  EASTERN  AIRLINES; 
RANDALL  MALIN,  VICE  PRESIDENT  OF  MARKET  PLANNING, 
AMERICAN  AIRLINES;  AND  MORRIS  SHIPLEY,  VICE  PRESIDENT 
OF  GOVERNMENTAL  AFFAIRS,  DELTA  AIR  LINES 

Senator  Kennedy  [continuing].  Mr.  Malin,  I  know  American  Air- 
lines did  a  study,  a  printout  really,  on  the  costs  of  providing  the  type 
of  service  that  PSA  or  Air  California  offers  in  other  parts  of  the 
country. 

Couid  we  start  off  with  that  ? 

THE  POSSIBILITY  OF  PSA -TYPE  SERVICE  IN  THE  NORTHEAST 

Mr.  Malin.  Yes,  we  said  we  felt  there  were  cost  reductions  that 
could  be  effected  were  we  to  offer  a  computer  only  type  service  in 
one  of  the  Northeast  markets.  We  estimated  that  cost  reduction  at 
approximately  22  percent.  We  spelled  out  the  savings  that  we  thought 
we  could  accomplish,  mainly  in  ticketing  and  reservations  and  on- 
board service.  We  did  not  take  any  savings  for  a  lower  union-wage 
scale  or  a  change  in  work  rules. 

The  point  that  we  see — the  difficidty  we  see  if  we  were  to  implement 
such  a  system  or  if  some  other  carrier  were  to  implement  such  a  sys- 
tem, is  that  it  would  have  an  impact  on  the  citizens  of  Boston,  not  in 
terms  of  their  connnuter  markets,  but  on  the  one-stop  service  that  we 
presently  provide.  We  pointed  out  that  we  currently  operate  15  flights 
in  those  markets  to  Washington  and  New  York,  and  it  may  come  as 
some  surprise  that  41  percent  of  our  passengers  onboard  to  New  York 
are  not  destined  for  New  York  and  20  percent  of  the  passengers  to 
Washington  are  going  beyond  or  connecting  to  another  carrier.  So 
some  ])rovision  has  to  be  made  for  that  traffic,  and  this  is  the  point 
that  others  have  been  making  this  morning,  that  we  are  certificated 
or  part  of  a  number  of  carriers  certificated  to  provide  a  system  of 
air  traffic.  We  are  not  specialists  in  the  commuter  market.  We  do  not 
regard  our  obligations  to  the  Boston  citizenry  just  to  minimize  fares 
fi-om  Boston  to  New  Yoi-k  and  Washington  at  the  expense  of  other 
services. 

So  that  we  feel  what  happens  to  those  other  markets  must  be  taken 
into  consideration  if  a  commuter  service  is  to  be  implemented.  At  the 
time  that  Eastern  implemented  their  shuttle  in  1961,  American  felt  it 
could  not  compete  and  Ave  ])retty  nuich  withdrew  from  the  shuttle 
market.  It  was  not  until  the  price  came  back  up  that  we  reentered  those 
markets. 

Mr.  Shipley.  Delta  has  not  made  any  studies  of  this  thing,  and  there 
is  one  item  that  has  not  come  up  and  I  would  like  to  point  out,  and 
that  is  the  limitations  of  the  use  of  Washington  National  Airport, 
Tliere  is  an  absolute  curfew  on  jet  operation  between  10  p.m.  and  7  a.m. 
in  the  morning.  As  it  happens  Delta  has  the  fcAvest  slot  operations  save 
one.  There  is  no  way  we  could  implement  any  high  frequency  opera- 
tions in  the  market. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  might  have  a  reduction  of  the  total  number 
of  planes.  If  you  had  the  planes  fuller  there  might  be  less  frequency. 


513 

There  is  no  reason  in  the  world  it  necessarily  means  you  will  have  more 
frequency  on  it. 

Mr.  Shipley.  With  the  slot  allocations  of  Delta  at  the  present  time 
we  cannot  operate  really  any  more  frequency  of  service. 

Senator  Kj:xnedy.  Who  allocates  that? 

Mr.  Shipley.  It  is  done.  The  limit  is  placed  by  the  FAA  and  within 
that  hourly  limit  the  carriers  primarily  on  grandfather  basis  and  with 
approval  of  the  CAB  made  the  actual  allocation  arrangements. 

Senator  Kexni:dy.  It  is  really  done  within  the  airlines  themselves,  is 
that  correct? 

Mr.  Shipley.  That  is  correct. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  would  not  welcome  having  some  other  people 
trying  to  come  in  there  and  having  them  really  shake  up  that  allocation 
again. 

Mr.  Shipley.  Delta  Avould  be  delighted  to  get  some  more  allocations, 
sir. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  Eastern  Airlines  has  been  flying  the  shuttle  for  many 
years  now  and  has  one  striking  characteristic,  it  seems  to  be  the  type 
of  service  that  people  who  travel  in  this  corridor  are  demanding.  We  at 
various  times  attempted  to  gain  a  larger  share  of  the  market.  We  run 
about  70  percent  of  the  market  at  roughly  that  load  factor. 

A  few  years  ago  we  attempted  to  put  on  a  meal  service  or  a  snack 
service  and  Ave  noticed  that  our  market  share  deteriorated  several 
points.  We  went  back  to  basic  no-frills  in-flight  ticket  plan  and  our 
market  shares  snapped  right  back. 

Our  conclusion,  although  we  have  looked  at  the  PSA  kind  of  service, 
we  feel  we  are  providing  precisely  the  type  of  service  that  traffic  in 
the  corridor  is  demanding  and  our  success  in  that  area  justifies  the  type 
of  service  we  are  providing. 

I  Avould  also  point  out  that  with  regard  to  the  slot  problem,  La 
Guardia  is  in  precisely  the  same  situation  as  Washington  National. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  as  I  understand.  Eastern  expansion  can 
expand  capacity  with  larger  backup  planes  in  parts  of  their  shuttle. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  That  is  right. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  could  you  not  provide  both  services:  a 
cheaper  service  that  Avould  be  available  to  consumers,  maybe  at  a 
time  when  they  would  need  to  make  a  reservation,  and  also  the  shuttle. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  We  tried  that  several  years  ago,  recognizing  the  fact 
we  do  have  backup  service,  and  that  is  largely  to  provide  passage  for 
peak  houi-s.  We  recognize  if  we  coujd  shift  traffic  off  the  peaks  it  would 
reduce  the  need  for  airplanes  and  thus  reduce  the  need  for  backup 
aircraft.  AVe  filed  for  lower  fares  and  the  Board  approved  it,  but  we 
did  not  move  one  single  passenger  off  peak  hours.  People  have  a  way  of 
travel  and  what  we  found  in  that  particular  corridor,  we  cannot  shift 
them  off  peak  travel  hours. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  much  did  you  discount  the  fare? 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  I  think  it  was  $8. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you.  Dr.  Ehrlich.  I  am  going  to  have  to 
leave. 

We  have  Mr.  Murphy  of  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission  who 
still  has  not  had  a  chance  to  testify.  There  are  a  few  further  points  I 
would  like  counsel  to  develop  with  you.  If  you  can  stay,  I  Avill  ask 
counsel  to  proceed. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  : 


514 

Mr.  Breter  [presiding] .  I  think  the  most  efficient  thing  to  do  would 
be  the  following.  The  staff  has  looked  through  everybody's  testimony 
and  the  various  documents,  to  try  to  answer  the  basic  question :  Why 
is  it  less  expensive  to  fly  in  California  than  it  is  to  fly  in  the  East  ? 
There  are  a  number  of  reasons  advanced.  We  have  had  to  use  what- 
ever facts  were  readily  available  to  evaluate  them,  I  would  like  to 
spend  10  minutes  reading  into  the  record  our  evaluation  of  each  of  the 
reasons  advanced.  I  would  appreciate  it  if  both  the  airlines  and  the 
Board  or  anyone  else  w'ho  is  interested  would  go  through  the  record 
and  correct  any  mistake,  fact,  or  evaluation.  I  think  that  would  be 
simpler  than  asking  you  questions.  Everybody  could  then  respond  to 
what  is  a  "rough  first  draft"  effort. 

These  are  the  various  reasons  given  to  explain  for  the  difference  in 
costs : 

The  first  is  "differences  in  weather."  We  asked  the  FAA  for  figures, 
They  told  us  that  less  than  1  percent  of  the  flights  in  Washington 
Airport,  Xew  York,  and  Boston  are  delayed  because  of  weather.  Thus, 
weather  does  not  account  for  much  of  the  cost  difference. 

The  second  factor  is  traffic  density.  If  you  compare  the  Wash- 
ington-Boston fare,  $44,  with  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  fare  of 
$18.50,  and  then  look  at  the  density,  you  find  that  Los  Angeles-San 
Francisco  route  is  much  denser.  There  is  no  question  about  that. 

But  other  fares  in  Texas  and  California,  such  as  the  Orange  County- 
San  Francisco  fare,  are  only  half  as  high  as  the  Boston- Washington 
fare  even  though  their  markets  are  only  one-third  or  one-half  as  dense 
as  the  Boston-Washington  market.  So  that  leads  us  to  believe  Pro- 
fessor Jordon's  statement  of  the  matter:  "Once  you  get  to  100,000 
passengers  a  year,  density  is  not  a  problem." 

The  third  factor  the  CAB  mentioned  is  the  direction  of  traffic  flow : 
That  is,  does  it  only  move  in  one  direction  ?  It  did  not  seem  to  us  that 
the  Boston-Washington  market  tends  to  move  in  one  direction  any- 
more than  the  California  markets,  or  that  it  is  particularly  more  sea- 
sonal than  the  California  market  or  the  Texas  market. 

The  fourth  factor  is  extra  reservation  costs  and  other  interlining 
costs.  Dr.  Summerfield  went  into  that  only  in  some  depth,  and  con- 
cluded that  it  amounts  to  $1.50  per  passenger. 

Fifth,  there  are  extra  labor  costs,  a  third  man  in  the  cockpit  and  a 
number  of  miscellaneous  costs,  meals,  frills,  and  so  forth.  Dr.  Summer- 
field  went  into  these  matters ;  they  came  to  another  $1.58  per  passenger 
or  so.  So  both  the  extra  reservations,  the  interlining  costs,  et  cetera 
seemed  to  come  to  $3  a  ticket  which  did  not  go  very  far  in  explaining 
$18  difference  between  interstate  and  intrastate  fares  within  Cali- 
fornia, or  the  $25  fare  difference  between  California  and  the  east 
coast. 

The  next  difference  was  that  the  CAB  claimed  different  airplanes 
are  flown  on  the  different  routes.  We  looked  to  see  what  airplanes  were 
flown.  The  airlines  in  Texas,  California,  and  on  the  CAB-regulated 
routes  all  fly  727's  or  737's.  On  the  CAB  routes,  they  fly  some  I)C-9's, 
too.  I  don't  see  Avhy  that  should  make  any  difference. 

The  seventh  factor  is  airport  congestion.  Airport  congestion  seems 
to  be  worse  in  the  East.  So  we  tried  to  look  at  flights  on  which  ramp- 
to-ramp  time  is  roughly  the  same.  That  should  take  into  account  con- 


515 

gestion  both  on  the  ground  and  in  tlie  air.  So,  if  you  compare  flightlegs 
with  ranip-to-ramp  times  that  are  roughly  comparabk\  it  looks  as  if 
routes  with  similar  times  in  California  or  in  Texas  have  about  two- 
thirds  the  fare  of  CxV15-regulated  routes.  The  CAB  chart  on  this  is 
quite  interesting.  The  CAB  chart  suggests  if  you  look  at  routes  on  a 
fare  per  minute  basis,  the  California  and  the  Texas  fares  are  about 
two-thirds  or  maybe  half  the  east  coast  fares. 

Then  there  were  items  like  regulatory  costs,  filing  fees,  et  cetera, 
that  is  number  eight.  They  did  not  seem  significant. 

Xumber  nine :  The  need  to  support  other  routes  in  the  system.  That 
seems  the  most  serious  and  the  hardest  to  get  firm  information  on. 
To  what  extent  should  people  who  fly  Boston-Washington  actually 
pay  more  to  subsidize  someone  else  in  a  different  part  of  the  system? 
Well,  are  there  such  people  who  are  being  subsidized?  DOT  and 
others  say  there  are  not  many.  The  Board  says  there  are  not  many. 
Are  there,  or  aren't  there  ?  We  are  trying  to  get  solid  information  on 
that.  If  there  are  such  subsidies,  we  should  like  to  know  why  they 
ought  to  exist. 

Number  10:  In  California  and  Texas,  airlines  fill  up  the  plane 
more  and  haA'e  more  seats  in  the  plane.  Everyone  seems  to  think  this 
factor  is  important.  Of  course,  that  raises  the  question  of  whether  the 
consumer  in  the  East  too  should  be  offered  a  choice  of  flights  with 
fuller  planes,  more  seats  in  the  plane,  and  no  meals.  I  think  that  is 
a  serious  question. 

Xow,  I  have  listed  the  factors.  Our  rough  information  on  each  is 
contained  in  our  charts.  We  have  to  write  a  report  that  will  reflect  a 
dialog  with  the  industry,  the  Board,  and  others.  It  would  be  helpful 
to  have  people  look  at  each  of  these  factors  and  either  substantiate 
our  conclusions,  or  show  these  tentative  conclusions  are  wrong^ 

[Tentative  conclusions  of  subcommittee  staff  follow :] 


Interstate/Intrastate  Fare  Comparison 

tentative  staff  conclusions 
The  problem 

Fares  on  intrastate  routes  (unregulated  by  the  CAB)  are  one-half  to  two- 
thirds  the  level  of  fares  on  apparently  similar  interstate  CAB-regulated  routes. 
For  example,  the  fare  for  the  338-mile,  55-minute  flight  from  San  Francisco  to 
Los  Angeles  is  $18.75 ;  but  the  fare  for  the  399-mile,  67-minute  flight  from  Boston 
to  Washington  is  $41.67.  Similarly  the  fare  for  the  109-mile,  30-minute  flight 
from  Los  Angeles  to  San  Diego  is  $10.10;  while  the  129-mile,  35-minute  flight 
from  Portland  to  Seattle  is  $22.22.  What  explains  these  fare  differences? 

Proposed  explanations 

The  CAB,  outside  exi>erts,  and  the  carriers  have  advanced  a  number  of  expla- 
nations. We  have  tried  to  evaluate  the  importance  of  each  of  them : 

1.  Differences  in  the  iccather. — The  carriers  argue  that  worse  weather  con- 
ditions in  the  East  add  to  the  cost  of  eastern  flights.  The  Federal  Aviation  Agenc.v 
reports,  however,  weather  conditions  cause  cancellation  or  delay  of  less  than 
1  percent  of  all  flights  at  Logan  Field  (Bo.ston),  La  Guardia  Airport  (New  York) 
or  National  Airport  (Washington).  Weather  does  not  account  for  a  significant 
portion  of  fare  differences  from  $20  to  $50. 

2.  Traffic  density. — The  carriers  argue  that  fare  differences  arise  because  it 
is  cheaper  to  serve  routes  with  a  high-traffic  density.  Although  the  Boston- 
Wa.shington  fare  of  $41.67  is  more  than  twice  as  high  as  the  San  Francisco- 
Los  Angeles  fare  of  $18.75,  nearly  7  million  passengers  fly  between  San  Fran- 


516 

Cisco  and  Los  Angeles,  while  only  980,000  fly  from  Boston  to  Washington.  The 
attached  table  however,  compares  Boston-Washington  and  other  routes  of  vary- 
ing densities  with  unregulated  routes  with  less  traflSc  density  as  well  (e.g.  Orange 
County-San  Francisco  with  300,000  passengers).  Once  a  traffic  level  of  100,000 
is  reached,  additional  density  seems  to  make  little,  or  no  cost  difference.  Thus, 
this  factor  is  of  little  significance. 

3.  Direction  of  traffic  flow. — The  CAB  pointed  out  that  routes  where  traffic 
flows  primarily  in  one  direction  or  are  highly  seasonal  are  more  expensive  to 
operate.  This  factor  is  not  relevant  in  the  case  of  the  routes  listed  on  the 
attached  table. 

■i-  Congestion. — The  carriers  and  the  Board  point  out  that  routes  in  the  North- 
east are  more  expensive  to  fly  because  of  added  congestion  in  the  air  and  on  the 
ground.  This  factor  can  be  measured  by  looking  at  ramp-to-ramp  flight  times, 
for  added  congestion,  either  on  the  ground  or  in  the  air,  and  will  simply  have 
the  effect  of  delaying  flights  and  increasing  the  total  flight  time.  The  attached 
chart  allows  comparisons  among  routes  of  roughly  similar  ramp-to-ramp  times, 
and,  again,  it  reveals  vast  fare  differences  between  California-Texas  and  else- 
where (compare,  for  example,  Boston-Washington  with  San  Diego-San  Fran- 
cisco). Additionally,  the  CAB's  tables  show  large  differences  in  "fare  per  minute" 
(the  fare  for  the  route  divided  by  the  number  of  minutes  necessary  to  fly  it). 
Thus  it  does  not  appear  that  congestion  could  account  for  more  than  a  small 
part  of  the  fare  difference. 

5.  Additional  labor  costs,  reservation  system  costs,  higher  airport  costs  and 
other  interline  system  costs. — The  airlines  argue  that  being  part  of  a  large 
system  imposes  additional  labor,  reservation  system,  baggage,  and  other  mi.s- 
cellaneous  costs  on  them  that  the  California  and  Texas  carriers  can  avoid.  Dr. 
Summerfield,  an  expert  consultant  hired  by  the  carriers"  Air  Transport  Associa- 
tion, measured  the  cost  burden  that  PSA — the  California  carrier — escapes  by 
not  being  part  of  such  a  system.  He  estimated  the  burden  at  .$20  million  per 
year,  or  approximately  $3  per  passenger.  This  figure  explains  only  half  of  the 
difference  between  the  .$18  fare  the  PSA  charges  to  fly  San  Francisco-Los 
Angeles  and  the  $26  (interstate)  fare  that  the  CAB-regulated  carriers  charge 
to  fly  exactly  the  same  route. 

6.  Regulatory  costs. — Several  witnesses  pointed  out  that  the  cost  of  appear- 
ing before  the  CAB  is  significant.  The  carriers,  in  their  answers  to  the  sub- 
committee's questionnaire,  however,  estimated  their  cost  at  several  hundred 
thousand  dollars  per  year,  or  a  few  cents  per  passenger. 

7.  Different  aircraft. — The  Board  pointed  out  that  different  costs  are  asso- 
ciated with  different  aircraft.  Since  the  California,  the  Texas,  and  the  CAB 
carriers  fly  727's  and  737's  (the  CAB  carriers  also  fly  some  DC-9's),  the  air- 
craft types  do  not  appear  to  account  for  much  of  the  fare  differences. 

8.  The  need  to  support  other  routes  in  the  system. — The  airlines  argue  that 
they  must  charge  a  higher  price  on  some  routes  in  order  to  provide  enough 
revenue  to  subsidize  service  on  other  routes.  So  far,  however,  the  airlines  have 
not  provided  us  with  a  list  of  routes  that  are  so  subsidized,  nor  have  they 
claimed  that  the  routes  directly  comparable  to  those  in  California  (e.g.,  Boston- 
Washington)  are  routes  on  which  their  fares  are  signiflcantly  higher  than  their 
losses. 

American  has  claimed  that  to  provide  turn-around  .service  between  Boston 
and  Washington  would  inconvenience  those  passengers  on  the  plane  going  beyond 
Boston  or  beyond  Washington,  yet,  the  inability  to  provide  turnaround  service 
would  raise  costs  only  $4  to  $5  per  passenger.  This  does  not  appear  to  be  an 
inordinate  amount,  since,  according  to  the  CAB,  83  percent  of  all  passengers 
flying  from  Boston  to  Washington  get  off  in  Washington.  It  is  not  clear  why 
the  public  shouM  have  to  do  without  turnaround  service  in  order  to  save  a  few 
travelers  the  trouble  of  changing  planes. 

9.  Seating  capacity  and  load  factors. — The  major  reason  for  lower  costs  in 
California  and  Texas  seems  to  be  that  the  airlines  there  put  more  seats  in  the 
airplanes  and  fill  up  more  seats.  For  example,  PSA  puts  158  seats  in  a  727-30 ; 
American  puts  121  seats  in  the  same  plane.  PSA  flies  at  a  60  percent  load  factor, 
carrying  an  average  of  95  paying  passengers  in  its  727-30,  while  American,  flying 
at  a  55  percent  load  factor  between  Washington  and  Boston,  carries  an  average 
of  66  paying  passengers  in  the  same  plane. 


517 


City-pair 


Passengers 
transported ' 


Load 
factor  < 


Block 
time' 


•Los  Angeles-San  Francisco $18.75 

Chicago-Minneapolis .  38.89 

New  York-Pittsburgh 37.96 

•Los  Angeles-San  Diego 10.10 

•San  Francisco-Sacramento. 9. 73 

Portland-Seattle _.  22.22 

•Los  Angeles-Sacramento 20.47 

Boston-Washington 41.67 

Cleveland-New  York... 43.52 

Chicago-Kansas  City 37.96 

Chicago-Pittsburgh _ _..  41.67 

•San  Francisco-San  Diego 26.21 

Detroit-Philadelphia.- 45.37 

Dallas/Fort  Worth-New  Orleans 44.44 

New  York-Raleigh/Durham 44.44 

Columbus-New  York_ 47.22 

•Dallas/Fort  Worth-Houston 23.15/13.89 

•Dallas/Fort  Worth-San  Antonio 23. 15/13.  89 

Las  Vegas-Los  Angeles 28.70 

Chicago-St.  Louis 29.63 

•Houston-San  Antonio 23.15/13.89 

Boston-New  York 24.07 

Reno-San  Francisco 25.93 

Miami-Orlando 25.93 


338 
339 
335 

9  7,483,419 

1,  424,  621 

975,  344 

59.0 
53.1 
52.5 

:55 
1:06 
1:05 

109 
86 
129 

2,518,701 

505, 148 

1,217,381 

52.0 
41.6 
37.3 

:30 
:30 
:35 

373 
399 
416 
404 
413 

915,  077 
981,456 
910,270 
813,235 
972, 543 

57.5 
55.1 
59.3 
56.5 
52.2 

1:00 
1:07 
1:25 
1:10 
1:23 

456 
454 
442 
423 
478 

399,  639 
313,439 
522,223 
267,  272 
294,  682 

60.3 
48.6 
48.0 
61. 5 
61.8 

1:05 
1:25 
1:15 
1:15 
1:18 

239 
248 
236 
258 

1,  620,  000 
980, 000 

1,181,466 
953,  604 

59.1 
59.3 
63.5 
61.8 

:50 
:50 
:50 
:50 

191 
191 
192 
193 

490,  000 

2,  493,  882 

312,811 

514,  475 

25.4 
56.7 
58.0 
40.5 

:40 
:50 
:46 
:40 

•Intrastate  markets. 

1  Interstate  markets:  Coach  fare.  Intrastate  markets:  Economy  fare.  Source:  "Official  Aiiiine  Guide,"  Feb.  1, 1975. 

2  Source:  Book  of  Official  CAB  Route  Maps  and  Airport-to-Airport  Mileages.  Most  entries  are  volume-weighted  averages 
of  two  or  more  airport-to-airport  mileages. 

3  Source:  Interstate  markets— CAB  service  segment  data,  special  computer  tabulation,  reporting  period  from  July  1, 
1973  to  June  30,  1974.  Intrastate  markets— California  PUC  form  1504  report,  reporting  period  from  Apr.  1,  1973  to  Mar.  31, 
1974. 

*  Revenue  passengers-available  seats.  Entries  for  California  and  Texas  intrastate  markets  include  PSA  and  Southwest 
only.  Source:  same  as  reference  3. 
5  Average  scheduled  flight  time.  Source:  Official  Airline  Guide,  Feb.  1, 1975. 

«  California  markets  include  traffic  to  and  from  suburban  airports.  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  includes  12  airport-pairs, 
for  example: 

LAX-SFO 18.75  338         2,984,985  59.0  :55 

ONT-SFO 20.47  363  334,208  60.2  :55 


Mr.  Breter.  I  would  like  to  ask  American  Airlines  a  question. 

Looking  at  your  chart  in  your  prepared  statement,  you  say  that  you 
really  could  make  a  Boston-Washington  commuter  service  pay  if  you 
had  112  passengers,  roughly.  Is  that  correct? 

Mr.  Malix.  Yes, 

Mr.  Breyer.  Couldn't  you  put  158  seats  in  the  plane  as  PSA  does? 
You  then  would  have  a  lower-load  factor  and  it  might  be  more 
practical. 

Mr.  Malix.  Yes ;  it  is  theoretically  practical.  It  reduces  the  break- 
even load  factor  to  the  low  seventies.  But  there  would  be  offsetting  dis- 
economies from  taking  a  fleet  of  airplanes,  say  four  727's,  isolating 
them  to  one  market,  and  just  spinning  them  around.  Obviously  those 
airplanes  could  no  longer  get  lost  in  the  system,  so  we  would  lose 
flexibility. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Which  might  raise  costs  somewhere  else. 

Mr.  Malix.  Could  raise  costs  someplace  else. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Could  you  work  out  the  economies  ? 

Mr.  Malix.  Thirteen  out  of  15  flights  in  these  markets  do  go  on, 
so  all  of  that  service  would  be  lost.  Some  Boston  residents  desiring  to 
get  to  Memphis  would  simply  have  to  find  some  other  way  to  do  it. 
That  is  the  offset,  the  loss  in  terms  of  public  service. 

Mr.  Breyer.  I  think  the  best  thing  to  do,  rather  than  have  me  ask 
questions  is  simply  to  leave  it  at  this.  You  have  a  set  of  factors  and 


518 

people  could  submit  statements  for  the  record^  unless  you  would  like 
to  say  anything  else, 

Mr.  Malin.  I  would  like  to  challenge  your  point  on  congestion 
American  flies  the  200-mile  segment  between  La  Guardia  and  Wash- 
ington in  2  minutes  shorter  than  the  PSA  flies  Los  Angeles-San 
Francisco.  This  is  not  comparable,  in  my  book. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Sorry.  We  had  brought  out  differences  in  airborne  time. 
If  you  look  at  the  airborne  plus  ground  times,  which  takes  this  delay 
into  account,  there  is  a  considerable  diiference.  We  have  roughly 
an  hour  and  10  minutes  for  the  Boston-Washington  segment  and 
roughly  59  minutes  for  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  you  are  right. 
But  look  at  other  routes  where  total  times  are  about  the  same.  There 
are  a  number  of  other  routes  which  we  have  on  our  charts.  Take  San 
Diego-Sacramento  and  compare  it  with  Chicago-Minneapolis.  You 
get  total  times,  ramp-to-ramp  times,  and  still  the  fare  looks  about 
two-thirds  as  high. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  Did  you  calculate  what  you  would  expect  to  be  the 
cost  differential  simply  because  of  the  speed  factor  and  block-to-block 
times  in  the  PSA  route  ? 

Mr.  Breyer.  We  tried  to  do  that.  As  you  know  much  better  than 
I  do,  it  is  extraordinarily  complicated.  We  have  all  kinds  of  different 
numbers.  I  will  give  you  copies  of  all  the  tables.  You  will  have  these 
numbers,  and  I  am  sure  that  there  are  lots  of  arguments  about  them. 
I  think  the  way  to  proceed  is  by  Avritten  dialog. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  I  would  strongly  urge  that  you  make  a  very  specific 
attempt  to  make  that  calculation,  because  what  you  will  find  is  that 
most  costs  are  based  on  block-to-block  times.  The  simple  fact  that  an 
airplane  is  forced  to  fly  a  lot  slower,  200  miles  relative  to  -350  miles, 
causes  the  cost  increment  to  increase  very,  very  substantially. 

Mr.  Breyer.  The  operating  costs  of  the  airplane  comprise  only  one 
portion  of  it. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  I  think  you  will  find  on  a  block-time  basis  that  the 
differential  would  run  into  several  dollars  of  cost. 
Mr.  Breyer.  Would  you  work  something  out  ? 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  The  other  point  I  would  urge  you  to  consider  is  the 
differential  in  landing  fees  among  the  airports. 
Mr.  Breyer.  ^ye  have  that. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  Based  upon  landing  fees  in  the  PSA  operation  relative 
to  the  east  coast  corridor  is  roughly  30  to  35  cents  difference  per 
passenger. 

Mr.  Brei-er.  Exactly.  I  think  Dr.  Summerfield  had  that  in  his 
testimony. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  I  think  another  element  makes  a  big  difference, 
roughly  a  half  dollar  per  passenger  is  the  difference  in  pilot  pay  in  the 
PSA  relative  to  the  trunk  carriers  on  the  east  coast,  and  that  adds 
roughly  another  half  a  dollar  increment. 

iNIr.  Breyer.  I  Avould  ask  Mr.  :Murphy  if  you  would  submit  written 
testimony  ?  Would  you  like  to  come  up  ? 

Mr.  jNIalix.  Before  we  step  down,  one  clarification.  The  Senator 
was  using  an  operating  factor  which  is  percentage  of  miles  completed. 
That  is  quite  different  from  delay.  Of  our  operations  at  La  Guardia,  50 
percent  are  delayed  to  some  degree.  They  may  all  complete  their  trip, 
but  it  is  delay  factor  that  is  important. 


519 

Mr.  Breyer.  Do  you  think  it  is  fair  to  look  at  routes  that  have 
roughly  the  same  ramp-to-ramp  time?  It  seems  to  me  that  is  a  reason- 
able way  to  take  delay  into  account  ?  Do  you  think  so  ? 

Mr,  Malin.  Yes. 

Mr.  Breyer.  All  right.  So  we  find  on  fairly  comparable  routes  the 
fares  are  still 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  When  you  consider  the  implications  of  on-time  per- 
formance and  the  costs 

Mr.  Breyer.  That  should  sliow^  up  in  ramp-to-ramp  time,  should  it 
not. 

Dr.  Ehrlich.  On  a  performance  basis? 

Mr.  Breyer.  Yes ;  on  a  performance  basis. 

Mr.  Shipley.  Mr.  Breyer,  I  would  like  to  note  in  connection  with 
your  request  that  we  submit  written  statements  on  this.  Delta  cer- 
tainly will  do  its  best,  and  if  the  information  is  available,  or  can  be 
made  available  without  undue  burden,  we  will  submit  a  response. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statements  of  Dr.  Ehrlich,  and  Messrs.  Kandall 
Malin,  and  Morris  Shipley  follow :] 

Prepared   Statement  of  Dr.   Morton   Ehrlich 

The  topic  of  today's  hearings  has  been  listed  as  "Comparison  of  State  and 
Federal  Regulation  of  Airlines  and  Comparison  of  State  Air  Fares  with  Inter- 
state Air  Fares."  The  major  domestic  markets,  both  long-haul  and  short-haul, 
served  by  Eastern  Airlines  are  in  interstate  air  transportation.  Eastern, 
unlike  some  of  the  other  Federally-certified  carriers,  is  not  authorized  to  serve 
any  significant  intrastate  markets,  such  as  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  on  the 
West  Coast  or  Dallas/Fort  Worth-Houston  within  the  State  of  Texas.  For  these 
reasons,  insofar  as  its  own  operations  are  concerned,  Eastern  is  not  a  carrier 
that  is  in  a  position  to  discuss  any  comparison  of  differences  that  may  exist  in 
the  State  and  Federal  regulation  of  air  transportation  markets,  particularly 
with  regard  to  air  fares. 

The  air  fares  in  Eastern's  domestic  interstate  markets  are  regulated  by  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board  under  the  powers  granted  to  that  agency  in  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act  by  Congress.  This  is  one  of  the  major  regulatory  functions  of  the 
Board  and  one  that  has  been  the  subject  of  intensive  proceedings  before  the 
Board  in  recent  years.  In  1970,  the  Board  instituted  the  Domestic  Passenger 
Fare  Investigation  to  determine  the  policies  and  standards  that  should  be  fol- 
lowed by  the  Board  in  its  review  and  regulation  of  domestic  air  fares.  The  guiding 
criteria  laid  down  by  Congress  to  be  followed  by  the  Board  in  completing  this 
large  task  are  set  forth  in  the  Declaration  of  Policy  (.section  102  of  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act)  and  the  Ratemaking  Standards  (section  1002(e)  of  the  Act).  In 
simplified  terms,  the  job  of  the  Board  is  to  determine  the  revenues  needed  by  the 
carriers  to  cover  their  costs  (including  a  reasonable  return  on  investment)  so 
they  can  offer  the  services  that  are  reqmred  by  the  public  interest. 

The  Board  is  just  now  completing  the  final  phases  of  the  Domestic  Passenger 
Fare  Investigation.  In  one  of  its  phases,  the  Board  has  determined  the  overall 
fare  level  need  of  the  carriers  (ba.sed  on  such  standards  as  load  factor,  seating 
configuration,  depreciation,  rate  of  return,  etc.).  The  Board  has  then  translated 
this  overall  revenue  need  into  a  fare  structure,  which  produces  fares  in  individual 
markets  varying  by  length  of  pas.senger  haul  (with  a  downward  taper  In  yield 
per  mile  as  the  length  of  haul  increases).  This  is  illustrated  in  the  attach- 
ment, which  is  a  chart  from  the  Board's  decision  in  Phase  9  of  the  DPFI,  showing 
how  the  Board's  fare  formula  relates  to  the  cost  of  .service  at  various  lengths  of 
haul.  While  the  fare  formula  does  not  "track"  the  cost  curve  precisely,  the  basic 
objective  of  a  cost-related  fare  formula  is  achieved.  It  is  of  interest  that  the 
Board's  fare  formula  in  markets  of  approximately  400  miles  or  less  produces 
fares  that  are  less  than  costs  at  the.se  distances. 

While,  as  indicated  above,  Ea.stern  does  not  operate  in  any  major  intrastate 
markets,  we  are  aware  of  fare  comparisons  that  are  sometimes  made  between  the 
interstate  markets  in  the  Northea.st  corridor  (e.g.,  the  New  York-Boston  and 
New  York-Washington  markets  served  by  Eastern)  and  the  intrastate  service 
between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  First  of  all,  it  must  be  understood,  as 


520 


stated  above,  that  under  the  Federal  regulation  of  interstate  markets,  fares  in 
individual  markets  are  not  set  in  isolation.  The  objective  of  the  Board  is  to 
establish  a  basic  formula  that  will  produce  a  rational  integrated  fare  structure 
for  the  entire  interstate  route  network  where  a  single  market  or  group  of  markets 
is  not  favored  to  the  detriment  of  other  markets.  It  is  this  overall  nationwide 
fare  formula  that  produces  Eastern's  fares  in  the  Northeast  corridor.  Specifically, 
the  fares  on  the  air  shuttle  in  the  Northeast  corridor  are  precisely  equal  to  the 
basic  coach  fare  produced  under  the  Board's  formula. 

Beyond  this,  there  are  other  factors  which  demonstrate  that  it  is  not  possible 
to  make  an  uncritical  comparison  of  the  Northeast  corridor  interstate  fares  and 
the  intrastate  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  fares.  There  are  a  number  of  substan- 
tial differences  in  these  two  operations  which  are  a  continent  apart.  For  example, 
such  factors  as  weather  and  aircaft  traffic  congestion  are  not  comparable.  There 
is  a  substantial  difference  in  the  speed  at  which  the  aircraft  operate  in  the  two 
services.  While  the  Northeast  corridor  stage  lengths  New  York-Boston  (185 
miles)  and  New  York-Washington  (214  miles)  are  shorter  than  Los  Angeles-San 
Francisco  (347  miles),  the  published  travel  times  are  the  same  (1  hour).  This 
means  that  Eastern's  jet  aircraft  are  able  to  attain  average  speeds  of  only 
185  m.p.h.  (New  York-Boston)  or  214  m.p.h.  (New  York-Washington)  compared 
to  347  m.p.h.  betwen  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  This  is  important  when  it  is 
remembered  that  labor  costs  are  incurred  by  the  hour,  a  factor  which  is  further 
compounded  by  the  rate  differentials  for  employees  that  exist  between  Eastern's 
service  and  the  intrastate  operations  on  the  west  coast.  In  addition,  there  are 
different  landing  fees  in  the  two  services,  with  a  rate  of  $1.45  at  La  Guardia 
compared  to  $0.40  at  Los  Angeles  per  1,000  pounds  landing  weight.  On  an  annual 
basis  this  amounts  to  $1,800,000. 

In  conclusion.  Eastern  believes  that  the  air  shuttle  services  in  the  Northeast 
corridor  are  an  important  public  service  in  these  markets.  The  service  has  been 
used  by  over  36  million  passengers  since  its  inception  and  the  no-reservation  back- 
up section  feature  has  been  well  received  by  the  public.  In  this  regard,  it  is 
important  to  note  that  the  air  shuttle  is  conducted  in  a  highly  competitive  en- 
vironment, with  12  airlines  having  authority  in  the  corridor,  four  of  them  on  an 
unrestricted  basis.  Thus,  the  air  shuttle  competes  against  other  carriers  in  the 
market,  including  those  operating  on  a  conventional  reservation,  two-class  serv- 
ice. It  is  up  to  the  public  to  make  its  choice  of  the  types  of  service  in  these 
markets.  There  is  abundant  authority  in  the  markets  that  enables  the  carriers  to 
offer  the  public  whatever  services  they  desire  at  fares  consistent  with  the  coach 
fares  derived  under  the  Board's  industrywide  fare  formula. 


PRESESI  FARE  FORMULA 


BOARD'S  fASE  Fo::.;uu 


SOL'.'^CE:      CAB  Oruer  74-3-32. 


521 

Prepared  Statement  of  Randall  Malin 

1.  It  is  our  understanding  that  the  purpose  of  this  phase  of  the  suhcommittee's 
hearings  is  to  discuss  the  costs  of  a  commuter-type  air  service  in  the  Boston/ 
New  York/Washington  corridor,  and  to  determine  if  there  is  justification  for 
fares  in  these  markets  to  be  different  than  those  offered  by  intrastate  carriers 
such  as  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  (PSA)  in  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco 
market. 

2.  For  purposes  of  this  inquiry,  American  has  appended  detailed  estimates  of 
operating  service  in  two  of  the  Northeast  corridor  markets,  Boston-Washington 
and  New  York-Washington.^ 

3.  Exhibit  1  estimates  the  costs  to  American  for  the  type  of  operation  it  con- 
ducts today  in  these  two  markets.  Exhibit  2  estimates  the  costs  of  conducting  a 
commuter-only  operation  confined  to  the  carriage  of  local  traffic.  For  purposes 
of  determining  a  break-even  passenger  load  factor  in  the  Boston-Washington 
market,  we  have  used  the  revenue  yield  per  passenger-mile  derived  from  the  fare 
offered  by  PSA  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  In  the  New  York- 
Washington  market,  we  have  used  PSA's  dollar  fare  ($18.75)  because  the 
scheduled  block-to-block  time  is  approximately  the  same  as  that  for  Los  Angeles- 
San  Francisco. 

4.  Costs  are  divided  into  five  major  areas :  Flight  and  maintenance,  servicing 
and  handling,  advertising  and  sales,  administrative  overhead,  and  aircraft  owner- 
ship. Costs  reflect  American's  actual  experience  for  the  type  of  operation  now 
conducted  by  American  in  these  two  markets.  Applying  the  PSA  fare  level  to 
these  markets,  the  break-even  load  factor  on  a  fully  allocated  cost  basis  (with 
no  allowance  for  a  proper  rate  of  return)  would  be  the  following  : 

Percent 

Boston-Washington 130.  6 

New  York-Washington 137.2 

5.  Exhibit  2  estimates  the  reduced  costs  if  American  were  to  offer  a  pure  com- 
muter operation,  carrying  only  local  traffic  (excluding  interline  and  intraline  pas- 
sengers moving  beyond  the  terminals  of  the  Boston/New  York/Washington  cor- 
ridor). In  computing  these  costs,  we  have  reduced  American's  experienced  unit 
costs  in  the  following  areas  : 

Reservations/ticketing 68  percent  reduction  to  reflect  reduced  time  of 

reservations  and  ticketing  agents  in  handling 
simple  point-to-point  passenger  routings. 

Baggage  handling 50  percent  reduction  to  reflect  reduced  volume 

of  baggage  of  commuter  traffic. 

Catering  and  food  service 100  percent  reduction  to  reflect  elimination  of 

free  amenities. 

Agency  commission 43  percent  reduction  in  travel  agent  commis- 
sions to  reflect  PSA  experience 

Wage  scales/work  rules No  change. 

6.  After  adjusting  costs  for  these  savings,  American  estimates  the  following 
break-even  load  factors  for  a  commuter-only  operation  (costs  do  not  include  an 
allowance  for  a  proper  return  on  investment)  : 

Percent 

Boston-Washington 92.  6 

New    York-Washington 93. 4 

7.  In  your  consideration  of  whether  it  is  fea.sible  to  obtain  lower  fares  in  these 
markets  with  a  commuter-only  operation,  it  should  be  borne  in  mind  that  such 
an  operation  may  well  result  in  less  service  for  those  passengers  traveling  beyond 


1  The  routes  are  comparable  to  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco.  The  distance  between  Los 
Angeles  and  San  Francisco  is  .338  miles.  The  distance  between  Boston  an(i  Washington 
is  399  miles.  While  the  distance  between  New  York  and  Washington  Is  on'y  214  miles, 
American's  58-minute  block-to-block  scheduled  time  on  this  route  Is  almost  identical  to 
PSA's  60-minute  scheduled  time  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  The  relatively 
slower  travel  time  between  New  York  and  Washington  is  related  to  ground  and  air  con- 
gestion that  affects  operations  in  the  Northeast  corridor.  For  example,  approximately  50 
percent  of  American's  operations  at  La  Guardia  Airport  are  subject  to  some  ground  or 
air  traffic  delay,  as  compared  with  approximately  20  percent  for  American's  operations 
at  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco. 


522 

the  Boston/New  York/Washington  terminals.^  American's  local  flights  to  and 
from  Boston  now  carry  the  following  percentage  of  passengers  moving  beyond 
the  Boston/New  York/Washington  terminals  : 

Percent 

Boston-Washington    (National) 26 

New  York    (La  Guardia ) -Washington   (National) 30 

Boston-New  York   (La  Guardia) 41 

Since  American's  schedules  today  are  supported  by  a  combination  of  local 
traffic  and  through  and  connecting  traffic,  any  loss  of  local  traffic  would  under- 
mine the  economic  soundness  of  American's  through  and  connecting  service  at  an 
affected  terminal.  In  all  likelihood,  the  amount  of  through  and  connecting  service 
offered  by  American  would  have  to  be  reduced.  This  result,  in  our  view,  would 
be  detrimental  both  to  the  general  public  and  to  the  airline  industry. 


-SHORT-HAUL  OPERATING  RESULTS  AT  INTRASTATE  FARE  LEVEL 
[Average  one-way] 


Boston-         New  York- 
Washington         Washington 


968 

771 

870 

837 

831 

743 

234 

189 

246 

184 

3, 149 

2,724 

(471) 

(455) 

Passenger  revenue  at  100  percent  load  factor $2, 678  $2, 269 

Expenses: 

Flight  and  maintenance 

Servicing  and  handling  costs 

Advertising  and  sales 

Administrative  and  overhead 

Aircraft  ownership 

Total 

Net  earnings - 

Additional  passengers  required  to  break-even 37  45 

Total  passengers  required  to  break-even 158  166 

Seats  available 121  121 

Break-even  passenger  load  factor  (percent) 130.6  137.2 

EXHIBIT  2.— SHORT-HAUL  OPERATING  RESULTS  AT  INTRASTATE  FARE  LEVEL  AND  MODIFIED  COST  STRUCTURE 

lAverage  one-way) 

Boston-         New  York- 
Washington         Washington 

Passenger  revenue  at  break-even  level $2,476  $2, 124 

Expenses: 

Flight  and  maintenance 968  771 

Servicing  and  handling 648  631 

Advertising  and  sales 380  349 

Administrative  and  overhead 234  189 

Aircraft  ownership 246  184 

TotaL 2~476  M24 

Net  earnings - 

Passengers  required  to  break-even 112  113 

Seats  available.. 121  121 

Break-even  passenger  load-factor  (percent) 92.6  93.4 

Biographical  Sketch  op  Randall  Malin,  Vice  President,  Market  Planning, 
American   Airlines,   Inc. 

Randall  Malin  is  vice  president  of  market  planning  for  American  Airlines, 
Inc.  In  this  capacity  he  is  responsible  for  American's  marketing  strategies 
and  plans. 


-  In  Boston,  for  example,  all  eight  of  American's  daily  Alights  to  La  Guardia  continue 
on  from  New  York,  providing  one-stop  service  from  Boston  to  St.  Louis,  Detroit,  Toronto, 
Dallas/Ft.  Worth  and  Memphis.  Five  of  the  seven  daily  flights  from  Boston  to  Washing- 
ton continue  on  from  Washington  to  Indianapolis,  Memphis  and  Cincinnati. 


523 

Mr.  Malin  has  worked  for  American  since  1961  and  has  held  the  positions  of 
director  of  economic  research,  assistant  to  the  president,  director  of  marketing 
plans  and  assistant  vice  president  market  planning.  He  was  elected  vice  president 
of  market  planning  and  schedule  development  in  June  1970,  and  a  year  later 
became  vice  president  of  passenger  market  plans.  In  January  1973  he  was 
elected  vice  president  of  resource  planning.  He  assumed  his  present  position 
in  September  1974. 

Throughout  most  of  the  period  from  June  1970  through  September  1974,  Mr. 
Malin  was  directly  responsible  for  American's  passenger  fares  and  schedules. 
He  also  negotiated  all  of  American's  capacity  restraint  agreements. 

Mr.  Malin  is  a  graduate  of  Dartmouth  College,  and  he  holds  a  master's  degree 
from  Dartmouth's  Amos  Tuck  School  of  Business  Administration. 


Prepared  Statement  of  Morris  Shipley,  Delta  Air  Lines 

Delta  has  previously  explained  to  the  subcommittee's  staff  why  our  company 
is  not  in  a  position  to  contribute  meaningfully  to  the  hearings  with  respect  to 
"shuttle"  or  other  mass-market  low-cost  services  in  the  northeastern,  and  particu- 
larly in  the  Boston-Washington  areas.  As  we  understand  it,  the  subcommittee 
hopes  to  explore  the  reasons  why  a  service  comparable  to  that  conducted  by 
Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  (PSA)  within  the  State  of  California  has  not  de- 
veloped between  major  northeastern  cities,  either  as  a  separate  "subsidiary" 
operation  by  one  of  the  carriers  presently  serving  the  markets,  or  by  some  new 
carrier.  Aside  from  the  matter  of  service  frequency,  which  will  be  discussed,  the 
basic  questions  here  are  whether  such  a  service  could  operate  at  lower  fares 
than  those  now  obtaining  in  the  markets  which,  in  turn,  involves  questions  of 
cost/revenue  relationships  in  the  Boston-Washington  and  other  northeastern 
markets. 

First,  however,  it  should  be  noted  that  if  the  reference  to  PSA-type  service 
means  turnaround  service  confined  to  a  particular  market  and  operated  with 
high  frequency,  northeastern  area  markets  have  had — and  at  least  one,  New 
York-Washington  still  does  have — service  comparable  in  these  respects  (and 
superior  in  terms  of  backup  equipment)  to  the  PSA  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco 
service,  which  is  that  carrier's  major  operation.  We  here  refer  to  the  Eastern  Air 
Lines  "shuttle"  which  previously  served  the  Boston-Washington  as  well  as  the 
New  York-Washington  market.  Initially  Eastern's  fares  were  lower  on  this 
service  than  on  some  other  services,  and  both  this  historical  fact  and  the  present 
situation  with  respect  to  the  shuttle  undoubtedly  can  be  expanded  upon  by 
Eastern.  Delta  is  not  in  a  position  to  comment  on  the  marketability  and 
economic  results  of  this  service. 

The  basic  reasons  why  Delta  Air  Lines  is  not  in  a  position  to  contribute  mean- 
ingfully to  discussion  of  the  various  causative  factors  relating  to  the  possibilities 
for  a  northeastern  area  PSA-type  service  are  as  follows  : 

1.  Delta  is  a  relative  newcomer  to  the  Boston  markets,  and  in  terms  of  un- 
restricted authority  is  also  a  newcomer  to  the  remainder  of  the  northeastern  area 
markets  (those  between  Washington,  Baltimore,  Philadelphia,  New  York, 
Hartford  and  Boston). 

Delta  acquired  its  first  Boston  and  Hartford  authority  on  August  1,  1972,  when 
it  and  the  former  Northeast  Airlines  merged.  Prior  thereto  Delta  held  authority 
only  in  the  markets  between  Washington,  Baltimore,  Philadelphia  and  New  York, 
which  authority  was  long-haul  restricted  in  the  sense  that  any  flight  serving  two 
or  more  of  these  cities  could  not  tiirn  around  or  shuttle  between  them,  but  was 
required  to  also  serve  specified  cities  in  the  southeastern  and  southwestern  por- 
tion of  the  nation.  (This  requirement  was  imposed  because  Delta  was  certificated 
for  purposes  of  connecting  the  Southeast  and  Southwest  with  the  Northeast,  and 
the  CAB  directed  that  Delta's  efforts  be  concentrated  on  the  development  of 
this  inter-regional  traffic. ) 

Since  the  merger  Delta  has  been  able  to  combine  Washington-Boston  service 
with  Delta's  Washington-Southeast/Southwest  services,  but  has  been  prevented 
from  significantly  increasing  the  volume  of  Washington-Boston  service  previously 
operated  by  Northeast,  and  from  seriously  considering  a  shuttle  or  other  turn- 
around or  PSA-type  service  because  of  the  following  overlapping  and  com- 
pounding circumstances : 

(a)  Delta  was  unable  to  assimilate  the  former  Northeast  and  Delta  systems 
from  a  scheduling  standpoint  until  December  of  1972/January  1973.  It  was  neces- 


524 

sarv  of  course,  to  conduct  the  combined  operation  as  initially  structured  for  a 
period  of  time  in  order  to  gain  experience  and  to  allow  sufficient  time  to  achieve 
post-merger  integration  of  the  various  employee  groups  of  the  two  carriers,  before 
altering  the  pattern  significantly.  Before  this  initial  trial  period  expired  the  fuel 
crisis  hit  While  official  governmental  regulations  based  on  the  fuel  crisis  were 
issued  in  October  of  1973,  Delta  was  feeling  the  effects  of  the  coming  crisis  even 
before  that  time  Because  the  airlines,  more  than  virtually  any  other  segment  of 
the  economy,  have  been  subjected  to  reduced  fuel  allocations  and  fuel  deliveries 
(the  airlines  remain  limited  to  an  allocation  of  no  more  than  their  1972  fuel 
consumption  despite  the  carriers'  critical  importance  to  the  U.S.  commerce),  and 
because  fuel  costs  have  rapidly  escalated,  the  fuel  crisis— and  the  following 
factor— have  resulted  in  Delta's  barely  hanging  on  in  the  Washington-Northeast 
markets  with  essentially  the  initial  post-merger  pattern. 

(b)  The  preferred  airport  at  Washington  for  Boston  and  for  most  medium- 
haul  services  is  Washington  National  Airport.  The  airport,  however,  has  not  been 
expanded  for  many  years.  This  circumstance,  together  with  the  results  of  en- 
vironmentalists' protests,  has  precluded  the  use  of  four-engine  jet  and  wide- 
bodied  aircraft  at  Washington  National  Airport,  and  has  severely  restricted  the 
number  of  daily  jet  operations  which  can  be  conducted  with  any  type  of  aircraft. 
For  safety  and  other  reasons,  the  carriers  have  been  limited  by  the  FAA  to  a 
maximum"  of  40  movements  iier  hour  for  all  carriers  combined,  with  a  total  ban 
on  all  jet  operations  between  10  :00  p.m.  and  7  :00  a.m.  Since  this  ban  was  ini- 
tially imposed,  adjustments  in  the  timing  of  each  individual  carrier's  flights  and 
its  number  of  operations  in  any  particular  hour  have  been  made  from  time  to 
time  on  a  regular,  recurring  basis,  under  a  cooperative  arrangement  authorized 
by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  in  order  that  the  best  overall  public  service  can 
be  provided  at  that  airport.  But  this  necessary  restraint  on  use  of  Washington 
National  Airport  effectively  puts  a  lid  on  the  number  of  services  which  Delta 
and  other  airlines  can  operate  in  the  Washington-Boston  market,  or  in  any 
other  Washington  market. 

The  slot  problem  manifests  itself  not  only  in  a  physical  inability  to  land  ad- 
ditional flights  at  the  preferred  Washington  National  Airport,  but  in  an  effec- 
tive continuation  of  Delta's  prior  long-haul  restriction  north  of  Washington.  Thus, 
while  Delta  inherited  Northeast's  unrestricted  turnaround  authority  in  the  mar- 
kets between  Washington,  Philadelphia,  New  York,  Hartford  and  Boston,  the 
merger  also  placed  service  obligations  on  Delta  between  Boston/Hartford  and 
points  on  the  former  Delta  system  in  the  Southeast,  via  Washington  or  one  of 
the  other  northeastern  cities.  At  the  same  time,  of  all  the  carriers  serving  Wash- 
ington National  Airport,  Delta  has  the  fewest  number  of  slots  save  only  one 
other  carrier.^  These  circumstances  combined  have  necessitated  discharge  by 
Delta  of  both  its  Washington-northeastern  city  and  Washington-southern  city 
local  service  obligations,  and  its  through  service  Boston/Hartford-south  service 
obligations,  with  sing'e-plane  services  in  most  instances  between  the  New  Eng- 
land points  and  the  South  via  Washington.  This,  in  turn,  has  prevented  a  PSA- 
type  turnaround  operation  north  of  Washington,  and  made  a  study  of  such  an 
operation  impractical. 

2.  Northeast  as  never  able  to  operate  an  hourly  service  between  Boston  and 
Washington,  so  there  is  no  experience  upon  which  Delta  can  draw  in  this  respect. 
Furthermore,  the  former  Northeast  Airlines  officials  who  were  in  charge  of  that 
carrier's  scheduling  and  fares  are  not  now  associated  with  the  merged  company. 
Whatever  records  of  premerger  scheduling  and  fare  development  might  have 
existed  at  one  time  no  longer  exist,  to  the  best  of  Delta's  information  and  belief. 

3.  Delta  has  not  made  studies  of  the  feasibility  of  conducting  a  PSA-type 
service.  As  noted  above,  prior  to  the  Delta/Northeast  merger  on  Augu.st  1,  1972, 
Delta  was  long-haul  restricted  in  northeastern  markets.  There  are  no  other  areas 
of  Delta's  system  that  have  the  combined  features  of  medium  length/high  traffic 
volume  -  which  are  normally  viewed  as  prerequisites  to  a  PSA-type  service. 

The  PSA-type  service  is  claimed  to  have  two  benefits — high  frequency  and 
somewhat  lower  fares  than  are  normally  available  on  regular  interstate  carrier 
service   (the  latter  comparison  is  usually  made  between  the  PSA  daytime  fare 

1  Delta,  for  example,  has  only  32  slots,  while  the  other  three  carriers  certificated  in  the 
Boston-Washington  market  have  a  much  larger  number  :  Allegheny  88.  American  70,  and 
Eastern  136. 

2  The  Boston-Washington  market  is  many  times  smaller  than  PSA's  Los  Angeles-San 
Francisco  market. 


525 

and  the  interstate  carriers'  normal  daycoach  fare,  and  ignores  the  substantial 
savings  available  on  the  latter  carriers  from  various  promotional  fares  and  the 
daily  20  percent  reduced  off-peak  fares  offered  by  carriers  such  as  Delta).  As 
explained  above,  the  high  frequency  of  sen-ice  can  equally  be  made  available 
by  operations  through  the  market,  and  this  factor  has  thus  not  called  for  study 
of  a  PSA-type  turnaround  service.  A  study  from  the  standpoint  of  fares  has 
not  been  feasible  as  long  as  the  CAB's  comprehensive  Domestic  Passenger  Fare 
Investigation  has  been  pending,  as  it  has  since  1970  (the  complexity  of  this 
massive  investigation  necessitated  such  an  extensive  period  of  time).  Until  the 
DPFI  is  fully  completed  (it  is  still  subject  to  pending  court  appeals,  and  is  sub- 
ject to  additional  court  review)  Delta  is  not  in  a  position  to  know  whether  it 
would  be  possible  to  charge  a  lower  fare  for  a  PSA-type  service  than  that  pre- 
.scribed  by  existing  law  and  CAB  decision  and  regulation.  This  cirmucstance, 
too,  has  made  it  impractical  to  study  a  "PSA-type"  operation. 

It  is  for  the  foregoing  reasons — and  particularly  Delta's  limited  experience 
with  the  Washington-Boston  market  (and  with  any  northeastern  market,  except 
on  a  long-haul  restricted  basis) — that  Delta  has  not  made  any  study  of  a 
PSA-type  operation  in  northeastern  markets,  and  cannot  contribute  meaning- 
fully to  the  subcommittee's  discussion  of  this  particular  matter. 

]Mr,  Breyer.  The  next  witness  is  ]Mr.  Charles  Murphy,  representing 
the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission.  ]Mr.  Murphy  is  an  attorney  and  a 
pilot  and  has  been  executive  director  of  the  TAC  since  September  1965. 
^Ir.  Murphy  is  also  chairman  of  the  air  transportation  subcommittee 
of  the  National  Association  of  Regulatorj^  Utility  Commissioners.  I 
would  like  to  welcome  you  to  these  hearings. 

Thank  you  very  much,  ]Mr.  ISIurphy  and  I  apologize  for  the  delay 
this  morning. 

STATEMENT    OF   CHARLES   MURPHY,    EXECUTIVE   DIRECTOR, 
TEXAS  AERONAUTICS   COMMISSION 

Mr.  ]MuRPiiY.  If  you  would  permit  me,  I  would  like  to  deviate,  just 
a  little  bit  from  some  of  the  testimony,  and  that  is  why  I  said  that  I 
would  like  to  make  an  oral  statement  rather  than  submitting  only  the 
prepared  statement,  because  some  of  the  testimony  here,  I  think, 
brought  u])  some  questions  that  I  would  like  to  respond  to  or  have 
something  to  say  about. 

STATE    REGULATION   IN   TEXAS 

I  view  this  situation  maybe  from  a  position  that  is  a  little  ditFerent 
from  most  of  the  people.  I  happen  to  be  director  of  a  State  agency 
that  performs  two  functions.  It  performs  not  only  the  regulatory  func- 
tion performed  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  but  also  the  system 
development  functions  as  performed  by  the  FAA. 

I  am  very  conscious  of  the  fact  that  wnthout  a  system  to  operate  over, 
the  finest  regulatory  policies  in  the  w^orld  would  be  ineffective.  I  think 
that  the  air  transportation  system  over  which  these  commercal  carrier 
are  now  operating  lacks  a  lot. 

I  would  from  my  prepared  statement  like  to  read  to  you  just  a  sen- 
tence that  I  put  in  a  letter  in  1966  to  then  Governor  Connally  of 
Texas.  After  having  made  a  previous  statement  I  said : 

That  has  been  equally  frightening  and  painful  to  see  that  in  the  field  of  air 
transportation  governmental  re.sponsibilities  of  the  states  and  their  aviations 
agencies  are  little  studies,  carelessly  approached,  unbelievably  misunderstood 
and  neglected. 


526 

This  results  in  not  an  economic  question,  but  a  political  question.  In 
any  given  area  or  in  an  industry,  if  you  have  only  one  organized  and 
well  finished  group,  other  less  organized  less  finished,  their  voice  is 
relatively  weak,  then  obviously  the  policies  of  the  well  organized,  well 
finished  group  ai-e  going  to  prevail,  such  as  in  the  case  of  the  aviation 
industry.  ATA  is  the  only  well  finished,  well  organized  aviation  group. 

There  is  another  political  question  that  comes  up,  and  that  is  that 
all  regulatory  agencies  tend  to  be  neglected  by  their  creating  agency, 
whether  it  be  Congress  or  the  State  legislature.  The  moment  that  the 
President  or  the  Governor  signs  a  bill  and  says  we  have  now  created 
a  regulatory  agency  to  solve  our  problems  that  agency  then  comes 
under  a  tax  and  just  by  the  mere  fact  that  it  associates  only  with  the 
people  that  it  regulates,  it  loses  contact  with  the  public  and  the  media, 
and  it  begins  to  move  in  a  direction  as  becoming  responsive  to  and  in 
some  instances  almost  captive  of  the  industry  it  regulates,  which 
brings  me  down  to  the  question  of  what  you  want  to  ask  me.  Why  have 
you  been  able  to  have  cheaper  rates  in  Texas  ? 

Mr.  Breyer.  Have  you  been  able  to  have  cheaper  rates  ? 

Mr.  Murphy.  I  think  so. 

Mr.  Breyer,  How  much  cheaper  have  they  been  ? 

Mr.  IVIuRPHY.  Well,  as  you  have  said  here,  they  vary  from  as  much 
as  one-half  to  two-thirds  of  CAB  regulations. 

I  would  also  add  that  the  only  unregulated  fare  in  Texas  is  the 
intrastate  fare  charged  by  the  CAB  carrier.  The  fares  charged  by  the 
intrastate  carrier,  regulated  by  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission, 
are  regulated.  The  intrastate  fares  of  the  CAB  carriers  are  unregu- 
lated, which  poses  a  problem  for  us  where  our  carriers  are  roughly  in 
competition  with  the  CAB  carrier. 

Mr.  Breyer.  You  have  lower  fares,  and  why  is  it  you  think  they  are 
lower  ? 

Mr.  Mtjrphy.  Well,  they  are  lower  because,  beginning  with  Gover- 
nor Connally  and  following  through  with  Governor  Smith  and  now 
with  Governor  Briscoe,  for  the  first  time  there  were  men  appointed  to 
the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission  who  were  not  appointed  to  that 
Connnission  because  of  their  previous  aviation  background.  They  came 
in  as  knowledgeable  men.  Today,  Governor  Briscoe  has  recently  ap- 
pointed a  gentleman  who  does  not  fly,  it  is  not  a  pilot,  he  does  not  own 
an  airplane,  and  to  be  purely  frank  about  it,  he  doesn't  like  to  fly. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Well,  I  think  the  CAB — the  profits  are  not  enormous, 
they  are  not  making  heaps  of  money. 

Mr.  Murphy.  I  am  not  saying  that  is  it.  I  am  only  trying  to  get 
around  to  the  point  that  these  gentlemen,  when  they  accept  the  same 
facts  and  figures  that  are  presented  to  them  for  their  ultimate  decision 
as  are  presented  to  the  Board  members  of  the  CAB  or  any  other  regula- 
tory body,  and  they  are  presented  with  voluminous  records,  that  the 
only  difference  between  them  and  another  regulatory  agency  is  that 
they  may  tend  to  put  into  their  final  decision  maybe  a  little  greater 
factor  of  public  opinion. 

REASONS   FOR   SOUTHWEST   AIRLINES'   SUCCESS 

Mr.  Breyer.  Are  the  load  factors  higher  in  Texas  ? 
Mr.  Murphy.  They  are.  The  load  factors  are  very  high.  They  do 
have  a  very  high-load  factor.  They  have  it  for  a  number  of  reasons. 


527 

One  reason  that  lias  been  overlooked  today  is  you  have  the  system  in 
California  that  you  have  because  of  the  availability  of  the  airports  to 
operate  out  of,  three  out  of  the  bay  area  to  five  in  the  Los  Angeles  area, 
an  accessibility  of  service,  people  wanting  to  go  where  they  want  to 
go.  They  can  go  from  any  one  of  three  to  any  one  of  five. 

In  any  opinion,  vrhat  makes  Southwest  so  successful  in  Texas,  it  is 
able  to  o])erate  from  the  close-in  and  convenient  Love  field  in  Dallas 
and  the  close-in  Hobby  field  in  Houston. 

I  was  just  going  to  say  this  is  one  of  the  three  factors  that  makes  the 
Southwest  operation  attractive  to  the  consumer.  It  is  convenient,  and  it 
is  cheap.  Xow,  Southwest  is  doing  an  unusual  thing,  partially  because 
of  the  flexibility  that  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Connnission  has  permitted 
them  to  have  in  trying  to  arrive  at  a  fare  structure  which  would  be 
attractive  to  the  public.  They  now  have  a  dual-fare  system.  I  don't 
know  whether  you  are  aware  of  it  or  not,  but  that  is  the  $25  flights 
from  say  8  a.m.  to  5  p.m.  or  6  p.m.,  but  any  flight  originating  before  8 
in  the  morning  and  after  6  in  the  afternoon  is  what  is  called  a  pressure 
class;  it  is  a  $15  flight. 

I  would  suggest  to  you  that  someone  from  the  Senator's  staff  visit 
the  airports  and  observe  the  difference  in  the  appearance  of  the  people 
who  utilize  the  $15  fare  as  opposed  to  the  $25.  These  people  are  people 
who  are  coming  to  the  airline  instead  of  going  to  the  bus.  It  is  almost 
like  they  are  getting  ready  to  takeoff  on  some  of  the  late  flights  and 
you  kind  of  wait  for  them  to  tie  the  chicken  coop  on  top  of  the  airplane. 
Mr.  Breyer.  We  have  about  5  or  7  million  who  go  by  car. 
Mr.  ]\IuRPHY.  Southwest  Airline  is  obviously  competing  with  the 
automobile,  there  is  no  doubt  about  that.  There  are  other  factors  per- 
mitting it  to  be  cheaper  than  those  named  here,  not  only  the  ticketing 
and  baggaging  and  what  have  you,  the  terminal  costs,  these  people 
proceed  to  get  a  ticket  and  get  on  the  plane.  You  don't  need  a  vast 
terminal.  They  are  not  sitting  around  waiting  for  a  flight  5  hours  from 
now.  The  bar  at  Love  field  is  a  little  table  about  like  this  with  a  few 
bottles  of  whiskey  sitting  over  in  the  corner.  All  they  have  is  a  cafe,  a 
restaurant,  that  really  is  for  the  people  who  work  there,  not  for  the 
passengers  who  are  coming  there.  It  is  purely  a  service-oriented 
activity,  and  maybe  evidence  to  the  contrary,  nobody  is  holding  any 
gun  to  anybody's  head,  making  them  use  that  service.  They  are  using 
it  because  it  is  a  cheap,  efficient,  economic  service.  That  is  a  high- 
density  market. 

I  have  heard  the  term  used  over  and  over  again  that  Southwest 
moved  into  a  high-density  market"  and  that  has  been  called  cream 
skimming,  that  we  came  in  and  skimmed  the  cream  off  the  market.  In 
a  most  recent  presentation  just  last  week  before  the  Texas  Aeronautics 
Commission  oral  arguments  were  made  into  Southwest  extention  into 
the  market  for  the  whole  valley  is  about  130,000  passengers,  180  this 
year  and  it  is  a  relatively  much  smaller  market  and  they  are  going  into 
it  because  of  the  tourist  attractiveness  and  trying  to  stimulate  a  tourist 
business. 

Mr.  Breyer.  They  are  making  money  on  that  route  ? 
Mr.  Murphy.  They  have  just  started. 
Mr.  Breyer.  They  expect  to  make  money  ? 

Mr.  Murphy.  They  expect  to  stimulate  the  market  to  the  extent  they 
will  make  money. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Are  their  fares  lower  ? 


528 

Mr.  Murphy.  Oh,  yes.  They  will  make  it  attractive,  hopefully,  ac- 
cording to  the  Southwest,  where  people  would  go  from  Dallas  or 
Houston  or  San  Antonio  to  the  valley  over  the  weekend  for  maybe  just 
a  few  days  on  the  Mexican  border  as  a  tourist,  on  a  weekend  vacation, 
which  is  not  unattractive  because  of  the  fare. 

But  I  wanted  to  say  in  response  to  cream  skimming,  I  must  give 
credit  to  the  attorney  for  Southwest.  He  said  the  cream  skimming 
indicates  that  milk  is  set  and  cream  has  come  to  the  top  and  skimmed 
milk  has  gone  to  the  bottom.  He  said  we  are  not  cream  skimming,  we 
are  actually  milk  dipping.  They  are  going  down  into  the  bottom  of  the 
market. 

I  would  like  to  show  you  some  exhibits  which  were  used  in  this 
proceeding.  These  are  the  latest  we  have.  Others  will  be  made  available 
to  you.  This  will  show  you  how  the  market  was  stimulated,  how  South- 
west came  into  the  market. 

RELATIONSHIP    BETWEEN    TEXAS    REGULATION    AND    CAB 

Mr.  Breyer.  Is  there  any  particular  problem  that  arises  because  of 
the  CAB's  jurisdiction  and  your  jurisdiction?  Does  it  overlap? 

Mr.  Murphy.  It  does  not  overlap.  Our  only  problem  is  that  the  CAB 
certificated  carriers  maintain  that  although  intrastate  fares  are  not 
subject  to  CAB  regulations  that  our  state  law,  by  language  within  our 
law,  prevents  us  from  regulating  their  fares. 

So  the  problem  is  that  we  have  some  difficulty  in  regulating  South- 
west when  a  competing  carrier  is  unregulated  in  the  market.  It  is  a 
matter  which  the  CAB  could  settle,  I  think,  rather  easily.  The  CAB 
has  created  problems  for  us,  I  would  think  more  with  maybe  what  is 
called  the  air-taxi  exemption  than  with  anything  else.  This  poses  a 
problem  and  will  pose  an  even  greater  problem  when  the  30-passenger 
airplanes  come  on  the  market. 

I  think  that  the  disastrous  effect  of  the  air-taxi  exemption  was  that 
it  made  the  aircraft  manufacturer  design  an  airplane  to  meet  an  arti- 
ficial weight  limit  rather  than  to  serve  a  need  of  the  public,  and  this 
I  think  has  hurt  air  transportation  in  the  small  communities. 
Mr.  Breyer.  I  don't  have  any  further  questions. 
Mr.  Murphy.  I  would  like  to  leave  you  here.  I  do  not  have  an  official 
document,  but  I  do  have  a  letter  saying  this  is  on  file  today  with  the 
Texas  legislative  reference  library.  It  is  a  report  of  a  special 
subcommittee. 

Mr.  Breyer.  There  is  one  question  I  will  ask  you,  and  that  is,  there 
has  been  legislation  proposed  to  extend  the  CAB's  jurisdiction  or 
maybe  regulations  into  California  and  Texas.  What  is  j^our  view  on 
the  merits  of  that  ? 

Mr.  Murphy.  I  think  that  in  order  to  develop  the  air  transportation 
system  in  the  way  that  I  visualize  and  hope  it  will  be  developed  in 
the  future  and  to  be  made  accessible  and  available  to  the  public,  which 
in  my  part  of  the  country  now  is  not  because  there  are  people  there 
200  miles  from  air  carrier  service,  maybe  250  miles  from  air  carrier 
service — I  think  that  that  only — well,  in  order  to  establish  this  system 
will  take  the  utilization  of  a  very  sophisticated  form  of  Government 
and  we  do  have  a  sophisticated  form  of  Government,  our  three  levels 
of  Government,  and  if  they  each  accept  their  authority  and  fulfill 
their  authority,  and  their "  responsibility,  it  will  mesh  together.  I 


529 

think  to  cut  out  one  level  or  two  levels  of  it  and  give  it  all  to  one 
really  defeats  the  purpose  and  the  utility  value  of  this  unusually  fine 
system  of  Government  we  have  that  has  built  the  highways  and  sur- 
faces. If  we  work  together  we  can  build  an  air  transportation  system. 
But  if  we  permit  it — the  airport  thing  was  going  to  a  critical  point, 
and  passed  the  airways  account.  It  failed.  Now  they  come  forward 
with  recommendations  which  are  going  to  even  exasperate  that  situa- 
tion. If  you  are  not  aware  of  the  failure  of  the  State  goverimients 
to  participate  in  the  building  of  airports  if  you  don't  begin  to  use  a 
carrot  and  stick  approach  to  encourage  the  States  to  become  more 
involved  and  to  destroy  the  myth  that  the  Federal  Government  has 
preempted  everything  in  aviation,  your  study  into  regulations  is  not 
going  to  be  as  meaningful  as  you  hope  it  will  be. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Thank  you  very  much. 

Mr.  Breyer.  We  will  recess  until  Tuesday  in  Washington. 

[Whereupon  at  1 :05  o'clock  p.m.,  the  subcommittee  adjourned,  sub- 
ject to  the  call  of  the  Chair.] 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Charles  A.  Murphy  and  charts  referred 
to  follow :] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Charles  A.  Murphy 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  am  deeply  grateful  to  you  and  to  the  other  members  of  your 
committee  for  this  opportunity  to  express  my  views  on  the  regulatory  policies 
and  procedures  as  they  affect  air  transportation.  I  would  like  to  think  that  the 
findings  of  this  committee  will  help  produce  a  new  era  of  cooperation  between 
federal  and  state  authorities  on  matters  of  mutual  concern  in  air  transportation. 

I  have  taken  the  liberty  of  looking  over  the  .ist  ot  other  witnesses  appearing 
■before  you  and,  in  deference  to  the  great  demands  upon  your  time,  will  try  to 
avoid  duplicating  the  testimony  you  are  likely  to  hear  from  them.  Instead,  I 
would  like  to  bring  to  your  attention  some  of  the  air  transportation  regulatory 
problems  which  have  become  evident  to  me  in  my  position  as  executive  director 
of  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission. 

First,  let  me  say  that  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission  was  created  in 
1945  and  has  jurisdiction  over  air  carriers  operating  within  the  State  of  Texas 
but  outside  the  scope  of  air  transportation  as  defined  in  the  Federal  Aviation 
Act.  Under  our  law,  we  issue  certificates  of  public  convenience  and  necessity 
to  such  air  carriers  when  we  fined  that  their  proposed  service  is  in  the  interest 
of  public  convenience  and  necessity. 

One  of  the  provisions  in  the  act  creating  our  Commission  declares,  and  I 
quote :  "In  determining  the  existence  of  a  public  convenience  and  necessity  for 
a  proposed  air  service,  the  Commission  shall  consider  the  encouragement  and 
development  of  an  intrastate  air  transportation  system  properly  adapted  to  the 
present  and  future  needs  of  the  State  of  Texas,  and  in  addition  shall  consider 
the  financial  responsibility  of  the  air  carrier,  its  proposed  routes  and  rates 
or  charges;  the  effect,  if  any,  upon  existing  air  carriers  and  CAB  certificated 
carriers,  and  any  other  factors  similarly  related  to  public  convenience  and 
necessity. . ." 

On  both  the  state  and  federal  levels,  we  obviously  face  some  difficult  and  com- 
plicated problems.  However,  I  believe  that  many  of  these  problems  require 
relatively  simple  solutions^if  we  work  together. 

When  I  came  into  this  business  about  10  years  ago,  my  first  impression  was 
one  of  shock.  I  was  shocked  to  realize  that  the  state  level  of  government  had 
such  vast  responsibilities  for  developing  and  regulating  an  air  transportation 
system  and  was  doing  so  little  to  fulfill  those  responsibilities.  I  began  investi- 
gating and  found  that  most  states  were  not  doing  anything  in  this  area  simply 
because  a  myth  had  been  perpetrated  on  the  Congress,  on  state  legislators  and 
on  the  public.  That  myth  was  that  the  Federal  Government  had  pre-empted  all 
matters  pertaining  to  aviation— and  this  is  not  true.  It  w/is  not  true  then  and 
it  is  not  true  now.  But  the  major  airlines  had  organized  and  they  were  able  to 
sell  this  idea  simply  because  they  were  the  only  substantial,  well-financed  voice 
within  aviation.  Their  resources  and  orsrani/ational  skills  have  enabled  them  to 
make  their  policies  the  policies  of  the  aviation  industry  and  its  main  regulatory 
authority.  In  effect,  the  CAB  has  created  a  political  power  which  has  also  l)een 
highly  successful  in  thwarting  the  efforts  to  establish  effective  state  regulation 


530 

and  state  development  of  air  transportation  facilities.  The  CAB  should  be 
aware  of  this  activity  and  should  denounce  it. 

About  one  year  after  I  joined  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission,  I  wrote 
a  letter,  dated  Aug.  29,  196G,  to  then  Gov.  John  Connally,  giving  him  some  of 
my  observations.  In  that  letter,  I  said,  and  I  quote :  "From  the  vantage  point 
of  director  it  has  been  exciting  and  stimulating  to  watch  air  transportation  as 
it  proceeds  in  its  fantastic  transformation  from  a  relatively  superficial  adorn- 
ment of  Texas  life  into  a  basic  industry  so  vital  that  the  State's  economy  could 
neither  exist  in  its  pre.sent  form,  nor  hojie  to  protrre>s,  without  it.  It  has  been 
equally  frightening  and  painful  to  .see  that  in  the  field  of  air  transportation, 
governmental  responsibilities  of  tue  SliUes  and  liuir  aviation  agencies  are 
little  studied,  carelessly  approached,  unbelievably  misunderstood,  and,  as  a 
result,  neglected." 

That  statement  was  made  in  1966.  During  the  succeeding  years,  I  think  I 
have  gained  a  better  understanding  of  the  basic  problems  but  they  really  are 
about  the  same  now  as  they  were  then.  And  they  boil  down  to  the  failure  of 
the  states  and  the  federal  government  to  participate  fully,  as  partners,  in  the 
development  of  a  truly  adequate  air  trans]  orration  system. 

We  talk  about  regulating  the  airlines — but  regulation  seems  somewhat  futile 
when  we  do  not  have  and  adequate  airport  system  upon  which  they  can  operate. 
We  simply  do  not  have  the  airports  necessary  to  meet  the  demands  and  needs  of 
the  public.  We  might  as  well  try  to  regulate  trucks  without  providing  the  high- 
ways for  them  to  use.  It's  almost  like  the  old  chicken-and-egg  dilemma  but  both 
California  and  Texas  have  demonstrated  that  adequate,  convenient  airport 
facilities  can  lead  to  high  public  acceptance  of  airline  service  on  a  short-haul 
basis. 

In  California,  for  instance,  a  person  leaving  the  San  Francisco  Bay  area  can 
depart  from  a  number  of  airports.  And  he  can  fly  from  there  to  any  one  of 
several  commercial  airports  serving  the  Los  An-reles  area.  This  flexibility  makes 
air  transportation  feasible  for  a  great  many  people,  particularly  those  involved 
with  one-day  business  trips.  Love  Field — located  not  far  from  downtown  Dal- 
las, and  Hobby  Airport,  in  Houston — are  more  abstractive  to  many  people  than 
are  the  new  Dallas/Fort  Worth,  and  Houston's  Intercontinental  Airport.  Busi- 
nessmen save  a  great  deal  of  time  by  usin-  the  airports  which  are  closer  to 
the  business  districts.  And  there  are  some  airline  passengers  who  cannot  afford 
excessive  ground  transportation,  such  as  a  $Ja  taxi  ride  or  even  a  $4  bus  fare. 
The  long-haul  passengers,  traveling  to  such  distant  points  as  Washington,  New 
York,  San  Francisco  or  Los  Angeles,  do  not  seem  to  mind  the  time  it  takes  them 
to  reach  the  Dallas/Fort  Worth  or  Houston  Airports. 

Incidentally,  it  seems  to  me  that  the  long-haul,  glamor  flights  always  are  at 
"Gate  1,"  or  whatever  the  nearest  gate  happens  to  be,  while  short-haul  pas- 
sengers find  their  planes  at  the  most  distant  gates.  This  seems  rather  typical 
of  industry  practice,  actually ;  the  short-haul  passengers  generally  get  the  short 
end  of  the  stick — and  the  longest  walks. 

Texas  has  more  places  to  land  airplanes  than  any  other  state  in  the  nation 
and  yet  it  still  is  woefully  short  on  convenient  airport  facilities — with  the  need 
continuing  to  grow.  Recent  forecasts  indicated  that,  by  1990,  Texas  will  need 
airport  facilities  to  accommodate  twice  as  many  aircraft,  four  times  as  many 
passengers,  and  ten  times  as  much  air  cargo  as  we  handle  now. 

In  1970,  Congress  passed  the  Airport  and  Airways  Development  Act,  with 
high  hopes.  Unfortunately,  it  has  failed  because  the  federal  government  pre- 
empted many  of  the  tax  sources  from  which  local  communities  might  have  been 
expected  to  get  revenue  for  the  necessary  matching  funds.  As  that  Act  now 
stands,  it  enables  the  rich  to  get  richer  while  the  poor  get  poorer;  it  lets  the 
big  get  bigger  while  the  small  get  smaller.  Some  of  the  amendments  now  being 
proposed  would  make  the  situation  even  worse.  To  me,  it  does  not  make  sense  to 
give  $290  million  in  federal  funds  to  the  big.  money-making  airports  to  use  as 
they  .see  fit,  when  we  so  de.sperately  need  so  many  new  airports.  There  is  no 
way  any  changes  in  regulatory  procedures  could  make  up  for  the  harm  this 
would  do  and  for  the  service  it  would  deny  to  so  many  potential  passengers. 

Instead  of  keeping  pace  with  the  growing  demand  for  new  airport  facilities, 
we  are  letting  the  development  of  bigger,  faster  airplanes  accelerate  the  obsoles- 
cence of  our  present  airports.  When  the  CAB  was  created,  one  of  the  first  things 
it  did  was  grant  an  "air  taxi"  exemption,  exempting  from  certification  require- 
ments all  passenger  planes  weighing  less  than  12, .500  pounds.  For  many  years, 
tliat  discouraged  aircraft  manufacturers  from  developing  jilanes  to  meet  the 
real  needs,  because  there  was  great  demand  for  these  smaller  planes  which 
could  qualify  for  CAB  exemptions.  For  years,  we  were  making  planes  that 
carried  about  15  passengers,  with  the  next  largest  size  a  plane  that  carried 


531 

about  100.  There  was  no  in-between,  such  as  a  40-  or  50-passenger  planes  that 
could  serve  a  great  many  small  communities  and  operate  on  the  vast  majority 
of  our  airports. 

Instead  of  building  planes  to  fit  our  airport  system,  we  started  building  bigger 
and  faster  and  heavier  planes,  and  sending  every  airport  manager  in  the  country 
racing  down  to  his  city  administration,  asking  for  the  issuance  of  another  $50 
million  in  municipal  bonds  to  lengthen  and  strengthen  runaways.  The  tail 
wagged  the  dog,  and  we  kept  modifying  the  system  to  fit  the  equipment,  when 
it  should  have  been  the  other  way  around.  This  was  almost  like  encouraging  truck 
manufacturers  to  build  wider  and  wider  trucks,  then  trying  to  rebuild  the  entire 
highway  system  to  accommodate  the  king-size  versions. 

The  727,  for  instance,  is  a  beautiful,  money-making  problem.  Simply  because 
it  has  only  four  main  wheels  and  thus  a  very  high  weight  per  square  inch  on 
each  of  them,  it  has  cost  the  airports  in  this  country  millions  of  dollars  in  repairs 
to  runways  and  parking  areas. 

I  believe  that  the  CAB  and  the  states  should  cooperate  in  the  regulation  of 
all  common  air  carriers,  regardless  of  aircraft  size.  The  CAB  should  work  with 
the  appropriate  state  agencies,  not  against  them.  We  should  have  something  of 
a  partnership  arrangement  instead  of  the  adversary  relationship  which  now 
exists. 

I  mentioned  earlier  the  shock  I  felt  when  I  became  director  of  the  Texas 
Aeronautics  Commission  about  10  years  ago  and  recognized  the  magnitude  of 
our  problems.  It  did  not  take  long  for  me  to  realize  that  we  had  many  prob- 
lems in  common  with  the  CAB — and  to  foresee  the  likelihood  of  problems  that 
would  involve  some  of  the  major  airlines.  Early  in  the  game,  I  made  a  nimiber 
of  visits  to  the  CAB  to  discuss  these  problems ;  my  reception  there  always  was 
very  cool.  No  offer  of  cooperation  ever  was  made,  even  though  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act  provides  for  the  CAB  to  cooperate  with  and  participate  with  state 
regulatory  agencies. 

It  seemed  to  me  that  this  was  a  rather  curious  stand  for  the  CAB  to  take  but 
some  light  was  shed  upon  it  in  July,  1970,  when  John  H.  Crooker  Jr.,  who  had 
been  chairman  of  the  CAB  a  short  time  before,  intervened  with  an  amicus 
curiae  brief  in  the  case  of  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission,  et  al,  vs.  Braniff 
Airways,  Inc.,  etal. 

Mr.  Crocker's  brief  attempted  to  explain  the  CAB's  failure,  which  had  been 
cited  by  an  appellate  court,  to  take  part  in  the  case  by  saying:  ".  .  .  If  the  CAB 
appears  before  a  state  agency  and  presents  its  views  to  the  agency,  this  makes 
the  state  agency  the  judicial  tribunal  and  the  CAB  a  party  or  a  witness  or  both. 
The  CAB  is  thus  present  before  the  state  agency,  and  the  decision  of  that  agency 
becomes  even  more  difficult  to  overturn  on  review,  even  if  a  Court  would  have 
reached  a  different  conclusion  had  the  matter  been  considered  de  novo.  Staying 
out  of  a  State  proceeding,  as  was  done  in  this  case,  has  the  obvious  drawback  of 
leaving  the  impression  with  a  Court  that  the  CAB  is  not  concerned  about  the 
possibility  that  too  much  competition  may  adversely  affect  the  financial  via- 
bility of  a  certificated  carrier  (especially  a  subsidized  one).  Such  matters,  of 
course,  might  have  some  adverse  effect  on  the  development  of  the  Nation's  air 
transportation  system  ..."  I  cannot  subscribe  to  this  theory. 

Furthermore,  I  doubt  that  it  ever  was  the  intention  of  Congress  to  have  the 
CAB  be  more  concerned  about  the  economic  health  of  the  airlines  than  it  is 
about  convenience  for  the  passengers.  -Both  factors  should  be  considered,  of 
course,  but  they  should  be  kept  in  proper  perspective.  It  is  precisely  because  they 
have  not  been  kept  in  perspective,  and  because  the  CAB  has  failed  to  concern 
itself  sufficiently  with  the  needs  of  the  passengers,  that  intrastate  airlines  in 
Texas  and  California  have  been  able  to  take  up  much  of  the  resultant  slack. 

In  my  opinion,  dual  regulation  could  work,  if  it  were  given  a  chance.  But 
dual  regulation  cannot  be  a  one-way  street.  There  must  be  a  reasonable  attitude 
on  the  part  of  both  state  and  federal  officials.  Instead  of  jealously  guarding  and 
trying  to  expand  their  own  powers,  everyone  involved  should  keep  constantly  in 
mind  the  fact  that  both  state  and  federal  agencies  exist  only  to  serve  the  tax- 
payers who  support  us. 

The  thrust  of  air  transportation,  historically,  has  been  to  cater  to  the  long- 
haul  passengers :  planes  have  been  built  to  suit  them,  and  airports  have  been 
built  to  suit  them.  But  those  airports  are  inconvenient  for  the  short  haul 
passenger  and  the  plane,  for  the  most  part,  are  not  economically  feasible  for 
short  trips. 

This  gap  in  the  system  led  to  the  success  of  the  intrastate  airlines  in  Texas 
and  California.  In  Texas,  people  are  attracted  to  the  turn-around  flights  be- 
tween Dallas  and  Houston  because  of  the  convenience   of  airports  near  the 


532 


downtown  areas,  because  of  the  frequency  of  the  flights  and  because  of  lower 
costs. 

But  the  public  still  is  paying  a  high  price  for  the  failure  of  the  states  to 
participate  in  the  development  of  an  adequate  air  transportation  system.  It 
seems  to  me  that  the  CAB  should  change  its  philosophy  and  encourage  the  states 
to  operate  as  full  partners.  We  already  have  the  finest  air  transportation  system 
of  any  country  in  the  world,  especially  when  it  comes  to  the  long-haul ;  working 
together,  we  could  improve  that  system  considerably  and  take  some  giant  strides 
forward  to  benefit  short-haul  passengers.  The  states  and  the  federal  government 
have  demonstrated  the  advantages  of  working  together  in  building  our  tremen- 
dous highway  system  ;  I  know  of  no  reason  they  should  not  work  together,  in 
similar  fashion,  to  make  our  air  transportation  system  all  that  it  should  be. 

Mr.  Chairman,  again  I  want  to  thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  appear  before 
your  distinguished  committee.  I  will  be  happy  to  try  to  answer  any  questions. 

SOUTllWES'i    AIRLIME   GL^RVICE   AV/AlCtNED    SLEEPING 
AIR  TRAVEL  LlARr.ETS  IN  TE)(AS  1971  -1972 


O^DrAr.SQJG 

:i;5 

600,000 
500,000 

A 

DALLA^ 

\~  i;ou 

3T0  \\ 

\ — A 

^^--^ 



— -—- - 

200,000 

T^ 

4 

/ 

D  ALLANS  At  J 

AfJTO:] 

0 

{■\    !U 

CAB. 
AIRLINES 

^^~         ^^ 

Jil-i^ 

> 

!!CU3T6:5-3Ar, 

auto:: 

!0 

100.000 
,90,000 
80,000 
70,000 
60,000 
50,000 

40,000 

-^         \ 

^^^^ 

"■^ — 

■ 

<rTf'T 

\ 

< 

^^-.^ 

tmSsi 

J- 

"\ 

— ■ 

/ 

2  0.000 

[A\DC-.-I',..tST    A—  •       ;  C 

Vl.r  .;•■,•'' 

10.000 

1 

V 


I9C5  IOC( 


I9C3  1970  1971 


533 


DALLAS-HOUSTON   MARKET 

AVERAGE   DAILY   LOCAL  PASSENGERS 
CARRIED  IN   EACH  DIRECTION 


1967  1968  1969  1970 


1972  1973 


CAB  REGULATION  OF  ENTRY  INTO  DOMESTIC  AIR 
ROUTES  AND  INTO  THE  DOMESTIC  AIR  TRANSPORT 
INDUSTRY 


TUESDAY,  FEBRUARY  18,  1975 

U.S.  Senate, 
Subcommittee  on  Administrative 

Practice  and  Procedure  of  the 

Committee  on  the  Judiciary, 

Washington,  B.C. 
The  subcommittee  met,  pursuant  to  notice,  at  9  :45  a.m.,  in  room  2228, 
Dirken  Office  Building,  Senator  Edward  M.  Kennedy  (chairman  of 
the  subcommittee)  presiding. 

Present:  Senator  Kennedy  and  Senator  Thurmond. 
Also  present :  Stephen  Breyer,  special  counsel ;  Philip  Bakes,  assist- 
ant counsel ;  and  Thomas  M.  Susman,  chief  counsel. 
Senator  Kennedy.  The  subcommittee  will  come  to  order. 

OPENING  STATEMENT  OF  SENATOR  KENNEDY 

The  focus  of  today's  hearings  is  on  the  process  by  which  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board  allocates  routes,  as  the  Subcommittee  on  Admin- 
istrative Practice  and  Procedure  continues  its  hearings  on  Federal 
regulation  of  the  airlines.  Our  hearings  have  so  far  examined  CAB 
charter  policies,  general  principles  of  airline  regulation,  and  the  dif- 
ferences between  regulated  and  unregulated  aviation.  At  each  stage 
of  our  inquiry,  we  are  asking  whether  the  procedures  used  by  the  CAB 
are  efficient,  fair,  open,  and  proper.  And  at  each  stage  we  are  likewise 
asking  whether  the  policies  applied  are  responsive  to  the  legitimate 
needs  of  the  public,  the  industry,  and  our  Nation  in  general. 

Searching  for  a  coherent,  consistent,  public-interest-oriented  entry 
policy  at  the  CAB  is  difficult.  For  the  past  2  years  not  one  airline  was 
granted  new  authority  to  serve  one  of  the  100  heaviest-traveled  routes 
in  this  country.  In  the  past  10  years,  only  142  certificates  for  these 
major  routes  were  granted,  although  airlines  filed  over  1,800  applica- 
tions for  these  certificates.  And  since  1950,  out  of  94  applications  for 
trunk  authority  filed  by  nontrunk  airlines,  not  a  single  application  was 
granted  by  the  CAB. 

The  Board  has  characterized  its  current  route  freeze  and  refusal  to 
hold  hearings  on  route  applications  as  reflecting  a  "policy  of  caution." 
''Caution"  is  a  strange  word  to  describe  a  policy  that  ignores  the  leg- 
islative intent  of  both  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  and  the  Administrative 
Procedure  Act. 

The  Federal  Aviation  Act  says  that  route  applications  shall  be  set 
for  public  hearing  and  shall  be  disposed  of  "as  speedily  as  possible." 
This  echoes  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act's  prohibition  against 
dilatory  handling  of  petitions:  "With  due  regard  for  the  convenience 
and  necessity  of  the  parties  *  *  *  and  within  a  reasonable  time,  each 
agency  shall  proceed  to  conclude  a  matter  presented  to  it."  Neverthe- 

(535) 


536 

less,  the  CAB  has  refused  to  allow  new  competitors  in  airline  markets 
not  only  by  deciding  to  keep  them  out,  but  by  refusing  even  to  hear 
their  cases.^The  CAB  staff  itself  has  acknowledged  that  over  the  past  5 
years  cases  involving  new  domestic  route  authority  have  generally  not 
been  set  for  hearing,  with  many  of  them  being  dismissed  as  stale  after 
lingering  for  years  unheard  on  the  CAB's  docket. 

The  procedural  effects  of  this  course  of  action  by  the  Board  are 
clear : 

First,  it  prevents  public  participation  in,  comment  on,  or  challenge 
to  CAB  entry  policies,  since  there  is  no  articulation  of  those  policies — 
if  indeed  there  are  any  such  policies — in  rulemaking  or  adjudications. 

Second,  it  prevents  "effective  judicial  review  of  any  specific  route  ap- 
plication because  no  final,  reviewable  order  is  ever  entered  on  that 
application. 

But  the  most  important  effect  of  this  overall  restrictive  entry  policy, 
and  in  recent  years  the  almost  total  route  freeze,  has  been  to  prevent 
additional  competition  in  existing  markets.  This  may  be  good  for  those 
airlines  granted  monopoly  status  or  at  least  insulated  from  new  com- 
petition. It  allows  them 'to  offer  gimmicks  and  frills  and  frequent, 
empty  flights  to  attract  customers.  But  it  also  allows  them  to  keep  their 
fares  unreasonably  high.  And  this  is  not  good  for  the  traveling  public. 
Last  Friday  one  witness  estimated  that  CAB  regulation  costs  Ameri- 
can consumers  about  $3.5  billion  each  year  over  Avhat  w^e  would  pay 
with  a  comparable  unregulated  airline  industry.  Other  witnesses 
showed  us  how,  in  an  intrastate  market  where  until  recently  new  com- 
petitors could  freely  fly  between  cities,  the  unregulated  intrastate  rates 
were  consistently  and"  significantly  lower  than  comparable  regulated 
rates.  This  begins  to  give  us  a  more  realistic  picture  of  one  of  the  prices 
we  are  paying  for  a  "policy  of  caution." 

Economists  have  proposed  liberalized  entry — freer  entry  into  airline 
markets — as  a  necessary  step  toward  lifting  the  costs  and  burdens  of 
Government  regulation  on  the  traveling  public  and  on  those  who  buy 
goods  which  have  travelled  by  air.  The  administration,  at  our  hear- 
ings earlier  this  month,  included  a  more  liberal  route-award  policy 
as  part  of  its  package  of  reform  proposals  directed  at  aviation  regula- 
tion. And  we  will  hear  from  some  carriers  this  morning  who  believe 
that  the  industry,  as  well  as  the  public,  would  be  better  off  with  more 
route  competition. 

The  CAB's  entry  policies  and  procedures  may  be  outdated.  They 
may  be  unwise.  They  may  also  be  illegal.  Today  we  will  hear  from  the 
Board,  as  well  as  some  of  its  critics,  who  will  discuss  those  policies 
and  procedures.  If  they  cannot  be  justified  as  serving  the  best  interests 
of  the  American  public,  then  we  will  continue  to  chart  a  course  for 
their  change. 

[In  addition  to  the  hearing  record  of  this  day.  materials  on  certifica- 
tion and  entry  have  been  collected  in  the  separately  bound  appendix 
to  these  hearings.] 

I  want  to  acknowledge  that  the  subcommittee  has  received  a  state- 
ment from  the  Maryland  Department  of  Transportation  concerning 
the  CAB's  entry  and  report  award  policy.  That  statement  will  be  en- 
tered into  the  "record.  I  want  to  thank  them  for  submitting  their 
statement. 


537 

[The  prepared  statement  referred  to  was  submitted  by  Robert  J. 
Aaronson,  State  aviation  administrator,  Maryland  Department  of 
Transportation.  It  is  printed  at  the  end  of  the  record  of  the  hearings 
of  this  day  (February  18,  1975,  p.  730,  below.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  Ave  could  have  the  representatives  of  the  vari- 
ous airlines  testifying  today  come  forward  together  we  can  save  some 
time  and  perhaps  get  some  discussion  later.  Messrs.  Hardenstine, 
Wexler,  Easenberger,  Tipton,  Colodny  and  De  Voursney. 

Mr.  Hardenstine  is  senior  vice  president,  and  a  director,  of  World 
Airways.  He  is  a  former,  often-decorated  lieutenant  commander  in  the 
Navy,  and  he  has  held  various  positions  in  the  airline  industry.  He 
joined  World  Airways  in  1963. 

We  have  received  your  statement,  Mr.  Hardenstine,  and  the  sub- 
committee appreciates  your  participation.  I  would  be  pleased  if  you 
could  summarize  your  statement  and  tell  the  subcommittee  the  experi- 
ence of  World  Airways  when  it  applied  for  transcontinental  scheduled 
authority. 

STATEMENTS  OF  WILLIAM  A.  HARDENSTINE,  SENIOR  VICE  PRESI- 
DENT— SALES,  WORLD  AIRWAYS;  RAYMOND  J.  RASENBERGER, 
COUNSEL,  NORTH  CENTRAL  AIRLINES;  HARVEY  J.  WEXLER, 
SENIOR  VICE  PRESIDENT,  INTERNATIONAL  AND  GOVERNMEN- 
TAL AFFAIRS,  CONTINENTAL  AIRLINES;  EDWIN  I.  COLODNY, 
EXECUTIVE  VICE  PRESIDENT,  MARKETING  AND  LEGAL  AF- 
FAIRS, ALLEGHENY  AIRLINES;  ANDREW  M.  DE  VOURSNEY, 
GROUP  VICE  PRESIDENT,  FINANCE  AND  PLANNING,  UNITED  AIR 
LINES;  AND  STUART  G.  TIPTON,  SENIOR  VICE  PRESIDENT,  FED- 
ERAL AFFAIRS,  PAN  AMERICAN  WORLD  AIRWAYS,  ACCOMPA- 
NIED BY  STANLEY  GEWIRTZ,  SPECIAL  ADVISER  ON  PUBLIC 
POLICY,  PAN  AMERICAN  WORLD  AIRWAYS 

WORLD   airways'    196  7    APPLICATION    FOR    ?75    TRANSCONTINENTAL   FARE 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Good  morning.  Mr.  Chairman. 

In  summarizing  the  statement  that  I  have  submitted  to  the  sub- 
committee, let  me  say  that  in  1967  World  Airways  submitted  to  the 
CAB  a  proposal  that  it  could  operate  a  transcontinental  thrift-class 
service  at  approximately  50  percent  of  the  regular  coach  fare.  It  was 
our  plan  to  serve  secondary  airports  to  the  extent  available,  which 
were  nonetheless  convenient  to  the  major  population  centers  of  Oak- 
land, Long  Beach,  and  Ontario  on  the  west  coast,  for  example. 

Our  idea  was  that  thrift  fare  should  be  available  to  everyone  every- 
day. It  was  our  forecast  that  this  plan  would  stimulate  a  substantial 
amount  of  new  traffic,  particularly  discretionary  traffic. 

After  filing  our  application  61/0  years  ago,  it  was  dismissed  as  stale. 
No  other  explanation  was  given.  We  still  believe  it  was  a  good  idea.  It 
is  still  valid  today. 

But  let  me  add,  we  were  prepared  to  meet  the  basic  statutory  test  of 
proving  our  plan  was  required  by  public  convenience  and  necessity. 
We  were  not  advocating  free  entry.  All  we  wanted  was  a  chance  to 


538 

provide  in  a  regular  administrative  procedure  that  our  plan  met  all 
the  conventional  standards  for  certification. 

Let  me  add  one  other  point  that  may  be  a  bit  tangential  to  your 
major  theme.  On  page  4  of  my  written  statement,  I  liave  summarized 
fees  paid  to  the  CAB  by  air  carriers.  Those  related  to  charter  matters 
represented  24  percent  of  the  total  paid,  even  though  charter  revenues 
are  only  3  percent  of  industry  revenues.  This  is  tJie  clearest  possible 
summary  of  the  overregulation  to  which  we  are  subjected. 

I  thank  you. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Could  you  not  have  gotten  judicial  review  of  the 
Board's  action  if  you  wanted  to  challenge  it? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  I  do  not  know,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  still  think  you  could  profitably  fly  the 
route  cheaper  than  the  prevailing  fare  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  I  know  absolutely. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  could  not  tell  us  now  what  rate.  At  that  time 
it  was  $75. 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Eight,  and  I  think  today  it  would  still  come  into 
an  area  of  50  percent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  might  give  us  a  note  if  your  legal  counsel 
did  consider  taking  some  court  action.  Obviously  you  should  not  have 
to  go  through  that  process,  but  I  would  be  interested  to  know  if  that 
was  given  thought.  You  can  submit  that  as  an  addendum  to  your  state- 
ment later  on.  Do  you  intend  to  refile  your  application? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  At  the  present  time,  and  I  would  say  under  the 
present  climate,  I  do  not  think  we  would. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  would  you  not?  What  is  there  about  the 
present  climate  that  would  discourage  you  from  refiling? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  No.  1  would  be  the  economic  condition  of  the 
country  at  the  present  time  and  also  the  status  of  the  action  of  the 
CAB  in  not  granting  any  of  the  applications  that  have  been  submitted. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  could  the  Board  dismiss  the  application 
without  even  giving  you  a  hearing  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Well,  as  I  have  stated,  the  application  was  in  for 
61/2  years  and  then  it  was  dismissed  as  stale,  and  this  is  just  one  case 
that  World  had  presented  and  did  not 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  happened  when  you  raised  this?  Your 
application  had  been  in  for  61'^  years.  Were  you  told  only  that  it  was 
dismissed  as  stale  ?  What  kind  of  response  did  you  get  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  If  I  recall  correctly.  Senator,  a  number  of  appli- 
cations were  dismissed  around  the  same  time  as  being  stale  after  they 
had  been  submitted  in  the  midsixties. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Did  your  company  try  during  this  period  of  time 
to  get  a  hearing,  and  were  you  unable  to  do  so  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  That  is  right,  sir.  They  were  submitted  and  we 
were,  during  the  period,  attempting  to  get  everything  set  up. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  it  is  possible  that  the  Board 
thought  you  could  not  fly  at  that  fare  without  losing  money,  and  there- 
fore did  not  feel  it  was  worthwhile  to  have  a  hearing  given  the  fares 
you  were  talking  about  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  No,  I  would  not  think  so,  because  in  the  case 
that  was  submitted  and  in  the  submission  to  the  Board,  it  clearly 
showed  it  could  be  operated  and  operated  at  a  profit. 


539 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  could  you  fly  with  a  fare  so  much  lower 
than  the  other  carriers  and  still  make  a  profit  ? 

Mr.  Hardexstine.  Our  feeling:  was  that  basically  in  operating  out 
of  secondary  airports,  first,  we  could  get  away  from  the  congested 
areas — our  cost  of  operation  would  be  less,  generally,  from  the  second- 
ary airports. 

Second,  with  the  price  that  we  were  offering  we  would  be  able  to 
have  approximately  75-  to  80-percent  load  factor. 

Senator  Kenxedt.  How  much  of  a  factor  was  less  congested  air- 
ports, how  much  a  load  factor?  "What  weight  would  you  say 
you  would  give  to  each  of  those  considerations  ?  Could  you  have  flown 
at  75-percent  load  factor  out  of  the  primary  air  terniinals  and  still 
made  a  profit,  or  would  you  have  to  go  at  75  percent  out  of  secondary, 
and  80  percent  out  of  primary  airports  ?  What  is  the  difference  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  The  difference  in  the  secondary  is,  one,  you  are 
away  completely  from  the  congestion  of  the  airport  and  generally  the 
fees  would  be  less. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Landing  fees  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Landing  fees,  handling  fees,  space  fees. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  do  not  some  of  the  scheduled  airlines  fly  out 
of  secondary  airports  and  reduce  fares  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  I  think  probably  the  scheduled  airlines  are  serv- 
ing the  secondary  airports,  but  in  general,  they  are  serving  them  with 
one-  or  two-stop  service.  As  an  example,  San  Francisco  to  the  east  coast, 
there  are  a  number  of  nonstop  services.  If  you  were  looking  at  Oakland 
to  the  east  coast,  I  do  not  think  that  Oakland  today  has  any  nonstop 
service. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  the  primary  reasons,  then,  that  you  are  not 
resubmitting  an  application:  (1)  because  of  the  policy  that  has  been 
adopted  by  the  CAB,  and  (2)  because  of  the  economic  situation  ?  If  the 
economy  turns  around  will  you  reconsider  submitting  an  application  ? 
Do  you  still  think  you  can  fly  substantially  below  scheduled  fares? 
Would  you  give  consideration  if  the  CAB  indicated  that  they  would 
hold  hearings — would  you  give  consideration,  then,  to  getting  back 
in  the  market  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Absolutely  we  would,  and  we  still  feel  that  the 
operation  of  the  type  that  we  did  submit  is  valid. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Just  the  assurance,  though,  that  the  Board  would 
give  you  a  hearing  would  not  be  enough  to  get  you  into  the  business, 
given  the  economic  problems  at  the  present  time,  or  would  it? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  If  we  knew  we  would  get  a  hearing  and  move 
ahead  with  the  proposal  we  would  go  ahead  with  it  at  the  present  time. 

Senator  Kenneedy.  Your  application  gave  a  fare  of  $75,  about  one- 
half  what  the  fare  was  then  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  And  flying  at  75  percent  of  capacity  out  of  sec- 
ondary airports,  you  still  think  that  at  half  the  scheduled  fare  you 
could  make  a  profit  ? 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  you  operated  out  of  the  primary  airports  what 
do  you  think  your  fare  would  have  to  be,  can  you  give  us  any  idea, 
given  75-percent  load  factor? 


540 

Mr.  Hardenstine.  If  we  were  operating  out  of  the  primary  areas, 
here  again  you  would  be  in  the  situation  of  attempting  to  find  space 
at  the  primary  airport  to  do  a  good  job  for  the  public  and  to  provide 
a  good  passenger  service  situation.  I  think  that  the  use  of  the  secondary 
airports  and  the  use  of  passengers  coming  to  the  secondary  airports  for 
a  lower  fare  travel  would  by  all  means  be  the  way  that  any  thrift-class 
service  would  take  place. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Had  you  given  consideration  to  other  routes,  be- 
sides the  transcontinental  flight  ? 

INIr.  Hardenstine.  No,  we  had  not,  not  at  the  time. 

Senator  Kennedy.  OK.  Thank  you  very  much.  Can  you  stay  with 
us  for  just  a  little  while  ? 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Hardenstine  is  printed  at  the  end 
of  the  oral  testimony  of  the  airline  panel,  pp.  365-73,  below.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  Our  next  witness  is  Mr.  Raymond  J.  Rasen- 
berger,  representing  North  Central  Airlines. 

For  the  past  10  yeare,  Mr.  Rasenberger  has  been  a  partner  in  the 
AVashington,  D.C.,'law  firm  of  Zuckert,  Scoutt,  &  Rasenberger. 

Mr.  Rasenberger  has  submitted  a  vei-y  illuminating  statement  to 
the  subcommittee,  which  describes  the  legal  and  practical  ramifications 
of  the  CAB's  route  moratorium  and  points  out  the  problems  raised 
under  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  and  the  Administrative  Proce.dure 
Act.  We  want  to  thank  you,  Mr.  Rasenberger,  for  focusing  on  the 
procedural  implications  of  the  Board's  route  freeze.  This  subcom- 
mittee is  concerned  with  administrative  procedures,  and  your  state- 
ment has  aided  our  work.  I  would  appreciate  it  if  you  would  briefly 
summarize  your  statement  for  us. 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

I  will  summarize  my  statement. 

As  you  mentioned,  we  are  here  at  the  request  of  the  staff  to  talk 
about  the  CAB  so-called  route  moratorium.  We  are  not  here  to  discuss 
the  merits  of  any  cases  pending  before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board — 
as  distinguished  from  the  procedural  history  of  cases  ^\e  have  pre- 
sented. The  merits  of  cases  are  things  we  will  deal  with  before  the 
Board. 

cab's    "route    moratorium,"     19  69-19  74:    HISTORICAL    PERSPECTIVE 

We  are  also  not  here  to  join  in  any  broad  attack  on  either  the 
Federal  Aviation  Act  or  the  CAB.  Of  course,  we  have  had  many 
liisagreements,  and  the  route  moratorium  is  certainly  one  of  the  major 
ones,  but  on  the  whole  we  have  worked  under  an  excellent  statute. 
And  we  think  the  CAB,  looking  at  it  from  a  longer  and  broader  view, 
has  done  a  very  credible  job  in  administering  that  statute. 

I  hasten  to  add  we  are  not  saying  no  changes  should  be  made  in 
the  act  at  all.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  we  think  these  hearing-s  are  very 
useful  in  oi'der  to  consider  the  possibility  of  change. 

What  Ave  are  saying  is  that  we  do  not  think  radical  changes  are  war- 
T-anted,  and  especially  changes  involving  unregulated  entry  and  exit. 

With  respect  to  the  route  moratorium,  as  you  know,  and  as  T  think 
the  CAB  staff  has  acknowledge,  the  moratorium  began  in  1970.  As  I 
indicated  in  our  written  statement,  for  perspective,  however,  it  is 
useful  to  look  before  1970.  First,  of  course,  at  the  language  of  the 


541 

statute  itself,  which  calls  for  public  hearings  as  speedily  as  possible, 
and  which  supports  the  idea  of  competition.  Second,  at  the  history  of 
aviation  before  the  1938  Civil  Aeronautics  Act,  which  seems  to  me  to 
underscore  the  importance  of  both  public  hearings  and  competition. 

Then  it  is  useful,  I  think,  to  look  at  CAB  history  between 
World  War  II  and  1970.  During  that  long  period,  the  CAB  did  hear 
a  lot  of  route  applications.  It  did  grant  a  lot  of  routes,  and  it  certifi- 
cated, and  many  people  seem  to  forget  this,  a  large  number  of  new 
airlines.  In  short,  it  built  the  system  we  have  today. 

North  Central  is  a  primary  example  of  what  that  building  process 
could  and  did  accomplish.  When  North  Central  was  certificated  in 
1946  it  was  operating  two  five-place  Cessnas  out  of  Clintonville,  Wis. 
Last  year  it  carried  4i/^  million  passengers,  serving  90  cities,  mostly  in 
the  upper  Midwest  but  going  all  the  way  from  New  York  to  Denver. 
While  North  Central's  primary  mission  still  is  today  serving  these 
smaller  cities,  it  also  serves  a  number  of  large  routes  where  it  provides 
strong  competition  for  some  of  the  grandfather  carriers,  such  as 
United  and  Northwest  and  Western. 

Now,  a  great  deal  of  North  Central's  development  as  a  strong  com- 
petitive carrier  took  place  by  virtue  of  those  route  awards  particularly 
in  the  last  half  of  the  sixties.  That  is  why  the  route  moratorium  has 
had  a  particularly  dramatic  impact  on  us.  Since  1969,  no  applications 
for  competitive  service  by  North  Central  have  been  set  down  for  hear- 
ing by  the  CAB. 

There  is  one  exception  to  that,  an  application  that  was  set  down  in 
1970.  But  that  case  has  never  gone  forward  since  that  time. 

Now,  this  has  not  exactlv  been  what  you  would  call  a  self-imposed 
moratorium.  North  Central  is  a  young,  very  strong,  aggressive  airline. 
It  wants  to  compete.  It  tliinks  it  kiiows  how  to  run  a  tight  ship.  It  has 
been  able  to  make  money  year  after  year  when  many  other  airlines 
have  not,  even  witli  one  of  the  worst  route  systems.  In  other  words,  it 
thinks  it  can  compete  effectively  with  larger  carriers  and  it  wants  the 
opportunity  to  provide  more  of  that  kind  of  competition. 

EXAMPLES  OF   NORTH   CENTRAL  ROUTE   APPLICATIONS  NOT  HEARD  BY  CAB 

That  is  why  we  have  found  the  route  moratorium  so  frustrating.  In 
my  statement  I  have  given  three  examples  how  that  moratorium  has 
impacted  on  us. 

One  was  an  application  filed  in  1972  to  give  nonstop  competition 
between  Detroit  and  Boston.  That  market  is  the  largest  monopoly 
market  in  the  Ignited  States  with  about  600  origin  and  destination 
passengers  a  day.  Today  it  actually  has  less  service  than  when  we 
sought  a  hearing. 

We  filed  that  application  and  a  motion  for  expedited  hearing.  The 
principal  civic  parties  supported  us  at  both  ends  of  the  route,  including 
civil  parties  beyond  Detroit  in  Michigan.  After  9  months,  the  CAB 
denied  that  motion  for  hearing.  A  petition  for  reconsideration  was 
denied  7  months  later. 

Another  example  was  our  application  for  Milwaukee-Denver  non- 
stop authority.  INIilwaukee-Denver  is  a  United  Air  Dines  nonstop 
monopoly,  and  has  been  one  since  1946.  Since  1969  we  filed  once  for 
single  plane  one-stop  authority  in  the  market.  Later  we  filed  two  mo- 


542 

tions  for  expedited  hearing  for  nonstop  authority.  In  these  cases  wp 
Avere,  of  course,  supported  by  the  cities  such  as  Milwaukee  and  Denver. 
We  have  had  no  success  in  getting  that  application  heard,  although 
I  should  emphasize  there  have  been  dissents  among  Board  member^ 
on  this  question. 

The  third  example  is  Milwaukee-Philadelphia.  That  is  a  market 
where  the  CAB  found  in  1970,  at  the  conclusion  of  a  long  case,  that 
competition  was  needed.  It  was  a  United  monopoly  at  that  time.  The 
Board,  therefore,  certificated  Northwest  to  compete.  In  1972  United 
dropped  its  service  in  the  market.  By  the  start  of  1973  Northwest  had 
yet  to  begin  the  service  it  had  been  authorized  to  provide.  So  in  1973 
we  filed  an  application,  supported  by  Philadelphia  and  Milwaukee 
and  ports  beyond  Milwaukee,  to  have  us  certificated  to  provide  that 
nonstop  service.  Our  motion  for  a  hearing  on  that  application  was 
denied  2  days  after  Northwest  inaugurated  a  single  nonstop  flight. 
That  is  the  service  the  market  is  still  getting,  one  flight  from  North- 
west, still  none  from  United. 

DIFFERENCE   BETWEEN   DENIAL.  OF   HEARING   AND   DISMISSAL 

Now,  let  me  emphasize  something  about  each  of  these  three  examples. 
The  issue  that  we  presented  to  the  Board  was  not  whether  to  grant  our 
application,  but  whether  to  hold  a  hearing  on  it.  If  a  hearing  had  been 
scheduled,  obviously  the  applications  of  other  carriers  would  have 
been  heard.  There  was  a  very  good  chance  that  some  of  those  appli- 
cations would  have  been  granted  in  lieu  of  our  own.  There  was  a  very 
good  chance  that  no  one's  application  would  have  been  granted.  But, 
to  us  at  least,  there  is  a  big  difference  between  denying  an  application 
after  hearing  and  denying  it  by  refusing  to  hear  it. 

A  decision  that  is  made  after  a  hearing  has  to  be  made  on  a  public 
record,  where  the  forecasts  and  all  the  allegations  of  all  the  parties, 
including  the  CAB  staff,  are  open  to  review  and  cross-examination. 
And  that  hearing  process  imposes  on  the  agency  a  discipline,  the  dis- 
cipline of  making  a  record  and  of  making  findings  based  on  that  rec- 
ord. Those  findings,  of  course,  are  reviewable  by  courts,  which  is  not 
true  in  general  of  decisions  not  to  go  forward  with  hearing 
applications. 

When  the  Board  refuses  to  hear  an  application  it  usually  does  so  on 
the  basis  of  internal  staff  memorandums  which  are  generally  not  sub- 
ject to  challenge  by  other  parties  or,  as  I  said,  to  review  by  the  courts. 

SUGGESTIONS   FOR  REFORM 

Now,  the  question  has  been  raised  as  to  what  ought  to  be  done  to 
change  all  this.  We  have  only  a  few  preliminary  thoughts  on  the  mat- 
ter. Senator,  but  let  me  give  them  to  you.  First,  we  think  the  Board 
ought  to  hear  every  application  it  can  hear  as  speedily  as  possible. 
Now,  we  recognize  that  unless  the  Board  gets  more  staff  it  can  not 
hear  every  application  that  is  filed.  It  is  going  to  have  to  pick  and 
choose.  But  we  think  that  picking  and  choosing  ought  to  be  on  the 
basis  of  public  interest  standards  that  are  adopted  after  public  pro- 
ceedings. We  think  further  those  standards  ought  to  be  simple  and  oh- 


543 

jective  standards,  and  deal  with  questions  like  is  there  competition  in 
the  market  ?  How  long  has  it  been  since  we  last  considered  this  market  ? 
What  are  the  traffic  flows  in  the  market  ? 

We  are  inclined  to  think  the  standards  should  not  be  based  on  fore- 
casts. It  seems  to  us  that  is  the  very  function  of  a  hearing  is  the  prob- 
ing of  forecasts.  That  is  the  basic  difference  we  have  with  the  standards 
suggested  recently  by  the  CAB  staff  in  their  route  study.  They  would 
require  all  carriers  to  make  elaborate  forecasts  in  order  to  get  a  hear- 
ing set  down  on  an  application,  those  forecasts  would  be  taken  up  by 
the  Board  staff,  outside  the  hearing  room,  beyond  the  reach  of  an 
administrative  law  judge,  and  beyond  the  opportunity  to  cross- 
examine.  In  effect,  what  the  staff'  has  proposed  is  standards  that  might 
be  appropriate  for  a  decision  by  the  Board  on  the  merits  that  these 
standards  be  applied  at  the  threshold  of  the  case  on  the  question  of 
Avhether  to  grant  the  hearing.  In  other  words,  the  same  kind  of  stand- 
ards would  be  used  for  managing  the  Board's  docket  as  for  deciding 
a  case.  We  think  that  kind  of  confusion  can  result,  and  in  the  past 
5  years  has  resulted,  in  denying  hearings  which  the  statute  calls  for. 

Now,  as  I  pointed  out  in  our  statement,  the  question  of  what  are 
the  proper  threshold  standards  is  not  a  simple  question,  and  our  views 
are  at  this  point  only  preliminary.  We  intend  to  give  this  more  thought 
and  to  respond  to  the  Board's  invitation  to  comment  on  it. 

But  meanwhile,  Ave  do  appreciate  the  fact  that  your  subcommittee 
considers  this  problem  serious  enough  to  warrant  your  own  thought- 
ful attention  to  it.  Thank  you. 

LEGALITY   OF   "rOUTE   MORATORIUM" 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much. 

I  would  like  to  ask  you,  if  I  could,  why  you  do  not  take  legal  action 
against  the  route  moratorium.  You  have  outlined  in  your  testimony 
how  the  Federal  Aviation  Act,  in  section  401(c),  states  that  applica- 
tion shall  be  set  for  public  hearing,  and  that  the  Board  shall  dispose 
of  applications  as  speedily  as  possible.  In  your  opinion  as  an  attorney, 
do  you  think  the  Board's  route  moratorium  violates  that  provision? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  I  would  say  a  consistent  and  unannounced  policy 
of  refusing  to  hold  hearings  on  applications  violates  the  act,  yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  And  then  section  6(a)  of  the  Administrative 
Procedure  Act  states  that,  with  due  regard  of  the  convenience  and 
necessity  of  the  parties  or  their  representatives,  and  in  a  reasonable 
time,  each  agency  shall  proceed. 

As  you  point  out  in  your  testimony,  this  was  meant  to  create  a  legal 
requirement  that  no  agency  fail  to  conclude  a  case.  Do  you  think  the 
CAB's  refusal  to  conduct  hearings  on  route  applications  violates  that 
particular  section? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  I  would  say  yes,  unless  it  is  clear,  and  CAB  would 
have  to  answer  this,  unless  it  is  clear  that  they  did  not  have  the  re- 
sources to  hear  any  of  those  applications.  Now,  if  they  did  not,  some- 
thing happened  very  suddenly  in  1970  to  deny  them  the  necessary 
resources.  If  an  agency  has  the  staff  resources  it  ought  to  devote  them 
to  trying  cases,  whether  it  denies  all  applications  or  not.  I  think  that 
is  what  the  act  intends. 


544 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  know  of  your  own  knowledge  whether 
staff  shortage  has  been  used  as  a  justification  for  refusal  to  hold 
hearings  ? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  In  denying  a  hearing  on  our  Detroit-Boston 
application  the  Board  gave  a  number  of  reasons,  but  one  of  them  was 
that  it  was  busy  with  rate  cases. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  about  the  other  reasons  ? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  Well,  the  others  had  to  do  with  impact  on  the 
incumbent  carrier,  which  seemed  to  be  of  considerable  concern  to  the 
Board.  It  was  also  said  we  had  not  shown  that  the  service  was  mate- 
rially deficient,  or  would  involve  substantial  benefit  to  the  public,  or 
that  we  could  make  a  profit  on  it.  That  pretty  w^ell  took  care  of  it. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  thought  you  could  ? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  Obviously  we  thought  so  and  we  still  think  so. 
These  questions  of  what  is  deficient  service  and  what  is  of  substantial 
benefit  to  the  public  is  also  questions  of  judgment.  We  think  that 
when  a  large  monopoly  exists,  regardless  of  load  factors,  service  is 
materially  deficient. 

susceptibility  of  route  moratorium  to  court  challenge 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  the  CAB  is  in  fact  violating  the  law,  and  it 
seems  from  your  testimony  you  believe  it  is,  why  can  you  not  as  an 
aggrieved  party  take  the  matter  to  the  courts  and  get  some  relief  ? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  It  is  very  difficult.  Senator,  because  what  you 
would  take  to  court  is  an  order  in  one  case,  and  what  you  are  dealing 
with  is  a  policy  which  is  not  announced  and  wliich  is  reflected  only  by 
the  accretion  of  case-by-case  denials.  You  cannot  take  a  bunch  of  cases 
to  court.  You  have  got  to  take  one,  and  in  no  particular  case  can  you 
prove  on  the  record  of  that  case,  or  at  least  it  is  very  difficult  to  prove, 
that  the  decision  was  pursuant  to  a  general  policy  of  a  route  morato- 
rium. 

As  you  perhaps  know,  the  courts  are  reluctant  to  interfere,  and 
properly  so,  I  think,  in  questions  that  involve  the  agency  managing  its 
own  clocket  and  questions  of  agency  discretion  generally  of  that  type. 
That  is  why,  in  a  way,  a  moratorium  is  such  an  insidious  "way  of  dealing 
with  applications,  because  it  is  so  hard  to  get  judicial  review. 

Senator  Kennedy.  So,  in  effect,  the  inaction  has  the  effect  of  making 
the  Board's  policy  immune  from  any  kind  of  judicial  review? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  Well,  it  makes  it  difficult.  I  do  not  know,  if  Ave 
went  to  the  court  of  appeals  today,  or  a  lower  court  and  explained  this 
long  history  of  a  moratorium,  which  the  CAB  staff  has  now  acknowl- 
edged existed,  whether  perhaps  we  could  make  a  case.  But  in  any  case 
we  have  not  done  so  and  have  no  plans  to  do  so. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  they  made  a  ruling  in  any  of  these  cases  ob- 
viously you  could  go  to  a  court  and  appeal  the  ruling,  but  the  practical 
effect  of  tlieir  decision  not  to  hear  a  case  is  that  it  is  concluded,  without 
the  opportunity  of  judicial  review— with  the  qualification  that  you 
indicated  in  the  last  response  to  my  question. 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  That  is  right.  I  do  not  mean  to  suggest  if  they 
held  a  hearing  and  denied  all  applications  it  would  be  that  easy  to  ob- 
tain a  reversal.  The  Board  could  make  findings  and  has  done  so.  In  at 
least  one  case  now  being  appealed  they  decided  the  market  did  not 


545 

require  additional  service.  If  those  findings  could  be  based  on  the 
record  and  if  they  Avere  otherwise  properly  related  to  the  statutory  cri- 
teria, the  Board's  decision  not  to  grant  a  hearing  Avould  be  upheld, 
presumably,  by  the  courts.  But  the  point  is  that  requires  the  kind  of 
discipline  and  thoughtfulness  that  is  not  required  by  the  process  of 
denying  a  motion  for  a  expedited  hearing. 

Senator  Kexnedy.  In  any  event,  it  is  running  quite  contrary,  cer- 
tainly to  the  spirit,  and  I  think  in  these  instances  to  the  letter,  of  legis- 
lation, and  obviously  no  applicant  should  be  required,  under  any  type 
of  governmental  process  to  go  through  the  kind  of  extraordinary 
lengths  which  you  have  described  as  being  necessary,  in  order  to  seek 
some  remedies. 

SMALL-TOWX    SERVICE     (CROSS-SUBSIDY) 

Earlier  in  your  testimony  you  spoke  about  air  service  to  weak  points, 
connecting  stronger  points.  Are  you  raising  the  cross-subsidy  issue 
here,  and  can  you  provide  us  with  any  examples  for  the  record  of  cross- 
subsidy  on  North  Central's  routes  ? 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  Yes,  sir,  I  am  suggesting  the  system  we  have  to- 
day involves  a  great  deal  of  cross-subsicly.  I  know  there  are  many  who 
feel  that  is  not  the  way  to  go  about  it.  But  that  is  the  system  we  have 
had.  We  have  built  it  for  30  years,  and  North  Central  is  a  perfect 
example  of  that  system  at  work.  We  serve  many  small  weak  points 
which  we  could  not  afford  to  serve,  even  with  subsidy,  except  for  the 
profits  thrown  off  from  some  of  our  stronger  routes.  That  is  why  the 
Board  gave  us  those  stronger  routes,  and  the  way  we  oj^erate  involves 
a  sharing  of  profits  from  stronger  routes  as  an  offset  to  the  subsidy 
needed  on  those  weaker  routes. 

In  addition  to  what  you  would  call  internal  cross-subsidy  situations 
within  North  Central,  I  think  the  whole  system,  the  whole  system  of 
intercarrier  operations,  involves  cross  subsidy  with  traffic.  In  other 
words,  our  weak  points,  and  we  serve  many  of  them,  all  funnel  into 
Chicago.  We  are  providing  traffic  support  at  Chicago  for  many  larger 
routes  out  of  Chicago.  The  existence  of  those  larger  routes  provides 
service  opportunities  at  Devil's  Lake  and  other  smaller  points  which 
need  service  to  Cleveland  and  other  places  that  they  cannot  get  on 
one  carrier. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  would  be  interested  in  that  particular  issue. 
I  won't  take  additional  time,  but  we  might  inquire  further  about  your 
airlines,  and  perhaps  about  others  as  well. 

Mr.  Rasenberger.  We  will  be  happy  to  cover  that,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Fine. 

Thank  you  very  much.  I  hope  you  will  be  able  to  stay  with  us  in 
case  we  have  some  issues  that  come  up  that  we  might  hear  responses 
from. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Rasenberger  is  printed  at  the  end  of 
the  oral  testimony  of  the  airline  panel,  pp.  573-80.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  hear  from  Mr.  Wexler  of  Continental 
Airlines,  where  he  is  now  the  senior  vice  president  of  international 
and  governmental  affairs.  Mr,  Wexler  was  a  Fulbright  scholar  at  Ox- 
ford, holds  an  M.B.A.  from  Harvard,  and  earned  the  Legion  of  Merit 
in  the  Air  Force. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  36 


546 

I  especially  want  to  thank  you,  INIr.  Wexler,  for  providing  the  sub- 
committee with  such  a  thoughtful  and  complete  statement.  The  sub- 
committee's work  will  be  much  more  fruitful  if  the  airlines  themselves 
think  about  these  issues  seriously,  and  Continental  has  certainly  done 
that.  I  would  appreciate  it  if  you  could  briefly  summarize  the  main 
points  of  your  statement,  especially  your  statement  that  competition 
and  route  awards  benefit  the  public,  your  views  on  free  entry  and  how 
that  has  worked  in  California,  and  the  effects  of  free  entry  on  service 
to  small  communities  and  acquisition  of  aircraft. 

Mr.  Wexler.  Mr.  Chairman,  thank  you. 

I  am  accompanied  by  Mr,  Thomas  Finney  on  my  right,  who  is 
"Washington  counsel  for  Continental  and  a  member  of  our  board  of 
directors. 

At  the  outset,  Mr.  Chairman,  let  me  say  that  we  fully  concur  with  the 
closing  comments  of  your  statement  of  December  16  on  the  floor  of  the 
Senate  where  you  mentioned  the  need  for  revitalization  of  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board  and  the  possibility  of  some  legislative  changes. 
As  we  stated  in  our  letter  to  you  of  December  20,  we  think  the  act  is 
basically  sound,  the  regulatory  framework  that  the  Congress  estab- 
lished is  perfectly  sound,  but  it  may  need  some  modification. 

The  Board  functioned  very  well  for  about  13  years,  and  it  developed 
the  world's  "finest  air  transport  network.*'  I  believe  it  is  the  most  ef- 
ficient in  the  world,  certainly  the  most  extensive,  and  also  by  any 
measure  the  most  competitive. 

But  of  recent  years,  the  Board  has  adopted  certain  regressive  poli- 
cies that  have  inhibited  the  further  development  of  that  very  system. 
I  shall  highlight  some  of  those. 

We  firmly  believe  that  the  regressive  policies  adopted  by  the  Board 
must  come  to  an  end  in  the  public  interest.  Specifically  we  urge  the 
following  changes : 

cab's    "route    moratorium"    19  69-74 

First  is  the  expanding  service  to  the  public.  The  Board  has  had 
a  freeze  on  new  route  awards  since  1969.  This  freeze  was  never  jus- 
tified and  should  be  brought  to  an  end.  The  oftheard  generalization 
that  the  economic  problems  of  air  carriers  are  the  result  of  too  much 
competition  in  the  air  transportation  system  is  nonsense.  The  route 
awards  of  the  sixties  were  in  now  way  responsible  for  the  losses  car- 
riers sustained  during  the  1970-71  recession.  During  that  period,  the 
smaller,  more  efficient  carriers  pulled  through  with  small  profits. 
It  was  the  big  carriers  who  suffered.  They  simply  couldn't  respond 
to  changed  economic  conditions  with  sufficient  rapidity  because  of 
their  size.  Moreover,  the  two  carriers  which  suffered  the  greatest  num- 
ber of  new  route  awards  to  other  carriers  in  their  major  markets, 
namely  Delta  and  United,  have  remained  highly  profitable.  The  reason 
is  that  they  are  well  managed  and  even  the  substantial  new  route 
awards  of  the  late  sixties  are  relatively  insignificant  in  their  economic 
impact  on  the  incumbents  or  the  carriers  granted  awards. 

The  prime  beneficiary  of  new  route  awards  is  the  public.  New  route 
awards  are  essential  to  assure  the  continued  growth  of  a  network  of 
air  transportation  to  meet  the  needs  of  all  communities.  New  route 
awards  also  assuer  a  competitive  industry,  responsive  to  the  public 


547 

needs.  Carriers  will  provide  effective  service  so  long  as  the  threat  of 
additional  carrier  certification  hangs  over  their  head.  Without  that 
threat,  we  become  lax  and  seek  to  extract  maximum  profits  from  our 
routes — often  at  the  public  expense.  Moreover,  new  route  awards  are 
the  proverbial  carrot  that  keeps  us  pulling  our  carts. 

cab's    staff   study,   the   domestic   route    system    (1974) 

I  might  note  that  the  recent  study  published  by  the  Board's  staff 
purporting  to  set  standards  for  route  awards  in  the  future  is  no  more 
than  an  outgrowth  of  the  Board's  recent  regressive  policies.  The  study 
proceeds  from  the  wrong  policy  objective:  the  protection  of  carrier 
profitability.  The  underlying  objective  should  be  to  meet  the  needs  of 
the  markets  and  to  properly  serve  the  public.  For  example,  the  study 
urges  that  competition  not  be  certified  unless  the  incumbent  has  a  6- 
percent  overall  rate  of  return.  That  has  nothing  to  do  with  need  of 
a  particular  market.  The  study  also  urges  that  competition  should 
only  be  certificated  when  the  incumbent  and  the  new  carrier  can  each 
achieve  a  12-percent  rate  of  return  in  the  market  involved  for  the  first 
year  of  competitive  operation.  This  substitutes  carrier  profits  for 
public  service  and  the  benefits  of  competition.  The  study  also  urges 
achievement  of  a  55-percent  load  factor  before  competition  can  be 
certificated.  Load  factor  alone  is  not  the  test  of  whether  a  market  needs 
or  can  reasonably  support  competitive  service. 

As  Congress  and  the  Board  have  recognized  in  the  past,  competition 
is  beneficial  in  and  of  itself.  In  the  Board's  own  words : 

Competition  invites  comparison  as  to  equipment  cost,  personnel,  organization, 
methods  of  operation,  solicitation  and  handling  of  traffic,  and  the  like,  all  of 
which  tend  to  insure  the  development  of  an  air  transportation  system  as  con- 
templated by  the  Act. 

These  important  benefits  of  competition  seemed  to  have  been  over- 
looked by  the  Board  in  the  recent  past.  If  I  may  say,  when  I  use  the 
word,  I  wish  to  make  the  point  there  has  been  a  healthy  disagreement 
between  members  of  the  Board. 

OTHER   NEEDED   CHANGES   IN    CAb's   POLICIES 

Next,  the  Board  should  take  immediate  steps  to  liberalize  carrier 
operating  authority.  Every  carrier  is  hampered  in  its  service  by  out- 
moded restrictions,  imposed  years  ago.  The  justifications  for  many  of 
these  restrictions  have  disappeared. 

Third,  the  Board  should  stop  trying  to  manage  carrier  service 
policies.  Its  restrictive  seating  standards  controvert  the  statutory  man- 
date to  leave  schedules,  equipment,  accommodations,  and  facilities  to 
the  discretion  of  carrier  management.  At  the  same  time,  the  Board 
should  be  encouraged  to  set  standards  of  efficiency  for  determining 
rates.  "We  supported  the  adoption  of  such  standards  and  the  expansion 
of  the  elements  of  carrier  efficiency  to  be  tested.  The  Board  should 
however,  leave  actual  operating  decisions  to  carrier  management. 

Fourth,  the  Board  should  give  the  carriers  much  greater  freedom  to 
experiment  with  promotional  fares  and  to  compete  with  lower  fares. 
The  Board's  present  policies  are  too  restrictive  and  put  a  damper  on 
experimentation  which  benefits  the  public  and  benefits  the  industry. 


548 

Fifth,  the  anticompetitive  capacity  restraint  agreements  should  be 
broii(?ht  to  an  end.  These  agreements  were  approved  on  an  emergency 
basis  due  to  the  f  aihire  of  the  Big  Three  and  Pan  Am  in  1970  to  respond 
with  sufficient  rapidity  to  economic  adversity.  They  have  been  extended 
with  the  rationale  of  fuel  conservation.  Today,  they  have  simply  no 
justification. 

None  of  these  changes  require  any  legislative  action.  In  fact,  all  are 
consistent  with  the  existing  statutory  requirements,  key  among  which 
is  the  competitive  mandate  of  section  102(d).  All  of  these  re.oressive 
Board  policies  requiring  reversal  presently  are  being  tested  before  the 
U.S.  Court  of  Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia  on  the  basis  that 
they  are  contrary  to  the  statute.  "We  have  three  such  actions  pending, 
as  I  mentioned  earlier.  The  Justice  Department  is  contesting  the  capac- 
ity restraint  agreements. 

Earlier,  the  Department  of  Transportation  and  the  Department  of 
Justice  so  testified  on  behalf  of  that  pro])osal.  Thus  it  is  our  view- 
that  a  significant  change  in  direction  is  needed  and  can  be  obtained  to 
a  large  extent  under  the  present  statute.  If  changes  are  necessary,  they 
are  largely  changes  to  reinforce  procompetitive  provisions  already 
set  forth  in  the  statute. 

[These  non-entry  suggestions  by  Continental  are  discussed  in  more 
detail  in  the  testimony  of  Mr.  Finney,  counsel,  Continental  Airlines, 
on  February  25,  1975,  pp.  1220-42,  below.] 

continental's  position  on  open  entry 

With  regard  to  the  matter-  of  open  entry,  I  have  in  my  written  testi- 
mony considerable  discourse  on  the  California  experience.  To  sum- 
marize it,  prior  to  1965,  California  had  \dii;ually  open  entry.  It  did 
have  open  entiy.  At  the  time  there  were  16  airlines  operating  within 
the  State,  14  of  which  went  bankrupt  there  were  two  survivors.  The 
State  of  California  in  its  wnsdom  adopted  an  act  quite  similar  to  our 
Federal  Aviation  Act,  and  today  there  is  quite  vigorous  controlled 
entry  in  the  California  intrastate  markets.  In  fact,  no  intrastate  Cali- 
fornia carriers  have  point  to  point  competition. 

Let  me  close  on  a  position  note.  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  in  a 
1950  decision  stated  that: 

An  objective  reading  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  leaves  no  doubt  that  the 
lawmakers  considered  competition  to  be  a  desirable  objective  which  should  be 
established  wherever  it  is  economically  feasible  and  will  contribute  to  the 
development  of  a  sound  national  air  transportation  system. 

I  hope  that  this  subcommittee  and  this  Congress  will  bring  to  bear 
its  energies  to  tliis  end,  but  we  have  a  basically  sound  system  and  a 
good  statutorv  framework.  Let's  try  to  make  it  work  as  Congress  in- 
tended in  1958  before  altering  it  and  destroying  our  effective  network 
of  air  transportation. 

cab's    staff    study,    the    domestic    route    system     (1974) 

Senator  Kennedy.  Very  fine  testimony. 

As  T  gather  from  your  testimony,  the  proposed  criteria  set  by  the 
Board's  BOK  in  their  January  statements  on  route  making,  you  feel 
move  us  very  little  down  the  road  toward  the  benefits  of  competition, 
which  you  stress  A^ery  extensively  in  your  statement? 


549 

Mr.  Wexler.  I  assume,  Mr.  Chairman,  you  are  referring  to  that 
staff  study  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes. 

Mr.  Wexler.  1  think  that  is  simply  a  perpetuation  of  the  existing 
route  freeze  only  in  a  more  rigid  system.  I  think  as  an  example,  where 
they  put  a  criteria  of  6-percent  rate  of  return  on  a  carrier  before  it 
can  be  subject  to  competition,  a  carrier  can  be  terribly  inefficient,  give 
very  poor  service,  operate  below  a  6-pei'cent  rate  of  return  and  the 
public  would  be  dooined.  It  would  not  have  the  benefit  of  competition 
under  that  type  of  criteria. 

results  of  open  entry 

Senator  Kennedy.  Have  you  had  a  chance  to  read  Professor  Jordan's 
testimony  on  the  California  experience? 

]\Ir,  Wexler.  No,  I  haven't. 

Senator  Kennedv.  I  wonder  if  you  would  take  a  look  at  it  and  give 
us  your  reactions  on  it,  because  it  goes  into  a  number  of  areas  which 
you  mention  in  your  testimony  but  which  haven't  been  elaborated  on 
here.  I  think  it  would  be  very  useful  for  us  if  you  would  be  kind  enough 
to  take  a  look  at  that. 

[The  reference  is  to  the  testimony  of  Dr.  William  A.  Jordan  before 
this  subcommittee  on  February  l4,  1975,  p.  452  ff..  above.  In  re- 
sponse to  the  chairman's  request,  James  L.  Mitchell,  vice  president  of 
regulatory  proceedings.  Continental  Airlines,  submitted  comments  on 
Dr.  Jordan's  testimony.  Dr.  Jordan  then  replied,  and  Continental  com- 
mented on  his  reply.  These  documents  are  printed  after  the  prepared 
statement  of  Harvey  Wexler,  p.  587  ff.,  below.] 

Mr.  Wexler.  I  think  the  point  is,  INIr.  Chairman,  California  today, 
unlike  pre-1965,  does  have  free  regulated  entry. 

Senator  Kicnnedy.  One  of  the  points  Mr.  Jordan  made  was  a  pre- 
diction that  free  entr\'  would  cause  a  large  expansion  in  the  number 
of  airlines.  He  estimated  perhaps  many  new  airlines  while  others 
tliink  an  open  entry  policy  would  lead  to  onh'  a  small  number  of  air- 
lines. I  wonder  if  you  might  be  able  to  elaborate  on  your  thinking 
on  that  issue. 

Mr.  Wexler.  Well,  we  believe  that  under  a  system,  total  free  entry, 
that  you  Avould  end  up  with  a  handful,  maybe  2  or  3  huge  giant  car- 
riers, they  would  end  up  being  high-cost  operators.  We  believe  there 
would  be  a  limited  amount  of  service.  We  believe  that  there  is  quite  apt 
to  be  predatory  practices,  and  we  think  it  would  be  in  violation  of 
everything  that  the  Congress  intended  insofar  as  the  U.S.  air  trans- 
portation system. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  weight  do  you  give  to  the  threat  of  monop- 
oly prices  in  a  system  with  open  entry?  Isn't  it  possible  that  other 
firms  would  come  into  the  market  and  charge  lower  prices  ? 

Mr.  Wexler.  Well,  sir,  I  think  that  today  the  operation  of  large 
jets  it  requires  a  great  deal  of  capital  and  the  air  transportation  sys- 
tem, particularly  in  the  trunkline  markets,  as  a  capital  intensive  in- 
dustry, and  under  the  classical  theory  of  their  high  profitability  there 
would  be  new  grants,  and  that  simply  hasn't  worked.  It  hasn't  worked 
in  other  industries.  There  has  been  a  corrolation  not  only  in  the  United 
States  but  abroad  that  capital  intensive  industries,  over  the  years 


550 

there  gets  to  be  a  greater  and  greater  degree  of  concentration,  and  I 
see  no  reason  why  it  wouldn't  happen  in  air  transportation. 

Senator  Kennedy.  There  have  been  some  examples  of  airlines, 
Southwest  in  Texas,  for  example,  which  started  out  several  years  ago 
without  CAB  protection,  and  they  were  able  to  get  100-percent  financ- 
ing on  their  jets,  and  began  to  compete  with  CAB  carriers  and  made 
good  profits.  As  I  understand  it,  the  supplemental  carriers,  too,  have 
been  able  to  buy  big  jets  with  no  route  security. 

I  am  just  wondering,  in  your  own  thinking,  how  you  would  respond 
to  their  presence  ? 

Mr.  Wexler.  I  think  there  are  two  aspects,  Mr.  Chairman.  One  is  I 
am  not  necessarily  referring  to  route  security,  but  certificate  security. 
In  the  case  of  Southwest  Airlines,  like  PSA,  like  California,  they  do 
have  certificate  security. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Did  they  when  they  started  ?  That  is  the  point ; 
isn't  it?  You  said  a  new  airline  would  have  trouble  getting  capital, 
but  PSA  was  able  to  raise  capital  when  it  began  operations,  without 
a  certificate. 

Mr.  Wexler.  Admittedly  at  that  time  the  market  was  not  as  capital 
intensive.  As  I  mentioned  earlier,  in  California 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let's  take  the  example  I  have  given  here.  I  have 
just  responded  to  your  point  that  there  Avould  only  be  a  small  number 
of  airlines  because  of  the  capital  intensiveness.  I  gave  you  the  example 
of  an  airline  that  didn't  have  any  secure  route  structure  and  was  still 
able  to  get  100-percent  financing.  I  am  Avondering  whether  this  is  a 
peculiar  set  of  circumstances  or  whether  it  begins  to  refute  your 
argument. 

Mr.  Wexler.  I  am  not  intimately  familiar,  Mr.  Chairman  with  the 
Texas  situation. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  fair  enough.  If  you  could  just  take  a 
look  though,  at  the  Jordan  testimony  and  give  us  your  reactions,  it 
would  be  very  helpful,  because  he  has  obviously  given  a  great  deal  of 
thought  to  this. 

Just  returning  to  the  CAB  staff  study  on  the  domestic  routes,  doesn't 
it  set  out  criteria  specifically  directed  at  pi'eventing  new  low  cost,  more 
efficient  competitive  service,  rather  than  promoting  it? 

Mr.  Wexler.  That  is  entirely  correct,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Senator  Kennedy.  All  right.  Thank  you. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  ]Mr.  Wexler  is  printed  at  the  end  of  the 
oral  testimony  of  the  airline  panel,  pp.  580-87.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  Our  next  witness  is  Mr.  EdAvin  Colodny  of 
Allegheny  Airlines.  Mr.  Colodny  joined  Allegheny  Airlines  in  1957 
and  is  now  executive  vice  president  of  marketing  and  les^al  affairs. 
Previously,  he  was  a  trial  attorney  for  the  CAB  and  the  GSA. 

We  liave  revicAved  your  statement,  Mr.  Colodny,  and  the  full  text 
Avill  be  made  part  of  the  record.  I  Avant  to  thank  you  for  talcing  the 
time  to  prepare  it.  I  Avonder  if  you  could  briefly  summarize  the  major 
points  in  your  prepared  statement,  including  the  part  dealing  Avith  the 
groAvth  of  Allegheny  under  Federal  regulation,  the  point  you  make 
about  freedom  of  entry  and  exempt  commuter  carriers,  and  your  recent 
experience  with  route  applications  filed  by  Allegheny  before  the  CAB. 

All  of  the  testimony  this  morning  Avill  be  made  a  part  of  the  record 
and  Ave  Avant  to  thank  you  for  preparing  it. 


551 

Mr,  CoLODNY.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman. 

We  are  pleased  to  be  inchided  in  the  list  of  companies  invited  to 
participate  in  these  vital  hearings  concerning  the  f  nture  course  of  regu- 
lation in  the  U.S.  domestic  air  transport  industry. 

I  will  summarize  as  best  I  can  what  I  have  set  forth  in  the  prepared 
statement,  first  emphasizing  that  we  support  the  continuation  of  the 
Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  which  we  think  by  and  large  has  been 
a  success.  We  think  so  because  of  the  ability  to  move  by  scheduled 
air  carrier  on  a  convenient  basis  throughout  the  United  States  as  being 
the  primary  objective  of  the  statute. 

The  safety  record  of  this  industry  is  also  remarkable  and  will  un- 
doubtedly continue  to  improve. 

DESCRIPTIOX    OF    ALLEGHEXY    AIRLINES 

As  for  Allegheny  itself,  our  growth  has  produced  a  unique  airline. 
Ten  years  ago  we  carried  IV2  million  passengers,  and  today  we  are 
the  largest  of  the  regional  carriers,  serving  about  11  million  passengers 
a  year.  With  our  tremendous  growth  in  assets  during  that  period, 
paying  no  cash  dividends  except  in  2  years,  but  achieving  a  milestone 
in  1974:  by  receiving  no  Federal  subsidy. 

Our  record  has  been  due  to  three  primary  sections  in  the  statute. 
First,  route  grants.  Second,  mergers  with  two  other  carriers.  Lake 
Central  and  Mohawk.  And  third,  the  approval  of  the  Allegheny  com- 
muter agreements  which  the  CAB  has  permitted  Allegheny  to  use  to 
suspend  service  at  loss  points  in  favor  of  independent  commuter 
operators. 

We  provide  a  lot  of  service  from  the  Mississippi  River  to  the  east 
coast. 

Prior  to  1965  the  CAB  had  not  permitted  the  local  service  carriers 
to  serve  the  short-  and  medium-haul  service  markets,  but  in  that  year 
it  shifted  its  policy  to  permit  this.  We  were  a  vigorous  applicant  in 
several  cases. 

We  haA'e  concentrated  our  jet  fleet  on  one  100  passenger,  twin-engine 
DC-9/30  aircraft  in  single  configurations  at  coach  fare  level.  We 
emphasize  convenient  service  with  necessary  amenities.  However,  no 
first-class  compartments  and  no  free  liquor. 

We  are  a  strong  competitor  against  carriers  such  as  United,  TWA, 
American,  and  Delta,  offering  a  wide  range  of  discount  fares. 

At  the  same  time  we  were  developing  as  a  major  competitor  in  the 
short-haul  markets,  we  started  the  commuter  in  1967  in  Hagerstown, 
Md.  This  was  a  very  successful  program  which  is  well  known  in  the 
aviation  community.  Twenty-seven  cities  now  receive  service  from  12 
independent  air  carriers  under  contract  to  Allegheny.  They  generated 
over  a  million  passengers  last  year,  primarily  to  and  from  smaller  cities 
which  previously  would  only  generate  few  passengers  with  limited 
frequency  and  heavy  subsidy. 

By  and  large  these  were  the  kind  of  communities  receiving  limited 
benefit  from  a  policy  of  free  entry  which  already  exists. 

RESULTS    OF   FREE   ENTRY 

We  appreciate  the  concern  of  the  subcommittee  as  well  as  the  con- 
cern of  some  persons  both  within  and  outside  of  the  government  that 


552 

our  regulatory  schemes  by  restricting  freedom  of  entry  or  exit,  has  led 
to  higher-cost  air  service  than  need  be  paid  by  the  traveling  public. 
In  my  opinion  freedom  of  entry  would  do  nothing  to  reduce  the  price 
of  air  travel  at  the  small  and  intermediate  cities  in  this  country.  The 
public  interest  in  the  small  cities  is  less  likely  to  be  related  to  the  price 
of  air  transportation  as  it  is  to  the  availability. 

As  the  Senator  and  the  subcommittee  are  well  aware  of  the  problem 
in  New  England,  which  was  recently  concluded  by  the  award  of  a  cer- 
tificate to  Air  New  England  where  they  were  not  trying  to  get  cheaper 
but  adequate  air  travel.  Had  freedom  of  entrj^  been  a  success  in  north- 
ern New  England,  it  would  not  have  been  necessary  for  CAB  to  cer- 
tificate Air  New  England. 

I  have  speculated  as  to  what  might  have  been  Allegheny's  policy 
toward  small  loss  points  had  we  had  freedom  to  exist  without  CAB's 
approval. 

It  is  questionable  whether  the  Allegheny  commuter  concept  would 
have  been  created  and  most  of  these  27  points  would  have  simply  dis- 
appeared from  the  scheduled  airline  map. 

What  about  larger  communities  and  city-pairs  generating  large 
traffic  pools.  The  CAB  study  which  was  recently  released  has  a  good 
deal  of  important  information  in  it.  Allegheny's  system  is  as  shown 
in  exhibit  1.  Fifty  percent  of  our  total  passengers  enplane  and  deplane 
on  just  39  pairs  of  points,  that  is  11  percent  of  the  total  of  369  pairs 
of  points  which  we  serve  on  a  single  plane  basis. 

Now,  a  lot  of  these  larger  markets  that  we  serve  act  as  a  conduit  for 
service  between  many  pairs  of  points.  For  example,  our  Chicago- 
Pittsburgh  services  also  serve  Chicago  to  points  such  as  Wilkes-Barre, 
Scranton,  and  Allentown,  Pa.,  and  our  flights  over  the  Philadelphia- 
Pittsburgh  segment  also  serve  cities  such  as  Albany,  Hartford,  Provi- 
dence to  the  oast  and  Erie,  Columbus,  Dayton,  Louisville,  and  Indian- 
apolis to  the  west. 

In  scheduling  our  system  we  evaluate  the  flight  as  a  whole  for  profit- 
ability, since  the  traffic  flows  are  made  up  of  a  series  of  individual 
markets  and  we  have  set  forth  in  our  statement  how  that  is  broken 
down. 

An  example  of  the  Philadelphia-Pittsburgh  segment  would  show,  if 
restrictions  were  eliminated  on  entry,  this  segment  could  be  attractive 
to  a  person  investing  in  a  small  fleet  of  jet  aircraft,  perhaps  two  or 
three  units  to  get  into  business,  slash  the  price  and  attempt  to  drive 
Allegheny  and  TWA  out.  We  would  have  to  have  to  choose  between 
meeting  the  competition  by  a  combination  of  price  or  service  adjust- 
ments. 

We  think  that  anything  that  destroys  the  system  that  we  have  in 
order  to  benefit  a  few  markets  should  be  very,  very  cautiously 
approached. 

It  is  conceivable  that  a  few  large  concentrations  of  traffic  would 
benefit  by  freedom  of  ent^^^  I  have  no  doubt  that  Los  Angeles  and 
San  Francisco  to  New  York  or  some  of  the  Chicago  markets  might 
benefit.  But  before  you  consider  going  this  route  T  would  suggest  very 
strongly  that  you  would  have  to  consider  as  concomitant  a  breakup  of 
largo  carriers  such  as  United,  TWA.  and  American  before  you  could 
ever  logically  proceed  to  freedom  of  entry.  The  predatory  nature  of 


553 

our  industry  is  such  that  we  will  eat  our  young,  we  will  go  after  other 
carriers'  markets,  if  given  a  chance. 

We  should  ask  ourselves  what  the  domino  effect  would  be.  Carriers 
forced  to  withdraw  from  their  markets  would  look  for  other  places  to 
fly  the  aircraft  in  which  we  have  invested.  There  is  no  easy  answer  to 
this  Pandora's  box.  We  also  urge  that  you  take  a  good  look  at  a  major 
reason  for  the  increased  demand  for  low-cost  air  service,  the  loss  of 
youth  and  family  plan  fares.  I  think  if  this  is  approached  by  reinstitut- 
ing  these  two  fare  programs  we  will  go  a  long  way  toward  meeting  the 
public  need  for  low-cost  service. 

A  major  burden  is  also  being  imposed  by  the  cost  of  fuel,  which  in 
Allegheny's  case  is  110  i)ercent  higher  in  1975  than  in  1973.  We  also 
urge  that  you  look  at  the  cost  of  operating  the  ground  portion  of  the 
air  transport  system,  noise  and  environmental  costs,  which  are  all 
passed  on  to  the  user. 

But  so  much  for  those  things  which  you  should  look  at.  Obviously 
there  are  things  which  we  as  airlines  must  do  to  control  the  cost  of  our 
business.  We  must  reexamine  the  technological  side  of  our  business  to 
avoid  premature  obsolescence.  AVhile  unit  cost  improvement  which 
came  about  through  jet  development,  and  which  obviously  has  been  a 
tremendous  boon  to  the  country,  future  development  must  proceed  on 
the  theory  of  improving  the  productivity  of  the  aircraft  in  that  neces- 
sarily increasing  the  size  of  the  machine.  If  the  Congress  adopts  a  pro- 
gram which  permits  freedom  of  entry,  the  airlines  would  be  faced 
with  the  impairment  of  the  stability  of  their  investment  capital  and  the 
ability  to  raise  long-term  funds. 

In  the  case  of  Allegheny,  our  interest  expense  last  year  was  $12  mil- 
lion on  our  funded  debt. 

In  summary,  we  do  not  believe  freedom  of  entry  is  really  the  issue. 
There  are  numerous  certificated  airlines  available  to  do  the  job,  pai:- 
ticularly  the  local  service  airlines  and  smaller  trunks.  We  are  willing 
to  invest  money  and  expand  service  at  reasonable  prices.  Since  the  late 
sixties  the  CAB  has  in  effect  created  eight  regional  trunklines  who  ef- 
fectively compete  in  many  markets  with  the  larger  carrier.  AVhile  we 
urge  the  Congress  not  to  disturb  the  sections  of  the  act  dealing  with 
route  entry  and  exit,  there  are  some  things  which  do  need  attention  and 
in  which  congressional  interest  can  be  beneficial.  One  is  the  vexing 
problem  of  route  moratorium  which  the  CAB  imposed  by  indirection 
in  1970  and  1971.  The  downturn  in  the  economy  which  occurred  at  that 
time  was  properly  recognized  by  the  CAB  as  requiring  a  slowdown  in 
the  new  route  authority. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Could  you  summarize  these  last  witnesses' 
points  ? 

Mr.  CoLODXY.  In  the  case  of  the  comments  made  by  Mr.  Rasenberger 
and  Mr.  Wexler,  we  generally  think  that  the  Board  can  correct  the 
situation  without  a  change  in  statute  simply  by  moving  forward  with 
setting  cases  for  hearing,  and  particularly  cases  involving  monopoly 
markets  where  trunklines  sit  on  dormant  grandfather  rights  and  do 
not  provide  scheduled  service. 

Thank  you  very  much,  Mr.  Chairman. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  not  really  the  thrust  of  your  testimony  that 
you  have  some  real  concerns  about  additional  competition  coming  into 
local  service  carriers'  markets  under  an  open  entry  policy,  because  of  a 


554 

threat  of  predatory  practices,  and  the  other  reasons  yon  mention  ?  It 
seems  yonr  profits  having  gone  up  pretty  well,  rising  from  $26  million 
to  $366  million. 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  Obviously,  Senator,  we  are  concerned  about  our  com- 
pany on  a  self-interest  basis  first.  As  I  point  out,  the  domino  effect  of 
creating  open  entry,  taking  for  example  United  Air  Lines  with  a  very 
large  fleet  of  two  and  three  engine  aircraft  which  are  quite  suitable 
for  serving  many  of  the  Allegheny  markets,  there  is  no  way  of  predict- 
ing what  would  happen  under  a  free  entry  system  such  as  Professor 
Jordan  suggests  with  100  or  200  airlines  each  serving  a  small  segment 
of  the  Industrie's  requirements.  We  do  not  know  what  the  impact  would 
be,  but  it  is  true,  we  are  concerned  with  our  own  system,  and  we  do  not 
see  open  entry  as  giving  us  an  opportunity  to  make  it  up  by  operating 
profitably  in  somebody  else's  markets. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Of  course  entry  may  be  a  threat  to  the  profits 
of  your  airline.  The  question  is.  What  does  free  entry  mean  to  the 
public  as  well,  in  terms  of  accessibility  to  air  travel  and  cost  ? 

Quite  frankly,  I  am  troubled  by  some  of  the  words  that  we  hear 
during  the  course  of  these  hearings.  On  the  one  hand,  people  in  the 
industry — and  I  am  not  directing  this  comment  specifically  at  your 
testimony,  but  just  as  an  observation  generally,  having  listened  to  the 
testimony  for  a  few  days — speak  of  the  problems  with  a  policy  of  open 
entry  and  freer  competition,  the  dangers  of  predatory  price  competi- 
tion and  chiseling.  On  the  other  hand  we  hear  the  same  policies  de- 
scribed as  encouraging  healthy  price  competition.  It  almost  seems  as  if 
it  were  a  question  of  whose  ox  is  getting  gored.  On  one  hand  free  entry 
is  portrayed  as  the  free  enterprise  systeui,  and  on  the  other  hand  it  is 
a  scurrilous  group  of  fly-by-night  operators  and  chiselers  getting  into 
the  market. 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  It  does  sound  as  if  we  talk  out  of  both  sides  of  our 
mouth,  and  sometimes  we  do. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Perhaps  that  is  true  on  this  side  of  the  table  as 
well. 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  The  fact  of  the  matter  is  that  the  philosophy  as  we  see 
it  has  been  one  of  building  a  system,  not  a  series  of  individual  fiefdoms, 
but  a  system  of  domestic  air  travel.  It  is  the  same  way — we  built  a  sys- 
tem in  other  fields  in  this  country  through  our  taxation,  social  security 
taxes  and  what  not.  Of  certain  peo})lc  paying  for  benefits  of  other 
people.  It  is  no  different  in  air  travel.  Tliere  is  a  public  interest  in 
having  tliis  system. 

Now,  there  has  been  open  entry  in  the  automotive  manufacturing 
business  for  a  good  number  of  years,  and  yet  there  are  only  three  large 
companies  dominating  that  whole  deal. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  do  not  think  General  Motors  sets  the  price 
for  all  the  others  ? 

Mr.  Colodny,  I  probably  over  stated  it,  it  may  be  only  one  manu- 
facturer dominating  the  scene,  but  I  am  frankly  not  close  enough  to 
know.  But  we  do  have  a  public  interest  in  having  demographic  dis- 
tribution of  our  population.  We  do  have  a  public  interest  in  seeing 
that  smaller  cities  can  survive.  We  do  have  an  interest  in  seeing  some 
decentralization  from  our  larger  urban  centers,  and  all  of  these  things 
are  part  of  Avhat  is  involved  in  maintaining  this  system  of  air  trans- 
port. Admittedly,  it  may  not  be  the  cheapest,  but  in  terms  of  value  I 
think  we  deliver  a  very  fine  product. 


555 

CROSS   SUBSIDY    (SMALL-TOWN    SERVICE) 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  cross-subsidy  does  occur,  I  think  the  public 
is  entitled  to  know,  in  terms  of  this  cross-subsidization,  what  they  are 
paying  for.  ^Ye  have  been  flying  back  and  forth,  up  to  Boston  and  on 
other  routes,  and  now  we  find  out  we  may  have  been  paying  extra 
high  prices  in  order  to  subsidize  Peoria,  and  yet  we  cannot  find  out 
for  certain.  We  ask  the  airlines  and  they  respond  that  it  is  too  complex, 
they  cannot  provide  specific  examples.  I  do  not  understand  why  the 
airlines  cannot  tell  me  exactly  what  we  are  paying  for,  what  we  are 
subsidizing  on  particular  routes.  Why  should  not  that  be  right  out  in 
the  open  rather  than  hidden  away  in  the  fare  structure?  And  if  it 
can't  be  identified,  then  perhaps  there  is  no  cross-subsidy. 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  I  think  it  is  out  in  the  open  first  in  two  respects.  First, 
the  two  phase  9  fare  structure  decision  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board 
lays  it  out  very  clearly  that  the  fares  will  be  based  on  cost  and  not 
on  any  other  factor. 

Senator  Kennedy.  If  fares  are  cost-based,  there  is  no  cross-subsidy. 
Is  there  cross-subsidization  ? 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  Absolutely. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Phase  9  is  against  that.  Is  that  correct  ? 

Mr.  Colodny.  No,  I  think  the  cross  subsidization  occurs  not  in  terms 
of  yield  per  mile  but  in  terms  of  traffic  density. 

In  the  case  of  Allegheny,  we  provide  services  both  to  the  cities 
which  are  classified  as  subsidy  eligible  and  cities  which  are  subsidy 
ineligible,  market  pairs,  such  as  Chicago-Pittsburgh  have  no  subsidy, 
Binghamton  to  Boston  is.  We  can  provide,  and  all  the  local  carriers 
do  provide  a  breakout  of  the  cost  of  their  subsidy  eligible  services 
to  the  CAB  every  6  months,  and  that  breakout  shows  the  deficit  at 
the  operating  level  or  at  the  net  level  of  operating  all  these  loss 
operations. 

The  other  side  of  the  equation  is  a  compilation  of  the  profits,  if  any, 
of  the  subsidy  ineligible  services,  and  those  profits  are  being  used  by  the 
CAB  to  directly  reduce  subsidy.  They  are  not  being  used  however,  to 
reduce  the  cost  of  air  travel.  In  the  case  of  local  airlines,  it  is  the  Fed- 
eral Government  who  takes  the  cream  off  the  top,  so  to  speak,  not  the 
public. 

Now,  in  the  case  of  the  larger  trunklines,  I  would  rather  let  United 
speak  for  itself,  but  I  am  absolutely  sure  they  have  the  same  process 
going  on  in  their  system,  and  our  cost  allocation  methodology  in  the 
industry  is  not  entirely  perfect,  but  We  do  have  a  pretty  good  idea  of 
the  level  of  profitability  of  a  given  market,  and  that  can  be  provided 
to  the  subcommmittee. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  have  heard  that  the  California  airlines  serve 
smaller  communities  at  low  fares  without  subsidy.  We  have  had  testi- 
mony to  that  effect. 

Mr.  Colodny.  I  frankly  am  not  familiar  with  the  California  situa- 
tion, Senator.  I  skimmed  Professor  Jordan's  comments  over  the  week- 
end, and  frankly  I  was  unable  to  tell  whether  that  situation  was 
really  comparable  to  that  situation  that  we  know. 

We  have  some  unique  problems 

_  Senator  Kennedy.  We  are  troubled  because  the  DOT  and  the  Coun- 
cil of  Economic  Advisers  indicate  to  us  that  there  is  very  little  cross- 


556 

subsidy.  That  is  what  they  tell  us,  and  then  we  hear  from  the  airlines 
that  there  is  cross-subsidy,  and  that  is  why  we  brina  these  kind  of 
questions  up. 

I  would  be  interested  if  any  of  the  others  want  to  make  a  comment. 
It  seems  the  public  has  frequent  service  with  the  existing  network  of 
interrelated  airline  services.  We  get  a  high,  perhaps  excessive,  fre- 
quency of  flights  and  a  lot  of  service  on  those  flights,  but  the  public 
has  no  alternative  of  less  frequent  flights  and  less  service  on  the 
flights,  at  lower  fares.  That  alternative  is  not  available  to  the  Ameri- 
can public.  That  is  an  observation  I  have  made  from  the  hearing  both 
this  morning  and  the  other  day. 

Let  me  ask  you  if  you  believe  consumers  should  have  that  alternative 
available  to  them  ? 

Mr.  CoLODNY.  May  I  just  make  one  comment.  Senator.  The  problem 
most  markets  have  is  a  lack  of  traffic  density  to  warrant  cutrate  prices, 
because  even  if  you  cut  tlie  prices  low  enough  there  are  not  enough 
people  interested  in  flying  at  any  price  between  some  markets  in  this 
country. 

Now,  between  Boston  and  Washington,  Allegheny  entered  that 
market — we  hold  a  certificate  for  nonstop — we  entered  that  market  a 
year  and  a  half  ago  and  thought  we  would  take  a  whack  at  Eastern, 
Delta  and  American.  We  put  in  5  round  trips  a  day  and  we  lost  a  good 
deal  of  money.  Unfortunately  the  one  thing  we  did  not  compete  with 
was  price.  I  have  no  doubt  we  could  have  competed  with  price  and  had 
a  temporary  advantage,  but  as  has  been  pointed  out,  our  fares  would 
have  been  matched  and  ultimately  we  would  have  had  a  problem 
staying  in  the  market,  though  I  have  a  feeling  that  we  will  be  back  in 
tliere  some  day  soon,  and  perhaps  with  some  new  experimentation 
that  the  subcommittee  will  be  interested  in. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Colodny  is  printed  at  the  end  of  the 
oral  testimony  of  the  airplane  panel,  pp.  620-29.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will,  and  the  public  might  have  had  cheaper 
transportation  as  a  result  if  you  had  gone  in  there,  at  a  lower  price. 

Mr.  DE  VouRSNEY.  I  havc  some  data  on  cross-subsidy.  United  Air 
Lines  in  1974  operated  at  698  one-way  city-pair  segments,  with  one  or 
more  schedules,  generally  more.  In  1974,  which  was  a  year  of  resumed 
profitability  for  us,  we  had  21  percent  of  those  segments  or  145  with 
revenues  below  variable  cost.  In  other  words,  we  were  not  recovering 
our  direct  labor,  landing  fees,  fuel,  and  oil.  Fifty-five  percent  of  those 
segments,  or  385  out  of  the  698  did  not  produce  a  profit  before  Federal 
income  tax. 

[These  figures  were  later  revised  by  United  Air  Lines  in  letters  to 
the  subcommittee  dated  February  28,  1975  and  April  29,  1975.  These 
letters  are  printed  following  Mr.  de  Voursney's  prepared  statement, 
pp.  635-37,  below.] 

Now,  there  is  the  best  measure  I  can  give  you  of  the  extent  of  cross- 
subsidization.  These  segments  include — I  have  numerous  examples. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  this  typical  of  recent  years  ? 

Mr.  DE  VouRSNEY.  I  think  if  you  go  back  into  1970,  obviously  the 
percentage  will  be  even  greater,  Jbut  1974  probably  is  a  very  good  year 
for  this  purpose.  On  a  single  month  basis  this  varies,  but  this  is  for 
the  year  as  a  whole.  I  have  numerous  examples. 


557 

Senator  Kennedy,  I  do  not  want  to  take  the  time  now,  but  if  you 
could  provide  these  figures  v\e  would  take  a  look  at  it.  It  would 
be  very  helpful.  Mr.  de  Voursney,  I  know  you  are  interested  in  dano;ers 
to  the  airline  industry,  and  I  want  to  thank  you  for  your  statement 
and  your  views  on  how  that  would  effect  small  communities,  and  your 
views  on  the  route  freeze  and  how  the  CAB  policy  serves  the  public 
interest. 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  In  a  year  such  as  1974,  with  55  percent  of  those 
route  segments  not  earnino-  a  pretax  profit,  you  can  easily  see  that  if 
our  total  profitability  is  impaired  as  a  result  of  free  entry  we  will  have 
to  look  long  and  hard  as  to  whether  we  can  continue  these  services, 
whether  they  be  the  21-percent  which  does  not  meet  variable  cost  or  the 
55  percent  which  does  not  earn  a  pretax  profit.  I  think  there  is  a  real 
danger  that  in  a  situation  of  adversity,  which  I  believe  free  entry 
w^ould  bring  on  that  the  odds  are  that  these  services  would  be  sub- 
stantially curtailed. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  those  21  percent  of  communities  or 

Mr,  de  Voursney.  Twenty-one  percent  of  the  segments  over  which 
we  fly,  a  segment  being  defined  as  Flint,  Michigan  to  Chicago. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  percent  of  those 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  Can  I  amplify  my  comment  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Sure, 

Mr,  DE  Voursney.  I  think  it  is  wrong  to  talk  in  terms  of  loss  cities. 
We  do  not  lose  money  on  the  city.  We  lose  money  flying  in-route  service 
between  cities.  You  can  lose  money  flying  between  New  York  and 
Boston,  and  those,  of  course,  are  two  very  large  traffic  generating 
points. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Well,  that  brings  me  closer  to  my  point.  Of  those 
communities,  what  percent  of  them  have  any  other  air  service? 

Mr.  DE  Vox  RSNEY.  When  you  get  down  to  these  marginal  segments, 
the  alternative  services  are  generally  a  good  deal  less  and  in  some  cases 
nonexistent.  Some  of  these  are  monopoly  points.  Very  few  are  served 
by  more  than  two  carriers.  Here  are  some  examples:  Denver-Grand 
Junction,  Detroit-Baltimore,  Fort  Wayne-Xew  York,  Omaha-Des 
Moines,  Baltimore-Buffalo,  Jacksonville-Atlanta,  Memphis-Char- 
lotte, and  so  on.  There  is  a  long  list. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  abandon  those  if  you  could  ? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney,  No,  we  have  made  no  effort  nor  do  we  plan  to 
abandon  those,  I  think,  however,  we  might  be  forced  out  in  a  situation 
where  our  profits  on  other  routes  were  insufficient  to  pay  the  deficit  of 
servicing  these  segments. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Can  you  give  us  an  idea  of  what  additional  costs 
consumers  are  paying  in  order  to  keep  these  smaller  segments  ?  Every 
time  I  fly,  then,  from  Boston  to  Washington  am  I  paying  for  somebody 
to  go  from  Jacksonville  to  Atlanta  ? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  I  think  our  accounting  system  would  permit  us 
to  make  that  calculation,  yes.  Well,  obviously  we  can  take  the  amount 
which  these  cities  are  below  a  pretax  profit  and  spread  that  over  the 
rest  of  the  system.  That  might  give  an  approximate  number  which 
would  give  you  what  you  want. 

One  thing  I  would  like  to  add  on  this  question  of  cross-subsidy,  you 
know,  airline  passengere  move  around  the  country  rather  generally 
and  a  man  wdio  is  subsidized  on  one  segment  may  well  be  helping  pay 


558 

for  his  own  subsidy.  We  are  customers  of  a  system,  not  tied  to  a  single 
route,  either  cross-subsidized  or  not. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  may  fly  from  Boston  to  Washington  20  or  30 
times  a  year,  but  then  wlien  I  fly  from  Boston  to  Binghampton  I  will 
get  a  little  back? 

Mr.  DE  VouRSNEY.  Yes,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  do  you  not  go  ahead  with  your  testimony. 

Mr.  DE  VouRSNEY.  Ycs,  sir.  For  almost  50  years  my  company  has 
grown  in  partnership  with  Government,  and  for  about  40  years  of  that 
time  under  regulation  of  the  CAB.  The  U.S.  airline  industry  has  be- 
come an  acknowledged  world  leader  in  safety,  in  service,  in  technol- 
ogy, and  in  efficiency,  and  I  might  say  in  fares  below  those  charged 
in  other  parts  of  the  world. 

We  have  improvements  that  can  and  should  be  made.  In  reviewing 
the  testimony  in  this  proceeding  and  in  earlier  writings  the  critics  of 
our  regulatory  system  generally  do  not  allege  that  economic  regula- 
tion of  the  airlines  has  produced  inadequate  or  inefficient  air  trans- 
portation; rather,  they  claim  it  would  be  even  better  were  their  vari- 
ous proposals  adopted. 

I  believe  that  the  task  of  evaluating  how  much  better  relief  we  could 
have  under  deregulation  is  a  formidable  one.  There  are  many  uncer- 
tainties. There  is  a  reasonable  case  that  hasty  judgments  or  actions  to 
discard  what  we  know  have  collated  to  deterioration  rather  than  im- 
provement and  the  impact  of  that  deterioration,  both  on  those  whose 
livelihood  depends  on  the  health  of  the  system  and  upon  the  Nation's 
economy  could  be  very  great.  That  is  why  we  welcome  a  thorough 
examination  of  these  issues  to  carefully  weigh  the  issues  to  carefully 
weigh  the  values  of  what  we  now  liave  against  the  benefits  of  indi- 
cated change. 

The  opponents  of  regulation  have  testified  before  you.  Virtually  all 
have  called  for  higher  industry  load  factors.  They  decry  scheduling 
as  an  uneconomic  form  of  nonprice  competition.  Some  assert  that  the 
CAB's  55-percent  load  factor  standard  is  too  low  and  that  low-load 
factors  promulgate  fares  which  are  excessive.  Mr.  Peck  made  the  asser- 
tion that  flying  planes  half-empty  is  not  good  economics,  and  I  could 
not  agree  more,  particularly  since  it  produces  disaster  at  the  bottom 
line. 

RESULTS  OF  FREE  ENTRY 

What  does  concern  me,  though,  is  that  in  their  next  breath  most  of 
these  gentlemen  urge  greater  freedom  of  entry,  a  step  by  which  load 
factors  somehow  would  be  forced  upwards  as  new  carriers  enter  tlie 
business  with  more  planes  and  more  schedules  or  as  existing  carriers 
move  into  markets  previously  closed  to  them.  This  logic  completely 
escapes  me.  If  any  development  is  guaranteed  to  drive  down  load  fac- 
tors and  drive  up  related  costs  it  is  the  invasion  of  the  market  by  a 
group  of  new  entrants  using  both  price  and  prime  time  service  fre- 
quency as  competitive  weapons  in  a  fight  for  market  share. 

PROFITS  AND  LOSSES  OF  BIG  FOUR  AIRLINES AIRLINE  ECONOMICS 

I  would  like  to  introduce  into  the  record  a  few  numbers.  Recently 
I  compiled  the  four  largest  carrier's  profits  for  the  last  10  years.  I 
found  some  interesting  things.  These  are  based  on  the  reported  results. 


559 

In  the  aggregate,  over  the  years  for  the  last  10  years,  himped  to- 
gether, TWA's  domestic  system  has  lost  money,  a  pretax  loss.  In  the 
last  8  years,  as  an  aggregate,  Eastern  Airlines  has  lost  money,  a  pretax 
loss.  In  the  last  6  years,  American  Airlines  has  suffered  a  pretax 
loss.  Fortunately,  we — United — have  lost  money  in  only  one.  I  think 
the  pretax  margins  are  interesting.  TWA's  domestic  system  is  six- 
tenths  of  a  cent  deficit.  Eastern,  a  profit  on  the  plus  side  in  the  10-year 
history,  amounted  to  a  profit  of  four-tenths  of  1  cent  out  of  every 
dollar ;  American,  2.2  cents  in  10  years ;  and  we  have  had  a  somewhat 
better  margin,  4.8  cents. 

To  paraphrase  a  speech  Charles  Baker  made  on  ICC,  if  the  regu- 
latory agencies  are  protective  of  those  they  are  designed  to  regulate, 
I  would  hate  to  see  the  plight  of  the  regulated  if  tlie  agencies  ever 
become  hostile. 

An  airline  has  three  primary  ways  to  reduce  costs.  The  first  is  higher 
load  factors,  the  second  is  more  seats  per  airplane,  and  the  third  more 
hours  per  plane  per  day.  These  factors  have  considerable  leverage,  but 
the  cost  benefits  of  each  would  be  much  harder  to  obtain,  in  my  judge- 
ment, under  a  condition  of  deregulation. 

In  looking  at  service  competition  we  should  remember  the  highly 
incremental  nature  of  airline  costs.  About  90  percent  of  the  fare  from 
each  passenger  above  the  break-even  level  goes  directly  to  pretax  profit. 
This  helps  explain  the  service  competition  which  it  promotes  and  the 
tactics  of  airline  marketers.  It  still  will  exist  no  matter  if  deregulation 
will  push  fares  down,  the  attraction  of  getting  that  marginal  passenger 
will  continue. 

Mr.  AVexler  said  something  about  the  industry  being  capital  inten- 
sive, and  I  am  a  good  friend  of  his,  and  I  respect  his  knowledge  of  the 
industry.  This  industry  is  not  capital  intensive,  it  is  labor  intensive. 
About  4-1  percent  of  our  expense  dollar  goes  for  wages  and  benefits. 
You  can  get  into  this  business  with  a  little  side  money  and  some  leasing, 
and  people  have  done  it  that  way. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  does  it  compare,  for  my  information,  to  say 
other  industries :  for  example,  automotive,  steel  ? 

Mr.  DE  VouRSNEY.  There  I  think  you  do  have  a  capital  problem. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  the  labor  cost,  as  a  percent  of  cost  of 
production. 

Mr.  DE  Vouesney.  In  those  industries  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  can  find  out,  but 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  I  do  not  have  the  numbers.  I  will  be  happy  to 
submit  them. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  was  just  wondering  how  the  airlines  compared 
to  other  industries. 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  Freedom  of  entry  is  possible  with  steel  and  rail- 
roads, but  I  have  not  seen  anybod}-  starting  up  new  steel  companies  or 
railroads.  One  other  point,  Mr.  Colodny  talked  about  breaking  up 
United  and  TWA,  et  cetera.  It  is  quite  a  relief  from  being  accused  of 
being  inflexible,  unmanageable  and  inefficient.  Thank  you. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Of  the  communities  that  you  serve  now,  if  there 
wei-e  freer  entry  into  the  market  do  you  think  those  communities  would 
be  denied  any  air  transportation  ? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  I  would  suspect  that  would  depend  on  if  others 
feel  they  could  provide  service  with  a  profit.  We  have  about  10  cities 


560 

which  we  have  made  applications  to  delete  at  one  time  or  another.  I 
would  suspect  we  would  go  back  and  look  at  them  and  possibly  take 
action  on  our  own. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Does  this  include  the  145  communities  that  you 
mentioned  ? 

Mr.  DE  VoTjRSNEY.  I  beg  your  pardon. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  you  mentioned  in  the  earlier  part  of  your 
testimony 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  Those  were  segments,  some  of  which  might  have 
served  the  cities  in  question.  These  were  10  cities  per  se. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  those  segments  be  served,  do  you  think, 
with  open  competition,  or  would  they  not  be  served?  Wliat  is  your 
judgment?  You  have  given  a  lot  of  thought  to  this  whole  problem. 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  Some  would  be  and  others  might  not  be.  We  have 
some  classics  which  I  doubt  would  be  attractive  to  any  one,  in  fact, 
even  at  very  high  prices. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  your  reaction  to  the  fact  that  the  CAB 
has  not  had  hearings  on  various  routes?  Do  you  have  any  kind  of  a 
response  to  points  that  have  been  made,  that  this  is  violating  at  least 
the  spirit  of  the  Aviation  Act  or  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  ? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  I  think  preferably  that  when  policy  matters  of 
that  kind  are  established,  just  as  for  the  new  route  study  proposals, 
that  there  be  public  hearings,  on  the  public  interest  in  imposing  mora- 
toriums, imposing  new  rules  such  as  are  imposed  in  that  study,  I 
think  there  should  be  a  broad  public  inquiry  and  in  a  public  forum. 

Senator  Kennedy.  So  they  should  have  an  opportunity  for  a  hear- 
ing? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  That  is  right. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  do  not  believe  that  if  the  Board  had  a  more 
open-route  entry  policy  that  the  antitrust  laws  would  be  sufficient  in 
terms  of  predatory  price  competition  to  maintain  some  stability  in  the 
market  ? 

Mr.  DE  Voursney.  Senator,  I  believe  we  would  be  substituting  a  sys- 
tem by  litigation.  "WHien  I  think  of  the  restraints  that  would  impose.  I 
do  not  see  how  you  can  run  an  airline  system  in  this  country  and  run  it 
effectively. 

Senator  Kennedy,  Thank  you  very  much. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Andrew  de  Voui-sney  is  printed  at  the 
end  of  the  oral  testimony  of  the  airline  panel,  pp.  629-35.] 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  hear  from  Mr.  Stuart  G.  Tipton,  senior 
vice  president  of  Pan  American  Airways,  and  Mr.  Stanley  Gewirtz, 
Pan  Am's  special  adviser  for  public  policy. 

Mr.  Tipton  has  worked  for  the  CAB.  He  has  been  general  counsel, 
president,  and  chairman  of  the  board  of  the  Air  Transport  Associa- 
tion. 

Mr.  Gewirtz  is  a  lawyer  who  for  the  past  30  years  has  served  with 
many  governmental  agencies  including  the  CAB,  the  Senate  Armed 
Services  Committee,  the  National  Aeronautics  and  Space  Administra- 
tion, and  the  Department  of  Transportation. 

INIr.  Tipton  and  Mr.  Gewirtz  have  supplied  a  very  detailed  state- 
ment that  points  out  the  differences  between  domestic  regulation  and 
regulation  of  international  carriers  like  Pan  Am.  The  statement  argues 


561 

that  repilation  of  entry  and  routes  in  the  international  field  is  radi- 
cally different  than  in  the  domestic  field,  and  that  free  and  liberalized 
entry  cannot  be  applied  as  easily  in  the  international  area.  I  think 
your  points  are  good  ones.  Could  we  go  right  to  questions,  or  are  there 
several  points  in  your  statement  you  wish  to  emphasize  first? 

Mr.  Tipton.  I  will  proceed  briefly,  Mr.  Chairman,  and  cover  a  num- 
ber  of  points,  and  then,  of  course,  be  available  for  any  questions. 

First,  let  me  be  sure  that  our  statement  is  in  the  record.  I  do  not  know 
whether  it  is  or  not. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes ;  it  is.  They  will  all  be  printed  in  the  record, 
and  any  supplemental  information  that  we  w^ant  to  provide  as  a  result 
of  these  questions  will  be  made  a  part  of  the  record,  too. 

DIFFERENOES    BETWEEN    DOMESTIC    AND    INTERNATIONAL    AIRLINE 
INDUSTRIES 

Mr.  TiPTON.  Most  of  our  discussion  up  to  this  point  has  been  re- 
lated to  purely  domestic  problems  that  have  bearing  upon  the  crea- 
tion and  operation  of  our  domestic  system.  We  will  discuss  the  prob- 
lem in  the  international  field  as  it  differs  from  the  domestic.  xVs  such,  it 
has  bearing  not  only  on  the  certification  process  of  the  Civil  Aeronau- 
tics Board,  but  also  on  the  issues  that  have  been  presented  to  the  sub- 
committee concerning  freedom  of  entry  and  exit,  and  the  alterations  in 
the  regulations  of  rates. 

Looking  at  the  international  field,  it  seems  quite  clear  that  it  presents 
a  wholly  different  set  of  problems  as  it  relates  to  the  determination  of 
policy  between  free  entry  and  regulated  competition  as  we  have  it  now. 
I  would  say  flatly  that  we  really  cannot  have  freedom  of  entry  in  the 
international  field,  and  we  really  cannot  have  an  elimination  of  rate 
regulation  in  the  international  field.  The  United  States  and  its  carriers 
must  deal  not  only  with  a  single  entity,  but  with  every  foreign  govem- 
nient  into  which  the  United  States  has  a  carrier  operating.  These 
differences  are  marked  and  fundamental.  Let  me  run  through  them 
rather  quickly. 

First,  as  to  entry  in  the  international  field,  the  entry  is  really  largely 
controlled  by  foreign  governments,  not  by  the  U.S.  Governnient.  The 
United  States  can  determine  it  would  like  to  have  a  carrier  go  some 
place  and  serve  a  particular  market,  but  in  order  to  have  that  actually 
take  place,  the  LTnited  States  has  to  get  the  consent  of  the  foreign 
government  and  get  it  through  bilateral  negotiations.  So  whatever 
might  be  said  as  to  freedom  here,  there  really  is  not  that  freedom. 

As  to  rates,  virtually  the  same  thing  can  be  said.  A  carrier  cannot 
cliarge  any  rate  to  which  a  destination  country  objects.  That  creates 
a  problem  on  a  multilateral  basis.  The  lATA  conferences  of  carriers 
has  been  utilized  for  that  purpose.  As  to  capacity,  the  main  area  in 
our  domestic  air  transport  system  where  you  do  have  a  large  measure 
of  freedom ;  in  the  international  field,  you  have  veiy  little  freedom.  It 
is  regulated  by  international  agreements. 

The  various  governments  carry  those  capacity  agreements  into  effect, 
and  thus  a  carrier  in  that  field  certainly  does  not  have  complete  control 
over  the  capacity  he  operates  on  his  routes. 

Market  environment  is  wholly  different.  In  the  domestic  system, 
carriers  are  unsubsidized  for  the  most  part.  In  the  international  field. 


146  O  -  76  -  pt.  1  -  37 


562 

competition  is  seriously  distorted  by  the  application  of  governmental 
policies  to  the  operation  of  subsidized  foreign-flag  carriers,  and  the 
application  of  their  policies  with  respect  to  balance  of  payments  and 
tourism  and  the  like. 

As  to  the  degree  of  competition  that  has  to  be  operated  over  a  partic- 
ular route  or  within  a  particular  area,  there  tlie  system  is  wholly 
diiferent  than  the  one  we  have  in  the  domestic  field.  The  level  of  com- 
petition relates  largely  to  the  workings  of  bilateral  agreements  and 
international  negotiations,  rather  than  on  a  determination  of  the 
economics  of  competition,  or  no  competition. 

A  quick  example.  We  have  three  domestic  carriers  opejating  between 
New  York  and  Miami,  and  3  million  passengers  move  over  there.  There 
are  10  carriers  from  New  York  to  London  and  it  is  a  million-passenger 
market.  So  that  it  reflects  no  determination  on  an  economic  basis  as  to 
the  amount  of  competition  you  should  have. 

The  level  of  competitive  opportunity  is  an  important  distinction  as 
well.  All  carriers  in  the  United  States  operate  with  an  equal  level  of 
competitive  opportimity.  In  the  international  field  any  carrier  is  sub- 
ject to  the  determinations  of  a  foreign  government,  which  may  well 
produce  discriminations  about  which  the  Congress,  this  last  session 
legislated,  the  level  of  user  charges.  In  this  country  we  have  levels  in 
airports  and  airways  that  are  fixed  first  by  Congress  in  the  case  of  air- 
ports by  negotiation — arm's  length  negotiations  between  the  carriers 
and  the  airports.  In  the  international  field  the  carriers  are  at  the  mercy 
of  whatever  the  Government  may  choose  to  charge  them  for  the  use 
of  airports  and  airways.  That,  also,  our  Congress  dealt  with  in  the  last 
session.  Cost  of  capital  is  a  major  difference.  ^lany  foreign  flag  carriers 
are  financed  by  their  own  governments. 

The  political  and  economic  environment  in  which  we  operate  is 
wholly  different.  Here  sometimes  we  think  the  United  States  is  a  little 
unstable,  but  we  have  to  agree  that  it  is  a  stable  environment  in  which 
to  operate.  Operating  in  foreign  governments,  anything  is  likely  to 
happen,  and  many  times  does. 

So  I  want  to  emphasize  here  these  distinctions  as  they  relate  to  the 
certification  process  the  Board  has  carried  out.  I  have  had  the  feeling 
for  a  long  time  that  the  Board  has  not  given  enough  weight  to  these 
facts,  to  these  differences  and  the  environment  that  an  international 
carrier  meets  as  contrasted  with  a  domestic  one.  As  far  as  the  applica- 
tion of  the  theories  of  the  free  market,  I  do  think  we  have  to  recognize 
in  the  international  field  you  just  cannot  have  it. 

WHY   PAN    AM    DOES    NOT    HA^^E    DOMESTIC    AUTHORITY 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  that  is  a  valid  point  and  one  which  is 
made  very  strenuously  in  your  statement,  with  a  great  deal  of  validity. 

I  have  just  a  couple  of  areas  that  I  Avould  like  to  talk  with  you  about, 
and  also  Mr.  Gewirtz,  and  that  is  why  you  have  not  applied  for  more 
domestic  routes. 

Mr.  Tipton.  I  would  be  glad  to  have  Stan  answer  that  question. 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  Thank  you. 

We  have  in  the  past  applied  for  domestic  routes.  In  fact,  we  have 
had  an  application  pending  now  for  some  years  in  which  we  have  had 
an  affirmative  recommendation  from  the  administrative  law  judge. 


563 

It  involves  the  certification  of  Pan  Am  between  Miami  and  Los  An- 
geles. That  administrative  law  judge's  decision  was  handed  down  in 
the  summer  of  1973,  and  further  action  deferred,  pending  a  request 
by  the  Board  for  an  environmental  protection  study  to  be  submitted 
to  the  Board.  But  oral  argument  has  not  yet  been  scheduled  even 
though  the  environmental  study  has  been  completed. 

In  terms  of  other  domestic  routes,  over  the  years,  Pan  Am  has 
applied  for  them.  I  guess  about  25  years  ago.  at  the  tijne  of  the  do- 
mestic route  case,  it  was  decided  there  would  be  no  mix  as  between 
the  international  operations  of  a  carrier  and  its  domestic.  You  know 
that  this  has  been  honored  in  the  breach  to  the  great  fiscal  instability 
of  Pan  American. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  mean  you  had  that  affirmative  decision  2 
years  ago  ? 

Mr.  (tewtrtz.  The  administrative  law  judge  decided  the  case  favor- 
ably as  to  Pan  American. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  see.  You  still  do  not  have  a  hearing  date  ? 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  Still  do  not  have  an  oral  argument  date  set,  no,  sir. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  think  if  you  had  been  able  to  get  that 
route  and  perliaps  some  others,  that  your  financial  plight  would  have 
been  somewhat  relieved  ? 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  It  would  certainly  have  been  helped.  The  administra- 
tive law  judge's  recommendation  supported  our  contention  that  we 
would  enjoy  about  a  $15  million  annual  profit  on  that  route. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Did  you  apply  for  any  other  routes,  or  just  that 
one? 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  We  have  applied  for  other  routes  in  connection  with 
our  international  operations.  We  have  asked  for  fill-up  rights.  We  op- 
erate between  many  United  States  points,  but  most  of  those  have  long- 
haul  restrictions — for  instance,  we  can  go  from  Xew  York  to  San 
Francisco,  and  we  intend  in  fact  to  put  that  service  back  on  again, 
but  in  order  to  fly  between  New  York  and  San  Francisco,  you  liave 
to  be  destined  for  a  point  west  of  Honolulu.  A  San  Francisco  passenger 
can  be  flown  to  New  York,  and  stopover,  but  he  can  only  be  carried  if 
he  is  destined  for  a  point  east  of  New  York,  and  that  is  London. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  mean  the  planes  fly  out  there  in  any  event, 
but  you  can  only  fill  it  if  people  are  going  west  of  Honolulu  ? 

^Ir.  Gewirtz.  Yes;  west  of  Ho^^ohilu.  We  have  quite  a  number  of 
routes  where  we  have  asked  for  fill-up  rights  which  would  help  tre- 
mendously. There  are  occasions  on  which  even  the  capacity  of  domestic 
carriers  on  some  of  these  routes  is  taxed  and  where  we  would  enjoy 
considerable  help  were  we  to  get  fill-up  rights. 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  plane  is  on  its  way  out  there  anyway. 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  We  burn  fuel  and  pay  at  least  13  cents  more  a  gallon, 
on  a  system  basis,  than  what  is  paid  iDy  the  domestic  lines.  If  we  had 
enjoyed  the  domestic  airline  fuel  price  this  past  year,  I  think  we  would 
have  broken  even  ratlier  than  lost  about  $80  million. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  apply  for  other  domestic  routes  if 
you  could  get  a  hearing? 

Mr.  Gewirtz.  At  this  point,  I  doubt  it.  With  Miami-Los  Angeles 
fill-up  rights,  and  some  additional  LT.S.  gateways  indigenous  to  our 
operation,  we  would  be  well  on  our  way  to  viability  with  some  of  the 
cost  controls  we  have  developed. 


564 


IRANIAN    LOAN   TO   PAN   AM 


Senator  Kennedy.  There  is  another  area  which  there  is  public  inter- 
est in,  and  that  is  the  loan  that  is  bein^  arranged  with  the  Iranian 
Government.  Will  this  give  the  Iranian  Government  control,  or,  some 
say  in  Pan  American's  management  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  No;  it  will  not  give  the  Iranians  control. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Will  it  give  them  a  voice  in  the  management? 

Mr.  Tipton.  They  will  have,  when  this  stock  is  issued,  13-percent  of 
the  common  stock  of  Pan  American.  They  will  have  one  member  on  a 
17-member  board  of  directors.  Now,  there  is  a  very  large  amount  of 
stock  outstanding  other  than  theirs  and  16  other  directors. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  does  the  Board  consider  to  be  presumptive 
of  control,  10  percent  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  Yes,  10  percent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  They  will  get  13  percent  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  Yes.  The  statute  provides  that  for  the  purpose  of  apply- 
ing to  the  Board  for  approval  of  an  acquisition  of  control  that  it  is 
presumed  that  10  percent  equity  ownership  constitutes  control.  That, 
of  course,  is  rebuttable.  We  have  proposed  to  submit  the  agreement 
when  and  if  it  is  negotiated  to  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  for  ap- 
proval, and  we  expect  to  convince  them  that  in  this  instance  that 
amount  of  stock  does  not  constitute  control. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Will  that  agreement  be  made  public  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  Oh,  yes,  it  will  be  made  public. 

Senator  Kennedy.  In  its  entirety  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  Yes,  it  will  be  made  public  in  its  entirety. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  read  over  the  weekend  that  the  administration 
has  approved  it  in  principle.  Is  that  correct  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  That  is  correct.  The  administration  approved  the  agree- 
ment in  principle,  and  thus  freed  us  to  continue  our  negotiations  with 
the  Government  of  Iran. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let  me  ask  you,  does  it  raise  any  questions  in 
your  mind  when  a  major  oil  producing  country  invests  substantially  in 
an  airline  that  may  be  competition  with  other  airlines  ?  Does  this  raise 
any  problems  in  terms  of  any  of  your  competitors  ? 

Mr.  Tipton.  It  does  not,  and  the  reason  it  does  not  is  because  not 
only  our  competitors  but  ourselves  are  so  closely  supervised  by  the 
Government,  almost  everything  we  do  must  have  Government  ap- 
proval of  some  sort,  public  approval,  that  it  would  be  very  difficult  to 
see  how  damage  could  be  done  to  our  competitors  as  a  result  of  this 
Iranian  loan. 

Senator  Kennedy.  OK.  Thank  you  very  much.  I  think  that  is  fine, 
Tery  helpful.  There  are  probably  other  additional  questions  which  I 
would  like  to  get  your  reaction  and  response  to  that  came  up  during 
the  course  of  the  morning,  so  we  would  like  to  get  back  to  you.  I  would 
like  to  thank  you  for  all  the  testimony.  It  was  very,  very  helpful  and 
very  responsive  to  our  areas  of  interest,  and  very  complete.  Your  re- 
sponses have  been,  I  think,  very  informative  in  making  the  record.  I 
want  to  thank  you  very  much. 


565 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Tipton  follows,  pp.  637-46,  below.] 
Prepared  Statement  of  William  A.  Hardenstine 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  greatly  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  present  to  you  the  views 
of  World  Airways  concerning  your  inquiry  into  CAB  practices  and  procedures. 
On  December  20,  1974,  Mr.  Edward  J.  Daly,  president  and  chairman  of  the  board 
of  World  Airways,  submitted  written  comments  to  specific  questions  which  had 
previously  been  presented  to  us.  Mr.  Daly  regrets  at  being  unable  to  be  present 
today  but  has  asked  me  to  supplement  those  views  with  specific  comments  con- 
cerning our  experience  with  respect  to  two  other  aspects  of  CAB  regulation  :  First 
is  the  handling  of  applications  for  new  service,  and  second  is  the  handling  of 
charter  regulations. 

I.  applications  for  new  service 

We  at  World  Airways  fervently  believe  in  the  importance  of  competition  in 
the  development  of  the  best  possible  air  transportation  system.  Supplemental 
carriers  like  World,  and  our  earlier  counterparts  which  were  known  as  irregular 
or  nonscheduled  carries,  have,  since  World  War  II,  performed  a  significant  role 
as  innovators  within  this  industry.  Without  overstating  the  case,  I  believe  it  is 
fair  to  say  we  have  had  a  major  part  in  the  development  of:  (1)  low-cost  coach 
service,  (li)  all-cargo  service,  (3)  charter  operations,  and  (4)  commercial  aug- 
mentation airlift  program  for  the  Department  of  Defense.  While  some  of  these 
innovations  go  back  .some  years,  it  is  our  opinion  that  there  are  still  important 
opportunities  for  improvement  in  air  service  and  that  these  are  most  likely  to 
occur  under  the  stimulus  of  regulated  competition. 

Early  in  19G7  World  made  a  comprehensive  study  of  the  need  for  just  such 
improvements  in  the  major  transcontinental  markets  and  concluded  that  although 
the  existing  jet  coach  fare  was  then  $145.10,  it  could  conduct  profitable  operations 
with  Boeing  747  equipment  at  a  transcontinental  one-way  fare  of  $75.  Its  applica- 
tion for  authority  to  conduct  such  as  operation  was  filed  on  April  26,  19C7  and 
designated  as  docket  18468.  Subsequently,  a  motion  for  expedited  action  was 
filed  which  contained  a  detailed  economic  analysis  of  our  plan,  a  summary  of 
which  I  have  attached  to  my  testimony  as  appendix  A.  There  was  never  any 
Board  action  on  this  motion  and,  in  fact,  the  only  Board  action  ever  taken  with 
respect  to  the  World  proposal  was  in  order  73-11-103  on  November  21,  1973,  when 
World's  proposal  in  docket  18468  was  dismissed  as  stale.  This  was  6^/^  years 
after  it  had  been  filed  ! 

Our  proposal  obviously  involved  intense  competitive  problems  and  we  were 
aware  that  other  facets  of  the  "public  convenience  and  necessity"  would  have  to 
be  balanced  against  what  appeared  to  us  to  be  .significant  advantages  to  the  con- 
sumer and  a  significant  economic  opportunity  for  World.  That  critical  judgment 
was  taken,  however,  in  the  decision  of  the  Board  not  to  consider  the  application 
at  all,  contrary,  in  our  view,  to  the  statutory  requirements  for  expeditious  hear- 
ings. 

We  appreciate  that  not  all  applications  filed  with  the  CAB  can  be  set  down  for 
hearing ;  the  agency  simply  does  not  have  the  resources  to  handle  such  a  work- 
load. But  this  was  a  proposal  of  major  consequence  submitted  by  a  carrier  which 
both:  1)  was  acknowledged  to  be  one  of  the  most  efficient  in  the  airline  in- 
dustry, and  2)  posses.sed  a  substantial  net  worth — in  other  words  we  clearly  had 
the  ability  to  perform.  World  was,  in  the-terms  of  the  statute,  unquestionably 
"fit.  willing  and  able." 

We  were  the  victims  of  a  "route  moratorium"  three  years  before  it  was  evident 
to  others.  At  the  very  least  we  were  entitled  to  know  why  the  Board  was  unwill- 
ing to  consider  our  very  serious  proposal. 

II.  excessive  redtape  in  charter  regulations 

Filing  fees. — Pursuant  to  part  389  of  the  Board's  special  regulations,  the  Board 
imposes  fees  for  special  services,  the  filing  of  documents,  and  the  issuance  of  li- 
censes. When  grouped  by  type  of  activity,  these  fees  provide  an  excellent  index 
of  activity  at  the  CAB  ;  for  a  recent  12-month  period  this  information  is  shown 
in  the  following  tabulation : 


566 

CAB  FILING  FEES  FOR  TWELVE  MONTHS  ENDED  JUNE  30,  1974 


Subject  matter 


Percent  of 

Fees  paid 

total  fees 

$194,  500 

39 

118,415 

24 

57,  500 

12 

25,  500 

23,  375 

23,  080 

11,300 

41,  495 

Tariff  matters 

Charter  matters..- 

Agreements _ _-_ _ 

Scheduled  route  applications _ 

Air  taxi  registrations. 

Mergers  and  acquisitions 

Air  freight  forwarder  applications 

Miscellaneous 

Total 495,165 


For  the  same  12  months,  the  charter  revenues  of  the  U.S.  carriers — scheduled 
and  supplemental  together^ — represented  only  3  percent  of  total  U.S.  carrier 
revenues.  I  suggest  to  you  that  this  discrepancy  represents  over-regulation  of 
the  charter  segment  of  the  industry — perhaps  by  a  factor  of  almost  ten.  The  level 
of  charter  fees  is  a  short-hand  way  of  saying  that  the  current  charter  regula- 
tions at  the  CAB  are  unbelievably  complicated,  time-consuming  and  expensive. 
No  one  seems  to  ask  the  question  as  to  why  it  is  necessary. 

Paperwork. — It  is  diflBcult  to  convey  the  burden  which  the  Board's  regulations 
impose  with  respect  to  some  of  our  charter  operations,  but  the  following  tabula- 
tion is  some  indication  of  the  volume  of  the  filing  requirements  : 

Typical  Travel  Group  Charter  Application  for  a  Single  Flight 
Title  of  Document  Number  of  pages 

Transmittal  letter 1 

TGC  option  agreement 2 

TGC  agreement 7 

Rider  to  surety  bond 2 

Contract  between  organizer  and  participants 15 

Terms  and  conditions  for  TGC  participants 6 

TGC  pleasure-break  application  form 1 

TGC  passenger  name  list 28 

Total 62 

Even  the  above  list  tends  to  understate  the  problem.  The  passenger  name  list, 
for  example,  must:  1)  have  the  passengers  numbered,  2)  alphabetized,  3)  identi- 
fied as  to  whether  they  are  on  the  main  or  standby  list,  4)  identified  as  to 
whether  they  are  departing  or  returning  passengers,  5)  we  must  show  the 
address  and  telephone  number  for  each  person,  and  6)  we  must  also  provide 
verification  of  identity  through  some  document  such  as  passport  or  social  security 
card,  which  in  turn  must  be  specified.  I  have  attached  to  my  testimony  as 
appendix  B  a  copy  of  the  filing  instructions  as  they  appear  in  the  Board's 
regulations  to  add  some  of  the  flavor  of  what  we  at  World  regard  as  over- 
regulation. 

Another  major  burden  of  the  regulation  is  its  lack  of  flexibility.  If  the  above 
flight  were  to  be  modified  in  certain  minor  respects :  if  it  were  to  start  a  day 
earlier  or  return  a  day  earlier;  if  it  were  to  serve  one  additional  city  or  one 
fewer  cities ;  if  a  few  people  were  to  be  added  to  the  passenger  name  list ;  then 
instead  of  a  simple  amendment  to  the  previous  filing,  an  earlier  new  application 
would  have  to  be  presented.  If  these  changes  occurred  suflSciently  in  advance  of 
the  planned  departure  the  only  problem  might  be  the  burden  of  the  additional 
paperwork.  But  if  these  changes  occurred  within  90  days  of  the  flight's  departure, 
perhaps  the  entire  flight  would  have  to  be  cancelled  because  the  advanced  filing  re- 
quirements of  the  regulation  could  not  be  satisfied. 

ni.    RECOMMENDATIONS 

Many  of  our  procedural  problems  have  their  origin  in  the  substantive  fabric 
of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  and  its  implementing  regulation.  As  this  subcommit- 
tee knows,  these  are,  in  part,  now  under  review  by  the  Aviation  Subcommittee 


567 

of  the  Senate  Commerce  Committee,  which  has  been  considering  S.  421.  There  are 
other,  perhaps  less  ambitious,  steps  which  can  be  taken  to  improve  the  situation, 
and  on  belialf  of  World  Airways  I  would  like  to  suggest  one :  the  independence 
of  the  Office  of  Consumer  Affairs  at  the  CAB  must  be  guaranteed  by  Congress, 
and  it  must  be  provided  a  staff  adequate  to  its  responsibilities. 

This  office  was  established  only  last  October,  as  a  kind  of  administrative  om- 
budsman, and  perhaps  as  a  token  acknowledgment  that  the  consumer  should  be 
represented.  But  if  it  is  to  be  anything  more,  for  example,  than  a  clearinghouse 
for  complaints  about  lost  baggage,  it  must  be  strengthened.  We  believe  it  is  es- 
sential for  the  Congress  to  spell  out  what  it  expects  this  office  to  do,  and  then  to 
provide  it  with  both  the  authority  and  the  resources  to  do  its  job. 

Had  such  an  office  existed  in  1967,  it  might  have  pressed  for  a  Board  decision 
as  to  why  a  proposal  to  cut  the  transcontinental  fare  by  almost  50  percent 
should  not  at  least  be  examined  through  an  evidentiary  hearing.  And  today  an 
adequately  staffed  Office  of  Consumer  Affairs  might  make  a  cost/benefit  analysis 
of  the  charter  regulations,  and  press  the  Board  to  explain  why  the  mountain  of 
paperwork  now  required  is  in  the  public  interest. 


Biographical  Notes  on   William   A.   Hardenstine 

Mr.  Hardenstine  w-as  born  on  May  21,  1922  in  Phillipsburg,  New  Jersey.  He 
attended  New^  York  University  and  Dartmouth  College  and  received  a  B.S. 
degree  in  transportation  and  traffic  from  New  York  University.  He  served  in 
the  U.S.  Navy  from  1942  to  1949  and  again  from  1951  to  1957  and  held  the  rank 
of  Lieutenant  Commander.  He  was  awarded  seven  battle  stars  while  in  the  Asian- 
Pacific  theater.  His  past  employment  in  the  transportation  and  aviation  industry 
included  the  positions  of  regional  sales  manager,  assistant  vice  president  of  opera- 
tions, and  vice  president  of  sales  of  Overseas  National  Airways,  Inc.  He  joined 
AVorld  Airway.?  in  1963  as  vice  president  of  sales  and  was  promoted  to  senior 
vice  president  of  sales  in  1970.  He  was  elected  director  of  World  Airways,  Inc.  and 
Worldameriea  Investors  Corp.  in  1971.  He  is  a  member  of :  Rotary  International, 
American  Society  of  Travel  Agents.  Pacific  Area  Travel  Association,  Discover 
America  Travel  Org.,  Smithsonian  Assoc,  National  Indus.  Recreation  Assoc, 
Travel  Council,  Alumni  Assoc,  of  Dartmouth  and  New  York  Universities. 


Appendix  A 

SUMMARY   OF  THE  PROPOSAL   OF   WORLD  AIRWAYS,   INC.   IN   CAB   DOCKET    18468   FOR  A 
TRANSCONTINENTAL    THRIFT    SERVICE 

The  major  California-east  coast  markets  are  not  being  adequately  developed. 
Although  there  are  seven  metropolitan  areas  in  the  State  of  California  of  ap- 
proximately 1  million  persons  or  more,^  nonstop  transcontinental  .service  has 
been  offered  consistently  at  only  two  airports :  Los  Angeles  International  and 
San  Francisco  International.  Both  are  highly  congested.  Three  other  airports 
in  California  (excluding  San  Diego)  serve  populations  of  several  million  each 
and  are  now  capable  of  handling  tran.scQiitinental  nonstop  operations.  Two  of 
these  airports— Ontario  and  Long  Beach — have  no  such  transcontinental  service. 
The  third.  Oakland,  has  token  service.  All  three  points — Ontario,  Long  Beach, 
and  Oakland — have  independently  requested  expedited  action  on  World's 
application.^ 

Development  of  these  transcontinental  markets  has  been  inhibited  by  exces- 
sive fare  levels  as  well  as  by  neglect  of  other  airports.  The  lowest  promotional 
fare  today  is  considerably  higher  than  the  lowest  fare  12  years  ago.  Basic  coach 
fares  have  never  been  higher,  and  have  not  fluctuated  in  5  years. 

The  existing  transcontinental  carriers  have  little  incentive  to  enr'age  in  genuine 
fare  competition  or  to  spread  their  operations  to  other  airports.   Experience 


^  Spp    nn^enriix    i?.    .An   piehth   are^.    San    .Tnsp.   has   a   nopnlatlnn   in   pxeess   of  900.000. 

=  The  citv  of  Oakland  filed  a  Retition  dated  Sept  8.  1967.  In  late  Sentember,  petitions 
were  filed  by  tlie  citv  of  Long  Beach  and  Long  Beach  Chamber  of  Commerce  and  the  city 
o''  On^^ario,  Ontario  Chamber  of  Commerce  and  Friends  of  Ontario  International  Airport 
Association. 


568 

shows  that  service  improvements  under  these  circumstances  will  result  only 
from  the  entry  of  a  new  aggressive  carrier. 

World  is  that  carrier.  It  will  operate  nonstop  service  to  New  York  and  Balti- 
more/Washington from  the  Long  Beach,  Oakland,  and  Ontario  airports.  It  will 
offer  a  single-class  service  with  more  spacious  seating  than  available  to  the 
coach  passenger  today.  And  it  will  offer  a  fare  of  $79  with  B-707  equipment. 
With  the  delivery  of  World's  B-747's  the  fare  will  be  reduced  to  $75.  These  fares 
will  accomplish  an  average  reduction  of  approximately  50  percent  in  the  cost  to 
the  public  for  basic  transcontinental  coach  service.  Unlike  current  promotional 
tariffs,  the  proposed  fares  will  be  available  to  everyone,  everyday.  Combined 
with  the  service  at  new  airports  and  with  other  promotional  activities  envisioned 
by  World,  the  low  fares  will  produce  a  radical  increase  in  the  use  of  trans- 
continental air  service,  particularly  for  pleasure  travel. 


WORLD    AIRWAYS.   INC 


570 


EGTIi':,\TZD  0?E?/Tira  RE-ULTS 


1st  Y!\\R   OrZR-TION 


Traffic  Statistics 

Passensors  5^7,826 

Revenue  Pacsen^or  Mil'DS  (OOO)  1,3^+8,092 

Passenger  Ton  Miles  (OOO)  l'+0,876 


Revenues 

Passencers,  Gross  $ij3,273,25^ 

Less  6^j  Dilution  2,396,695 

Passenger  Revenue           .  $40,681,5^9 

Cargo  and  lii.il  2,610,1+00 

Other  Revenue  438,g6l 

Total  Revenues  $^3,730,220 


Ol^erstinr  Smensps 

Aircraft  Operrting   (E:.:c1.  Depr.)  $l3,i+15,460  l/ 

F.E.  Depreciation  2,990^030 

Sub-Total:  Direct  Costs  $21,405 ,460 

General  and  Aduinistrative  $13,938,630 

Contingency  1,600,000 

Depreciation  of  Ground  Equipment  294,750 

Arcorti-ation  of  Prcoperating  E::pense  2/  227,600 

Sub-Total:   Indirect  Costs  i|ii6,Q6o,980 

Total  Operating  E>:pense  $37>466,440 

Estiiiated  Operating  Profit  $  0,263,780 


1/     Flying  Operations   (ll,ll6,l40)  plus  total  iraintenance  including 
burden   (7,299,320). 

2/     Five-year  amortization:     Page  6  of  this  appondix,    "E£tin-.ated 
Investment" . 


Source:      Aopendix    11,     Page    4    of   6,     CAB    Docket    1846J 


571 

Appendix  B 
instructions  for  travel  group  charter  application 

Introduction 

Form  372a  ^  is  to  be  used  in  making  the  various  filings  of  the  travel  group 
charter  passenger  name  list  (TGCPNL).  The  list  is  first  required  to  be  filed 
by  the  travel  group  charter  organizer  (CO)  no  earlier  than  90  days  and  no  later 
than  60  days  before  the  scliedu!ed  date  of  departure,  pursuant  to  sections  3<a.22 
(b)  and  (d)  (first  filing)  ;  and  a  photostatic  or  similarly  reproduced  copy  of 
this  form,  stamped  by  the  Board,  is  to  be  used  as  the  enplanement  list  required 
to  be  prepared  by  the  direct  air  carrier  (DAC),  and  filed  after  the  departure  or 
return  fiight  is  performed,  pursuant  to  section  372a.50(a).  The  information 
required  by  all  items  on  form  372a  shall  be  typewritten ;  however,  names  of 
assignees  entered  in  item  11  subsequent  to  the  first  filing,  and  items  12  (pas- 
senger status),  15  (enplanement  identification)  and  18  (prepared  by),  may  be 
handwritten  in  pen. 

Procedures  for  First  Filing 

The  CO  will  prepare  form  372a  according  to  the  instructions  set  forth  and 
shall,  in  its  first  filing,  file  an  original  and  two  photostatic  or  similarly  repro- 
duced copies  (not  carbons)  accompanied  by  a  self -addressed  and  postage-prepaid 
return  envelope,  with  the  Board's  Supplementary  Services  Division,  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights  (BOR).  BOR  will  stamp  the  original  and  two  copies  to  validate 
their  receipt,  and  return  the  two  stamped  copies  to  the  CO.  One  stamped  copy 
will  be  for  use  by  the  DAC  who  is  to  perform  the  TGC  departure  flight  and  the 
other  stamped  copy  will  be  for  use  by  the  DAC  who  is  to  perform  the  TGC  return 
flight. 

Preparation  of  Form  372a 

Each  page  provides  for  twenty  (20)  TGC  names.  Items  1,  2,  and  6  through 
15  will  be  completed  on  each  page  on  which  original  participants  (OP's)  are 
listed,  and  items  16  through  18  will  be  prepared  only  on  the  first  page,  by  the 
CO  or  DAC,  as  the  case  may  be. 

Note:  Since  only  verified  and  stamped  copies  of  form  372a  may  be  used 
for  entering  the  names  and  identification  of  such  assignees  as  may  be  sub- 
stituted for  original  participants  subsequent  to  the  first  filing,  the  CO  shall 
submit  in  his  first  filing  a  sufl3cient  quantity  of  pages  with  items  1,  2  and 
6  through  10  completed  to  provide  space  for  making  entries  for  the  maximum 
permissible  number  of  assignees,  i.e.,  15  percent  of  original  participants. 

Item  1,  page  of. — The  left  blank  is  to  contain  a  sequential  number  beginning 
with  "1"  representing  the  page  number  in  the  set  of  pages  submitted  for  the 
TGCPNL.  The  right  blank  is  to  contain  the  total  number  of  pages  in  the  set  for 
the  TGCPNL. 

Item  2,  TGC  Number.— Enter  the  number  assigned  by  BOR  for  the  TGC  pro- 
gram, e.g.,  74-37 ;  the  CO  should  further  identify  the  passenger  lists  filed  within 
the  program  by  assigning  another  number  for  each  passenger  list  filed,  such 
numbers  to  be  in  sequence  and  begin  with  "1."  Thus,  the  first  passenger  list  filed 
in  the  program  74-37  would  be  74-37-1,  and  the  fifth  list  filed  would  be  74-37-5. 

Item  3,  Date  of  First  Filing. — Leave  blank. 

Item  4,  Date  Departure  List  Filed. — Leave  blank. 

Item  5,  Date  Return  List  Filed. — Leave  blank. 

Item  6,  Name  of  Charter  Organizer. — Enter  the  name  of  the  charter  organizer, 
exactly  as  shown  on  the  TGC  option  filed  with  the  Board. 

Item  7,  Name  Departure  Trip  Direct  Air  Carrier. — Enter  the  name  of  the  DAC 
who  will  perform  the  departure  journey  for  the  TGC,  exactly  as  shown  on  the 
TGC  option  filed  with  the  Board. 

Item  8,  Name  Returning  Trip  Direct  Air  Carrier. — Enter  the  name  of  the  DAC 
who  will  perform  the  return  journey  for  the  TGC,  exactly  as  shown  on  the  TGC 
option  filed  with  the  Board.  (Although  this  will  generally  be  the  same  as  shown 
in  item  7,  ditto  marks  are  not  acceptable.  The  item  must  be  completed.) 

Item  9,  Departure  Journey. — Enter  details  about  the  departure  journey  on  this 
line.  Show  the  origin  and  destination  as  city,  state  (or  otherwise),  and  country. 


Copies  are  obtainable  from  the  Board's  Publications  Services  Section. 


572 

Airport  names  are  acceptable  only  as  an  addition  to  the  city,  state,  and  country 
information.  The  date  should  appear  in  the  form  YYMMDD  where  YY  represents 
the  last  two  digits  of  the  current  calendar  year,  MM  represents  the  month  in  a 
scale  where  01  is  January  and  12  is  December,  and  DD  is  the  day  of  the  month 
from  01  to  31.  For  example,  December  10,  1974,  would  be  shown  as  741210.  The 
ADP  coding  boxes  to  the  left  of  item  9  are  intended  for  the  3-letter  codes  of 
the  origin  and  destination,  i.e.,  Washington,  D.C.  USA  (National  Airport)  to 
Baltimore,  Md.  USA  should  be  shown  as  DCABAL.  Enter  these  if  known,  other- 
wise, leave  blank. 

Item  10,  Return  Journey. — Follow  the  same  directions  as  for  item  9  above  in 
describing  the  return  journey. 

Item  11,  Passenger  Sequential  Number. — Two  or  more  pages  will  be  required 
to  list  the  names  of  original  participants  and  any  tour  conductors  or  a.ssignees. 
Each  original  participant  is  to  receive  a  sequential  number  beginning  with  "1", 
so  that  the  last  sequential  number  shown  on  TGCPNL  at  the  first  filing  should 
equal  the  number  of  original  participants.  At  enplanement,  the  DAC  shall  enter 
in  item  11  the  name  of  each  assignee.* 

Item  12,  Passenger  Status. — These  four  (4)  columns  are  to  be  marked  with  an 
"x"  as  appropriate  to  .show  that  the  pa.ssenger  named  on  this  line  is  an  OP,  an 
assignee  (ASNE),  departing  enplaned  passenger  (DEP),  or  returning  enplaned 
passenger  (RET).  The  TGCPNL  at  first  filing  will  contain  "x's"  only  in  the  (OP) 
column.  The  total  number  of  "x's"  in  the  OP  column  for  all  pages  must  be  equal 
to  at  least  90  percent  of  the  number  of  seats  contracted  for.  The  DAC  performing 
the  departure  flight  will  mark  an  "x"  in  the  departure  column  and  the  DAC 
performing  the  return  flight  will  mark  an  "x"  in  the  return  column.  Each  DAC 
will  complete  items  12  through  15  for  each  assignee. 

Item  13,  Name. — Enter  the  prospective  passenger's  last  name  first,  followed  by  a 
comma,  the  first  name  or  initials  and  the  middle  initial,  if  any  (for  example. 
Doe,  John  A.).  Check  block  whether  male  or  female.  Enter  the  name  on  one  line 
only,  if  necessary,  by  dropping  any  element  other  than  the  fully  spelled  out  last 
name.  Enter  all  prospective  passengers'  names  in  alphabetical  order,  according  to 
the  last  name  and  in  the  case  of  like  last  names,  according  to  initials  of  first 
names. 

Item  14,  Address  and  Telephone  No. — Enter  the  address  in  enough  detail  to 
allow  contact  by  mail,  and  telephone  number  (including  area  code,  if  any). 

Item  15,  Enplanement  Identification. — The  DAC  performing  the  departure  or 
return  flight  will  verify  each  enplaning  passenger's  identity,  using  as  the  docu- 
mentary source  of  such  verification  the  passenger's  passport,  or,  if  he  has  no 
passport,  using  his  travel  identity  document.  Only  if  no  passport  or  travel  identity 
document  is  available  should  any  other  document  be  used,  preferably  a  Social 
Security  card.  When  a  passport  or  social  security  card  is  used  for  identification, 
enter  only  the  number  in  the  appropriate  space.  Where  a  travel  identity  document 
or  document  other  than  a  passport  or  social  security  card  is  used,  then,  in  addi- 
tion to  entering  the  number  in  the  appropriate  space,  a  brief  description  of  such 
document  should  also  be  noted. 

Item  16,  Column  Totals. — Boxes  shown  are  to  be  used  for  recording  the  total 
"x's"  .shown  on  all  the  pages  of  this  TGCPNL  in  the  particular  column.  These 
entries  must  appear  only  on  page  1  of  the  TGCPNL.  The  box  under  the  column 
head  OP  (titled  A-OP)  should  contain  the  total  number  of  original  participants 
and  the  box  under  the  column  headed  ASNE  (titled  B-ASNE)  should  contain  the 
total  number  of  assignees.  The  box  under  the  column  headed  DEP  (titled  C- 
DEP)  should  contain  the  total  number  of  departure  flight  passengers  and  the  box 
under  the  column  headed  RET  (titled  D-RET)  .should  contain  the  total  number 
of  return  flight  passengers.  The  A-OP  flgure  will  be  shown  on  the  First  Filing. 
The  B-ASNE,  C-DEP,  and  D-RET  figures  will  be  .shown  on  the  filings  made  by 
the  departing  DAC  and  returning  DAC,  respectively. 


-Where  the  number  of  sents  contracted  for  includes  one  or  more  seat.s  for  tour  con- 
ductors. p\irsnant  to  section  .^72n. 14(d).  then:  1)  following:  the  last  sennentinl  number  for 
original  participants  there  shall  be  entered,  in  Item  l.S.  either  the  name  of  ench  conductor, 
if  known  at  the  time  of  first  filina:,  or  the  letters  "TC".  and  2)  at  the  time  of  enplanement 
the  DAC  shall  complete  the  information  reauired  by  item  15.  as  to  tour  condu'-tors  named 
in  item  13.  nnd  if  item  l.S  contains  only  the  initials  "TC",  then  the  DAC  shall  also  enter 
the  tour  conductor's  name  in  item  1.3. 

.«;ource:  Part  .372a  of  Special  Regulations  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  [Subcommittee 
note  :  as  of  May  1975]. 


573 

Item  17a. — This  computation  will  be  completed  by  the  CO.  The  calculation 
requires  a  division  of  the  total  number  of  passengers  listed  in  the  A-OP  column 
by  the  total  number  of  seats  contracted  for.  The  total  number  of  A-OP  column 
must  equal  no  less  than  90  percent  of  the  seats  contracted  for.  Express  the  result 
to  the  nearest  tenth  of  a  percent. 

Item  17b. — This  computation  will  be  completed  by  the  departure  DAC.  The 
calculation  requires  a  division  of  the  number  of  as.-^ignees  enplaned  on  the  de- 
parture journey  by  the  total  number  of  original  participants.  Express  the  result 
to  the  nearest  tenth  of  a  percent. 

Item  18,  Prepared  By. — Enter  the  signature  of  the  person  preparing  the  form 
for  the  CO,  the  departing  DAC,  and  the  returning  DAC,  as  the  case  may  be. 


Prepared  Statement  of  Raymond  J.  Rasenberger 

North  Central  Airlines  has  asked  me  to  appear  on  its  behalf  at  today's  hearings. 
I  would  like  to  begin  with  a  brief  description  of  North  Central.  Headquartered 
in  Minneapolis,  North  Central  is  one  of  the  eight  local-service  air  carriers  cer- 
tificated by  the  CAB.  North  Central  was  incorporated  in  1944  as  Wisconsin  Central 
Airlines  and  was  initially  certificated  by  the  CAB  in  1946.^  Today,  its  route  sys- 
tem extends  from  New  York  to  Denver,  encompassing  some  90  cities  in  13  states 
and  Canada,  operated  with  a  fieet  of  nineteen  100-passenger  Douglas  DC-9-30 
fan  jets  and  thirty-one  48-pas!^enger  Convair  580  prop  jets,  and  boarding  an 
average  of  more  than  12,000  passengers  each  day.  Among  North  Central's  accom- 
plishments are  ranking  as  one  of  the  50  largest  U.S.  transportation  companies," 
first  listing  by  a  local  service  carrier  on  the  New  York  Stock  Exchange,  and  a 
profitable  operation  for  20  of  the  last  21  years  under  the  current  management. 
My  firm  has  served  as  Washington  counsel  for  North  Central,  particularly  in 
matters  involving  CAB  regulation,  for  approximately  10  years. 

The  subcommittee  staff  has  asked  that  we  review  at  these  hearings  North 
Central's  experience  with  the  CAB's  so-called  "route  moratorium."  I  understand 
the  committee  would  like  to  explore  our  ideas,  as  well  as  those  of  other  airlines, 
about  possible  changes  in  procedures  now  followed  by  the  CAB  to  determine 
whether  to  hear  new  applications  for  route  authority. 

We  will  try  to  be  as  responsive  as  possible  to  this  request.  We  are,  of  course, 
constrained  from  arguing  the  merits  of  our  applications  in  any  forum  other  than 
the  CAB  itself.  We  will  be  pleased,  however,  to  summarize  for  the  subcommittee 
the  facts,  all  of  which  are  in  the  public  record,  relating  to  North  Central's  efforts 
to  have  its  route  applications  set  down  for  hearing. 

Let  me  also  make  clear  at  the  outset  that,  while  North  Central  has  been  notably 
unsuccessful  in  getting  its  route  applications  heard  in  recent  years,  neither  North 
Central  nor  I  as  their  counsel  want  to  be  associated  with  across-the-board  attacks 
on  the  regulatory  system  in  general  or  the  CAB  in  particular.  In  our  view,  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938  (now  the  Federal  Aviation  Act)  is  generally  an 
exemplary  piece  of  legislation — a  collection  of  extraordinarily  wise  policies  and 
sound  procedures.  The  proof  of  this  is  in  part  the  result  we  see  today — an  airline 
industry  that  has  come  through  three  decades  of  incredibly  rapid  technological 
change  and  growth  and  now  provides  the  United  States  with  an  unparalleled 
system  of  air  transportation. 

I  particularly  want  to  emphasize  the  .word  "system"  because  too  often  the 
economic  interrelationship  of  the  various  portions  of  our  air  transportation  net- 
work is  forgotten,  particularly  by  those  who  advocate  unregulated  entry.  Air 
service  to  weak  points  is  supported  by  routes  connecting  stronger  points.  Stronger 
points  obtain  their  strength  in  part  from  traflSc  flows  which  are  generated  by 
weaker  points.  North  Central  as  a  local  service  carrier  particularly  is  aware  of 
this  relationship.  Unless  that  interrelationship  is  fostered  under  a  statutory 
scheme  .such  as  we  now  have,  the  result  will  necessarily  be  the  disappearance  of 
air  service  at  many  small  communities  now  receiving  it  and  poorer,  less  reliable 
service  at  many  others. 

Of  course,  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  alone  has  not  built  the  system  we  have. 
It  took  an  agency  to  make  it  work.  By  and  large  that  agency,  with  the  help  of  a 
remarkably  competent  and  independent  staff,  has  done  an  outstanding  job  of 
particularizing  the  statutory  directives  into  sound  policies.  North  Central  has 


1  North  Central  Case.  7  CAB  639  (1946). 

2  Fortune,  Double  500  Directory,  July  1973. 


574 

had  many  disagreements  with  the  Board  over  particular  policies  and  actions — 
and  certainly  the  recent  refusal  to  hear  our  route  applications  is  a  major  ex- 
ample— but  in  terms  of  a  longer  and  broader  view  we  think  the  Board  is  entitled 
to  the  thanks  of  Congress  and  the  public  for  a  job  well  done. 

DEVELOPMENT  OF  THE  HEARING  REQUIREMENT  UNDER  SECTION   401 

To  understand  the  current  route  moratorium,  it  is  useful  to  review  briefly 
some  of  the  background  of  CAB  route  regulation  and  the  related  hearing  require- 
ment. The  domestic  airline  industry  began  not  as  a  passenger  system  but  rather 
as  a  system  for  carriage  of  mail.  Airmail  contracts  sustained  the  industry  from 
the  period  following  World  War  I  through  the  early  1930's  when,  with  the  devel- 
opment of  new  engine  and  structural  technology,  it  became  possible  to  carry  mail 
and  a  substantial  number  of  passenger.s.  It  was  at  this  point  that  a  domestic  pas- 
senger route  system  began  to  emerge,  but  airmail  contracts  still  marked  the 
difference  between  a  profitable  and  an  unprofitable  operation  and  the  obtaining 
of  these  contracts  was  the  key  to  success. 

Although  the  Air  Mail  Act  of  1930  provided  for  competitive  bidding,  the  Post 
Ofl5ce  Department  encouraged  the  carriers  to  work  out  the  details  in  private, 
leading  to  the  notorious  "spoils  conferences"  and  an  industry  that,  by  1934,  was 
dominated  by  three  manufacturing  and  carrier  combines.  Through  the'' direct 
intervention  of  President  Roosevelt  and  new  airmail  legislation  in  1934  and  1935, 
the  system  was  made  somewhat  more  equitable  but  it  still  favored  the  large, 
financially  strong  carriers  who  could  afford  to  underbid  on  the  airmail  contracts. 
On  the  other  hand,  these  carriers  were  seriously  concerned  about  unregulated 
competition  by  carriers  that  did  not  have  airmail  contracts. 

The  end  result  was  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938,  the  economic  provisions 
of  which  were  reenacted  virtually  intact  in  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958. 
Two  sections  of  that  Act  bear  directly  on  the  proce-ssing  of  route  applications. 
The  first  is  the  unequivocal  requirement  in  section  401(c)  that  any  application 
for  a  route  "shall  be  set  for  a  public  hearing,  and  the  Board  shall  dispose  of 
such  application  as  speedily  as  possible." "  Patterned  after  the  hearing  require- 
ment in  the  Interstate  Commerce  Act,  this  provision  was  the  legislative  disavowal 
of  the  "spoils  conferences"  and  was  meant  to  insure  that  henceforth,  all  matters 
concerning  route  awards  would  be  decided  on  the  basis  of  a  public  record. 

With  an  industry  that  was  still  in  its  infancy,  this  provision  was  fully  im- 
plemented in  the  early  years  and — with  the  exception  of  World  War  II — route 
applications  were  generally  heard  "as  speedily  as  possible."  The  controversy  in 
this  period — and  still  today — centered  on  another  provision  of  the  Act,  section 
102(d),  which  states  that  one  of  the  fundamental  goals  of  CAB  regulation  is 
"competition  to  the  extent  necessary  to  assure  the  sound  development  of  an  air- 
transportation  system  properly  adopted  to  the  needs  of  the  foreign  and  domestic 
commerce  of  the  United  States,  of  the  postal  service,  and  the  national  defense." 

"Competition  to  the  extent  necessary"  is  an  ingeniously  vague  term,  but 
its  legislative  history  clearly  indicates  that  it  was  included  in  the  Act  to 
make  certain  that,  if  competition  could  be  provided  economically,  it  should 
he  authorized.*  Several  large  carriers,  the  most  notable  of  which  was  Pan  Ameri- 
can, advanced  another  view :  namely,  if  the  incumbent  carrier  was  providing 
reasonably  adequate  service  over  a  route,  that  carrier  was  the  "chosen  instru- 
ment" for  that  route  and  competition  should  not  be  authorized.  One  of  the  CAB's 
earliest  actions  was  to  reject  the  "chosen  instrument"  theory  and  to  cast  a 
strong  aflSrmative  vote  for  competition  in  the  airline  industry  : 


3  The  "as  speedily  as  possible"  requirement  Is  over  and  above  the  reoulrement  In  section 
6(a)  of  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  (.5  U.S.C.  5'.t.5)  that  "[w]lth  due  regard  for 
the  convenience  and  necessity  of  the  parties  or  their  representatives  and  within  a  reason- 
able time,  eich  acency  shall  proceed  to  conclude  a  motter  presented  to  it."  *s  this  nrovl- 
slon  appeared  when  the  Administrative  Procednre  Act  was  Initially  enacted  in  1946,  it 
required  each  agency  to  "proceed  with  reasonable  dispatch  to  conclude  any  manner  so 
presented"  and  was  sneclflcallv  intended  to  create  a  "legal  requirement  that  no  aprency 
shall  In  effect  deny  relief  or  fail  to  conclude  a  case  by  mere  inaction."  (S.  Rept.  7.52.  79th 
Concr..  1st  Sess.  IS  (194.5).)  The  recodification  of  the  Act  In  it«!  present  form  restates, 
"without  substantive  change,  the  laws  replaced."  (Pub.  L.  89-.5.54,  R9th  Conp.,  2d  Sess., 
section  7(a). 

*  This  provision  was  not  Included  in  earlier  versions  of  the  Act  in  which  the  views 
of  the  incumbent  airmail  carriers  were  dominant,  hut  was  added  at  the  insistence  of 
Government  representatives.  .Tones,  Antitrust  and  Sneclfic  Kconomic  Resrulition  :  An  Intro- 
duction  to   Comparative  Analysis,   19   ABA   antitrust  section  261,  309    (1961), 


575 

"As  the  justification  for  competition  in  any  case  does  not  depend  upon  the 
failure  or  inability  of  an  existing  carrier  to  render  adequate  service,  neither 
does  its  ability  and  willingness  to  furnish  a  sufficient  volume  of  service  in  itself 
constitute  a  bar  to  a  competitive  service.  The  greatest  gain  from  competition, 
whether  actual  or  potential,  is  the  stimulus  to  devise  and  experiment  with  new 
operating  techniques  and  new  equipment,  to  develop  new  means  of  acquiring 
and  promoting  business,  including  the  rendering  of  better  service  to  the  customer 
and  to  the  Nation  and  affording  the  Government  a  comparative  yardstick  by 
which  the  performance  of  the  carriers  may  be  measured.  Competition  invites 
comparison  as  to  equipment,  costs,  personnel,  methods  of  operation,  solicita- 
tion of  traffic,  all  of  which  tend  to  assure  the  development  of  an  air  transporta- 
tion system  as  contemplated  by  the  Act."  ° 

While  this  was  certainly  not  a  policy  of  free  entry,  it  nevertheless  made  it 
clear  that  the  route  system  was  not  fixed  when  there  was  simply  a  carrier  pro- 
viaing  service — the  question,  instead,  was  how  many  carriers  could  proviue  that 
service  economically.  And,  when  combined  with  the  "public  hearing  ...  as 
speeoily  as  possible"  requirement,  those  provisions  produced,  in  the  next  two 
decades  a  vast  system  of  uomestic  and  international  air  service. 

Not  that  the  CAB  granted  every  application  it  heard  or,  for  that  matter, 
heard  every  application  on  its  aocket.  lo  the  contrary,  the  CAB  quickly  aban- 
doned the  first-come-first-served  policy  of  assigning  priority  to  applications  and 
used  its  discretion  in  this  area  to  approach  route  applications  in  a  logical  se- 
quence, setting  down  cases  in  individual  markets  when  adequate  support  was 
shown,  or  instituting  on  its  own  motion  larger  area  investigations  designed  to 
examine  at  one  time  a  number  of  interrelated  issues  of  route  authority. 

As  time  pas-sed  and  the  Board  founu  itseif  faced  with  a  rapidly  growing  docket 
of  route  applications,  it  took  several  steps  aimed  at  helping  it  sort  out  those  most 
woriliy  of  prompt  hearing.  In  Moz,  the  Board  auopteu  stanaards  for  priority  of 
hearing  (14  CFR  399.60)  and  these  are,  at  least  nominally,  still  in  effect.  In  1968 
and  1969  the  Board  adopted  special  procedures  under  subpart  M  and  subpart 
N  of  its  proceaural  regulations.  There  was  a  commendaole  effort  to  shorten 
sometimes  elaborate  hearing  procedures  in  connection  with  the  applications  for 
removal  of  route  restrictions.  The  thou^^ht  was  that  such  applications  tend  to  be 
relatively  noncontroversial  and  thus  lend  themselves  to  simplified  proceaures. 

Another  action  taken  by  the  Board  was  the  establishment  in  1963  of  subpart 
K,  a  standardized  system  of  forecasting  the  costs  of  operating  routes  proposed 
by  local  service  carriers.  In  recent  year.s,  with  the  advent  of  the  route  mora- 
torium, subparts  M  and  N  have  fallen  into  disuse.  Subpart  K  costing,  however, 
is  still  used.  As  noted  below,  subpart  K  tends  to  overstate  the  cost  of  operating 
a  new  route  and  makes  it  extremely  difficult  to  show  that  any  new  service  can  be 
operated  profitably.  Subpart  K  results  have  been  relied  upon  frequently  by  the 
Board  to  supiK)rt  a  decision  not  to  hear  a  route  application. 

Finally,  in  recent  years  we  have  seen  a  shift  to  the  "show  cause"  procedures 
in  those  instances  where  the  Board  has  agreed  to  entertain  relatively  minor 
applications  for  new  route  authority  such  as  "route  realignments."  Under  those 
procedures  the  Board  announces  a  tenative  decision  first  on  the  basis  of  staff 
recommendation.  These  tentative  findings  are  later  made  final  if,  as  is  usually  the 
case,  no  one  demands  a  hearing  in  terms  which  the  Board  finds  convincing.  The 
precise  limits  of  Board  power  to  act  by  show  cause  order  have  not  yet  been 
established. 

NORTH    central's    EXPERIENCE    PRIOR    TO    THE    19  70's 

Before  examining  the  North  Central  applications  that  have  been  victims  of  the 
route  moratorium,  it  is  important  to  note  the  company's  experience  in  more  "nor- 
mal" times.  North  Central  has  received  many  awards  of  new  authority  in  the 
79  years  it  has  been  certificated.  Four  of  the  most  significant  for  North  Central 
took  place  in  the  last  half  of  the  1960's  : 

1.  Twin  Cities— Denver  nonstop  authority  (CAB  docket  18828).  On  Septem- 
ber 26,  1966,  the  City  of  Denver  applied  for  nonstop  service  to  the  Twin  Cities, 


sHawaiiin  Airlines.  Ltd..  et  al.,  Hawaiian  Case.  7  CAB  83,  103-104  (1946).  Also  see 
American  Export  Airlines.  Inc.-Certificate  of  Public  Convenience  and  Necessity  (Trans- 
atlantic Service).  2  CAR  16.  29-31  (1940)  ;  Northeast  Airlines.  Inc.,  et  al.-Western  Atlantic 
Route  Case,  6  CAB  319,  323-320  (1945)  ;  Southwest-Northeast  Service  Case,  22  CAB  52, 
60  (1955)  ;  Aloha  Airlines,  Inc.,  Hawaiian  Airlines,  Inc.,  Certificate  Amendment  Proceed- 
ing, CAB  order  E-25650,  at  2  (1967). 


576 

Omaha.  Phoenix  and  Las  Vesras.  On  April  12.  1967.  Denver  mored  for  an  ex- 
l)edited  hearinc:.  North  Central  supported  that  motion  as  it  applied  to  its  appli- 
cation for  Tvvin  Cities-Denver  authority.  The  Board  granted  the  motion  on 
July  25.  1967  and  instituted  a  proceeding  which  culminated  on  April  2.  1969.  with 
an  award  to  North  Central  (.order  6i>— 1-20). 

2.  Milwaukee-Dayton  Columbus  Cincinnati  authority  (docket  19692).  On 
November  24.  1967.  the  City  of  Milwaukee  and  the  State  of  Wisconsin  applied  for 
new  authority  to  certain  Ohio  points.  The  Board  instituted  an  investigation  on 
March  S.  li>68  (order  E-2l>488).  and  North  Central  was  awarded  the  authority 
on  October  13.  1969  (order  69-10-57 K 

3.  Milwaukee-New  York  nonstop  authority  (docket  19097) .  North  Central  filed 
this  application  in  the  spring  of  1967.  together  with  a  motion  for  an  expedited 
hearing.  The  Board  instituted  an  investigation  on  Octol>er  11.  1967  (order  E- 
25S05>.  and  North  Central  was  granted  the  authority  on  Jime  4.  1970  (order 
70-6-36). 

4.  Omaha-Twin  Cities  nonstop  authority  (docket  1S401K  The  City  of  Omaha 
tiled  an  application  on  October  21.  1966.  and  a  broad  investigation  was  instituted 
on  April  13.  1967  (order  E-24977).  North  Central  was  granted  Omaha-Twin 
Cities  nonstop  authority  on  July  6.  1970   i  order  70-7-24). 

In  each  of  these  cases  North  Central  was  authorized  to  provide  non  top  service 
in  comi^etition  with  an  incuml>ent  carrier.  In  general.  North  Central  was  chosen 
over  other  carriers  on  the  bit  sis  of  cvmventional  elements  of  public  convenience 
and  necessity  including  the  ability  and  incentive  to  provide  a  stiperior  service. 
In  striking  the  balam^  in  favor  of  North  Central,  the  Board  gave  weight  to 
the  fact  that  the  new  route  v\ould  strengthen  North  Central's  existing  system. 
thus  helping  pay  for  service  at  many  unprofitable  points.  A  characteristic  .shared 
by  all  local  service  carriers  is  a  very  shi»rf  average  aircraft  hop  and  passenger 
haul.  ( Even  t<xiay  the  average  passenger  on  North  Central's  system  travels  only 
220  miles,  the  lowest  jvissenger  haul  in  the  domestic  airline  industry.)  By  award- 
ing larger,  more  dense  routes  to  local  service  ctirriers.  the  Board  enables  them 
to  spread  out  their  operating  costs  over  a  larger  base  as  well  as  increase  their 
internal  traffic  load.  By  the  same  token  each  of  the  routes  awarded  to  North 
Central  was  made  ineligible  for  subsidy.  They  remain  as  such  and  now  contribute 
to  a  reduction  of  North  Central's  subsidy  uee<l. 

It  should  be  emphasized  that  not  every  North  Central  application  heard  resulted 
in  a  route  award.*  The  ix>int.  however,  is  that,  in  a  substantial  iiercentage  of 
the  cases  where  applications  were  heard,  it  was  found  that  the  public  con- 
venience and  necessity  required  an  award. 

POST    1970   EXPEBIEXCE 

North  Central  has  not  ^eoei^■ed  a  new  route  award  since  July  6.  1970.'  It  has 
not  had  an  applic:iti<^n  for  new  route  authority  set  down  for  hearing  since 
July  19.  1969.*  What  has  hapjvned  in  the  ivtst  6  years'?  One  thing  that  hasn't 
happened  is  the  failure  of  North  Central  to  file  such  applications.  North  Central. 
as  well  as  a  number  of  other  carriers,  have  ct^ntinually  presented  the  Board  with 
applit^nitions  that  ha\e  either  gone  unnoticed,  have  been  dismissed  without  a 
hearing,  or  denied  a  timely  hearing. 


» In  The  Twin  Citles-XTliwaukee  Sontheasrt  Points  Investigation  (docket  20267).  North 
Centrnl  was  an  unsucoessful  applicant  for  Twin  Cit'es-Milwanke^-Atlanta— Tampa-Miami 
authority.  (Eastern  was  awarded  the  route.)  Order  70-11-6.  In  the  Chicasro-B.iltimore 
Nonstop' SerNice  Investigation  (dix^ket  21101).  North  Central  wa5  an  unsuccessful  appl'cant 
for  Chicaco-BalTimore  nonstop  auihoriTv.  (TWA  wa5  awarded  the  route.)  Order  71-9-64. 
In  fact,  in  each  of  the  cases  where  North  Central  received  new  authority  that  authority 
represented  only  part  of  Xorth  Central's  appr.cation. 

•  Omaha-Twin  Cities  nonstop  authority.  Order  70-7-24.  North  Central  did  receive 
in  the  interim  an  exemption  to  operate  a  Duluth-Winnipe?  route  pursuant  to  the  U.S.- 
Canada Air  Transport  Agreement,  after  agreeing  to  accept  restrictions  re<iuired  by  an 
oppos'ns  carrier. 

*  ChicaffO-Baltimore  Nonstop  Service  Investigation,  order  69-6-9S.  On  February  2.  1970 
the  Board  did  grant  consolidation  of  a  North  Central  Application  (docket  212.'>4>  in  the 
Ohto'Indiana  Points  Nonstop  Service  Investigation  (docket  21162).  However,  for  the  last 
five  years  no  further  action  has  been  taken  by  the  Board  to  move  that  case  toward  decision. 

Xorth  C-^ntraVs  i>etirion  fo-  ro'Ue  re.-j'inemenr — .1  reonest  that  <^rt'in  resrrictions  in 
noncompetitive  mstrkets  on  North  Centrafs  system  be  lifted — was  filed  on  July  16.  1973 
(docket  23705)  and  was  gr:\nted  with  modifications  by  show  cause  proceedings  on  Feb- 
ruary 5.  1975  (order  75-2-22). 


577 

In  short.  North  Central  encuimtered  the  full  force  of  the  route  moratorium,  a 
policy  which  came  iuto  being  quietly  and  without  announcement."  but  which 
has  been  enforced  with  unremitting  diligence.  The  statute  has  remained  the  same ; 
even  the  former  rule  on  priority  of  hearings  has  remained  on  the  books.  The 
Board  has  steadfastly  refused  to  hear  even  the  most  compelling  applications  tc 
add  competitive  service. 

This  is  perhaps  the  most  important  point,  namely,  the  moratorium  has  not  only 
been  on  Cvm,reiiiivf  awanls — it  has  been  on  Juurini/s.^"  'the  CAH  has  simply  re- 
ftised  to  permit  a  record  to  be  developed  on  any  of  these  applications.  Three 
North  Central  case  histories  will  illustrate  the  situation  : 

1.  Detroit-Boston  nonstop  authority  (docket  24S74).  American  was  granted 
nonstop  authority  in  this  market  in  liMo.  making  it  one  of  the  oldest  nongrand- 
father  routes.  By  1968  Mohawk  (which  was  later  merged  into  Allegheny)  had 
one-stop  authority,  but  the  market  had  already  emerged  as  the  largest  remaining 
nonstop  monoix^ly.  By  1971'  American  was  olTering  only  4  daily  nonstop  round- 
trips  with  a  total  of  940  one-way  seats  per  day.  The  market  was  producing  almost 
550  O&D  passengers  per  day.  Some  of  the  available  seats  were  also  occupied  by 
passengers  moving  to  or  from  pi)ints  beyond  Detroit.  Data  filed  by  American  with 
the  CAB  revealeil  that  in  19;2  :  the  average  coach  load  factor  was  60  percent :  one- 
half  of  these  coach  passengers  moved  on  flights  with  a  coach  load  factor  in  excess 
of  75  percent ;  the  prime  flights  routinely  experienced  coach  load  factors  from  80 
percent  to  92  percent :  and  many  passengers  were  being  forced  to  fly  first-class 
by  the  high-coach  load  factors. 

On  October  27.  1972.  North  Central  filed  its  application  for  nonstop  authority 
in  the  market  together  with  a  motion  for  expedition.  North  Central's  motion  was 
supported  by  the  Massachusetts  Port  Authority,  the  communities  of  Detroit. 
South  Bend.  Grand  Rapids.  Kalamazoo.  Flint.  I^uising.  Saginaw.  Midland.  Bay 
City  and  Green  Bay.  the  States  of  Michigan  and  "Wisconsin  and  Delta  and  North- 
west. Allegheny.  Delta  and  Northwest  also  filed  similar  applications. 

Only  July  16.  1973.  the  CAB  denied  the  motion.  Order  73-7-'i8.  The  grounds 
given  were  :  1)  no  evidence  of  existing  service  deficiencies  :  2)  a  lack  of  sufficient 
beyond  market  traliic:  ;s )  a  stateti  "i  eMef  "  that  the  pmposal.s  wouldn't  reduce 
subsidy  ;  and  4)  a  brief  reference  to  the  impending  fuel  shortage.  Member  Minetti 
concurred  i  nt  expie  ed  iiismay  oer  the  ix)li('y  ot  vauiion."  Member  Murphy 
dissented  on  the  groimds  that  adequate  justification  had  been  given  for  the  in- 
stitution of  a  hearing. 

On  August  10.  19.3.  North  Central.  South  Bend,  Kalamazoo  and  the  State  of 
Michigan  petitioned  for  reconsideration,  contesting  the  Board's  factual  "find- 
ings" and  raising  the  legality  of  a  policy  of  "caution.'"  The  various  parties  lined 
up  in  stipport  of  or  in  opposition  to  the  petitittn  much  as  they  had  in  response 
to  the  initial  motion.  This  petition  was  denied  on  March  27.  1974,  by  order  74-3- 
120  (which,  as  we  shall  see.  also  denied  two  other  North  Central  petitions), 
with  the  CAB  indicating  that  it  had  broad  discretion  to  control  its  own  calendar 
and  that  it  would  continue  to  monitor  the  incumbent  carrier's  performance  in 
the  market. 

At  the  present  time,  the  market  has  grown  to  approximately  600  O&D  passen- 
gers per  day  while  American's  nonstop  service  has  declined  from  4  to  3  round- 
trips  and  750  seats  per  day  instead  of  940. 

2.  Milwaukee-Denver  nonstop  authority  (dockets  19676  and  26646).  I'nited 
has  held  nonstop  authority  in  this  market  since  194(i.  In  1968,  North  Central  filed 


*The  existence  of  the  moratorium  as  a  formal  policy  w.ns  recently  acknowledged  by  the 
CAB  staff  domestic  route  study  :  "Since  approximately  1.970  cases  Involving  new  domestic 
route  authority  have  generally  not  been  set  fo"-  hearing  and  applications  filed  under  sub- 
part yi  and  X  have  been  stayed  or  dismissed.'    iForewnrd,  p.  i.) 

'"The  one  exception  to  this  is  the  Atlanta-PetroiT  rieveland/Clncinnatl  Investigation 
(docket  20724).  where  the  Biard.  in  effect,  found  itself  with  a  case  that  was  initiated 
before  the  moratorium  began.  The  case  was  set  down  on  February  12,  1969  (order  69-2-55) 
and  on  September  4.  1970.  tlie  examiner  iss\ied  an  inl'ial  i^e^ision  finrfing  -i  neei  for 
competitive  nouston  service  in  each  of  the  three  nonstop  markets  at  issue,  by  applicants 
other  than  North  Central.  The  Board  did  nothing  for  almost  2  years,  then  issued  an  order 
on  .Tuly  2S.  1972.  finding  that  the  record  was  "stnle"  and  remanding  It  for  further 
hearings.  (Order  72-7-98).  The  Kxaminer.  in  a  second  in'tial  decision,  again  found  a  need 
for  competitive  service  in  each  of  tliese  markets.  However  on  Mav  S.  1974.  the  Board 
denied  all  applications  (Order  74-5-18>  on  grounds  that  had  no  basis  in  the  record — 
the  illeged  fuel  shortage.  Thnt  order  is  presently  being  challenged  In  the  U.S.  Court  Of 
Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia  circuit. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


578 

an  application  for  nonstop  authority  in  docliet  19676.  After  North  Central  re- 
ceived Twin  Cities-Denver  authority  in  191)9  with  a  single-plane  restriction  on 
Milwaukee-Denver  service,  it  applied  under  subpart  M  for  removal  of  that 
restriction.  Ihe  CAB,  by  order  69-8-77  held  that  subpart  M  was  not  applicable. 

On  July  31,  1970,  North  Central  moved  for  an  expedited  hearing.  Continental 
filed  a  similar  application  together  with  a  motion  for  expedition.  Order  71-0-7 
denied  the  motions,  again  over  member  Minetti's  dissent,  "without  prejudice  to 
these  carriers'  right  to  file  new  motions  for  immediate  hearing  at  such  time  as 
economic  conditions  have  improved." 

By  January  5,  1973,  North  Central  felt  that  the  economic  condition  had  im- 
proved. The  market  was  generating  approximately  110  O&D  passengers  per  day 
(a  17.3  percent  increase  over  1971)  and  United  was  still  offering  only  3  nonstop 
roundtrips  per  day.  Accordingly,  North  Central  filed  another  motion  for  expedi- 
tion, supported  by  the  communities  of  Milwaukee,  Denver  and  Dayton  and  the 
State  Oj.  Wisconsin.  Seventeen  days  after  the  motion  was  tiled,  order  73-1-56  dis- 
missed the  underlying  application  as  "stale."  Finally,  on  July  25,  1973,  order 
73-7-129  denied  the  motion  and  upheld  the  dismissal,  with  member  Minetti  once 
more  dissenting.  North  Central  petitioned  for  reconsideration,  the  denial  of 
which  was  accomplished  by  order  74-3-120. 

North  Central  has  retiled  the  application  in  docket  26646.  At  the  present  time, 
the  market  has  grown  to  more  than  180  O&D  passengers  per  day  while  United 
still  offers  only  3  nonstop  roundtrips. 

3.  Milwaukee-Philadelphia  nonstop  authority.  Although  smaller  than  the  other 
two  markets,  it  is  unique  because  in  1970  the  CAB,  in  order  70-6-36,  found  a 
need  for  two  carrier  competitive  service  and  chose  Northwest  (over  North  Cen- 
tral and  several  other  carriers)  to  compete  with  United.  By  1973  Northwest 
had  still  not  instituted  nonstop  service  and  United  had  dropped  out  of  the 
market  entirely.  Accordingly,  on  April  23,  1973,  North  Central  applied  for  5 
years,  experimental  nonstop  authority  and  moved  for  an  expedited  hearing.  The 
communities  of  Milwaukee,  Madison,  Duluth,  and  La  Crosse,  as  well  as  Alle- 
gheny and  Ozark,  supported  the  motion.  United  and  Northwest  answered  in 
opposition. 

pn  August  1, 1973,  Northwest  instituted  nonstop  service  (1  roundtrip  per  day). 
On  August  3,  order  73-8-24  denied  North  Central's  motion.  Another  petition  for 
reconsideration  was  denied  by  order  74-3-120.  At  the  present  time  the  market 
is  producing  more  than  110  O&D  passengers  per  day  while  Northwest  still  offers 
only  1  nonstop  roundtrip,  and  United  continues  to  offer  no  nonstop  service. 

I  believe  it  would  be  fair  to  state  that,  prior  to  the  post-1970  moratorium,  each 
of  the  above  applications  would  have  at  least  been  noticed  for  hearing.  The  facts 
presented  in  support  of  a  hearing  were  not,  in  our  opinion,  dissimilar  from  facts 
which  prior  to  1970  resulted  not  only  in  hearings  but  competitive  route  awards. 
Again,  I  am  not  saying  that  North  Central's  application  would  have  been  granted 
in  each  of  these  cases.  There  would  have  been  a  number  of  other  applicants  in 
each  case,  by  both  local  service  and  trunk  carriers.  However,  the  final  decision — 
including  the  decision  on  whether  or  not  to  award  any  competitive  authority — 
would  have  been  based  on  an  evidentiary  record. 

In  the  process  of  making  that  record,  the  forecasts  and  contentions  of  all 
parties,  including  the  CAB's  own  staff,  would  have  been  subjected  to  review  and 
cross-examination  in  public  proceedings.  In  lieu  of  that  procedure  we  have  been 
encountering  under  the  moratorium  what  amounts  to  the  de  facto  denial  of 
applications  based  upon  in  camera  proceedings  within  the  Board.  These  internal 
proceedings  involve  forecasts  and  contentions  of  the  Board's  staff  which  are  not 
made  public  or  subject  to  challenge  except  to  the  limited  extent  they  may  be 
reflected  in  the  Board's  order  of  denial.  Let  me  emphasize  that  we  are  not  ques- 
tioning the  obvious  and  general  need  of  the  Board  for  confidential  communica- 
tions with  its  staff.  Our  concern  goes  only  to  those  instances  where  such 
proceedings  are  used,  in  effect,  as  a  substitute  for  the  public  hearings  required 
by  the  statute. 

POSSIBLE  ALTEENATIVES 

Has  the  domestic  air  transportation  system  reached  its  point  of  optimum 
growth  and  should  it  now  be  subject  only  to  consolidation  and  contraction?  We 
obviously  think  not,  and  even  if  there  were  some  truth  in  this  assumption,  that 
could  adequately  be  determined  only  through  the  hearing  process. 


579 

North  Central,  as  well  as  other  carriers,  have  not  given  up  and  continue  to 
seek  new  authority  that  they  believe  will  benefit  themselves  as  well  as  the  entire 
system.'^  The  possibility  of  judicial  redress  through  a  mandamus  action,  while 
available,'"  is  frankly  a  difficult  step  to  take,  if  for  no  other  reason  that  the 
reluctance  of  the  courts  to  intervene  in  matters  of  agency  discretion." 

North  Central  believes  that  it,  and  other  applicants,  are  entitled  to  something 
more  in  keeping  with  the  statute  than  the  moratorium  of  the  last  6  years.  One 
possible  alternative  was  suggested  by  the  CAB  staff  in  its  recently  released 
study  of  the  domestic  route  system  ^*  which  called  for  the  adoption  of  new  formal 
standards  for  granting  hearings.  Presumably  the  standards  proposed  by  the 
staff  would  be  in  lieu  of  the  present  moribund  rule  on  priority  of  hearing. 

The  staff  proposal  would  have  the  advantage  of  equating  policy  with  practice, 
but  unfortunately  it  seems  to  create  a  presumption  that  most  applications  should 
not  be  heard.  Ihe  key  problem  is  that  the  proposed  standards — which  require 
the  applicant  to  submit,  inter  alia,  a  2-year  profit  and  loss  not  only  for  itself 
but  also  for  any  other  carrier  competing  in  the  market — go  far  beyond  the 
the  information  the  CAB  requires  in  order  to  make  the  kind  of  threshold  deter- 
mination needed  to  manage  its  docket.  The  proposed  standards  would  be,  in 
effect,  decisional  standards,  precisely  of  the  type  the  CAB  might  apply  to  a 
record  developed  in  a  public  hearing.  Under  the  staff's  proposal,  however,  there 
would  be  no  hearing  to  test  the  reliability  and  probative  value  of  the  informa- 
tion submitted,  and  the  CAB  would  still  be  free  to  deny  hearings  at  will,  some- 
thing it  could  do  quite  easily  : 

One  proposed  standard  would  require  an  applicant  for  competitive  authority 
to  demonstrate  that  the  proposed  operations  would  earn  at  least  a  12  percent 
rate  of  return  on  investment  in  the  first  year.  This  requires  a  forecast  of  traflBc 
and  costs.  For  local  carriers,  subpart  K  presumably  would  be  used  to  forecast 
the  costs.  However,  that  subpart  establishes  an  impossibly  high  return  and 
tax  requirement.  Because  of  a  number  of  faulty  premises  (including  an  assump- 
tion that  every  operation  will  be  conducted  with  newly  purchased  aircraft). 
Subpart  K  requires  a  profit  generally  to  approximate  40  percent  of  the  operating 
costs  on  a  typical  route  proposal.  Put  another  way,  unless  the  applicant  can 
project  that  revenues  will  exceed  expenses  by  40  percent  in  the  first  year,  a 
hearing  will  be  denied.  In  our  judgment  this  burden  of  proof  has  no  proper 
relationship  to  the  question  of  whether  or  not  the  application  should  be  heard. 

Another  proposed  standard  would  deny  a  hearing  unless  the  applicant  could 
show  that  it  would  not  divert  more  than  35  percent  of  the  incumbent  carrier's 
traflSc.  This  may  or  may  not  be  adequate  grounds  for  denying  an  application 
after  a  hearing,  but  the  fact  is  that,  in  the  absence  of  public  hearing  delving 
into  the  question  of  the  incumbent's  service  in  the  market,  it  is  simply  not 
possible  to  determine  an  acceptable  level  of  diversion. 

In  short,  the  alternatives  suggested  by  the  CAB  staff  would  seem  likely  to 
merely  memorialize  the  in  camera  process  that  North  Central  and  others  in  the 
industry  have  experienced  during  the  past  several  years. 

What  then  are  the  other  alternatives?  In  an  ideal  world  of  course  priority  of 
hearing  standards  would  not  be  required  because  the  Board  would  be  compelled 
to  set  down  and  hear  all  applications  in  literal  compliance  with  the  "speedily  as 
possible"  language  of  the  statute.  However,  this  is  a  "luxury"  which  the  appro- 
priations process  has  never  seen  fit  to  provide,  apparently  on  the  assumption 
that,  if  all  applications  were  heard  promptly,  time  and  money,  both  governmental 
and  nongovernmental,  would  be  wasted. 


11  For  example.  North  Central  recently  filed  an  application  for  Chicago-New  Orleans 
nonstop  fiuthority  together  with  a  m  icion  fcr  expedition.  The  market  ia  similar  to 
Milwaukee-PhlladelpMa  In  chat  compttltive  service  was  authorized  only  a  few  years  ago 
but  has  since  disappeared. 

12  Section  10(e)  of  the  Administrative  Procedure  Act  (5  U.S.C.  706)  confers  the  ability 
to  seek  a  mandatory  injunction  to  "compel  agency  action  unlawfully  withheld  or  unreason- 
ably delayed."  See  International  Assn.  of  Mech.&A.  Wkrs.  v.  N.M.B..  425  F.2d  527  (D.C. 
Cir.  1970)  ;  Kessler  v.  FCC,  326  F.2d  673  (D.C.  Cir.  1963)  ;  Harvey  Radio  Laboratories  v. 
U.S.  &  FCC,  289  F.2d  458  (D.C.  Cir.  1961)  ;  Bearing  Milliken,  Inc.  v.  Johnston,  295  F.2d 
856  (4th  Cir.  1961). 

13  See  City  of  San  Antonio  v.  CAB,  374  F.?d  326.  329  (D.C.  Cir.  1967);  Frontier 
Airlines.  Inc.  v  CAB  349,  F.2d  587,  591  (10th  Cir.  1965)  ;  Great  Lakes  Airlines,  Inc.  v. 
CAB.  293  F.2d  153  (D.C.  Cir.  1S61 ). 

1*  CAB,  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  The  Domestic  Route  System  :  Analysis  and  Policy 
Recommendations  (October  1974). 


580 

Assuming  that  the  CAB  continues  to  function  without  the  resources  to  hear  all 
applications  speedily,  it  must  of  necessity  pick  and  choose  some  applications  for 
prompt  hearing  in  preference  to  others.  This  picking  and  choosing  must  be  pur- 
suant to  some  concept  of  public  interest.  We  think  it  not  unreasonable  that  the 
agency  should,  after  appropriate  public  proceedings,  indicate  the  specific  public 
interest  standards  it  intends  to  use  in  managing  its  docket.  To  the  extent  the 
Board's  Domestic  Route  Study  proposes  that  some  standards  be  adopted  after 
public  proceedings,  it  is  a  step  in  the  right  direction.  The  difficulty,  as  noted 
above,  is  that  the  standards  proposed  by  the  staff  would  be  such  as  to  assure 
the  de  facto  denial  of  most  applications  without  hearings. 

What  standards  would  make  sense?  We  believe  that,  at  the  outset,  any  stand- 
ards fixed  should  be  such  as  to  allow  for  hearing  the  maximum  number  of  appli- 
cations the  Board  is  physically  capable  of  handling.  Obviously,  the  standards  must 
also  be  somewhat  general  in  nature,  and  they  must  allow  for  unforeseeable  cir- 
cumstances. At  a  minimum,  however,  they  must  be  objective  in  nature,  dealing 
only  with  readily  identifiable  facts,  such  as  :  whether  the  market  has  competition  ; 
when  service  needs  in  the  market  were  last  considered  by  the  Board  ;  and  historic 
traffic  flows.  As  a  general  principle  we  do  not  beileve  the  determination  of  whether 
or  not  to  hear  an  application  should  be  made  on  the  basis  of  a  forecast,  whether 
by  a  carrier  or  the  CAB  staff.  In  route  cases,  all  forecasts  are  inherently  contro- 
versial. The  probing  of  such  controversy  is  the  function  of  the  hearing.  When 
the  Board  decides  such  matters  before  hearing,  it  robs  that  process  of  its  principal 
purpose. 

In  concluding  let  me  emphasize  that  we  fully  recognize  that  the  job  of  estab- 
lishing fair  and  reasonable  standards  for  priority  of  hearing  is  not  an  easy  one. 
The  above  comments  represent  only  our  preliminary  observations  on  this  matter. 
As  you  may  know  the  Board  has  indicated  that  it  intends  to  ask  for  formal  com- 
ments at  a  later  date  on  the  priority  standards  suggested  by  its  staff.  North  Cen- 
tral, possibly  in  conjunction  with  the  other  local  service  carriers,  expect  to  direct 
more  specific  comments  to  the  Board  at  the  appropriate  time.  Meanwhile,  how- 
ever, we  appreciate  this  opportunity  to  share  at  least  our  initial  thoughts  on 
this  problem  with  the  subcommittee,  and  we  are  hopeful  that  your  consideration 
of  this  matter  will  help  all  of  us  think  our  way  towards  a  sound  and  constructive 
solution  to  this  most  important  issue  of  administrative  procedure. 


Prepaked  Statement  of  Harvey  J.  Wexler 

Mr.  Thomas  D.  Finney,  Jr.,  Washington  counsel  for  Continental  Air  Lines  and 
a  member  of  Continental's  Board  of  Directors,  and  I  appreciate  the  opportunity 
to  appear  at  these  hearings.  They  could  not  come  at  a  more  appropriate  time.  We 
are  at  an  important  crossroads  in  the  air  transportation  industry.  The  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board  has  passed  from  the  era  of  the  sixties  when  it  encouraged 
competition  both  in  pricing  and  routes  to  a  period  of  overly-protective  action 
during  the  first  half  of  the  decade  of  the  seventies.  We  at  Continental  believe 
that  it  is  a  time  for  a  sharp  change  in  direction— time  to  return  to  giving  full 
force  and  effect  to  the  competitive  mandate  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958. 

Before  proceeding  with  the  issues  before  you  and  our  suggestion  for  a  positive 
plan  of  action  to  move  forward  in  the  public  interest,  let  me  note  that  we  have 
submitted  detailed  comments  to  your  committee's  questionnaire  of  November  20, 
1974.  Our  submission  was  sent  December  20,  1974  and  I  would  welcome  the 
opportunity  to  expand  on  any  of  the  answers  we  submitted  as  well  as  my  testi- 
mony todav.  We  have  tried  to  respond  as  fully  as  time  permitted. 

It  goes  without  saying  that  Continental  will  assist  the  subcommittee  in  any 
way  in  which  it  can.  We  recognize  that  the  Congress  has  the  ultimate  respon- 
sibility for  the  regulation  of  interstate  and  foreign  commerce.  The  major  limita- 
tion on  our  comments  today  is  that  placed  upon  us  by  the  Board's  rules  of 
conduct,  namely  not  to  seek  any  indirect  interference — outside  the  public 
recoTd— by  members  of  Congress  or  its  committees  in  pending  CAB  proceedings. 
Within  that  one  limitation,  I  will  seek  to  expose  our  basic  thinking  and  to 
answer  your  questions  fully. 

Just  about  four  years  ago.  Continental's  president.  Bob  Six  made  dear  our 
basic  view  that  competition,  in  both  service  and  rates,  is  absolutely  essential  to 
preserve  a  healthv.  effective  air  transportation  industry.  On  Febrnarv  .^.  1971, 
in  his  appearance  before  the  Aviation  Subcommittee  of  the  Senate  Commerce 


581 

Committee,  Mr.  Six  warned  against  the  airline  prophets  of  doom  and  gloom  and 
their  anticompetitive  proposals.  Let  me  begin  my  discussion  of  the  substantive 
issues  before  you  by  quoting  from  his  opening  remarks  : 

"I  would  be  the  last  person  to  tell  you  that  the  airline  industry  doesn't  have 
serious  problems.  The  management  of  every  airline  is  experiencing  great  difficul- 
ties and  a  profit  is  hard  to  come  by.  Times  are  admittedly  bad.  But  the  point  I 
want  to  stress  at  this  hearing  is  that  the  industry  can  survive  without  our 
radically  altering  the  competitive  structure  of  the  industry  or  drastically 
revamping  the  regulatory  framework. 

"The  real  cause  for  worry  is  the  disastrous  impact  on  the  industry  and  the 
public  which  would  result  from  adopting  some  of  the  solutions  being  proposed 
by  the  "Big  Four"  and  Pan  American.  We  have  serious  problems  today  at  Con- 
tinental. But,  frankly  I  am  much  more  worried  that  the  Government  might 
accept  some  of  the  big  carriers'  proposals  than  I  am  about  working  my  company 
out  of  the  current  economic  slump." 

The  situation  is  not  much  different  today.  Then,  we  were  in  the  midst  of  the 
1970-1971  recession.  Now,  we  are  in  the  midst  of  the  1974-75  recession.  There 
are  only  two  differences.  In  1971  most  airlines  had  just  finished  a  relatively  poor 
year  in  terms  of  profitability  because  of  a  serious  regulatory  lag  in  considering 
fare  increases  to  meet  escalating  costs.  In  1974,  the  efficient  carriers  had  a  reason- 
ably good  year.  Two  of  the  biggest  carriers.  Delta  and  United,  had  record  profits. 
However,  now  we  face  the  prospect  of  further  drastically  escalating  fuel  costs. 
If  the  President's  program  of  decontrol  and  import  taxes  goes  into  effect,  we 
estimate  that  our  costs  would  increase  by  $33.7  million  this  year.  It  would  take 
a  substantial  fare  increase  to  offset  this  expense.  However,  with  fares  already 
at  a  high  level,  such  an  increase  is  likely  to  drive  a  significant  amount  of  traffic 
away  from  the  airlines. 

Even  with  these  differences,  our  judgment  has  not  changed.  The  real  threat 
remains  the  anticompetitive  remedies  urged  on  the  Board  in  1971  by  the  Big 
Four  and  Pan  American,  most  of  which  unfortunately  have  been  adopted  by  the 
feoard  in  the  last  four  years.  It  is  the  continuation  of  these  anticompetitive 
policies  which  threatens  the  health  of  the  air  transportation  industry. 

The  principal  remedies  advocated  by  the  Big  Four  in  the  1970-1971  period,  as 
discussed  by  Mr.  Six  were  mergers,  capacity  agreements,  controls  on  in-flight 
services,  a  moratorium  on  new  route  awards,  and  the  imposition  of  further  limi- 
tations on  the  supplemental  carriers.  He  opposed  all  of  these  solutions  then  and 
we  oppose  them  now. 

A  majority  of  the  Board — and  I  emphasize  majority  because  there  has  been  a 
healthy  disagreement  among  the  members — have  put  into  effect  all  but  one  of 
these  solutions.  Fortunately,  the  merger  of  health  trunklines  was  denied  in  the 
American- Western  and  Northwest-National  merger  cases.  We  took  a  major  role 
in  opposing  these  mergers. 

In  addition  to  these  anticompetitive  remedies,  the  Board  has  stifled  fare  com- 
petition. It  brought  an  end  to  the  promotional  fares,  which  were  so  successful  in 
generating  traffic  in  the  mid  and  late  sixties.  Only  recently  has  the  Board  realized 
that  new  promotional  fares  are  needed  to  stimulate  sagging  traffic  but  it  has 
approved  them  only  on  a  highly  restricted  basis. 

In  addition,  the  Board  now  seeks  to  kill  our  economy  fare.  This  is  an  un- 
restricted low  fare  available  in  all  of  Continental's  markets — and  only  in  Conti- 
nental's markets  on  the  U.S.  mainland.  The  fare  is  presently  10  percent  below 
coach  and  we  have  asked  to  increase  the  discount  to  15  percent  below  coach 
to  stimulate  traffic  in  these  bad  economic  times.  Instead,  the  Board  is 
seeking  to  force  us  to  increase  the  fare  to  a  maximum  differential  of  .$4  and 
eliminate  it  altogether  on  nonmeal  flights.  This  would  destroy  the  marketability 
of  the  fare  and  effectively  force  us  to  eliminate  it  entirely.  We  have  appealed 
the  Board's  action  to  the  U.S.  Court  of  Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia.  We 
also  presently  have  before  the  Court  the  issue  of  the  Board's  route  freeze  and  its 
seating  standards.  We  have  raised  the  issue  of  the  inconsistency  of  all  three 
actions  with  the  competitive  mandate  of  the  Act. 

This  brings  me  to  the  heart  of  the  issues  before  you  in  this  phase  of  your  hear- 
ing, namely  the  Board's  route  policies.  I  have  agreed  to  testify  again  in  the  pha.se 
dealing  with  the  Board's  ratemaking  process.  So  I  will  direct  my  remarks  today 
principally  to  the  Board's  route  policies  and  the  policy  of  "open  entry"  suggested 
by  some  prior  Administration  witnes.ses. 

Continental  firmly  believes  that  the  regressive  policies  adopted  by  the  Board 
must  come  to  an  end.  Specifically,  we  urge  the  following  changes: 


582 

(1)  Expanding  service  to  the  public.  The  Board  has  had  a  freeze  on  new  route 
awards  since  1969.  This  freeze  was  never  justified  and  should  be  brought  to  an 
end.  The  oft-heard  generalization  that  the  economic  problems  of  air  carriers 
are  the  result  of  too  much  competition  in  the  air  transportation  system  is  non- 
sense. The  route  awards  of  the  1960s  were  in  no  way  responsible  for  the  losses 
carriers  sustained  during  the  19(0-1971  recession.  During  that  period,  the 
smaller,  more  efficient  carriers  pulled  through  with  small  profits.  It  was  the  big 
carriers  who  suffered.  They  simply  couldn't  respond  to  changed  economic  con- 
ditions with  sufficient  rapidity  because  of  their  size.  Moreover,  the  two  carriers 
which  suffered  the  greatest  number  of  new  route  awards  to  other  carriers  in 
their  major  markets,  namely  Delta  and  United,  have  remained  highly  profitable. 
The  reason  is  that  they  are  well  managed  and  even  the  substantial  new  route 
awards  of  the  late  sixties  are  relatively  insignificant  in  their  economic  impact 
on  the  incumbents  or  the  carriers  granted  awards. 

The  prime  beneficiary  of  new  route  awards  is  the  public.  New  route  awards 
are  essential  to  assure  the  continued  growth  of  a  network  of  air  transportation 
10  meet  the  needs  of  all  communities.  New  route  awards  also  assure  a  com- 
petitive industry,  responsive  to  the  public  needs.  Carriers  will  provide  effective 
service  so  long  as  the  threat  of  additional  carrier  certification  hangs  over  their 
head.  Without  that  threat,  we  become  lax  and  seek  to  extract  maximum  profits 
from  our  routes,  often  at  the  public  expense.  Moreover,  new  route  awards 
are  the  proverbial  carrot  that  keeps  us  pulling  our  carts.  They  are  the  incentive 
for  efficient  operation  and  a  high  quality  of  public  service. 

I  might  note  that  the  recent  study  published  by  the  Board's  staff  purporting 
to  set  standards  for  route  awards  in  the  future  is  no  more  than  an  outgrowth 
of  the  Board's  recent  regressive  policies.  The  study  proceeds  from  the  wrong 
policy  objective :  the  protection  of  carrier  profitability.  The  underlying  objective 
should  be  to  meet  the  needs  of  the  markets  and  to  properly  serve  the  public. 
For  example,  the  study  urges  that  competition  not  be  certificated  unless  the 
incumbent  has  a  6  percent  overall  rate  of  return.  That  has  nothing  to  do  with 
need  of  a  particular  market.  The  study  also  urges  that  competition  should 
only  be  certificated  when  the  incumbent  and  the  new  carrier  can  each  achieve 
a  12  percent  rate  of  return  in  the  market  involved  for  the  first  year  of  competi- 
tive operation.  This  substitutes  carrier  profits  for  public  service  and  the  benefits 
of  competition.  The  study  also  urges  achievement  of  a  55  percent  load  factor 
before  competition  can  be  certificated.  Load  factor  alone  is  not  the  test  of 
whether  a  market  needs  or  can  reasonably  support  competitive  service.  These 
standards  ignore  years  of  Board  precedents  recognizing  "the  statutory  need  for 
competition  as  a  stimulus  to  provide  good  service  to  the  public  and  to  develop 
a  sound  air  transportation  system." 

As  Congress  and  the  Board  have  recognized  in  the  past,  competition  is  bene- 
ficial in  and  of  itself.  In  the  Board's  own  words,  "competition  invites  comparison 
as  to  equipment  cost,  personnel,  organization,  methods  of  operation,  solicitation 
and  handling  of  traffic,  and  the  like,  all  of  which  tend  to  insure  the  development 
of  an  air  transportation  system  as  contemplated  by  the  Act."  These  important 
benefits  of  competition  seemed  to  have  been  overlooked  by  the  Board  in  the  recent 
past. 

(2)  The  Board  should  take  immediate  steps  to  liberalize  carrier  operating  au- 
thority. Every  carrier  is  hampered  in  its  service  by  outmoded  restrictions,  imposed 
years  ago.  Tlie  justifications  for  many  of  these  restrictions  have  disappeared,  yet 
the  restrictions  hamper  us  in  meeting  public  service  needs  and  operating  more 
efficiently.  The  Board  undertook  a  program  to  consider  restriction  removal,  but 
this  program  stalled  out.  The  Board  removed  only  a  few  restrictions  that  were 
non  controversial.  Others,  to  which  there  was  opposition  which  required  a  hearing, 
were  never  set  for  hearing — a  byproduct  of  the  Board's  route  freeze. 

(3)  The  Board  should  stop  trying  to  manage  carrier  .service  policies.  Its  restric- 
tive seating  standards  controvert  the  statutory  mandate  to  leave  schedules,  equip- 
ment, accommodations,  and  facilities  to  the  discretion  of  carrier  management.  At 
the  same  time,  the  Board  should  be  encouraged  to  set  standards  of  efficiency  for 
determining  rates.  We  supported  the  adoption  of  such  standards  and  the  expan- 
.sion  of  the  elements  of  carrier  efficiency  to  be  tested.  The  Board  should,  however, 
leave  actual  operating  decisions  to  carrier  management.  Any  carrier  that  fails  to 
operate  efficiently  within  the.se  standards  will  sustain  losses,  but  the  public  won't 
bear  the  cost  of  inefficiency.  Any  carrier  that  operates  with  a  higher  than  average 


583 

degree  of  efficiency  will  be  free  to  either  profit  from  that  efficiency,  or  offer  the 
public  better  service  or  lower  fares,  or  a  combination  thereof. 

(4)  The  Board  should  give  the  carriers  much  greater  freedom  to  experiment 
with  promotional  fares  and  to  compete  with  lower  fares.  The  Board's  present 
policies  are  too  restrictive  and  put  a  damper  on  experimentation  which  benefits 
the  public  and  benefits  the  industry.  We  supported  and  continue  to  support 
fare  flexibility  within  at  least  a  zone  of  reasonableness,  as  urged  by  the 
Departments  of  Justice  and  Transportation. 

(5)  The  anticompetitive,  capacity  restraint  agreements  should  be  brought  to  an 
end.  These  agreements  were  approved  on  an  emergency  basis  due  to  the  failure 
of  the  Bi,.^  Tiiree  and  i  an  Am  in  1970  to  respond  with  suflScient  rapidity  to 
economic  adversity.  They  have  been  extended  with  the  rationale  of  fuel  con- 
servation. Today,  they  have  simply  no  justification.  However,  in  the  recent  words 
of  a  majority  of  the  Board,  they  have  become  the  "status  quo."  All  they  do  now 
is  eliminate  competition  between  the  Big  Three  in  their  major  competitive  mar- 
kets and  give  each  of  them  tremendous  new  competitive  power  in  other  markets 
for  use  against  smaller  carriers.  Surely,  United  Airlines  with  a  record  profit 
of  $86.4  million  in  1974  and  $400  million  in  cash  does  not  need  the  protection 
of  these  anticompetitive  agreements. 

None  of  these  changes  require  any  legislative  section.  In  fact,  all  are  con- 
sistent with  the  existing  statutory  requirements,  key  among  which  is  the  com- 
petitive mandate  of  section  102(d).  All  of  these  regressive  Board  policies 
requiring  reversal  presently  are  being  tested  before  the  U.S.  Court  of  Appeals 
for  the  District  of  Columbia  on  the  basis  that  they  are  contrary  to  the  statute. 
We  have  three  such  actions  pending,  as  I  mentioned  earlier.  The  Justice  De- 
partment is  contesting  the  capacity  restraint  agreements. 

If  the  Board  does  not  voluntarily  change  its  direction  soon,  and  is  not  required 
to  do  so  by  the  Court,  then  legislative  action  might  become  necessary.  Such 
action,  hosvever,  need  only  reinforce  the  successful  statutory  scheme  already 
adopted  and  should  consist  of  the  following  elements  : 

(1)  State  clearly  in  section  102  of  the  Act  that  there  is  a  statutory  mandate 
in  favor  of  competition.  Section  102(d)  directs  Board  action  to  promote  competi- 
tion. AVhen  enacted.  Congress  made  clear  that  this  was  intended  as  a  competi- 
tive mandate.  The  Board  for  years  so  interpreted  it.  But  recently,  a  majority 
of  the  members  have  put  the  emphasis  on  the  qualifying  clause  which  states  "to 
the  extent  necessary."  The  Board  has  gone  so  far  as  to  thrust  aside  its  own 
precedents  recognizing  the  existence  of  a  mandate  in  favor  of  competition  and 
enunciating  a  presumption  to  the  effect  The  mandate  can  be  made  even  clearer, 
if  the  Board  persists  in  its  present  position. 

(2)  State  clearly  in  section  401(e)  that  the  Board  cannot  interfere  indirectly 
with  management  discretion  in  schedules,  equipment,  accommodations,  and  fa- 
cilities, through  its  ratemaking  process.  Again,  the  change  should  not  be  neces- 
sary. We  believe  the  statute  is  clear  and  recent  action  by  the  U.S.  Court  of 
Appeals  for  the  District  of  Columbia  supports  this  position.  But  if  the  Board  re- 
mains reluctant  to  permit  needed  competition,  more  explicit  congressional  direc- 
tion may  be  required. 

(3)  State  clearly  in  section  1002(e)  that  in  considering  proposals  for  promo- 
tional fares  or  reduced  basic  fares,  the  Board  must  take  into  account  the  genera- 
tive impact  of  such  fares  on  traffic.  Again  the  statute  would  appear  to  be  clear 
enough,  but  the  Board  has  taken  the  position  that  fares  must  be  strictly  cost- 
related,  except  for  short-term  promotional  fares.  If  the  Board  persists  in  this 
position,  it  will  need  clearer  congressional  direction. 

(4)  Modify  the  Act  to  permit  carrier  freedom  to  set  fares  within  a  zone  a 
reasonableness  to  be  established  by  the  Board.  The  Board  could  do  this  under  its 
exi-sting  authority  but  rejected  this  approach,  as  recommended  by  the  Depart- 
ments of  Justice  and  Transportation  and  a  few  of  the  carriers  including  Con- 
tinental. If  the  carriers  are  to  be  free  to  set  fares  within  a  zone,  legislative  action 
is  required. 

There  is  one  other  statutory  change  that  would  materially  improve  the  com- 
petitive climatp.  That  is  modifi«^ati'''n  of  section  414  of  the  Act  granting  antitrust 
immunity.  We  agree  with  the  Department  of  Justice  that  this  section  needs  to  be 
changed.  The  Board  unfortunately  has  not  given  adequate  weight  to  the  views 
of  the  Justice  Department,  which  has  actively  sought  to  protect  the  public  in- 
terest through  this  period  of  regressive  agency  action  by  participation  in  CAB 


584 

proceedings.  One  way  to  assure  that  this  will  not  happen  again  is  to  remove  the 
antitrust  immunity  created  by  section  414 — at  least  to  the  extent  that  action 
by  the  CAB  approving  agreements  would  not  preclude  the  Justice  Department 
from  bringing  an  action  against  the  parties  under  the  antitrust  laws.  Section  4i4 
might  be  retained  to  protect  parties  to  an  agreement  from  subsequent  private 
suits  following  a  hearing  and  CAB  approval. 

Thus,  it  is  our  view  that  a  significant  change  in  direction  is  needed  and  can  be 
obtained  to  a  large  extent  unuer  the  present  statute.  If  changes  are  necessary, 
they  are  largely  changes  to  reinforce  procompetitive  provisions  already  set  forth 
in  the  statute.  The  only  change  in  the  statute  that  is  necessary  is  a  mouification 
of  the  antitrust  immunity. 

Xnis  bungs  me  to  tue  issue  of  "open  entry."  We  agree  with  the  Departments  of 
Justice  ana  Transportation  that  a  change  in  the  competitive  environment  is 
necessary.  I'm  afraid,  however,  they  would  get  rid  of  the  bugs  in  the  house  by 
burning  it  down,  rather  than  simply  resorting  to  fumigation. 

Open  entry  might  vvorK  were  we  starting  from  scratch.  I  would  note,  however, 
that  prior  to  the  1938  Act  conditions  in  the  infant  air  transportation  industry 
were  chaotic.  There  was  a  serious  lack  of  safety  and  a  large  element  oi  economic 
uncertainty,  with  many  carriers  in  serious  trouble  and  falling  by  the  w  ayside.  A 
cohesive  system  of  transportation  to  serve  the  public  was  nonexistent. 

More  recently,  contrary  to  the  generally  held  view,  open  entry  did  not  work 
among  intrastate  carriers  in  California.  That  experiment  began  over  25  years  ago. 
Most  of  the  carriers  went  bankrupt — 14  in  all.  In  fact,  I  understand  that  United 
and  Western  often  found  themselves  faced  with  thousands  of  passengers  who 
had  a  return  ticket  on  a  carrier  that  was  no  longer  in  existence.  But  for  their 
generosity,  the  passengers  would  have  had  trouble  getting  home. 

This  is  not  to  detract  from  the  success  of  PSA  or  Air  California.  We  at  Con- 
tinental have  great  respect  for  pioneers  and  innovators.  Kenneth  Friedkin  of 
PSA  was  both.  He  did  a  great  job.  But  his  experience  is  hardly  the  basis  for  a 
generalization  about  our  national  air  transportation  network.  He  had  a  number 
of  unique  benefits. 

Let  me  mention  a  few  facts  that  are  often  forgotten  in  citing  PSA's  success 
story.  First,  PSA  began  in  the  high  density  San  Francisco-Los  Ange'es-San  Diego 
markets.  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles  is  the  largest  market  in  the  world — by  a 
wide  margin.  PSA  had  no  service  responsibilities  to  smaller  communities.  Second, 
for  many  years  PSA  got  a  real  benefit  in  operating  costs — about  a  25  percent  edge 
over  its  competitors,  by  operating  under  visual  rather  than  instrument  flight 
rules  into  the  congested  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  International  airports. 
The  certificated  carriers,  all  of  which  had  agreed  to  operate  under  positive  con- 
trol, were  subject  to  an  average  of  15-minute  delay  since  they  operated  under 
instrument  control.  In  contrast  PSA  was  permitted  to  pop  in  and  out  of  these 
approximately  one  hour  flight  segments,  thereby  saving  substantial  amounts  in 
operating  expense.  Third,  PSA  had  no  unions  and  paid  its  pilots  and  crews  on  a 
piece-meal  basis — a  specified  amount  per  trip.  FourtJi,  PSA  was  free  of  regulation 
on  ticket  sales.  It  used  hotel  doormen  and  bellhops,  noncoms  at  the  San  Diego  and 
San  Francisco  Naval  Bases  and  anyone  who  would  peddle  its  tickets.  Fifth,  and 
of  great  importance,  PSA  and  Air  California  are  carefully  protected  from  com- 
petition by  new  entrants  by  the  California  Public  Utility  Commission  and  have 
been  so  protected  for  almost  10  years.  Thus,  PSA  is  the  example  of  how  a 
specialist  can  enter  the  air  transportation  field,  pick  a  few  dense  markets,  and 
provide  service  on  a  highly  profitable  basis  at  lower  fares.  But,  it  is  no  argu- 
ment for  unregulated,  open  entry. 

PSA  has  had  a  highly  protected  and  special  position.  No  other  intrastate 
carrier  has  been  permitted  to  compete  with  PSA  and  vice  versa.  Open  entry 
also  has  not  worked  well  in  the  air-taxi  indtistry.  A  large  number  of  carriers 
have  gone  in  and  out  of  business.  The  public  served  by  them  end  up  with  un- 
certainty in  their  air  service.  Assuring'  such  certainty  to  the  public  was  a  major 
reason  for  certificating  Air  New  England  to  provide  needed  service  to  fill  the  gap 
created  when  Northeast  was  merged  out  of  existence. 

In  considering  this  subject,  I  also  ask  you  to  bear  in  mind  that  our  certificates 
confer  an  obligation  as  well  as  a  benefit.  We  have  good  markets  ;  we  have  mediocre 
markets;  and  we  have  poor  markets.  But,  we  must  serve  them  all.  And.  we  live 
in  a  fishbowl.  If  we  don't  meet  our  obligations,  the  Board  will  quickly  hear 
about  it.  So  long  as  there  is  a  real  threat  of  new  competition  being  certificated 


585 

and  we  are  rewarded  for  good  service  and  efficient  operation  by  new  route  oppor- 
tunities, we'll  do  our  job  well— serving  the  thin  routes  as  well  as  the  fat  ones. 
We  even  have  the  incentive  to  undertake  developmental  responsibilities,  such 
as  Continental's  pioneering  service  to  :\[icronesia  and  our  pioneering  effort  to 
develop  service  between  Seattle-Portland  and  the  so-called  satellite  airports 
in  the  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  areas.  We  perform  these  tasks  with  the 
hope  that  our  good  efforts  will  lead  to  new,  significant  route  opportunities. 

The  theory  of  the  present  system  is  to  create  a  total  air  transportation  net- 
work— to  bring  fast,  convenient  service  to  every  community  that  can  possibly 
support  it.  At  the  outset,  new  services  often  are  marginal  or  may  even  be 
operated  at  a  loss.  Some  come  around  quickly  ;  some  get  cross-subsidized  for 
quite  awhile  by  our  profitable  operations.  But  the  service  is  provided  and  a  very 
complete  network  has  been  established.  This  permits  the  develompent  of  the 
economy  of  our  smaller  as  well  as  our  large  and  intermediate-sized  communities. 

When  you  look  at  the  results,  the  situation  begins  to  come  into  perspective. 
We  have  established  an  unusually  complete  air  transportation  network,  more 
complete  than  anywhere  else  in  the  world.  Moreover,  it  is  a  relatively  efficient 
operation.  Our  present  competitive  system  has  brought  the  lowest  cost  to  the 
public  of  any  air  transportation  system  in  the  world.  Illustrative  comparisons 
are  shown  on  appendix  A. 

Further,  the  assertion  that  there  have  been  no  new  entrants  is  inaccurate.  Use 
of  numbers  alone  is  deceptive.  In  1938,  there  was  no  local  service  carrier  indus- 
try as  such.  Today,  there  are  8  regional  carriers.  In  1938,  there  were  no  supple- 
mentals.  Today  there  are  10  supplemental  carriers.  In  1133,  many  of  the  trunk- 
line  carriers  were  tiny  and  had  limited  responsibilities.  For  example,  we  served 
only  624  route  miles  and  a  geographic  area  covering  8  cities  in  3  states.  Today, 
as  the  smallest  trunkline,  we  serve  17,020  route  miles  and  31  cities  in  14  states, 
excluding  Micronesia.  In  addition,  there  are  today  two  neA  elements:  the  intra- 
state carriers  principally  in  Texas  and  California  and  a  large  number  of  air- 
taxi  operators.  Compared  to  any  other  transportation  system,  this  is  a  highly 
competitive  system.  And,  the  public  is  getting  a  high-quality  service  at  reason- 
able prices. 

We  have  given  considerable  thought  to  what  would  happen  if  we  were  to 
move  from  the  present  system  of  route  security  to  a  system  of  a  generally  uncon- 
trolled open  entry.  I  hope  we  havent  become  so  hide-bound  in  this  industry  as  to 
lose  sight  of  the  nerd  for  innovation  and  change.  After  all.  Continental  under  the 
leadership  of  Bob  Six  got  to  where  it  is  today  by  bucking  the  system— pressing 
for  new  opportunities  and  greater  competitive  freedom,  'that's  why  we're  fighting 
so  hard  today  against  what  we  regard  as  anticompetitive  Board  policies.  We  re- 
gard their  overlv-protective  policies  as  rortrary  to  the  public  interest.  We  want 
them  changed.  We  want  more  freedom  and  are  fully  prepared  to  seek  more  free- 
dom for  others. 

In  our  judgment,  however,  open-entry  and  freedom  of  air  carriers  to  serve  any 
market  they  choose  would  be  a  tragic  mistake.  Whatever  theoretical  studies  may 
indicate,  we  believe  the  practical  consequences  would  be  disastrous. 

First  and  foremost,  I  think  we  would  risk  losing  many  of  the  links  in  the  net- 
work of  air  service  that  have  been  so  carefully  created,  as  each  of  us  scurried  to 
avail  ourselves  of  what  we  believed  to  be  the  most  profitable  opportunities. 
Moreover,  there  would  be  a  constant  shifting  of  our  service  to  improve  our  profits. 
The  situation  for  the  traveling  public  and  shippers  is  likely  to  be  chaotic.  Smaller 
communities  are  bound  to  suffer  from  service  gaps  and,  even  more  significant,  un- 
certainties in  their  air  service.  The  result  would  be  to  stifle  the  growth  of  these 
communities.  Industry  would  tend  once  again  to  cluster  around  the  major  cities 
where  transportation  needs  would  more  likely  be  met  with  some  continuity.  To 
get  reasonably  good  ser\ice  to  smaller  communities  would  probably  require  heavy 
government  subsidization. 

Second,  the  threat  of  oligopoly  in  this  industry  would  increa.se.  Without  se- 
curity of  routes,  smaller  units  would  have  difficulty  surviving.  There  might  well 
be  a  lot  of  small  entities  going  in  and  out  of  business,  as  occurred  in  the  Cali- 
fornia intrastate  situation  and  in  the  air-taxi  business.  But  the  major  elements 
serving  the  mass  of  the  public  are  likely  to  be  reduced  to  a  very  small  number. 
Predatory  practices  by  the  biggest  carriers  would  be  difficult  to  control  as  car- 
riers shifted  from  market  to  market.  Consider  for  example  the  economic  power 
of  United  Airlines  with  over  $400  million  today  in  cash  and  liquid  securities. 


586 

In  an  open-entry  situation,  they  could  control  markets  at  will.  In  a  regulated 
situation,  they  are  under  much  more  significant  restraints  not  to  abuse  their 
substantial  power.  You  must  remember  that  to  operate  larger  jets  substantial 
financing  is  required.  Without  security  of  routes,  I  can't  imagine  the  bankers 
and  insurance  companies  lending  the  millions  of  dollars  needed  for  ground  and 
air  equipment  required  in  our  business.  If  I'm  right  you'd  end  up  with  a  few 
large,  high-cost  operators  serving  most  of  the  public.  This  would  inevitably  lead 
to  higher  prices  and  a  lower  quality  of  service. 

Third,  technological  development  might  be  stifled.  Manufacturers  won't  build 
new  aircraft  without  firm  orders  in  advance  of  production  from  financially 
secure  purchasers.  There  thus  has  been  no  significant  development  of  new  air- 
craft for  the  air-taxi  end  of  our  industry. 

Fourth,  is  the  impracticality  of  the  free  movement  among  markets  presumed 
by  the  proponents  of  open-entry.  No  one  suggests  freedom  in  international  routes. 
This  means  that  only  those  carriers  without  international  routes  would  be  with- 
out any  route  security.  This  would  put  a  carrier  like  Continental  at  a  grossly 
unfair  position  vis-a-vis  a  carrier  with  a  strong  international  route  structure. 
We  would  have  no  anchor.  They  would.  They  could  direct  their  attention  to  do- 
mestic markets  feeding  into  their  international  routes,  creating  a  strong  eco- 
nomic base  for  their  operations.  We  would  be  left  to  fend  without  such  a  base. 
This  could  result  in  a  domestic  route  system  principally  geared  to  serve  inter- 
national routes. 

The  nub  of  it  is  that  we  have  a  reasonably  successful  air  transportation  system 
today.  I  urge  that  we  try  to  make  it  work  better  before  substituting  another 
system. 

Let  me  add  that  we  don't  oppose  new  entry  into  the  industry.  What's  happened 
in  New  England,  for  example,  justified  new  entry.  Other  new  entrants  may  be 
called  for  to  meet  special  ne^^ds  or  merely  to  assure  the  continued  healthy  spur 
of  competition  to  the  industry.  We  have  no  objection  to  congressional  pressure  on 
the  Board  to  consider  the  applications  of  new  entrants  for  certificate  authority ; 
but  we  must  recognize  that  without  the  security  of  a  certificate,  financing  neces- 
sary to  success  is  difl5cult  to  obtain  on  a  continuing  and  reasonable  basis. 

The  Board  has  been  lax  in  this  area.  They  have  been  unwilling  to  consider 
the  applications  of  new  entrants  even  in  good  times.  Maybe  legislation  is  neces- 
sary to  force  them  to  do  so.  We  would  welcome  the  opportunity  to  work  with 
Congress  to  suggest  legislation  to  require  such  consideration.  But  this  is  a  far  cry 
from  open  entry  and  the  unlimited  freedom  of  carriers  to  choose  which  they  will 
serve  and  which  they  will  abandon. 

Let  me  close  on  a  positive  note.  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  in  a  1950  decision 
stated  that : 

"An  objective  reading  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  leaves  no  doubt  that  the 
lawmakers  considered  competition  to  be  a  desirable  objective  which  should  be 
established  wherever  it  is  economically  feasible  and  will  contribute  to  the  de- 
velopment of  a  sound  national  air  transportation  system." 

It's  time  to  return  to  this  kind  of  positive  orientation  to  permit  continued 
growth  and  development  of  our  air  transportation  system.  It's  time  to  bring  an 
end  to  the  recent  period  of  regressive  policies.  I  hope  that  this  subcommittee  and 
this  Congress  will  bring  its  energies  to  bear  to  this  end.  But  we  have  a  basically 
sound  system  and  good  statutory  framework.  Let's  try  to  make  it  work  as  the 
Congress  intended  in  1958  before  radically  altering  it  and  destroying  our  ex- 
cellent network  of  air  transportation. 


587 

APPENDIX  A 
COMPARATIVE  UNITED  STATES  AND  FOREIGN  COACH  FARES 


Market 


Lcndon-Paris 

Lubj  ck-Lawton 

Lon.on-Frankfurt 

Colorado  Springs  -Wichita. 

Lisbon-Milan 

Houston-Phoenix 

Athens-Amsterdam 

Kansas  City-Poitland 

Osaka-Seoul 

Amarilb-Houslon 

Tokyo-Seoul. 

El  Paso-Los  Angeles 

Taipei-Tokyo 

New  Orleans-Phoenix 

Hong  Kong-Tokyo 

Chicago-Los  Angeles 

Brisbane-Sidney 

Tu'sa-Houston 

r  ert  i-Adelaide 

New  Orleans-Phoenix 

Darwi  i-Adelaide 

San  Fiancisco-Houston... 


209 

$55. 17 

205 

26.65 

400 

87.90 

404 

44.44 

1,037 

158.67 

1,010 

87.04 

1,466 

237.48 

1,481 

117.59 

511 

79.12 

518 

bl.85 

725 

105. 66 

714 

63.89 

1,304 

151.39 

1,301 

104. 63 

1,788 

237. 87 

1,744 

135. 19 

465 

51.20 

423 

45.37 

1.316 

130. 30 

1,301 

104. 63 

1,630 

164. 00 

1,636 

128.70 

'  Based  upon  rate  of  exchange  as  of  Feb.  11, 1975. 

Note:  Intra-Canada  fares  approximate  those  of  the  United  States.   The  Canadian  fare  structure  is  more  tapered  than  the 
Unied  States,  i.e.,  Canadian  short-haul  fares  are  higher  than  the  United  States. 


DIALOG  BETWEEN  CONTINENTAL  AIRLINES  AND  DR.  WILLIAM  A.  JORDAN  ON 
THE  SUBJECT  OF  CALIFORNIA  INTRASTATE  AIRLINES 

[On  February  14,  1975,  Dr.  William  A.  Jordan  testified  concerning 
the  low- fare  air  service  in  California  provided  by  intrastate  carriers 
not  regulated  by  the  CAB.  See  p.  452  ff.,  above.  During  the  hearing 
of  February  18,  1975  Senator  Kennedy  asked  Continental  Airlines  to 
comment  on  Dr.  Jordan's  testimony.  Mr.  James  L,  Mitchell,  vice  presi- 
dent of  regulatory  proceedings,  responded  for  Continental.  Dr.  Jordan 
replied,  and  Continental  commented  further.  These  materials  follow  in 
chronological  order.] 

Prepared  Statement  of  James  L.  Mitchell 

March  31,  1975 

The  purpose  of  this  statement  is  to  respond  to  the  request  made  by  Senator 
Kennedy  to  Mr.  Harvey  J.  Wexler,  senior  vice  president  for  international  and 
governmental  affairs  of  Continental  when  he  testified  before  the  subcommittee 
on  February  18,  1975.  The  request  was  for  any  comments  Continental  might  have 
regarding  the  analysis  of  the  California  intrastate  situation  presented  to  the 
subcommittee  by  William  A.  Jordan  on  February  14, 1975. 


588 

I  have  closely  observed  the  California  intrastate  situation  over  my  past  29 
years  in  the  air  transportation  industry.  From  March  4,  1946  to  September  1, 
1968,  I  held  various  positions  in  Western  Airlines,  dealing  principally  with  air- 
line scheduling,  market  research,  route  analysis,  and  the  preparation  of  route  and 
rate  cases.  I  began  in  Western's  Los  Angeles  ticket  office.  From  mid-1947  to  mid- 
1949,  I  was  manager  of  sales  control  and  research.  Two  of  my  major  functions 
were  aircraft  scheduling  and  the  analysis  of  traffic  and  sales  data  to  deter- 
mine allocation  of  sales  and  advertising  expenditures.  On  July  15,  1949,  I  be- 
came director  of  research  and,  later,  vice  president  of  research.  My  functions  in 
this  capacity  included  the  responsibilities  of  my  previous  job  together  with  the 
responsibility  for  the  preparation,  analysis  and  presentation  of  Western's  route 
and  rate  cases  before  regulatory  agencies,  including  the  California  Public 
Utilities  Commission. 

On  September  1,  1968,  I  joined  Continental  as  staff  vice  president  of  corporate 
planning  with  responsibilities  for  all  economic  planning  projects,  including  such 
matters  as  fleet  planning,  schedule  analysis  and  advanced  route  planning.  On 
February  1,  1973,  I  became  vice  president  of  regulatory  proceedings,  where  I 
have  continued  to  work  on  advanced  planning  projects  and  have  assumed  re- 
sponsibility for  the  preparation  of  all  route  and  rate  cases. 

Throughout  my  almost  30  years  in  the  airline  industry,  I  have  resided  in  the 
Los  Angeles  area  and  have  maintained  a  close  and  continuing  interest  in  the 
California  intrastate  air  carrier  operations.  This  was  an  important  part  of  my 
job  at  Western,  inasmuch  as  Western  had  and  still  has  a  significant  operation  in 
the  California  intrastate  markets. 

It  was  in  connection  with  this  activity  at  Western  that  Professor  Jordan  did 
much  of  the  background  work  that  led  to  his  doctoral  thesis  on  the  "Economic 
Effects  of  Airline  Regulation."  In  1960,  I  hired  William  A.  Jordan  as  an  analyst 
in  Western's  research  department.  His  functions  were  to  aid  me  in  the  prepara- 
tion of  material  for  presentation  in  regulatory  matters  before  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board  and  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission.  He  worked  for 
me  in  that  capacity  until  1964,  spending  part  of  his  time  at  the  University  of 
California  on  his  doctoral  work.  I  am  thus  intimately  acquainted  with  the 
material  he  compiled  on  the  California  intrastate  carriers. 

While  at  Western,  I  also  worked  closely  with  the  California  Public  Utilities 
Commission.  In  fact,  during  1949  and  1950,  I  provided  considerable  assistance 
to  the  staff  of  the  Commission,  to  help  them  to  learn  about  the  regulation  of  air 
transportation.  Up  to  that  time,  the  Commission's  activity  had  been  focused  on 
truck  and  rail  transportation.  During  a  portion  of  their  learning  period,  the 
Commission  staff  worked  out  of  my  office. 

Since  moving  to  Continental,  I  have  maintained  my  interest  in  the  California 
intrastate  air  transportation  activity  on  a  personal  and  professional  basis. 
Shortly  after  coming  to  Continental,  I  interested  the  carrier  in  serving  the  so- 
called  "satellite"  airports  in  the  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  areas.  Con- 
tinental began  operations  at  Ontario  in  connection  with  its  Chicago-Kansas 
City-Denver-Los  Angeles  route,  and  later  was  authorized  to  provide  service 
between  the  Pacific  Northwest  terminals  of  Seattle  and  Portland  and  all  the 
satellite  airports  at  San  Francisco  (Oakland  and  San  Jose)  and  Los  Angeles 
(Burbank,  Long  Beach,  Ontario  and  Santa  Ana). 

Professor  Jordan's  studies,  conducted  largely  during  the  period  when  he 
worked  for  me  at  Western,  form  the  basis  for  his  contention  that  free  entry  and 
exit  in  the  domestic  air  transportation  system  would  significantly  benefit  the 
public.  His  position,  in  turn,  appears  to  provide  a  basis  for  the  position  on  entry 
and  exit  taken  by  the  Department  of  Justice.  See  particularly  page  18  of  Mr. 
Kauper's  testimony  of  February  6,  1975,  and  page  7  of  Mr.  Baker's  testimony  of 
February  18,  1975. 

I  believe  that  Professor  Jordan  has  accurately  and  quite  fully  set  forth  the 
history  of  the  California  intrastate  situation  prior  to  September,  1965.  I  depart 
from  him,  however,  in  the  conclusions  he  draws  from  these  facts.  His  principal 
conclusions  from  this  experience  are  that:  1)  the  intrastate  service  pattern 
produced  far  healthier  results  for  the  traveling  public  than  did  the  regulated 
U.S.  domestic  industry;  2)  absent  regulation,  there  would  be  200-300  air  car- 
riers in  the  United  States,  and  fares  would  be  lower;  and  3)  the  period  of  "ad- 
justment" after  the  institution  of  free  entry  and  exit  would  be  in  the  order  of  10 
years.  I  believe  that  the  history  he  has  compiled  refutes  these  conclusions  and, 
in  fact,  establishes  that :  1)  there  would  be  serious  instability  in  the  markets  that 
are  served,  and  many  markets  served  today  would  not  be  served;  2)  this  insta- 


589 

bility  would  not  decrease  after  an  initial  period;  3)  a  large  number  of  small 
carriers  would  enter  and  exit,  and  their  entry  and  exit  would  liave  little  to  do 
with  public  need  for  service;  4)  after  a  prolonged  "shakedown"  period  which 
would  exceed  the  20  years  experienced  in  the  comparatively  simple  California 
situation,  a  small  number  of  large  carriers  would  eventually  dominate  our  air 
transportation  system;  and  5)  over  the  long  term,  fares  would  be  higher  and 
service  would  be  inferior  to  that  existing  under  a  properly  regulated  system. 

1.  The  Relevance  of  the  California  Intrastate  Experience. — I  agree  that  the 
only  experience  that  exists  on  what  has  occurred  with  a  free  entry  and  exit  sys- 
tem in  the  air  transportation  field  is  the  California  intrastate  experience.  At  least 
for  a  20  year  period  from  1946  to  1965,  carriers  were  completely  free  to  enter  into 
and  exit  from  service  within  this  one  highly  populated  area  of  the  United  States. 
However,  there  are  some  limitations  on  generalizing  too  much  from  this  ex- 
perience. The  area  is  limited  geographically.  The  weather  conditions,  the  mileages 
involved,  and  the  high  population  density  of  the  principal  cities  served,  namely 
Los  Angeles,  San  Francisco  and  San  Diego,  present  ideal  operating 
circumstances. 

The  only  other  experiences  with  open  entry  are  the  pre-1938  era  on  a  national 
basis  and  the  air-taxi  situation.  Prior  to  1938,  there  was  no  national  regulation 
on  entry  or  exit.  At  the  time  regulation  was  instituted,  the  carriers  were  in  finan- 
cial diflScu'ty,  and  safety  problems  existed.  One  significant  purpose  of  federal 
regulation  was  to  provide  route  security  in  order  to  bring  about  greater  finnncial 
stability  in  the  air  carrier  industry.  But  commercial  aviation  was  in  its  infancy. 
Certainly,  it  is  fair  to  conclude  from  the  circumstances  that  existed  during  this 
era  that :  1)  the  lack  of  route  regulation  could  not  be  said  to  have  been  beneficial, 
and  2)  the  lack  of  safety  regulation  was  detrimental. 

The  air-taxi  situation  today  indicates  that  large  numbers  of  smaller  opera- 
tors will  enter  the  air  transportation  industry  if  permitted  to  do  so.  They  can 
serve  in  special  market  situations.  But,  they  evidence  a  considerable  lack  of 
economic  stability.  As  the  United  States  Court  of  Appeals  noted  in  Hughes 
Air  Corporation  v.  CAB.  492  F.2d  567.  577,   (D.C.  Cir.  1973)  : 

"In  fiscal  1970  the  entire  commuter  industry,  numbering  126  firms,  generated 
total  estimated  revenues  of  $70  million,  or  an  average  of  $550,000  per  firm.  A 
1970  study  done  for  the  Department  of  Transportation  found  that  the  commuter 
industry  as  a  whole  has  been  operating  at  a  loss,  with  individual  firms'  per- 
formances ranging  from  substantial  losses  to  only  slight  profitability.  The  failure 
rate  among  commuters  is  quite  high  and  old  firms  leave  and  new  ones  enter  the 
industry  regularly.''  (Emphasis  supplied.) 

Some  air  taxi  operators  who  have  achieved  stability  did  so  either  by  concen- 
trating in  high-density  vacation  markets  or  by  tying  themselves  to  a  certificated 
carrier  through  a  commuter  "feeder"  agreement  which  passes  on  the  route  secu- 
rity enjoyed  by  the  certificated  carrier. 

The  Texas  intrastate  situation  is  of  little  relevance,  since  the  sole  intrastate 
carrier  is  regulated  by  the  Texas  Aeronautics  Commission.  Southwest  Airlines 
now  operates  an  intrastate  monopoly,  similar  to  the  monopoly  intrastate  routes 
in  California. 

2.  California  Intrastate  Service  1946-1965. — Set  forth  in  appendixes  A  through 
C  is  the  information  on  the  California  intrastate  carriers  operating  during  the 
20-year-period  of  free  entry,  the  cities  served  and  the  period  of  service  both  by 
carrier  and  service.  The  information  is  obtained  from  Professor  Jordan's  book. 
When  this  information  is  displayed,  cert&in  conclusions  emerge : 

First,  while  16  carriers  entered  during  this  period.  14  of  them  exited.  In 
essence,  there  was  an  87  percent  failure  rate.  There  was  little  or  no  head-to-head 
competition  at  any  time  during  the  20  years.  One  of  the  two  surviving  carriers 
provided  only  a  specialized  Saturday  and  Sunday  service  to  Brown  Field,  a 
secondary  airport  20  miles  south  of  San  Diego,  on  the  Mexican  border.  This 
operation  was  conducted  for  the  purpose  of  carryincr  passengers  to  and  from  the 
Caliente  Racetrack  on  package  deals  for  the  operators  of  the  racetrack.  As  far  as 
truly  scheduled  service  between  the  major  California  markets  is  concerned,  the 
period  of  free  entry  produced  a  single  carrier  monopolizing  all  of  the  California 
markets.  That  single  carrier  had  evolved  as  the  only  such  carrier  by  February, 
1965,  eight  months  prior  to  the  legislation. 

Second,  most  of  the  carriers  lasted  only  a  short  period  of  timf.  Nine  carriers, 
or  56  percent  of  the  entrants,  stayed  in  business  for  periods  of  less  than  1  year. 
Seven  lasted  6  months  or  less,  and  the  other  two  lasted  only  7  and  9  months.  Of 
the  remaining  7  carriers  which  lasted  more  than  a  year,  5  lasted  less  than  2 
years. 


590 

Third,  the  carriers  came  into  existence  in  two  clusters.  Eight  came  into  exist- 
ence in  the  1-year  period  January  1949  to  January  1950.  Six  had  failed  by  May 
1950.  Another  six  came  into  existence  during  the  period  May  Ji>02  to  September 
1964.  All  went  out  of  existence  by  the  mid-sixties.  The  entry  of  these  carriers  was 
not  related  to  any  pressing  public  demand  for  intrastate  air  transportation,  but 
to  the  sudden,  easy  availability  of  excess  aircraft. 

During  the  late-forties,  cheap,  used  military  aircraft  became  available.  Virtu- 
ally all  of  the  intrastate  carriers  that  came  into  existence  in  the  1949-1950  pe- 
riod (six  out  of  eight)  were  offshoots  of  .supplemental  air  carriers  operating  used 
military  equipment  out  of  their  bases  at  Burbank  and  Oakland.  The  following  is 
a  list  of  those  relationships  : 

Intrastate  carrier  Supplemental  carrier  tie-in 

California   Central   Airlines Airline  Transport  Carrier. 

Robin  Airways Robin  Airlines. 

California   Skycoach Trans-American  Airways. 

California  Arrow Arrow  Airways. 

California  Pacific  Airlines Mercer. 

California   Coastal   Airlines Airline  Transport  Carriers. 

In  addition,  Western  Air  Lines  of  California  leased  its  aircraft  from  AVestern 
Airlines.  Even  PSA  was  not  wholly  independent.  It  was  an  offshoot  of  the 
Friedkin  School  of  Aeronautics. 

Similarly,  the  six  airlines  that  came  into  existence  in  the  1962-1964  period 
did  so  as  a  result  of  a  new  influx  of  u>ed  aircraft  into  the  market  which  had 
been  replaced  by  the  jets.  As  trunklines  moved  to  jets,  a  surplus  of  conventional, 
propeller-driven  aircraft  was  created. 

Fourth,  the  number  of  cities  of  California  served  by  the  intrastate  carriers 
was  limited.  The  principal  cities  were  Los  Angeles,  with  its  satellite  airports  of 
Burbank  and  Long  Beach ;  San  Francisco,  with  its  .satellite  airports  of  Oakland 
and  San  Jose ;  and  San  Diego.  These  are  extremely  high-density  markets,  includ- 
ing the  largest  air  transportation  market  in  the  world  (San  Francisco-Los  An- 
geles). The  other  cities  served  were  the  state  capital,  Sacramento,  and  the  cities 
of  Lake  Tahoe,  Fresno,  Palm  Springs,  Bakersfield,  Modesto,  Stockton,  and 
Van  Nuys. 

Fifth,  the  service  at  most  of  the  few  cities  involved  in  the  intrastate  carrier 
activity  received  only  sporadic  service,  and  for  very  limited  periods.  Only  the 
three  major  cities  received  any  significant  level  of  service  during  the  entire 
20-year  period.  The  Los  Angeles  area  received  intrastate  service  during  most 
of  the  period  at  the  Burbank  airport,  but  the  service  at  the  main  airport  was 
erratic  (from  1950  to  1965  with  some  interruptions  in  1955  and  1957)  and  at  Long 
Beach  was  very  limited  (1949  and  1953-1954).  The  San  Francisco  area  received 
intrastate  service  during  most  of  the  period  at  the  Oakland  and  San  Francisco 
International  Airports,  but  the  service  at  San  Jose  was  very  limited  (1962  to 
1965).  The  service  at  San  Diego  was  continuous  from  1949  to  1965.  Sacramento, 
the  state  capital,  received  very  little  service  (1946-1947,  1949,  1962).  The  other 
cities  received  even  less  service.  Lake  Tahoe  received  service  for  21 1/^  months, 
or  about  9.2  percent  of  the  time.  Fresno,  California  received  service  for  dVz 
months  in  the  aggregate  by  3  separate  carriers  or  about  3  percent  of  the  time, 
71/2  months  in  1946-1947,  1  month  in  1949,  and  1  month  in  1962.  Palm  Springs 
received  service  for  4^/^  months  or  about  2  percent  of  the  time.  Bakersfield  received 
service  for  1  month  or  one-half  of  1  percent  of  the  time.  Modesto  received  service 
for  1  month.  Stockton  received  service  for  3^/^  months.  Van  Nuys  received  service 
for  19  days. 

Thus,  the  public  in  California  had  little  by  way  of  intrastate  service  during 
this  20-year  period.  The  public  did  receive  the  benefits  of  lower  fares  in  the  high- 
density  San  Francisco-Los  Angeles-San  Diego  markets.  But,  they  received  very 
little  service  in  any  other  markets.  And,  during  this  period,  they  paid  a  significant 
price  in  the  disruption  caused  by  a  large  number  of  local  air  carriers  going  out  of 
business.  People  were  stranded  in  the  midst  of  trips,  as  carriers  went  bankrupt 
without  prior  notice  to  the  traveling  public. 

Sixth,  none  of  the  intrastate  carriers  provided  an  integrated  pattern  of  service. 
Most  of  the  service  was  conducted  between  two  pair  of  points.  No  connections  or 
interline  reservations  were  made.  These  services  were  point-to  point  operations 
provided  by  individual  carriers,  totally  divorced  from  the  operations  of  other  car- 
riers. That  situation  prevails  in  California  today.  There  is  no  effort  by  either  of 


591 

the  present  two  intrastate  carriers  to  provide  an  integrated  pattern  of  service 
between  a  series  of  marlcets.  This  is  wholly  unlike  the  integrated  system  opera- 
tions of  the  federally-certificated  air  carriers  and  their  concern  with  connections 
and  reservations  on  other  carriers,  v.hith  results  in  an  overall  integated  national 
pattern  of  air  service. 

In  conclusion,  very  little  can  be  said  about  the  number  of  air  carriers  that  would 
come  into  existence  in  an  open  entry  situation.  Most  of  the  intrastate  carriers  en- 
tered at  a  time  when  inexpensive,  surplus  aircraft  had  become  available.  That 
experience  may  or  nmy  noc  oe  repeated.  What  can  be  concluded  from  this  ex- 
perience, however,  is  that  if  200-3U0  air  carriers  were  to  come  into  existence,  as 
Professor  Jordan  projects,  they  would  do  so  on  a  scattered  basis,  unrelated  to 
pressing  market  needs.  Rather,  their  entry  vvouid  oe  concentrated  during  periods 
when  used  equipment  is  available.  The  other  conclusion  that  can  be  reached  is 
that  most  of  tae  carriers  would  quickly  fail  and  exit  from  the  field  of  air  transpor- 
tation. 

Piofessor  Jordan's  conclusion  that  the  situation  would  stabilize  after  10  years 
is  wholly  unsupported  by  the  Caliiorinia  intrastate  experience.  Events  were  in  as 
chaotic  a  state,  in  terms  of  carrier  stability,  20  years  after  the  period  of  entry 
began  as  they  were  at  the  beginning.  In  the  early  .sixties,  15  years  after  the  intra- 
state industry  began,  six  new  carriers  came  into  existence.  Five  folded  up  in 
periods  ranging  from  2  months  to  2%  years,  and  the  sixth  provided  only  weekend 
service  to  a  racetrack  for  horseracing  enthusiasts.  And  it  must  be  emphasized 
that  California  presents  an  ideal  situation  for  airline  service.  If  California  air 
service  remained  in  a  state  of  chaos  for  20  years,  the  country  as  a  whole  could 
expect  a  far  worse  period  of  instability. 

3.  Regulation  by  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commis.sion. — The  California 
PUC  began  to  regulate  entry  in  September  1965.  It  did  so  for  two  principal  rea- 
sons. First,  there  was  a  public  outcry  for  an  end  to  the  uncertainty  and  chaos 
resulting  from  the  free  entry  and  exit  of  the  intrastate  air  carriers.  The  chaotic 
situation  that  had  occurred  in  1949  and  1950,  when  six  out  of  eight  new  carriers 
failed  in  approximately  one  year  or  less,  reoccurred  during  the  period  19G2  to 
1965.  Another  six  carriers  entered  into  business  and  five  folded.  People  were  left 
stranded  in  the  midst  of  trips*,  and  had  no  assurance  of  receiving  reliable  air  serv- 
ice, xhe  resulting  public  outcry  forced  the  California  PUC  and  the  State  Legis- 
lature to  consider  action  to  get  the  situation  under  control. 

The  second  factor  was  the  plea  for  route  security  by  the  one  carrier  that  had 
succeeded  over  the  entire  iieriod,  namely  PSA.  I'SA  wanted  to  upgrade  its  iOeet 
from  Electras  to  727s  and  expand  its  oi^erations.  PSA's  management  believed  it 
could  not  obtain  the  necessary  financing  without  the  security  of  a  certificate. 

Since  the  I'UC  entered  the'  picture,  it  has  given  great  protection  to  the  regu- 
lated carriers.  Each  has  been  given  monopoly  intrastate  routes  (appendix  E).  No 
competitive  authority  has  been  authorized,  despite  carrier  efforts  to  overlay  one 
another.  Where  dual  authority  is  involved,  one  or  the  other  carrier  is  not  per- 
mitted to  carry  traffic. 

PSA  remained  as  the  strongest  intrastate  carrier  and  began  to  expand  from 
the  primary  markets  of  San  Francisco-Oakland-Los  Angeles-San  Diego,  which 
were  the  oiily  markets  served  by  PSA  during  the  period  of  free  entry  into  some 
secondary  markets.  ( See  appendix  D. )  Air  California  entered  business  in  Janu- 
ary 16,  1967,  serving  the  Santa  Ana-San  Francisco  market  exclusively.  It  later 
expanded  to  a  number  of  other  major  monopoly  routes.  (See  api>endix  E.)  The 
only  other  entrant  was  Holiday  Airlines  that  specialized  in  serving  Lake  Tahoe. 
It  went  bankrupt  earlier  this  year. 

Rates  have  increased  under  the  PUC's  regulations.  But,  a  slightly  broader 
pattern  of  -issured  intrastate  service  has  emerged  as  well. 

If.  Conclusion  from  the  California  Situation.— It  we  project  the  California 
intrastate  situation  to  the  national  scale,  what  emerges  as  reasonable  conclu.  ions 
are  the  following:  -,     ,     ,    ^ 

( 1 )  The  number  of  entrants  may  be  substantial.  Professor  Jordan  s  figure 
of  200-300  may  be  reasonable,  although  it  will  depend  more  on  availability 
of  excess,  used  equip"!ent  th.nn  on  market  demand. 

(2)  Most  of  the  carriers  will  go  out  of  busine.ss  over  periods  of  2  years  or 
less,  with  the  majority  folding  in  6  months.  .^  ^,    . 

(3)  At  most,  a  few  carrires  will  survive  and  they  will  tend  to  limit  their 
activities  to  the  densest  markets.  . 

Free  entrv  wou^d  certainly  lead  to  the  rapid  destruction  of  the  present  air 
transportation  network,  with  smaller  cities  receiving  little  if  any  .service.  The 


592 

large  number  of  entrants  may  drive  fares  down  temporarily,  but  they  will  enter 
sporadically,  with  most  exiting  rapidly.  The  public  will  be  left  with  great  uncer- 
tainty over  the  availability  of  air  service  by  an  existing  carrier  or  air  service  in 
any  given  market.  Ihis  is  the  most  that  can  be  coiiciudeu  from  the  zo  years  of 
California  intrastate  experience. 

5.  Other  Problems  of  Free  Entry. — There  are  two  other  aspects  of  the  free 
entry  concept  that  were  not  discussed  by  the  advocates  of  this  system.  This  is 
the  added  aistortion  resulting  from  protected  international  operations  at  one  end 
of  the  spectrum,  and  protected  instrastate  operations  at  the  other  end  of  the 
spectrum.  Both  act  as  a  bar  to  the  evolution  of  any  true  free  entry  and  exit  sys- 
tem and  would  seriously  distort  the  air  transportation  system  resulting  from 
applying  the  theory  of  free  entry  and  exit. 

If  entry  to  international  markets  is  to  be  controlled,  yet  free  entry  is  to  be 
permitted  in  domestic  markets,  two  distortions  would  occur.  First,  carriers  with 
strong  international  routes  would  have  a  substantial  competitive  advantage 
which  could  and  undoubtedly  would  be  used  to  improve  their  economic  position 
to  the  detriment  of  carriers  without  such  protected  routes.  In  general,  interna- 
tional routes  have  been  more  profitable  than  domestic  routes.  This  is  shown  by 
appendix  F.  Thus,  a  carrier  with  such  a  route  would  have  an  unfair  competitive 
advantage  in  relation  to  carriers  without  such  routes,  particularly  under  cir- 
cumstances in  which  all  of  their  markets  are  subject  to  free  entry.  Second,  car- 
riers with  international  routes  would  tend  to  direct  their  domestic  operations 
to  those  routes  that  flow  into  their  international  operations.  In  this  manner,  they 
would  achieve  a  further  advantage  over  competitiors  in  the  domestic  markets. 
Tliey  would  be  feeding  traffic  moving  over  the  international  leg  of  a  journey  to 
and  from  interior  points  over  domestic  operations.  The  protection  of  their 
international  operations  would  be  extended  in  a  very  real  sense  to  most  if  not 
all  of  their  domestic  operations.  Even  aside  from  the  unfair  competitive  advan- 
tage the  carrier  with  international  routes  could  thus  achieve  over  certain  do- 
mestic routes,  the  markets  these  stronger  carriers  would  tend  to  serve  would 
have  little  to  do  with  domestic  air  transportation  needs  of  the  public.  The 
markets  served  would  be  those  best  suited  to  international  travel,  and  the  serv- 
ices would  be  so  geared. 

At  the  other  end  of  the  spectrum,  the  air  transportation  system  would  be 
distorted  by  protective  action  by  state  aeronautic  boards  and  public  utility  com- 
missions. As  experience  has  demonstrated  in  California  and  Texas,  state  officials 
will  regulate  to  protect  intrastate  carriers.  If  they  continue  to  do  so  under  a 
national  system  of  open  entry  and  exit,  new  carriers  will  be  attracted  to  serve 
protected  "intrastate  markets  rather  than  unprotected  interstate  markets.  This 
would  ultimately  lead  to  the  formation  of  regulatory  commissions  in  each  state 
and  the  complications  inherent  in  40  or  more  regulatory  bodies  each  exercising 
independent  control. 

6.  Continental's  Position.— As  Continental  has  made  clear  in  its  testimony 
before  the  subcommittee,  we  do  not  oppose  new  entrants  to  the  federally-regulated 
air  transportation  industry.  In  fact,  we  believe  that  new  entrants  maintain 
vitality  in  the  industry.  They  bring  innovation,  which  means  public  benefits. 
Moreover,  the  mere  threat  of  new  entrants  being  permitted  into  the  industry 
spurs  the  incumbents  to  better  serve  the  public.  It  is  for  this  reason  that  we 
have  urged  that  the  Board  have  a  more  open  mind  "than  it  has  shown  in  the  past 
to  consider  the  applications  of  new  entrants. 

At  the  same  time,  we  believe  that  the  incumbent  carriers  must  continue  to 
have  opportunity  to  expand  both  into  domestic  and  into  international  markets. 
Such  expansion  means  a  higher  level  of  competition  with  its  resulting  benefits 
in  improved  service,  and  lower  fares.  In  addition,  so  long  as  the  air  carriers  are 
given  new  opportunities,  and  performance  is  a  significant  factor  in  awarding 
new  route  opportunitties,  the  carriers  will  be  spurred  to  better  serve  both  their 
existing  and  their  new  markets. 

We  believe  that  the  combination  of  considering  new  entrants  and  expanding 
the  authority  of  the  encumbents  will  provide  the  benefits  of  competition  being 
sought.  The  public  will  be  assured  as  complete  and  effective  a  system  of  air  trans- 
portation as  is  economically  feasible  by  the  continuation  of  the  present  system  of 
individual  carriers  being  assigned  responsibility  to  provide  service  over  given 
air  routes.  The  chaos  and  uncertainty  that  marked  the  California  intrastate 
situation  up  to  1965  and  that  marks  the  air  taxi  situation  today  will  be  avoided. 


593 


u 
o 
>  ^ 

iLl     llJ 

(/)    -o 
(T    ° 

<  I 

I-  tt) 

<    a> 
h-    it 

<;° 

<  ^ 

Z    ^ 

q:  e 
o   3 

IJ.    Q 

_j 
< 


i 

-•t 

i 

5 

h  -^ 

1  ^ 

i 

UJ 

u 

i 

1 

i 

i 

i 

I 

s 

l^ 

1 

■ 

3     1 

? 

i     ! 

-             s 

|J 

1 

-     J 

^ 

I 



I 

I 

Jlj 

^      1. 

1 

;i  ii  ^  ^ 

1 

^ 
2 

Ij 

2! 

li 

OS       C 


594 


lij 
o 

>  ^ 

q:  X 

U  UJ 

(/)  -o 

c 

<  ^ 

UJ  i5 

<  J? 
P  li: 

So 

<  - 

z  ;, 

o  ^ 

ll  q 

_i 
< 


Oakland 

11^49                            2<55 

4/49  5/49 

5/49                                 3/54                                           10/60  3/61                  1/66 

H 

8/49  5/50 

3/55             a/57 

6/62  7/62 

H 

8/62           10/64 

11/64  1/6 
H 

1 

!o 

c 

D 
(/) 

il 

5 
^"^ 

3 

<        in        p 

<J  4>  ^ 


<    5J 


SI 


in       ^ 
C        4) 


595 


o 
>  ^ 

q:  X 

UJ    liJ 

(/)   -o 

<  ^ 
lij  i5 

I-  li: 

<;° 
<  ^ 

z  Z^ 

O    3 

U.     Q 

_l 
< 


SI 


T 


1 


7TF 


:i 


ii 


ii  i^ 


il 


<i 


<     r 

0)        < 


^      < 


596 


u 
o 

>  ^ 

111  u 

tr  ° 

<  r 

IxJ  u 

fef  $ 

<  ^ 
f  I 

<  ^ 

z  ^ 

cr  g 

o  ^ 


Brown  Field 

San  Diego 

5/49                                     2/55 

5/49 

C  <  C 

O  C  O 

■^       !o      ~ 


^       .>-      — 


597 


lij 
o 

>  ^ 

U  UJ 

(/)  x> 

c 

<  1^ 

U  u 

b  <" 

<f  OJ 

P  li: 

CO  *. 

<  ° 

<  ^ 

p  ^ 

-I 
< 
u 


hi 


1  I 


|I 


"55      ,n 


u      E 


(J      cj      $      o 


598 


PACIFIC  SOUTHWEST  AIRLINES 
ROUTE  STRUCTURE  -  June  1965 


Los  Angeles 
International  Airport 


SonFroncisco 
International  Airport ' 


Oakland  International  Airport 


^--O  Hollywood/Burbank  Airport 


San  Diego 
International  Airport 


PSA-  June  1965 


Mercer- June  1965  (Sot,  Sun  only) 


599 


Appendix  E 


AIR  CALIFORNIA  and  PACIFIC  SOUTHWEST  AIRLINES 
ROUTE  STRUCTURE  -  PRESENT  ROUTES  ONLY 


SonFroncisco 
InternationolAiri 


San  Jose 
Municipal  Airport 


Hollywood/Burbank  Airport 

Los  Angeles 
International  Airport 


■Vv»*-0  Stockton  Metropolitan  Airport 
Oakland  International  Airport 


Palm  Springs 
Onta'rio  International  Airport 


I  San  Diego 
Internotionol  Airport 


PRESENT  ROUTES: 

Air  Cal 

PSA 


NOTE:   Ttie  following  outhorities  ore  "closed  door" 

authorities  in  which  origin -destination  passengers 
may  not  be  transported: 


AIR  CALIFORNIA 

1 .  Ooklond  -  San  Franciso 

2.  Oakland-Son  Jose 

3.  San  Francisco- San  Jose 

4.  San  Francisco- Ontario 


PSA 

1.  Ooklond -Son  Jose 


600 


Appendix  F 


RELATIONSHIP  OF  INTERNATIONAL  TO  SYSTEM 
REVENUES  AND  PROFIT-SELECTED  TRUNKS 


Dollars  in  Thousands 


BRANIFF:  Revenues 
Operating  Profit 
New  Profit 

NATIONAL:   Revenues 
Operating  Profit 
Net  Profit 

NORTHWEST:   Revenues 
Operating  Profit 
Net  Profit 

WESTERN:  Revenues 
Operating  Profit 
Net  Profit 


System 

International 

%  International 

428.1 

104.8 

24.5% 

41.4 

17.6 

42.5 

23.4 

12.2 

52.1 

413.8 

22.6 

5.5 

50.6 

5.7 

11.3 

20.6 

2.3 

11.2 

584.6 

157.3 

26.9 

49.5 

17.7 

35.8 

51.1 

20.8 

40.4 

414.7 

32.1 

7.7 

40.1 

7.0 

17.5 

20.4 

3.5 

17.2 

CAB  Interim  Financial  Statement 


601 

Supplementary  Testimony  of  William  A.  Jordan 
April  21,  1975 

AIRLINE   deregulation  :    CHAOS    IN    THE   EYES   OF   THE   BEHOLDER 

Introduction 

Mr.  James  L.  Mitchell,  vice  president  of  regulatory  proceedings  of  Continental 
Air  Lines,  has  presented  a  supplementary  statement '  discussing  some  of  the 
points  covered  in  my  testimony  to  this  subcommittee  on  February  14,  1975.^  The 
thrust  of  his  statement  is  that  the  relatively  unregulated  experience  within  Cali- 
fornia prior  to  1965  indicates  that  chaos,  uncertainty  and  instability  would  exist 
in  scheduled  air  transportation  without  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  (CAB)  regu- 
lation, all  to  the  detriment  of  the  public.  The  conditions  to  be  faced  without 
CAB  regulation  may  well  appear  chaotic  and  detrimental  to  the  established  mem- 
bers of  the  regulated  airline  industry,  but  it  is  unlikely  that  this  viewpoint  would 
be  shared  by  consumers  of  air  transportation. 

Many  important  services  in  North  America  are  amply  provided  by  the  open- 
entry,  private-property  system  without  the  assistance  of  government  regulation. 
For  example,  an  airline  passenger  arriving  at  most  airports  can  rely  upon  finding 
unregulated  car-rental  services  available.  In  fact  he  can  often  choose  between 
making  an  advance  reservation  with  a  national  car-rental  firm  or  turning  to  the 
yellow  pages  of  the  phonebook  upon  arrival  to  obtain  the  lower-priced  services  of 
various  "cutthroat"  competitors.  He  can  then  drive  his  rented  full-size  Chev- 
rolet with  air-conditioner  (or  his  Volkswagen)  to  the  local  member  of  a  large 
unregu  ated  h'>te^  (h;iiu  win  e  hr  ha<  foMlnnu'd  reservations,  or  he  can  search 
out  some  small  motel  that  competes  "unfairly"  with  the  hotel  chain  by  charging 
lower  prices.  Finally,  he  can  enjoy  «n  elegant  dinner  in  an  unregulated  (except 
for  a  liquor  license)  restaurant,  or  he  can  survive  on  a  more  modest  meal  at  the 
cafe  he  noticed  while  driving  in  from  the  airport.  All  these  services  are  important 
to  the  tiav(  >••.  be  n-'icw  u]H>n  their  bei^'^:  avai'ab'e  and  seldom  is  he  disappointed 
even  though  they  are  not  regulated.  The  suppliers  of  these  services  may  find 
the  market  conditions  to  be  "chaotic,"  but  that  is  not  the  perception  of  the  con- 
sumer. The  cafe  may  be  under  new  management  and  the  hotel  may  have  just 
been  merged  into  another  parent  company,  but  the  traveler's  eating  and  sleeping 
will  be  little  affected  by  these  changes  in  supply  factors. 

While  all  of  the  above  services,  and  others,  are  supplied  without  benefit  of 
direct  economic  regulation,  the  interstate  traveler's  fiight  to  his  destination  is 
on  an  airline  that  is  heavily  regulated.  Is  there  something  about  air  transporta- 
tion that  makes  economic  regulation  necessary  to  prevent  chaos  and  to  ensure 
its  reliable  provi'-ionV  On  the  one  hand.  Mr.  Mi*^'"hell  and  other  experienced 
members  of  the  CAB-regulated  airline  industry  believe  this  to  be  the  case.  On 
the  other  hand,  some  observers  of  airline  operations  have  been  led  to  the  opposite 
conclusion  by  the  history  of  the  relatively  unregulated  California  intrastate 
carriers,  supported  by  still  o^^hpr  evidf>ncp  from  thf>  Texas  intrastate  experience, 
from  U.S.  military  airlift  procurement,  from  the  operations  of  unregulated  com- 
muter airlines,  and  from  regulated  airline  performance  in  Canada.  Is  it  possible 
that  the  predicted  chaos  largely  exists  in  the  eyes  of  the  members  of  the  regulated 
airline  industry?  The  following  supplementary  testimony  will  analyze  Mr. 
Mitchell's  statement  and,  in  the  process,  will  indicate  how  perceptions  of  eco- 
nomic chaos  are  greatly  influenced  by  one's  point  of  view. 

PASSENGER    BENEFITS   AND    NUMBER   OF   AIRLINES   IN    EXISTENCE 

Mr.  Mitchell  states  that  my  principal  conclusions  from  the  California  intra- 
state experience  are  that:  "(1)  the  intrastate  service  pattern  produced  far 
healthier  results  for  the  traveling  public  than  did  the  regulated  U.S.  domestic 
industry,  (2)  absent  regulation,  there  would  be  200-300  air  carriers  in  the  United 
States,  and  fares  would  be  lower,  and  (3)  the  period  of  'adjustment'  after  the 
institution  of  free  entry  and  exit  would  be  in  the  order  of  10  years."  ^  It  happens 
that  this  is  only  a  partial  summary  of  my  conclusions  and  two  points  are  some- 
what inaccurate.  First,  my  testimony  contained  no  mention  of  "healthier  results 


1  James  L.  Mitchell,  "Supplementary  Stntement,"  Subcommittee  on  Administrative 
Practice  and  Procednre.  Committee  on  the  Judiciary.  U.S.  Senate   (n.d.  :  processed). 

2  William  A  Jordan  "Results  of  Civil  Aoronautics  P,oard  Resrulntion."  Testimony  Before 
the  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure,  Committee  on  the  Judiciary, 
U.S.  Senate  (Feb.  14.  1975:  orocessed). 

3  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  4. 


€02 

for  the  traveling  public,"  and,  second,  the  200-300  air  carrier  estimate  is  inflated 
by  about  100  airiiiies  and  tiiere  is  «  conceptual  problem  wiLli  Mi:  Mitcbell's 
analysis  of  this  estimate. 

My  conclusions  about  the  efliects  of  CAB  regulation  on  passengers  were  as 
follows : 

Passengers  who  value  high-quality  airline  service  relatively  more  than 
other  goods  and  passengers  who  do  not  pay  for  their  air  travel,  have  also 
benetiied  from  the  high-quality  service  flowing  from  CAB  regulation.  Pas- 
sengers who,  in  contrast,  prefer  low-price  and  somewhat  lower-quality  serv- 
ice have  been  harmed,  either  by  having  to  pay  higher  prices  for  airline 
services  or  by  using  less  preferred  means  of  travel,  or  by  not  taveling  at  all. 
Also  harmed  through  having  to  pay  higher  prices  or  higher  taxes  are  the 
many  consumers  of  goods  and  services  produced  by  firms  or  government 
agencies  utlizing  air  transportation  in  their  production  and/or  distribution 
activities.* 
Overall,  if  "health"  refers  to  economic  benefits,  I  conclude  that  CAB  regulation 
has  increased  the  health  of  some  passengers  while  without  CAB  regulation  the 
health  of  a  larger  number  (but  not  all)  passengers  and  many  consumers  would 
have  been  significantly  improved  over  what  they  actually  experienced. 

My  statement  regarding  the  number  of  airlines  in  existence  at  various  times 
in  the  absence  of  CAB  regulation  was  : 

Based  on  the  system  sizes  and  traffic  volumes  of  the  California  intrastate 
carriers,  it  appears  that  without  CAB  regulation  from  100  to  over  200  air- 
lines operating  large  aircraft  would  have  existed  at  any  one  time  in  the  48 
contiguous  states  from  1940  through  1965.  (Emphasis  added. )^ 
The  important  point  is  not  whether  the  range  of  unregulated  airlines  in  existence 
extends  from  100  to  over  200  or  from  200  to  600.  What  is  imporiant  is  whether  or 
not  there  would  have  been  several  times  'nore  scheduled  airlines  in  existence  at 
any  one  time  without  CAB  regulation  than  the  35  to  24  trunk  and  local  service 
carriers  that  CAB  actually  allowed  to  operate  between  1949  and  1965,  and  the 
implications  this  has  regarding  the  dispersion  of  airline  services  over  the  country 
in  the  absence  of  regulation.  Due  to  some  confusion  over  concepts,  Mr.  Mitchell 
failed  to  come  to  grips  with  the  evidence  pertaining  to  this  matter. 

Mr.  Mitchell's  analysis  of  the  California  experience  on  pp.  6-11  of  his  statement 
concluded  that  ".  .  .  very  little  can  be  said  about  the  number  of  air  carriers  that 
would  come  into  existence  in  an  open  entry  situation,"  and  "(w)hat  can  be 
concluded  from  this  experience,  however,  is  that  if  200-300  air  carriers  were  to 
come  into  existence  .  .  .  they  would  do  so  on  a  scattered  basis.  .  .  .""  It  happens 
that  his  analysis  was  based  on  the  information  given  in  my  book  in  the  section 
entitled  "Intrastate  Carrier  Entry  and  Exit."  '  This  section  demonstrated  that 
CAB  regulation  has  significantly  limited  both  entry  into  and  exit  from  the 
industry.  But  the  following  section,  entitled  "Number  of  Airlines  in  Existence," 
pointed"  out  that  the  flow  of  airlines  into  and  out  of  the  industry  cannot  be  used 
to  estimate  the  stock  of  airlines  in  existence  at  various  points  in  time,*  just  as  the 
annual  earnings  statement  of  a  firm  cannot  be  used  to  derive  its  end-of-year 
balance  sheet.  My  estimate  of  100  to  over  200  airlines  in  existence  at  any  point 
in  time  from  1949  through  1965  was  made  in  that  latter  section  and  was  based 
on  system  sizes  and  trafl!ic  volumes.  Since  Mr.  ]\Iitchell  made  no  reference  to  that 
analysis  in  his  statement,  there  is  nothing  to  cause  me  to  change  my  evaluation  of 
the  evidence.  Thus,  the  estimated  number  of  airlines  in  existence,  together  with 
other  evidence  to  be  outlined  below,  still  imply  that  airline  services  would  not 
have  been  provided  on  a  "scattered  basis"  in  the  absence  of  CAB  regulation. 

AIRLINE   FAIL!  RE   AND   COVERAGE 

When  describing  the  high  failure  rate  and  lack  of  coverage  of  the  California 
intrastate  carriers  during  the  1946-65  period  of  open  entry,  Mr.  Mitchell  chooses 
to  analyze  the  California  experience  only  in  terms  of  the  intrastate  carriers.  This 
is  exemplified  by  the  major  title  of  appendixes  A,  B  and  C  of  his  statement,  to 
wit:  California  Intrastate  Air  Service.  To  be  accurate,  this  title  should  have 


*  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2.  at  4r>-46.  Also,  William  A.  Jordan,  Airline  Regula- 
tion in  America  :  Effects  and  Imperfections,  227  (1970). 
5  Id.  at  6.  Also.  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4.  at  24-32. 
"  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  10-11. 
'  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  17-24. 
8  Id.  at  24-32. 


read :  California  Air  Service  by  Intrastate  Carriers.  The  change  in  wording  is 
small,  but  the  change  in  meaning  is  important. 

Considering  only  intrastate  carrier  service  ignores  the  fact  that  other  airlines 
also  provided  service  within  the  state.  In  l'J4t>,  when  the  first  major  wave  of 
intrastate  entry  occurred,  the  managers  of  every  potential  intrastate  carrier  had 
to  face  the  reality  that  California  was  already  blanketed  by  airline  service  au- 
thorized and  subsidized  by  tlie  Federal  Government.  As  at  March  31,  19'^9, 
American,  TWA,  United  and  Western  were  authorized  to  serve  22  airports,  while 
Southwest  Airways  (the  original  name  of  Pacific  Air  Lines,  now  a  part  of 
Hughes  Airwest)  was  authorized  to  provide  local  service  at  24  California  air- 
ports." Combined,  the.se  five  CAB-regulated  airlines  served  38  unduplicated  air- 
ports throughout  the  populated  portions  of  the  state.  It  was  against  the  estab- 
lished .services  of  these  sul)sidized  carriers  (who  were  also  allowed  to  carry  U.S. 
mail)  that  the  intrastate  carriers  sought  to  introduce  service  within  the  confines 
of  California.  Then,  even  more  than  now,  traffic  between  many  city-pairs  was  so 
limited  that  it  would  support  only  one  carrier.  Since  most  of  the  .smaller  city 
pairs  in  California  were  already  served  Ijy  a  subsidized  carrier  and  since  adja- 
cent interstate  points  such  as  Tucson,  Phoenix,  Las  Vegas  and  Reno  could  not  be 
served,  it  is  evident  that  the  California  intrastate  carriei-s  laced  seririus  restric- 
tions on  the  demand  for  their  .services  and  on  opportunities  to  utilize  their  air- 
craft efficiently. 

Given  all  the  above,  the  .surprising  thing  is  not  that  such  a  high  proportion  of 
intrastate  carriers  failed,  but  that  a  few  did  manage  to  survive.  Certainly  they 
emphasized  the  high-density  city-pairs.  Surely  one  is  not  going  to  risk  his  wealth 
in  serving  such  monopoly  points  at  Bakersfield.  Stockton  and  i^ureka  when  a 
subsidized  airline  was  already  providing  service  between  tho.se  cities.  Certainly 
they  began  .service  through  the  old  Lockheed  Air  Terminal  at  Burbank  rather 
than  at  the  new  Los  Angeles  International  Airport.  It  was  cheaper  to  operate 
through  Burbank  and  costs  were  crucially  imiKjrtant  to  those  early  carriers 
offering  service  at  coach  fares  less  than  half  the  fares  of  the  CAB-regulated 
airlines.  Certainly  intrastate  carriers  entered  during  periods  when  aircraft  were 
relatively  low  priced.  Mr.  Mitchell  refers  to  "free"  entry.  Xo  economic  activity 
is  free.  Open  entry  (referring  to  the  lack  of  legal/regulatory  barriers)  is  the 
correct  terminology  and,  when  legally  possible,  more  entry  occurs  when  entry 
eo.sts  are  low  than  when  they  are  high.  Overall,  the  intrastate  carriers  were  play- 
ing the  economic  game  constrained  by  the  CAB's  rules,  and  those  rules  were 
biased  against  them. 

Appendixes  B  and  C  of  Mr.  Mitchell's  statement  contain  the  dates  of  service 
at  most,  but  not  all,  of  the  California  airports  served  by  the  sixteen  intra.state 
carriers.  These  appendixes  emphasize  the  .sporadic  coverage  of  these  carriers 
from  1046  to  lOOo  as  they  sought  to  establish  themselves  despite  the  rivalry  of 
the  entrenched  CAB-regulated  airlines.  Also  shown,  but  not  emphasized  by  these 
appendixes,  is  the  fact  that  low-fare  services  were  offered  continuously  by  one 
or  more  intrastate  carriers  in  the  San  Francisco  and  Los  Angeles  areas  and  in 
San  Diego  throughout  the  i>eriod  from  104JJ  to  lf>65  and  beyond.  True,  a 
pa.ssenger  might  have  had  to  utilize  Burbank  rather  than  Los  Angeles  Interna- 
tional at  various  time.s,  but  he  did  have  intra.state-carrier  service  available  at 
each  major  population  c-enter.  The.se  appendixes  al.so  fail  to  show  that  the  intra- 
state carriers  offered  the  first  or  only  .single-plane  .service  to  Inyokern,  Ed- 
wards AFB,  Brown  Field,  Lake  Tahoe  and,  recently,  Mammouth.'"  The  CAB- 
regulated  airlines  did  overlook  some  small  points  within  California  and  the 
intrastate  carriers  moved  in  if  there  was  an  exi^ectation  of  profitable  unsub.si- 
dized  operations. 

With  regards  to  the  CAB-regulated  airlines,  Mr.  Mitchell's  bar  diagrams  do  not 
depict  such  things  as  United's  suspension  of  all  sert-ice  at  Burbank  in  April  19(51 
and  at  Long  Beach  in  October  1962,  and  Western's  suspensions  at  the.se  points  in 
September  1962  and  October  1973,  respectively."  Also,  they  do  not  mention  the 
fact  that  the  CAB-regulated  trunk  carriers  concentrated  their  services  at  the  Los 
Angeles  and  San  Francisco  International  airports  and  essentially  ignored  the 


"'AH.  Tnltpd  States  .Air  Transnortation  Svstptn.  Roufps  Pprman*>ntlv  CprtlfioatPrl  Mar. 
31,  1949.  anr]  Limitpfl-Ppriofl  anrl  Plfkiip  Routps  Cprtlfimtprl.  AInr.  .31.  1949. 

'"William  A.  .Jordan,  supra,  notp  4,  at  ^^~>-?,?,  and  2.58-0.3.  Also.  California  Public 
Utilitlps  Commission   (PUC)  dpcisions  7.5.37.'i   (F.'b.  2.5,  1969).  and  79100   (Sept.  21,  1971). 

"William  A.  .Jordan,  supra,  note  4  at  277.  Al.so,  CAB  orders  E-18819  (Sept.  24,  1902), 
and  7.3-9-72  (Sept.  18,  197.3). 


604 

airport  at  Ontario,  Santa  Ana,  Oakland  and  San  Jose  until  Pacific  Southwest 
Airlines  (PSA)  and  Air  California  demonstrated  the  traflic  generating  capabil- 
ities of  those  satellite  airports  during  the  late  sixties.  As  importantly,  these  ap- 
pendices fail  to  indicate  qualitative  aspects  of  service.  For  example,  they  do  not 
show  that  Pacific's  regulated  service  at  San  Jose  generated  a  maximum  of  only 
73,000  annual  online  origin  and  destination  passengers  to  and  from  Los  Angeles 
throughout  the  many  years  Pacific  provided  the  only  single-plane  service  in  this 
city-pair,  while  during  its  first  full  year  of  oi)eration  in  this  city  pair  (1967), 
PSA  carried  557,000  O&D  pas.sengers."  Finally,  these  diagrams  do  not  show 
such  things  as  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission  (PUC)  decision  that 
ordered  Western  to  remove  the  discrimination  in  the  fares  it  offered  at  Oakland 
and  Long  Beach  relative  to  San  Francisco  and  Los  Angeles." 

Mr.  Mitchell  mentioned  that  he  interested  Continental  in  serving  the  Los  An- 
geles and  San  Francisco  satellite  airports  after  he  joined  that  company  in  Sep- 
tember 1968.  He  states  that  "Continental  began  operations  at  Ontario  in  con- 
nection with  its  Chicago-Kansas  City-Denver-Los  Angeles  route,  and  later  was 
authorized  to  provide  service  between  the  Pacific  Northwest  terminals  of  Seattle 
and  Portland  and  all  the  satellite  airports.  .  .  ."  "  Of  course,  authorizations  are 
one  thing,  actual  service  another.  The  OflBcial  Airline  Guide  shows  that,  during 
this  past  March,  Continental  provided  no  service  whatsoever  to  half  the  satellite 
airports  (Long  Beach,  Santa  Ana  and  Oakland),  and  that  is  operated  only  a 
single  daily  round  trip  between  Ontario  and  Chicago/Denver  (but  not  to  Kansas 
City),  about  l^/^  daily  round  trips  between  Ontario/Burbank  and  San  Jose,  and 
3  to  SV2  daily  round  trips  between  Ontario/Burbank/San  Jose  and  Seattle/ 
Portland.^®  In  total,  it  provided  six  daily  departures  at  Burbank,  just  over  seven 
at  San  Jose  and  eight  at  Ontario.  This  is  in  sharp  contrast  to  the  multiple,  daily 
frequencies  provided  by  Air  California  and/or  PSA  at  all  six  satellite  airports.^" 

Actually,  it  is  misleading  to  emphasize  the  negative  aspects  of  airline  service 
within  California.  Overall,  the  rivalry  between  individual  carriers,  regardle.ss 
of  their  regulatory  classification,  has  resulted  in  an  outstanding  coverage  and 
quality  of  service  being  provided  by  all  airlines  as  a  group.  As  far  as  the  con- 
sumer is  concerned  it  is  this  overall  level  of  service  that  counts,  and  the  airline 
consumer  has  been  amply  blessed  in  California.  In  addition,  wherever  intrastate 
carriers  have  operated  the  consumer  has  also  enjoyed  fares  appreciably  lower 
than  those  which  would  otherwise  have  been  authorized  by  the  CAB." 

THE   ROLE   OF   DEMAND 

Mr.  Mitchell  asserts  that  without  regulation  airline  entry  and  exit  "would  have 
little  to  do  with  public  need  for  service,"  would  be  "unrelated  to  pressing  market 
needs,"  and  would  "depend  more  on  availability  of  excess,  used  equipment  than 
on  market  demand."  "  The  terms  "public  need,"  "market  needs,"  and  "market 
demand"  are  not  defined,  but  it  appears  that  they  are  synonymous  and  that  they 
refer  to  the  economic  concept  of  demand. 

An  assertion  that  unregulated  airlines  would  place  little  importance  on  the 
demand  for  their  services  when  considering  entry  or  exit  would  be  surprising 
were  it  not  consi-stent  with  the  CAR's  great  emphasis  on  supply  considerations 
when  setting  its  "cost-based"  fares.^"  This  common  practice  of  regulators  is  in- 
consistent with  economic  reality  and,  certainly  since  the  publication  of  Alfred 
Marshall's  Principles  of  Economics  in  1890,  economic  theory  has  recognized  that 
the  viability  of  an  enterprise  in  an  open  market  depends  both  upon  the  costs  of 
providing  a  good/service  and  on  there  being  adequate  demand  for  that  good/ 
service.  It  is  the  "sci.s.sors  of  supply  and  demand"  that  define  economic  viability 
and  equilibrium  prices.  By  and  large,  the  California  experience  indicates  that 
demand  would  not  be  ignored  by  unregulated  air  carriers  when  they  sought  to 
enter  new  markets,  nor  would  they  ignore  the  costs  of  operations. 


12  William    A.    Jordan,   supra,   note  4,   at   129-30.   Also.   PUC.   Transportation   Division, 
Traffic  Data,  exhibit  submitted  In  application  52970,  sheet  5  (Feb.  11,  1972). 
"PUC  decision  07077  (Apr.  7.  1964). 
1*  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1.  at  3. 

IS  1  Official  Airline  Guide  (North  American  edition,  Mar.  1,  1975). 
i«Id. 

"  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  113-14  and  131-33. 
18. Tames  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1.  at  4.  11  and  13,  respectively, 
lo  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2,  at  28-29. 


605 


Mr.  Mitchell  feels  that  the  recent  experience  of  the  air-taxi/commuter  airlines 
is  evidence  of  "a  considerable  lack  of  economic  stability,"  -"  and  he  quotes  a  U.S. 
Court  of  Appeals  decision  to  support  his  belief.  This  subcommittee  has  been  given 
a  statement  on  this  point  with  a  different  conclusion. 

The  proponents  of  entry  and  exit  regulation  in  that  case  (the  New  England 
Service  Investigation)  argued,  and  the  Board  agreed,  that  there  is  a  public 
interest  in  "continuity  of  service"  which  requires  .some  entry  and  exit  regu- 
lation. We  question  this  result,  in  view  of  the  Administrative  Law  Judge's 
uncontroverted  finding  that    although  commuter  carriers  had  entered  and 
exited  several  New  England  markets,  there  had  been  no  significant  lapses  of 
service  to  the  public  because  of  this  turnover.  (Footnotes  omitted.)^ 
The  difference  is  one  of  viewpoint.  From  the  airline  point  of  view  there  certainly 
is  instability  with  open  entry  and  exit.  Many  airlines  enter  and  a  large  number  of 
these  exit.  From  the  passenger  viewpoint,  however,  service  is  quite  stable,  even 
during   periods   when   a    relatively   young   industry   is   testing   and    developing 
markets. 

Mr.  Mitchell  notes  that  "[s]ome  air  taxi  operators  who  have  achieved  stability 
did  .so  either  by  concentrating  in  high  density  vacation  markets  or  by  tying  them- 
selves to  a  certificated  carrier  through  a  connnuter  'feeder'  agreement.  .  .  ."  "^ 
Unfortunately,  he  fails  to  .specify  the  numbers  of  air-taxi  operators  in  each  of 
these  two  categories,  nor  does  he  give  the  number  of  operators  who  have  found 
stability  in  other  circumstances. 

A  CAB  study  of  the  commuter  air  carriers  for  the  year  ended  June  30,  1973, 
reported  201  such  carriers  filing  required  reports  for  one  or  more  quarters,  with 
126  doing  so  for  the  entire  year.^  Of  the  201  carriers,  151  provided  pas^:enger 
service  and  accounted  for  549  million  revenue  passenger-miles  (RPM),  which  was 
0.45  percent  of  the  total  122,009  million  RPM  carried  by  the  domestic  trunk,  local 
service  and  commuter  carriers  combined."*  This  left  the  trunk  and  local  .service 
carriers  with  99.55  percent  of  total  KP:M.  If  less  than  one-half  of  1  percent  of 
total  RPM  can  support  100  or  more  carriers  operating  small  aircraft  having  19 
seats  or  less,  there  is  nothing  surprising  about  221  times  that  traffic  supiwrting 
well  over  100  airlines  operating  large  aircraft  with  50  to  400  seats,  especially 
since  California  (and  the  Texas)  experience  provides  evidence  that  full  econo- 
mies of  scale  can  be  achieved  with  around  five  aircraft  of  a  type  suited  to  the 
carrier's  routes  and  traffic  densities.^  Furthermore,  with  this  much  larger  demand 
service  would  be  even  more  stable  for  the  passenger  than  what  they  have  already 
obtained  from  the  constrained  commuter  carriers. 

FINANCIAL  AND  SAFETY  PROBLEMS  IN  THE  THIRTIES 

Referring  to  the  pre-1938  era,  Mr.  Mitchell  notes  that  the  carriers  of  that  period 
were  "in  financial  difficulty,  and  safety  problems  existed." '"  He  does  not  mention 
that  many  industries  had  financial  difficulties  during  the  Great  Depression  and 
that  the  domestic  airlines  were  a  growth  industry  even  during  that  iieriod.  Be- 
tween 1930  and  1938  their  RPM  grew  by  404  percent  and  pas.senger  revenues 
increased  by  242  percent  (in  a  period  of  deflation),  while  mail  revenue  ton-miles 
expanded  by  203  percent  from  1934  to  1938." 

Safety  then  was  certainly  a  greater  problem  than  it  is  today,  but  airline, 
aircraft  and  air  traffic  control  technologies  in  the  thirties  were  rudimentary  com- 
pared with  the  present  time.  As  stated  in  my  testimony,  the  evidence  is  unclear 
regarding  whether  or  not  economic  regulation  by  the  CAB  (as  distinct  from  direct 
operational  regulation  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Administration)  improves  airline 
safety."^  Even  comparing  passenger  fatalities  per  100  million  RPINI  may  be  mis- 


2"  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  5.  .  ,     .   .  ^     ^, 

21  Thomas  E.  Kan  per,  "Testimony  Before  the  Senate  Subcommittee  on  Administrative 
Practice  and  Procedure  Concerning  Airline  Regulation  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board," 
21-22  (Feb.  6.  197.5  ;  processed). 

^-  James  L.  Mitchell,  si.pra.  note  1,  at  6.  „,,„/-, 

23  CAB,  "Commuter  Air  Carrier  Traffic  Statistics,  Year  Ended  June  30,  1973,'  3  (June 
1974  ;  processed). 

2*  Id.  at  1  and  14.  Also,  CAB,  Air  Carrier  Traffic  Statistics,  2  and  4   (June  1973). 

2=  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  191-94. 

2«  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  5. 

2T  CAB  Handboolc  of  Airline  htati.stics,  23,  48  and  79  (1973  ed.). 

28  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2,  at  43-45. 


606 

leading.  For  example,  to  the  extent  higher  fares  resulting  from  CAB  regulation 
have  caused  travelers  to  substitute  more  dangerous  automobile  travel  for  safer 
air  travel  the  overall  safety  of  the  total  traveling  public  has  been  decreased 
by  CAB  regulation,  assuming  airline  safety  standards  would  be  maintained 
with  larger  traffic  volumes.  The  question  of  safety  is  very  complex  and  many 
factors  must  be  considered  explicitly  or  held  constant,  especially  when  making 
comparisons  between  different  historical  periods. 

INTEGRATED    SERVICES 

Mr.  Mitchell's  statement  regarding  the  lack  of  "an  integrated  pattern  of  serv- 
ice" by  the  intrastate  carriers  is  surprising.^'  The  route  maps  given  in  his  ap- 
pendix E  show  that  the  services  of  Air  California  and  PSA  are  close  substitutes 
for  each  other  rather  than  being  complementary,  thereby  decreasing  passenger 
demand  for  integration.""  Also,  he  fails  to  point  out  that  a  California  passenger 
can  easily  obtain  integrated  services  by  going  to  a  travel  agent  to  purchase  tickets 
and  having  reservations  made  on  two  different  intrastate  carriers  should  his 
travel  plans  warrant  this.  Finally,  Mr.  Mitchell  has  overlooked  Air  California  and 
PSA's  unsuccessful  efforts  to  obtain  the  necessary  authorization  from  the  CAB 
to  establish  interline  arrangements  with  the  CAB-regulated  airlines."^  If  in- 
creased integration  is  desirable,  it  is  within  the  CAB's  power  to  allow  it  to  happen. 

Much  has  been  made  of  the  desirability  of  the  CAB-regulated  airlines  being 
able  to  issue  tickets  and  make  reservations  for  each  other.  While  this  is  con- 
venient for  some,  it  has  resulted  in  other  passengers  having  to  experience  long 
and  impatient  delays  at  ticket  counters  while  agents  make  reservations  and  issue 
multicarrier  tickets  for  other  passengers.  My  own  travel  experience  has  shown 
that  it  is  very  easy  to  fly  to  Los  Angeles  on  American,  United  or  Air  Canada  and 
then  make  reservations  and  purchase  tickets  for  travel  within  California  on 
PSA  or  Air  California,  especially  with  the  widespread  acceptance  of  credit  cards. 
Each  carrier  sells  a  simple  one-  or  two-coupon  ticket.  The  only  difference  is  that 
in  Toronto  the  ticket  may  be  written  out  by  hand  in  considerable  detail,  while 
in  Los  Angeles  it  is  issued  more  quickly  as  a  cash-register  receipt.  I  happen  to 
Drefer  the  speed  of  the  latter  method. 

RELEVANCE    OF    THE    CALIFORNIA    EXPERIENCE 

Mr.  Mitchell,  in  common  with  other  industry  spokesmen,  warns  against  general- 
izing too  much  from  the  California  experience.  "The  area  is  limited  geographi- 
cally. The  weather  conditions,  the  mileages  involved,  and  the  high  population 
density  of  the  principal  cities  served  .  .  .  present  ideal  operating  circum- 
stances." ^  Aside  from  occasional  dense  fogs  at  most  airports  and  the  heavy  snow 
falls  at  Lake  Tahoe  and  Mammouth,  weather  conditions  in  California  are  good, 
but  so  are  weather  conditions  all  across  the  southern  U.S.  The  population  densities 
of  the  principal  cities  are  not  unique;  they  are  duplicated  in  many  other  cities  in 
the  nation.  Finally,  the  mileages  involved  are  far  from  ideal.  The  fact  is  that 
California  is  a  relatively  constrained  geographic  and  economic  area  and  this  has 
served  to  harm  the  intrastate  carriers  that  sought  to  survive  under  open  entry. 

During  20  years  of  experience  in  CAB  regulatory  activities  and  related  re- 
search, this  is' the  first  time  I  have  ever  heard  route  segments  of  109,  340,  or  even 
449  miles  called  "ideal."  To  the  contrary,  routes  that  allow  nonstop  flights  of 
1,000  miles  or  more  are  the  ideal.  Listening  to  airline  spokesmen  would  lead  one 
to  think  the  CAB  had  done  the  California  intrastate  carriers  a  tremendous  favor 
by  not  allowing  them  to  risk  introducing  low-fare  coach  service  to  such  cities  as 
Phoenix.  Seattle,  Denver.  Dallas,  Minneapolis-St.  Paul,  Chicago,  Detroit,  Atlanta, 
Miami.  Washington.  New  York,  Boston  and  numerous  large,  medium  and  small 
cities  in  between.  As  the  old  saying  goes,  "with  a  friend  like  this,  who  needs 
enemies?"  . 

There  are  indeed  limitations  to  generalizing  from  the  California  (and  lexas) 
experience,    but   these   limitations    are   opposite   to   those  indicated   by    airhne 


».Tnnies  I^.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1.  at  10.  ,    ^     ^     -       „    t  i 

•■»  William   A.   .Tordan.   "Air   Transportation   Markets:   Definitional   Confusion,     .Journal 

of  Air  T>^w  and  Conimercp  (forthcominR  :  nn.  18-25  of  the  mannscript) .     ^^^^^      .,         ^„  . 

31  CAB  orders  E-IOfi.'i.^  (.Tune  10,  19fi.3)  and  71-8-57  (Aue.  12.  1971).  Also  PSA. 
"Responses  to  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure,  '  16-17  (Feb.  6, 
1975). 

32  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  5. 


607 

spokesmen.  With  open  entry  nationwide,  airlines  could  operate  more  efficiently 
and  enjoy  lower  operating  costs  than  experienced  in  constrained  intrastate  areas, 
demand  for  their  services  would  be  far  greater,  and  there  would  probably  be 
proportionally  fewer  failures  than  what  occurred  within  California. 

Critics  of  the  California  intrastate  experience  also  emphasize  that  the  success- 
ful carriers  operated  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  which  has  the 
largest  passenger  flow  in  the  world.  Mention  is  never  made  of  the  fact  that  this 
was  not  the  case  in  1948  before  the  intrastate  carriers  introduced  low-fare  coach 
service  to  that  city-pair.  As  pointed  out  in  my  testimony,  in  1948  Boston-New 
York/Newark  accounted  for  550,000  true  O&D  passengers  while  only  297,000 
such  passengers  flew  between  Los  Angeles/Burbank/Long  Beach  and  San  Fran- 
cisco/Oakland.'" An  important  reason  for  the  large  traffic  densities  in  the  pres- 
ent California  city  pairs  is  the  existence  of  low  fares  for  long  periods  of  time. 
Had  the  same  fares-per-mile  been  permitted  throughout  the  U.S.  during  the  past 
25  years,  other  city-pairs  would  be  challenging  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  for 
the  distinction  of  being  the  largest  in  the  world. 

BANKRUPTCY   AND   THE   PASSENGER 

At  two  points  in  his  statement  Mr.  Mitchell  points  out  that  passengers  "paid 
a  significant  price  in  the  disruption  caused  by  a  large  number  of  local  air  carriers 
going  out  of  business,"  and  that  "[p]eople  were  left  stranded  in  the  midst  of 
trips,  and  had  no  assurance  of  receiving  reliable  air  service."  ^  Surely,  given 
the  continuing  services  of  PSA,  United,  TWA,  Western,  Pacific  and  other  air- 
lines, it  is  incorrect  to  say  that  passengers  had  no  assurance  of  receiving  reliable 
air  service.  Service  terminations  and  carrier  bankruptcies  certainly  inconven- 
ienced passengers  who  had  to  make  alternative  air  or  surface  travel  arrange- 
ments, but  this  inconvenience  was  less  than  that  caused  by  a  foggy  night  when 
all  airline  services  were  suspended.  In  bankruptcy,  the  most  extreme  case  of 
service  termination,  the  main  harm  suffered  by  passengers  was  that,  in  com- 
mon with  other  creditors,  they  suffered  financial  losses.  It  is  worthwhile  to 
investigate  the  likely  extent  of  such  losses. 

The  largest  and  most  important  airline  to  go  bankrupt  was  California  Central 
Airlines  (CCA)  on  February  14,  1955.  California  Central  was  the  true  pioneer  of 
low-fare  coach  service  within  California.  It  was  the  first  to  inaugurate  such 
service  in  1949  and  over  the  next  six  years  it  consistently  carried  more  passen- 
gers than  any  other  intrastate  carrier  (a  high  of  169,000'in  1953).®  Let  us  con- 
sider the  financial  loss  of  a  CCA  passenger  who  purchased  a  round-trip  ticket 
between  Burbank  and  San  Francisco  just  prior  to  February  14,  1955.  At  that  time 
CCA's  one-way  fare  in  this  city-pair  for  Martin  202  service  was  $13.50  (it  was 
$11.70  for  DC-3  service),  so  a  round-trip  ticket  cost  $29.70,  including  the  10- 
percent  federal  transportation  tax  then  in  effect.'*  Therefore,  if  CCA  went  bank- 
rupt before  the  outbound  portion  of  the  ticket  was  used  the  passenger  lost  the 
full  $29.70  (assuming  no  payments  were  made  to  general  creditors  when  CCA's 
assets  were  sold  by  the  court).  If,  however,  the  passenger  had  flown  to  San 
Francisco  just  before  the  bankruptcy  he  either  lost  $14.85,  the  extra  price  he  had 
to  pay  United  or  Western  to  fly  him  back  to  Burbank,  or  $30.90,  the  price  charged 
by  PSA  for  this  service.^  In  addition,  he  may  have  had  to  incur  such  added  costs 
as  a  phone  call  to  his  wife,  one  or  two  meals,  an  overnight  stay  in  San  Francisco, 
and  a  higher  parking  fee.  Finally,  he  might  even  have  had  to  buy  a  first-class 
ticket  on  United  or  Western  for  $24.26  in  order  to  get  back  in  time  for  the  lodge 
meeting  that  night.'®  Overall,  our  representative  CCA  passenger  would  have  per- 
ceived his  loss  to  have  been  between  $11  and,  perhaps,  $35  because  of  CCA's 
bankruptcy.  Certainly  he  would  have  felt  aggrieved,  especially  since  a  dollar  was 
worth  more  in  1955  than  it  is  today.  But,  then,  he  would  have  been  similarly 
aggrieved  had  he  put  a  $35  down  payment  on  a  chair  ordered  from  a  furniture 
store  that  went  bankrupt  before  delivery  of  the  chair.  In  either  case  he  might 
have  written  a  complaint  to  his  state  legislator,  but  probably  not. 


^  William  A.  Jordan,  .supra,  note  2,  at  15n. 

34  .Tnnips  L.  Mi^^cbpll.  snnra.  note  1  at  10  and  12. 

^  ■\Villiani  A.  .Jordan,  .^iipra.  notp  4.  at  20  and  264. 

Mid.  at  135  and  284-87.  In  early  195.5.  I'nited  and  Western,  as  well  as  CCA.  operated 
the  niaiority  of  their  nonstoo  coach  service  between  San  Francisco  and  the  Los  Angeles 
area  through  Burbank.  PSA  operated  only  through  Burbank.  11  Official  Airline  Guide 
(Feb.  1955). 

="  Id.  at  l.-^S,  279-80  and  284-87. 

38  Id.  at  135  and  276-78. 


While  the  above  may  have  been  the  perceived  loss  of  the  CCA  passenger,  it 
is  not  the  full  story.  Had  CAB  regulation  been  able  to  totally  prevent  intrastate- 
carrier  service  within  California,  one-way  coach  fares  vvouid  have  been  higher 
than  the  $13.50  (or  $11.70  or  $9.99)  that  existed  in  this  city-pair  in  early  19o5. 
In  October  i958  the  CAB  announced  a  new  coach  fare  policy  in  conjunction  with 
the  short-haul  coach  fare  case,  so  it  is  likely  that  by  early  1955  some  limited 
day-coach  service  would  have  been  inaugurated  between  Burbank  and  San 
Francisco  on  long-haul  flights  at  a  one-way  fare  of  $16.;  9  plus  tax.^  Assuming 
coach  service  as  a  part  of  long-haul  flights  would  have  been  convenient  for  our 
Burbank-San  Francisco  passenger,  this  means  that  he  would  have  paid  $36.94 
for  his  round-trip  ticket  on  a  CAB-regulated  airline,  $7.24  more  than  the  $29.70 
he  paid  for  his  CCA  ticket.  Thus,  this  $7.24  saving  due  to  the  existence  of  intra- 
state carriers  should  be  deducted  from  the  $29.(0  financial  loss  to  obtain  the 
passenger's  true  net  loss  of  $22.46  had  CCA's  bankruptcy  occurred  before  he 
began  his  trip.'"  Similarly,  $7.24  should  also  be  deducted  from  the  $11  to  $35 
estimated  loss  in  the  situation  where  the  passenger  was  in  San  Francisco  at  the 
time  of  service  termination.  This  reduces  the  overall  range  of  possible  loss  down 
to  between  $3.76  and  $27.76. 

The  above  is  the  full  story  for  the  first-time  intrastate  air  traveler,  but  not  for 
the  person  who  flew  on  intrastate  carriers  between  Burbank  and  San  Francisco 
at  other  times  from  1949  to  early  1955.  In  1949,  for  example,  because  of  CCA's 
innovative  efforts  such  a  passenger  was  able  to  make  his  round  trip  for  $26.43 
(including  the  15-percent  transportation  tax)  compared  with  United  or  Western's 
CAB-regulated  charge  of  .$48.42— a  saving  of  $21.99  for  this  single  trip  would 
have  covered  most  or  all  of  his  subsequent  loss  in  1955.''^  Similar  calculations 
should  be  made  for  every  other  trip  taken  at  lower  fares  because  of  intrastate- 
carrier  service.  Overall,  it  is  clear  that  the  maximum  loss  suffered  by  a  Burbank- 
San  Francisco  passenger  due  to  CCA's  bankruptcy  was  less  than  $30,  and  that 
almost  any  passenger  who  made  one  or  more  round-trip  flights  on  an  intrastate 
carrier  between  1949  and  early  1955  broke  even  or  enjoyed  a  financial  gain  despite 
his  loss  when  CCA  went  bankrupt. 

Mr.  Mitchell  reports  that  Holiday  Airlines,  the  intrastate  carrier  connecting 
Lake  Tahoe  with  the  major  California  cities,  went  bankrupt  earlier  this  year. 
He  did  not  elaborate  on  what  effect  this  has  had  on  Holiday's  service,  but  the 
Oflicial  Airline  Guide  reports  (perhaps  incorrectly)  that  Holiday  is  still  operat- 
ing." Maybe  Holiday's  current  passengers  will  suffer  losses  as  a  result  of  its 
bankruptcy.  It  should  not  be  forgotten,  however,  that  the  first  scheduled  service 
to  Lake  Tahoe  was  inaugurated  by  an  intrastate  carrier  on  May  14.  1962,  and 
that  the  first  CAB-regulated  airline*  (Pacific/Hughes  Airwest)  did  not  begin  such 
service  until  October  27,  1963  and  subsequently  terminated  service  in  May  1974. 
Thus,  the  harm  done  to  passengers  through  Holiday's  bankruptcy  should  be 
balanced  by  the  benefits  received  by  the  same  and  other  passengers  through  the 
earlier  service  inauguration  and  the  continuation  of  service  after  Hughes  Air- 
west's  withdrawal. 

MONOPOLY   IN    CALIFORNIA? 

Was  there  an  airline  monopoly  in  California?  Mr.  Mitchell  states  that  by  1965 
the  period  of  open  entrv  in  California  "produced  a  single  carrier  monopolizing 
all  of  the  (major)  California  markets.""  He  fails  to  mention  that  at  that  time, 
in  addition  to  PSA.  service  was  provided  in  major  California  city-pairs  by 
American,  Delta,  National.  TWA.  United,  Western  and  the  three  predecessors  of 
Hughes  Airwest  (Bonanza,  Pacific  and  West  Coast).  This  was  hardly  a  monopoly 
situation.  ,  .  ,,     

While  Mr.  Mitchell  correctly  points  out  that  entry  was  no  longer  fully  open 
after  September  1965.  he  makes  little  mention  of  the  information  given  in  my 
testimony  that  it  was  not  until  1969  that  the  PUC  actually  closed  entry  to  new 
intrastate  carriers  operating  large  aircraft.  During  tho.se  four  intervening  years 

«  In'  otVe?''w^or^dl%  one'has  to  compare  the  passenger's  outlay  of  $29  70  for  the  unused 
CC\  ticket  plus  $29.70  for  a  ticket  on  United  or  Western,  with  the  $36.94  outlay  that 
he  would  have  had  to  pay  in  the  absence  of  intrastate  carriers. 

«  William  A.  .Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  l.'')."i,  276-78  and  284-87.    _ 

*2  1  Official  Airline  Guide  (Xorth  American  edition   Mar   15   197o).  74   q   inr? 

« William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  117  and  122-25.  Also,  CAB  orders  74-3-105 
(Mar.  25,  1974)  and  74-5-75  (May  15,  1974). 

4*  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  7. 


609 

the  PUC  authorized  service  by  Air  California,  Holiday  Airlines  and  California 
Sierra  Airlines  (subsequently  replaced  by  Sierra  Pacific  Airlines).'^  From  the 
viewpoint  of  this  Subcommittee,  the  relevant  fact  is  that  in  recent  years  the 
absence  of  CAB  regulation  has  resulted  in  four  additional  airlines  providing 
scheduled  service  with  large  aircraft  within  California.  Thus,  there  is  appre- 
ciably more  airline  rivalry  in  California  today  than  there  would  have  been 
under  CAB  regulation.  This  is  obviously  undesirable  to  the  CAB-regulated  air- 
lines, but  it  has  demonstrably  benefited  many  California  residents  and  visitors, 
and  it  has  certainly  not  resulted  in  "a  single  carrier  monopolizing  all  of  the  Cali- 
fornia markets,"  neither  in  1965  nor  in  1975. 

REGULATOEY    PEOTECTION 

Mr.  Mitchell  is  right  when  he  says  that  the  PUC  "has  given  great  protection 
to  the  regulated  (intrastate)  carriers,"  but  his  further  statement  that  "[n]o 
competitive  authority  has  been  authorized"  is  incorrect."  Between  1968  and  1974 
the  PUC-authorized  rival  service  between  Air  California  and  PSA  in  the  follow- 
ing seven  city-pairs  :  Burbank-San  Jose/Oakland,  San  Diego-San  Jo.se/Oakland, 
Sacramento-Ontario/San  Diego,  and  short-haul  San  Jose-Oakland."  Further- 
more, in  1973  the  PUC  authorized  Holiday  Airlines  to  carry  local  pas.sengers  in 
the  San  Diego-Los  Angeles,  Los  Angeles-Burbank  and  Los  Angeles/Burbank- 
San  Jose/Oakland  city  pairs  on  flights  also  serving  Lake  Tahoe.'^  This  provided 
limited  rivalry  to  PSA's  unrestricted  services  between  those  cities. 

There  is  no  question  but  what  both  the  PUC  and  the  CAB  have  given  route  se- 
curity to  the  airlines  under  their  respective  jurisdictions.  There  is  also  no  ques- 
tion but  what  the  adoption  of  regulation  was  supported  by  the  trunk  carriers  in 
1938  and  by  PSA  in  1965.  Indeed,  this  support  of  regulation  by  the  concerned  car- 
riers is  extremely  relevant  evidence  about  their  perceptions  of  who  benefits  from 
government  regulation.  There  is  considerable  question,  however,  about  Mr. 
Mitchell's  statement  that  PSA's  management  believed  it  could  not  obtain  the 
necesary  financing  to  buy  Boeing  727  aircraft  "without  the  security  of  a  certifi- 
cate," ^°  and  there  is  also  some  question  that  "there  was  a  public  outcry  for  an 
end  to  the  uncertainty  and  chaos  resulting  from  the  free  entry  and  exit  of  the 
intrastate  air  carriers."  ™ 

Several  pieces  of  information  are  relevant  to  the  matter  of  buying  new  Boeing 
727's.  First,  PSA  was  able  to  finance  and  purchase  six  new  Electras  between  1959 
and  1963  without  the  benefit  of  regulated  route  security.^^  Second,  during  the  six 
years  from  1959  through  1964,  PSA  accumulated  profits  after  taxes  of  $7.3  million 
on  total  operating  revenues  of  76.0  million — hardly  a  record  that  would  discourage 
investors,  especially  in  light  of  the  low  profits  of  the  CAB-regulated  airlines  dur- 
ing the  early  1960s.^'  Third,  note  1  of  PSA's  1964  annual  report  contains  a  full  de- 
scription of  PSA's  financing  for  its  first  six  Boeing  727's  and,  as  can  be  seen  by 
reading  appendix  A  of  this  testimony,  there  is  no  indication  in  that  note  of  any 
undue  financial  diflSculties.  This,  even  though  the  arrangements  were  completed 
in  February  1965,  several  months  before  the  enactment  of  assembly  bill  413  gave 
the  PUC  the  power  to  grant  I'oute  security  to  PSA."^ 

Whether  or  not  there  was  actually  a  "public  outcry"  for  regulation  is  more 
diflicult  to  determine.  The  first  attempt  to  extend  substantial  PUC  regulation 
over  intrastate  airlines  occurred  back  in  early  1949.  If  there  was  a  public  outcry 
for  such  regulation  it  was  unsuccessful,  for  Senate  bill  1624  was  not  enacted.^ 
Appendix  B  of  this  testimony  gives  two  eclitorials  from  that  period  which  opposed 
or  questioned  the  purpose  of  that  bill,  so  it  is  clear  than  any  possible  outcry  was 
not  unanimous. 


« William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2,  at  7.  Mr.  Mitchell  mentions  Air  California  and 
Holiday  Airlines  on  pp.  12  and  13  of  liis  statement,  but  he  overlooljs  Sierra  Pacific  Airlines. 

"  James  L,  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  12. 

47  PUC  decisions  7424S  (June  11,  1968),  76110  (Sept.  3,  1969),  79085  (Aug.  24,  1971), 
and  83476  (Sept.  17,  1974).  PSA's  successful  effoi  t  to  eliminate  Air  California  from  the 
Burbank-San  Jose/Oakland  cit.v-pairs  is  described  in  William  A.  Jordan,  "Some  Predatory 
Practices  Under  Government  Regulation?"  10-22  (University  of  Toronto-York  University 
Joint  Program  in  Transportation,  Research  report  26,  January  1975). 

«PUC  decision  81S93  (Sept.  14,  1973). 

*»  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  rote  1,  at  12. 

sold,  at  11-12. 

"^1  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  42-43.  Also,  PSA  Annual  Report,  1   (1973). 

^  Id.  at  336-38.  Also.  CAB,  supra,  note  27,  at  74 

"•Td.  at  2. 

"«nate  bill  1024,  introduced  Apr.  20,  1949. 


610 

My  own  intensive  study  of  the  California  intrastate  carriers  began  in  January 
1965,^'  yet  I  was  unaware  of  the  State  Legislatures  plan  to  increase  the  i'l^C's 
jurisdiction  over  intrastate  passenger  airlines  until  my  first  visit  to  the  PUC's 
offices  in  early  March  1905.  At  that  time  a  PUC  official  advised  me  that  assembly 
bill  413  was  being  considered  and,  when  I  asked  why  this  was  happening  after  so 
many  years  of  unregulated  service,  his  reply  was  to  the  effect  that  this  time  PSA 
supported  the  legislation.^®  If  there  were  a  public  outcry  favoring  regulation  one 
would  expect  it  to  be  reflected  in  newspaiier  articles  of  that  period.  In  the  course 
of  my  research  I  went  through  the  clipping  files  of  the  Los  Angeles  Times  and  the 
San  Diego  Tribune  looking  for  information  concerning  intrastate  carriers.  No- 
where in  those  files  did  I  come  across  an  article  containing  statements  from 
passengers  (or  others)  complaining  about  intrastate-carrier  service  and  asking 
for  airline  regulation.  Mr.  Mitchell  may  be  able  to  supply  contrary  evidence,  but 
until  he  does  my  experiences  lead  me  to  believe  that  assembly  bill  413  was 
enacted  with  little  publicity,  let  alone  'public  outcry." 

EFFICIENCY   AND   LONG-RUN   PROBLEMS 

Unfortunately,  Mr.  Mitchell  failed  to  focus  on  that  part  of  my  testimony  con- 
cerning the  effect  CAB  regulation  has  had  in  substantially  decreasing  airline 
efficiency."'  The  evidence  that  regulation  greatly  decreases  eflSciency  (and  in- 
creases costs)  should  be  particularly  disquieting  to  the  regulated  airlines  because 
it  indicates  that  there  is  a  fundamental  economic  weakness  in  their  position  even 
if  they  are  successful  in  maintaining  the  regulatory  status  quo.  The  history  of  the 
regulated  airlines  has  been  one  of  recurrent  financial  problems  despite  an  overall 
secular  growth  rate  since  World  War  II  of  12.7  percent  per  year,  compared  with 
a  growth  in  constant-dollar  GNP  of  3.5  percent.^'  Thus,  there  is  reason  to  predict 
even  more  problems  will  occur  under  existing  regulation  should  the  airlines  enter 
a  period  of  small  growth  or,  eventually,  secular  decline. 

The  conclusion  of  my  testimony  mentions  two  legislative  alternatives  to  the 
status  quo  which  would  serve  to  increase  airline  eflSciency.  One  alternative  is  to 
"perfect"  CAB  regulation  by  placing  every  significant  aspect  of  airline  opera- 
tions under  the  control  of  the  Board.  The  second  alternative  is  to  deregulate  by 
abolishing  the  CAB's  control  of  entry  and  exit  and  to  allow  any  airline  to  lower 
its  fares  without  regulatory  constraint.^"  Furthermore,  under  this  second  alterna- 
tive the  airlines  would  be  subject  to  existing  antitrust  laws. 

The  CAB  has  been  moving  in  the  direction  of  the  first  alternative  over  the 
past  six  years  by  authorizing  an  increasing  number  of  capacity  agreements  and 
by  discouraging'  other  aspects  of  service-quality  rivalry  such  as  lounges  and 
liquor  "wars."  ""  The  perfection  of  CAB  regulation  may  have  considerable  appeal 
to  many  airline  executives  and  investors  since  it  should  do  much  to  solve  the 
current  financial  problems  of  some  of  the  airlines.  At  the  same  time,  however, 
this  move  would  be  detrimental  to  airline  suppliers  such  as  aircraft  and  engine 
manufacturers,  would  decrease  the  quality  of  service  offered  passengers  without 
compensating  decreases  in  fares,  and  would  allow  unions  and  other  monopolistic 
suppliers  of  inputs  to  increase  the  prices  of  their  inputs  or  to  establish  work  rules 


«sOn  pages  2  and  3  of  his  statement.  Mr.  Mitchell  reports  that  most  of  the  research 
for  my  dissertation  was  done  while  1  worl<ed  at  Western  Air  Lines  from  1960  to  1964. 
I  wish  that  had  been  the  ease,  both  because  it  would  have  resulted  in  the  dissertation 
being  completed  in  1966,  rather  than  1968,  and  because  I  much  prefer  being  paid  to  do 
research.  Unfortunately,  as  reported  in  the  preface  to  my  boolv,  while  my  work  at  Western 
made  me  keenly  aware  of  the  intrastate-carrier  "problem,"  and  thus  was  necessary  for 
the  conception  and  design  of  the  dissertation,  the  actual  research  was  undertaken  primarily 
between  January  1965  and  August  1967  while  I  was  a  doctoral  student  at  UCLA  and  an 
acting  assistant  professor  at  Stanford  University.  During  this  time,  however,  my  friends  and 
former  associates  at  Western  very  generously  allowed  me  to  use  Western's  library  of  CAB 
publications,  tariffs.  Official  Airline  Guides  and  files  concerning  Western  Air  Lines  of 
California.  These  were  very  important  contributions  to  the  study. 

50  Conversation  with  Mr.  John  L.  Pearson,  California  Public  Utilities  Commission 
(Mar.  8,  1965). 

E7  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2,  at  29-43. 

^  Total  certificated  route  air  carriers  produced  791  million  revenue  ton-miles  in  1946 
and  22,425  RTM  in  1974.  Gross  national  product  in  1958  dollars  increased  from  .$312.6 
billion  in  1946  to  $821.1  Mllion  in  1974.  CAB,  supra,  note  27,  at  12,  and  Air  Carrier 
Traffic  Statistics  1  (December  1974).  Also,  Economic  Report  of  the  President,  250 
(February  1975). 

^  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  2,  at  46-47. 

*>  William  A.  Jordan,  "Airline  Capacity  Agreements:  Correcting  a  Regulatory  Imper- 
fection," 39  Journal  of  Air  Law  and  Commerce,  184-93  and  202-5   (spring  1973). 


611 

whereby  less  input  is  received  for  a  given  price.  This  latter  point  is  very  impor- 
tant because  it  implies  that  vphile  short-run  efficiency  is  possible  through  in- 
creased regulation,  the  long-term  picture  is  not  encouraging. 

In  addition  to  the  long-run  efficiency  problem,  unless  those  administering  this 
"perfect"  CAB  regulation  prove  to  be  remarkably  perceptive  and  re.si>onsive  to 
the  development  of  substitutes  for  airline  services  and  to  this  and  other  sources 
of  changes  in  the  demand  for  airline  services,  the  perfection  of  regulation  has 
the  added  drawback  of  introducing  rigidities  and  economic  excesses  that  will 
hasten  the  decline  of  the  airline  industry.  A  Penn  Central  type  problem  is  much 
more  likely  under  the  extensive  regulation  of  a  few  large  airlines  than  under  the 
deregulation  alternative.  Deregulation  would  result  in  services  being  provided 
by  many  smaller  airlines.  Not  only  would  these  airlines  have  to  be  responsive 
to  economic  changes  in  order  to  survive,  but  the  failure  of  any  one  or  several  of 
them  would  cause  little  dislocation  in  the  economy.  The  recent  proposal  to  merge 
Pan  American  and  TWA  is  only  one  indication  of  how  merger,  a  frequent  regu- 
latory solution  to  airline  problems,  could  result  in  the  development  of  an  airline 
that  was  so  large  that  its  demise  would  yield  a  crisis  for  the  nation.^^ 

Since  increased  regulation  promises  immediate  solutions  to  problems,  and 
since  short-run  solutions  are  often  given  priority  over  long-run  solutions,  the 
alternative  of  "perfecting"  CAB  regulation  is  one  that  will  have  considerable 
appeal.  Some  specific  suggestions  on  how  CAB  regulation  can  be  improved  are 
presented  in  one  of  my  recent  papers  which  the  Subcommittee  may  find  useful.*^ 
Mr.  Mitchell,  however,  chose  to  emphasize  possible  problems  resulting  from 
deregulation,  so  the  following  sections  of  this  testimony  will  respond  to  some  of 
his  analyses  and  predictions  concerning  deregulation. 

SERVICE   TO   DENSE   MARKETS    ONLY? 

A  frequent  prediction  by  airline  executives  is  that  without  CAB  regulation 
scheduled  airline  service  would  be  available  only  over  the  densest  routes  con- 
necting the  largest  cities  in  the  country.  Mr.  Mitchell  makes  one  of  the  milder 
statements  in  this  vein  when  he  says  "[a]t  most,  a  few  carriers  will  survive  and 
they  will  tend  to  limit  their  activities  to  the  densest  markets."  ^ 

There  are  several  things  wrong  with  this  prediction.  First,  it  is  inconsistent 
with  the  California  intrastate  exi)erience.  Second,  it  ignores  the  long-standing 
policy  of,  initially,  the  regulated  trunk  carriers  and,  now,  the  local-service 
carriers  to  drop  small  cities  from  their  routes.  Third,  it  is  inconsistent  with  the 
law  of  diminishing  marginal  returns. 

Evidence  on  the  California  experience  is  presented  in  my  book.*^  Actually,  as 
discussed  above,  the  efforts  of  the  intrastate  carriers  to  serve  small  city-pairs 
are  quite  remarkable  given  the  prior  coverage  of  the  subsidized  CAB-regulated 
airlines  in  California. 

The  relative  coverage  of  small  cities  by  various  classes  of  airlines  is  also  in- 
structive. As  of  May  1,  1973,  the  trunk  carriers  provided  service  to  only  183 
communities  in  the  48  contiguous  states,  compared  with  401  for  the  subsidized 
local  service  carriers  and  333  for  the  unregulated  and  unsubsidized  commuter 
carriers.*^  Of  the  244  unduplicated  communities  with  1970  populations  of  25,000 
or  less  having  scheduled  airline  service,  the  trunk  carriers  provided  service  to 
only  17  (at  ten  they  provided  the  only  service),  while  the  local  service  carriers 
operated  at  129  such  communities,  and  the  communter  carriers  at  132  (102  of 
which  received  their  sole  service  from  a  commuter  carrier).""  When  it  comes  to 
unsubsidized  service,  small  communities  clearly  received  much  more  service  from 
the  unregulated  commuter  carriers  than  Irom  the  regulated  trunk  carriers.  If 
deregulation  meant  the  termination  of  trunk-carrier  service  at  such  small  com- 
munities, the  loss  would  be  negligible  and  would  quickly  be  taken  up  by  com- 
muter or  local  service  carriers. 

The  law  of  diminishing  marginal  returns  says,  simply,  that  if  you  hold  one 
physical  input  constant  and  increase  the  use  of  another  input,  eventually  the 


81  Charles  E.  Schneldei-,  "Banks  Asked  to  Support  Pan  American,"  101  Aviation  Week 
and  Space  Teclinology,  31-32  (Sept.  23,  1974). 

*-  William  A.  Jordan,  "If  We're  Going  to  Regulate  the  Airlines,  Let's  do  it  Right," 
James  C.   Miller  III,  ed..   Perspectives  on  Federal  Transportation  Policy    (1975). 

«3  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  13. 

^  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  17-24,  115-33  and  258-59. 

«  CAB,  A  Profile  of  Airline  Service  in  the  48  Contiguous  States.  May  1.  1973  table  1 
(December  1974). 

«8  Id.  at  tables  3,  4.  5  and  9. 


612 

marginal  output  from  using  more  of  tlie  second  input  readies  a  peak  and  begins 
to  decrease.  A  common  classroom  example  is  adding  fertilizer  to  an  acre  of  land 
to  grow  wheat,  but  an  analogy  for  the  airlines  would  be  adding  airplanes  to  a 
single  major  route,  such  as  New  York-Chicago-Los  Angeles,  to  produce  airline 
service.  The  results  of  operating  over  2,000  aircraft  eight  hours  a  day  on  this 
single  route  are  obvious  and  ludicrous."'  Somewhat  less  obvious,  but  equally 
ludicrous,  would  be  the  operation  of  more  than  2,000  aircraft  over  routes  con- 
necting just  the  top  100  city-pairs.  The  law  of  diminishing  returns  predicts,  and 
quite  reflection  supports,  that  aircraft  fleets  would  be  dispersed  over  the  entire 
U.S.,  covering  high,  medium-  and  low-density  routes  until  the  cost  (including 
the  market  rate  of  return  on  investment)  of  producing  the  last  flight  with  a 
suitable  aircraft  on  each  route  would  roughly  equal  the  revenues  obtained  from 
that  flight.  This  doesn't  mean  that  scheduling  would  be  error  free.  Scheduling 
mistakes  are  made  under  regulation  and  they  would  occur  without  regulation. 
The  difference  is  that  without  regulation  open  entry  would  quickly  discipline 
those  who  make  frequent  mistakes,  while  the  discipline  of  the  market  works 
more  slowly  under  regulation. 

SERVICE    QUALITY    AND   FARES    WITHOUT   REGULATION 

The  California  intrastate  experience  leads  Mr.  Mitchell  to  believe  that  "over 
the  long  term,  fares  would  be  higher  and  service  would  be  inferior  to  that 
existing  under  a  properly  regulated  system."  **  Unfortunately,  it  is  impossible 
to  make  a  precise  evaluation  of  this  statement  because  the  characteristics  of 
"a  properly  regulated  system"  are  not  specified.  However,  assuming  such  a  system 
would  have  many  of  the  properties  of  historical  CAB  regulation,  the  California 
experience  does  demonstate  that  service  quality  without  regulation  would  indeed 
be  inferior  to  that  existing  under  CAB  regulation.  Without  regulation  coach 
service  would  be  even  more  dominant  than  it  is  today  and  there  would  be  little 
first-class  service  ;  aircraft  design  would  emphasize  low  operating  costs  relatively 
more  than  the  traditional  emphasis  on  service  quality  ;  and  passenger  load  factors 
in  excess  of  70  percent  would  be  the  norm  rather  than  the  present-day  50- 
to  55-percent  average."'  But,  in  contrast  to  Mr.  Mitchell's  prediction,  the  Cali- 
fornia evidence  is  clear  that  without  regu'ation  fares  would  be  as  i,auch  as  50 
percent  lower  than  the  coach  fares  authorized  by  the  CAB.  The  great  acceptance 
of  intrastate-carrier  service  in  California  indicates  that  a  majority  of  passengers 
prefer  this  tradeoff  of  somewhat  inferior  service  quality  for  much  lower  fares. 

DISTORTIONS    FROM    PROTECTED    INTERNATIONAL    OPERATIONS 

Mr.  Mitchell  raises  the  interesting  possibility  that,  with  open  entry  domesti- 
cally, carriers  having  governmental  protection  in  their  international  operations 
would  enjoy  "a  substantial  competitive  advantage"  over  carriers  limited  to  do- 
mestic operations."  If  this  were  truly  an  important  advantage,  TWA  should 
now  be  the  dominant  transcontinental  carrier  (which  it  is  not),  and  American 
should  have  fought  to  retain  its  North  Atlantic  routes  in  1950  and  its  South 
Pacific  routes  in  1974  ( which  it  did  not ) . 

Actually,  the  California  experience  provides  relevant  evidence  regarding  this 
matter.  As  far  as  airline  regulation  is  concerned,  California  can  be  considered 
to  have  been  a  "country"  with  entry  open  to  any  carrier  on  its  domestic  routes, 
but  with  controlled  entry  into  "international"  routes  to  all  other  countries,  in- 
cluding those  47  "sovereign  states"  located  to  the  north  and  east  of  it.  Despite 
the  limited  geographic  size  of  the  "country"  of  California  and  the  resulting 
relatively  small  demand  for  "domestic"  airline  services,  its  unprotected  "do- 
mestic" carriers  set  the  basic  service-quality  and  fare  levels  wherever  they  pro- 
vided service,  and  were  able  to  force  the  protected  "international"  airlines  to 
oifer  low-fare  coach  services  in  those  city  pairs.  True,  the  citizens  of  California 
were  greatly  benefited  by  their  airlines,  and  only  the  most  eflScient  of  the  Cali- 
fornia carriers  were  able  to  survive,  but  those  few  carriers  that  did  survive  were 
also  benefited  by  their  government  allowing  them  the  opportunity  to  enter  and 


87  The    system    fleets    of    all    trmk   carriers    (minus   Pan    American)    and   local    service 
carriers  totaled  2.164  aircraft  as  of  Dec.  31,  1972.  CAB,  supra,  note  27,  at  1-2. 
8s  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  4. 
«»  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  4,  at  34-56  and  200-209. 
TO  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  i  ote  2,  at  7-29 
71  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  14. 


613 

test  their  mettle  against  the  protected  "international"  airlines.  To  use  Mr. 
iUitcheil  s  word,  the  results  may  have  been  "distorted"  from  what  would  have 
occurred  had  entry  been  open  in  the  much  larger  market  provided  by  the  47 
adjacent  "countries,  "  but  many  consider  the  results  to  have  been  preferable  to 
the  other  distortion  that  would  have  occurred  had  entry  never  been  open  so  that 
California  would  have  had  to  depend  on  "international"  airlines  for  all  of  its 
airline  services. 

Mr.  Mitchell  points  out  a  major  problem  faced  by  airlines  with  "interna- 
tional" routes  when  he  says  "the  markets  these  stronger  (international)  carriers 
would  tend  to  serve  would  have  little  to  do  with  domestic  air  transportation 
needs  of  the  public.  The  markets  served  would  be  those  best  suited  to  interna- 
tional travel,  and  the  services  would  be  so  geared."  '"  This  may  explain  why  the 
certificated  trunk  carries  were  unable  to  maintain  their  dominant  positions  in 
California  city  pairs  large  enough  to  support  two  or  more  carriers.  The  special- 
ized California  intrastate  carriers  geared  their  services  to  the  air  transportation 
preferences  of  the  California  public,  and  the  majority  of  these  passengers  re- 
sponded by  utilizing  those  more  convenient  services.  The  same  would  occur  were 
all  U.y.  city-pairs  open  to  any  carrier  meeting  FAA  operating  standards.  To  the 
extent  carriers  with  international  routes  geared  their  services  to  international 
demand  they  would  be  at  a  disadvantage  in  domestic  U.S.  routes, 

Mr.  Mitchell  also  states  that  "carriers  with  strong  international  routes  would 
have  a  substantial  competitive  advantage  which  could  and  undoubtedly  would 
be  used  to  improve  their  economic  position  to  the  detriment  of  carriers  without 
such  protected  routes."  "  I  assume  he  means  that  profits  from  international  routes 
would  support  predatory  pricing/practices  by  these  carriers.  Since  1958,  there 
have  been  a  number  of  studies  of  alleged  predatory  pricing  in  unregulated  in- 
dustries, and  all  have  found  predation  to  be  relatively  costly  and,  therefore,  rare. 
I  have  recently  completed  a  study  of  three  alleged  cases  of  predatory  practices 
among  airlines  operating  under  government  regulation,  and  my  findings  are 
generally  consistent  with  the  earlier  studies.''^  Predation  appears  to  be  a  favorite 
spectre  to  be  raised  by  suppliers  who  fear  the  "chaos"  of  open  entry.  It  happens, 
however,  that  predation  occurs  much  more  frequently  in  speeches  and  trade- 
journal  articles  than  it  actuaHy  occurs  in  the  economy.  It  may  be  that  the  CAB- 
regulated  airlines  practiced  predation  against  the  California  intrastate  carriers 
from  1949  to  1965.  If  so,  they  are  certainly  in  a  position  to  provide  clear  evidence 
to  support  allegations  that  carriers  with  international  routes  will  have  a  pre- 
datory advantage  over  domestic  carriers  operating  under  open  entry.  But  this 
evidence  should  be  forthcoming  before  any  great  weight  is  given  to  such  allega- 
tions. 

DISTORTIONS    FROM    PROTECTED    INTRASTATE    OPERATIONS 

"At  the  other  end  of  the  spectrum,  the  air  transportation  system  would  be 
distorted  by  protective  action  by  state  aeronautic  boards  and  public  utility  com- 
mission." "®  This  is  another  interesting  idea  and  it  has  antecedents  in  the  rail- 
road industry  through  1920.  The  problem  for  the  railroads  was  largely  resolved 
by  the  Supreme  Court  and  Congress  in  favor  of  the  primacy  of  interstate  com- 
merce.™ Similar  decisions  for  the  airlines  would  be  even  more  effective  since  the 
comparative  advantage  of  the  airlines  is  in  long-haul  transportation,  making 
interstate  traffic  much  more  important  in  airline  than  in  railroad  operations.  If 
nothing  else,  the  relative  size  of  interstate  traffic  is  evidenced  by  the  fact  that 
there  are  only  a  few  states  in  which  intrastate  airlines  have  appeared. 

Appendix  B  of  my  original  testimony  shows  that  intrastate  city-pairs  provided 
21  out  of  the  top  100  origin-destination  city-pairs  in  1972  in  terms  of  passengers 
(but  not  RPM).''  However,  14  of  these  21  city-pairs  were  located  in  California 
and  two  were  in  Texas,  leaving  only  five  more  large  intrastate  city-pairs  in  the 
remaining  47  states  (excluding  Hawaii).  Also,  there  is  no  evidence  to  date  that 
state  regulation  in  California  and  Texas  has  been  detrimental  to  pas.sengers. 
Furthermore,  even  assuming  full  carrier  protection,  it  is  difficult  to  imagine  many 


72  Id.  at  15. 

73  I,J     n^   24 

'*  William  A.  Jordan,  supra,  note  47.  Several  of  the  earlier  studies  are  noted  in  this 
paper. 

"s  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  ro.  

•'"Gibriel   Kolko,   Railroads   and   Regulation,   1877-1916,   164-69   and  217-30    (1965). 

77  William  A  Jordan  supra,  note  2.  at  50-52.  The  state  of  Hawaii  is  excluded  sinco 
flights  over  international  waters  mt.ke  all  intratJtate  service  subject  to  CAB  regulatioc. 


614 

new  airlines  being  attracted  to  intrastate  city  pairs  witliin  Vermont,  New  Hamp- 
shire, Massachusetts,  Rhode  Island,  Connecticut.  New  Jersey  and  Delaware;  nor 
do  the  city-pairs  within  North  Dakota.  South  Dakota,  Nebraska,  AVyoming.  Mon- 
tana, Idaho,  Utah  and  others  seem  to  hold  much  promise  to  intrastate  carriers 
operating  large  aircraft.  Overall,  given  the  allure  of  cities  in  adjacent  states  and 
the  evidence  that  protective  regulation  decreases  airline  efficiency,  it  would  be 
very  surprising  if  state  regulation  would  significantly  distort  air  transportation 
in  the  U.S. 

PERIOD   OF   ADJUSTMENT 

Mr.  Mitchell  contends  I  am  incorrect  in  predicting  that  about  ten  years  would 
be  required  for  the  airlines  to  adjust  to  the  deregulation  of  entry  and  fare  de- 
creases. Instead,  he  predicts  that  conditions  would  remain  chaotic  and  unstable.'™ 
For  understandable  reasons,  he  equates  stability  with  no  new  entry  and  with  no 
carrier  failure.  This  is  similar  to  an  error  students  frequently  make  in  thinking 
that  equilibrium  in  a  perfectly  competitive  market  structure  means  there  is  no 
change  in  industry  membership.  Actually,  in  a  competitive  market  structure  inef- 
ficient firms  are  regularly  replaced  by  new,  more  eflScient  firms.  Tlius,  individual 
firms  experience  "chaos,"  but  the  industry  itself  functions  smoothly  in  efficiently 
providing  desired  goods  and  services  to  consumers  at  low  prices. 

Nothing  in  the  California  experience  nor  in  my  analysis  indicates  that  after  a 
10-year  adjustment  period  all  of  the  100  to  over  200  airlines  then  in  existence 
would  continue  providing  service  with  no  failures,  no  new  entry  or  similar 
rigidities.  This  is  not  the  way  an  unregulated  economy  works.  Aggressive,  effi- 
cient firms  will,  of  course,  replace  inefficient  firms.  This  is  undesirable  to  those 
replaced,  but  it  benefits  consumers  as  well  as  the  owners  and  employees  of  the 
efficient  firms.  My  10-year  prediction  refers  to  the  period  of  time  required  to 
eliminate  the  excess  capacity,  high  fares  and  important  inefficiencies  that  have 
developed  in  the  CAB-regulated  industry  over  the  past  37  years.  From  Mr. 
Mitchell's  viewpoint,  and  that  of  individual  airlines,  "chaos"  will  remain  long 
after  this  period  of  adjustment  is  over. 

CONCLUSION 

Enough  has  been  said  to  explain  why  I  disagree  with  Mr.  Mitchell's  analysis 
of  the  evidence  from  the  California  intrastate  and  other  relatively  unregulated 
airline  experiences.  Now  it  is  time  to  step  back  and  look  at  the  overall  picture. 
No  sensible  person  will  argue  that,  given  the  limits  of  technological  developments, 
the  service  of  the  existing  CAB-regulated  airlines  has  been  anything  but  out- 
standing during  the  past  37  years.  Similarly,  it  cannot  be  seriously  proposed  that 
California  travelers  have  had  inadequate  .service  from  the  combined  operations 
of  all  the  airlines  with  routes  in  the  state.  Certainly,  over  the  years  the  average 
quality  of  service  within  California  has  been  somevihat  lower  than  that  offered  in 
similar  East  coast  city-pairs,  but  California ns  were  given  a  choice  between  high- 
quality,  high-fare  service  and  lower-quality,  lower-fare  service,  and  the  great 
majority  (but  not  all)  opted  for  the  latter.  The  expressed  preference  favored 
those  intrastate  carriers  able  to  provide  service  in  a  very  efficient  manner.  There 
were  many  painful  and  heartbreaking  experiences  among  those  California  intra- 
state carriers  unable  to  succeed  within  the  restricted  confines  of  the  .state,  but 
at  least  they  were  allowed  to  try  and  tho.se  few  that  were  successful  did  benefit 
from  that  opportunity.  At  the  same  time,  most  passengers  also  benefied. 

Mr.  Mitchell  says  that  Continental  Air  Lines  does  not  oppose  new  entrants  into 
the  CAB-regulated  airline  industry  and  that  it  has  urged  the  Board  to  "have  a 
more  open  mind  than  it  has  shown  in  the  past  to  con.sider  the  applications  of  new 
entrants."  ™  Unfortunately,  the  Board  has  had  an  absolutely  closed  mind  regard- 
ing new-carrier  applications  for  trunk  .service  since  1938,  and  it  has  allowed  only 
one  airline.  Air  New  England,  to  enter  the  ranks  of  the  local  service  carriers 
since  1950.  Given  this  consistent  record,  it  seems  reasonable  to  conclude  that  "a 
more  open  mind"  will  be  inadequate  to  provide  the  benefits  of  open  entry  to  con- 
sumers of  airline  services.  Furthermore,  Mr.  Mitchell  makes  no  mention  of  the 
related  requirement  that  there  be  no  regulation  of  fare  reductions. 

Perhaps  the  most  eloquent  testimony  regarding  the  actual  effects  of  CAB 
regulation  is  contained  in  the  published  statements  of  industry  spokesmen  con- 


's Id.  at  47.  Also,  James  L.  Mitcholl,  supra,  note  1,  at  4  and  11. 
''  James  L.  Mitchell,  supra,  note  1,  at  15-16. 


615 

cerning  the  likely  destruction  of  the  airline  industry  if  open  (free)  entry  were 
to  become  a  reality.""  In  essence  they  are  saying  that  regulated  airlines  with  as 
much  as  37  years  of  experience  would  be  no  match  for  new  airlines.  Why  should 
these  experienced  airlines  with  their  existing  aircraft,  trained  personnel,  estab- 
lished routes  and  markets  have  such  fear  of  commuter  carriers  growing  into 
larger  operations,  supplemental  carriers  providing  scheduled  services,  existing 
intrastate  carriers  expanding  into  adjoining  states,  and  completely  new  airlines 
being  organized  by,  say,  former  airline  or  Air  Force  personnel?  Do  they  really 
appreciate  the  apparent  degree  to  which  their  regulated  operations  have  become 
inefficient,  or  is  it  merely  a  habitual  and  understandable  effort  to  protect  the 
status  quo  and  save  themselves  from  making  minor  adjustments  if,  indeed,  they 
are  the  best-qualified  producers  of  airline  services  ? 

The  fears  of  industry  chaos  and  instability  reflect  the  viewpoint  of  suppliers, 
not  consumers.  Furthermore,  it  overlooks  the  fundamental  reality  that  there 
is  a  great  demand  for  airline  services.  The  advantages  of  air  travel  have  been 
apparent  to  man  since  the  dawn  of  time.  Man's  ingenuity  made  air  travel  ix)s- 
sible  starting  in  iyu3,  commercial  air  transportation  become  economically 
feasible  in  the  late  twenties  and  early  thirties,  and  the  tremendous  technologi- 
cal advances  achieved  in  World  War  II  and  subsequent  years  have  made  air 
transportation  the  most  preferred  way  to  travel  long  distances.  While  the  rate  of 
growth  shows  some  signs  of  tapering  off  (assisted  by  relatively  high  fares),  the 
fundamental  demand  for  this  service  remains  strong  and  pervasive.  It  is  this  de- 
mand, not  CAB  regulation,  that  has  provided,  and  will  continue  to  provide, 
stability  in  the  industry  from  the  viewpoint  of  the  consumer.  This  great  demand 
means  that  airlines  will  continue  to  operate  for  many  years  under  existing  CAB 
regulation  as  well  as  under  a  "perfected"  CAB  regulation,  despite  the  long-run 
problems  and  rigidities  associated  with  regulation.  Alternatively,  it  also  means 
ihai  airline  services  will  continue  to  be  supplied  if  regulation  is  abolished.  Under 
deregulation,  however,  the  economic  viability  of  the  industry  will  be  greater  than 
under  regulation  because  surviving  airlines  will  be  more  efficient  and  more  sen- 
sitive to  consumer  demand. 

Appendix  A. — Notes  to  PSA's  1974  Financial  Statements 

1.  Boeing  Model  727-14  jet  aircraft.— The  company  has  on  order  six  Boeing 
Model  727-14  jet  aircraft.  Five  aircraft  are  scheduled  for  delivery  in  1965  and 
the  sixth  in  1966.  Unpaid  open  commitments  relating  to  these  aircraft  and  re- 
lated spare  equipment  totaled  $25  million  at  December  31,  1964  of  which  $22.5 
million  is  due  in  1965. 

In  connection  with  these  purchases,  in  February  1965,  the  company  entered 
into  a  loan  agreement  with  the  Bank  of  America  National  Trust  and  Savings 
Association,  Connecticut  General  Life  Insurance  Company  and  Teachers  Insur- 
ance and  Annuity  Association  of  America  to  borrow  $23  million  by  issuing  51^ 
percent  series  A  installment  notes  in  the  amount  of  $14  million  and  5i/>  percent 
series  B  installment  notes  in  the  amount  of  $9  million.  Series  A  installment 
notes  will  be  payable  in  monthly  installments  of  $166,667  commencing  January  1, 
1966  with  the  final  payment  due  December  1,  1972.  Series  B  installment  notes  will 
be  payable  in  quarterly  installments  of  $500,000  commencing  March  1,  1973  with 
final  payment  due  June  1,  1977. 

The  existing  51/2  percent  installment  notes  payable  to  bank  of  $3,258,319  are 
to  be  prepaid  without  penalty  from  the  proceeds  of  the  above  notes. 

In  addition  to  the  above  mentioned  financing,  the  company  has  made  arrange- 
ments to  borrow  up  to  $1.1  million  at  6  percent  interest  from  the  manufacturer 
for  purchase  of  the  sixth  aircraft.  The  amount  borrowed  will  be  repaid  over  a 
5-year  period. 

The  company  will  use  certain  of  its  current  funds  to  meet  the  commitment  de- 
mands in  1965  in  lieu  of  drawing  on  loan  funds  until  necessary. 

Under  the  terms  of  the  related  chattel  mortgage  indenture,  the  Electra  air- 
craft, flight  equipment  and  parts  inventory  and  the  Boeing  Model  727-14  air- 
craft and  spare  equipment,  when  delivered,  are  pledged  to  secure  these  notes. 
The  indenture,  among  other  restrictions,  limits  the  retained  earnings  available 
for  payment  of  cash  dividends  to  $1  million  plus  75  percent  of  net  income  less 
100  percent  of  net  losses  after  December  31,  1964.  Further,  the  company  must 

so  102  Aviation  Week  and  Space  Technology,  20-22  (Apr.  7,  1975). 


616 

maintain  stockliolders'  equity  of  not  less  than  $9  million  and  as  of  September 
1965,  working  capital  of  $1  million  or  SVs  percent  of  cash  operating  expenses  for 
the  preceding  fiscal  year  whichever  is  greater.  $6,347,871  of  retained  earnings  at 
December  31,  1964  is  not  available  for  cash  dividends  under  these  provisions. 

2.  Common  stock.— In  January  1964,  the  company  declared  a  40  percent  stock 
split  in  the  form  of  a  stock  distribution  of  two  shares  of  common  stock  for  each 
five  shares  held.  In  addition,  the  Board  of  Directors  increased  the  stated  value 
of  the  common  stock  to  $1  per  share. 

Under  the  restricted  stock  option  plan  approved  by  the  stockholders  in  De- 
cember 1962,  options  on  the  company's  common  stock  were  authorized  to  be 
granted  to  certain  key  employees  at  not  less  than  95  percent  of  the  fair  market 
value  of  the  stock  at  the  date  of  grant.  The  options  are  exercisable  one-third  each 
year  beginning  1  vear  after  grant  date  and  will  expire  5  years  from  giant  date. 
Options  to  purchase  56,000  shares  were  granted  in  1963  at  an  option  price  of 
$12.90  per  share  after  giving  effect  to  the  above  mentioned  stock  split).  At  De- 
cember 31,  1964,  49,237  shares  of  common  stock  are  reserved  for  employee  stock 
options  outstanding  and  options  for  11,904  shares  are  exercisable. 

At  December  31,  1964,  7,283  shares  of  common  stock  are  reserved  for  conversion 
of  the  61/2  percent  subordinated  convertible  notes  based  on  the  conversion  price 
of  $7.14  per  share. 

3.  Federal  income  tax.— In  1964,  the  investment  credit  has  been  reclassified  on 
the  accompanying  balance  sheet  from  accumulated  obsolescence  and  deprecia- 
tion, and  is  included  within  the  deferred  federal  income  tax.  The  balance  of  the 
investment  credit  is  being  amortized  as  a  credit  to  the  provision  for  federal  in- 
come tax  over  the  remaining  useful  lives  of  the  related  assets. 

Jf.  Commitments. — Commitments  for  purchase  of  new  flight  equipment  are  dis- 
cussed in  note  1. 

Annual  rent  commitments  under  various  long-term  property  and  equipment 
leases  are  approximatelv  as  follows:  1965— $294,000 ;  1966— $226,000 ;  1967— 
$221,000;  1968— $167,000;  1969— $130,000 :  1970  through  1972— $105,000 ;  1973 
through  1981— $87,000  and  $76,000  thereafter  until  1990  (the  reductions  resulting 
mainly  from  the  expiration  of  leases). 

5.  Expanded  route  structure  and  fare  changes. — In  January  1965,  the  company 
made  or  has  pending  changes  in  its  route  and  fare  structures.  See  the  president's 
letter  for  comments  regarding  these  matters. 

Appendix  B. — Editorials  Regarding  Senate  Bill  1624  (May  1949) 

The  Dogfighting  Airlines 

[From  the  Burbank  Daily  Review,  2,  May  10, 1949] 

The  airline  politicians  are  at  it  again. 

This  week,  air  politics  threaten  another  of  the  low-cost  independent  flying 
services  based  at  Lockheed  Air  Terminal  in  Burbank. 

Under  a  bill  introduced  into  the  state  senate  and  now  before  the  committee 
on  public  utilities,  airlines  which  carry  on  their  business  entirely  within  the 
state  would  come  under  regulation  of  the  state  public  utilities  commission. 

The  independent  airline  carriers,  which  charge  $9.99  for  a  trip  from  Burbank 
to  San  Francisco,  not  including  tax,  against  $21  for  the  major  airlines,  are 
protesting  the  bill  introduced  by  State  Senator  George  J.  Hatfield  of  Newman. 

Senator  Hatfield  represents  Madera  and  Merced  counties,  both  of  which  to- 
gether have  a  population  which  approximates  that  of  the  city  of  Burbank. 
Neither  county  boasts  of  a  city  which  would  merit  service  by  any  scheduled  air 
carrier  or  conceivably  have  an  interest  in  the  airline  problem — except  for  the 
private  interests  of  individuals  like  Senator  Hatfield. 

Nevertheless,  Senator  Hatfield  has  made  air  politics  his  own  particular  inter- 
est, clearly  in  the  interest  of  "protecting"  the  public  from  low-cost  air  trans- 
portation. 

Any  casual  onlooker  who  has  only  a  smattering  [sic]  of  information  concerning 
the  machinations  of  the  airline  politicos  ought  to  be  disgusted  by  the  series  of 
attempts  made  to  hamstring  air  progress. 

All  planes  operating  out  of  major  airfields  are  under  the  supervision  of  air 
safety  regulations  of  the  federal  Civil  Aeronautics  Authority.  There  is  no  ques- 


Source  :  PSA  Annual  Report  (1974). 


617 

tion  that  the  Burbank-to-San  Francisco  lines  fly  safely.  One  airline  involved 
has  a  record  of  5,800,000  accident-free  passenger  revenue  miles.  There  is  no 
question  that  the  service  is  not  cutthroat  comi^etition,  because  the  independent 
small  airlines  cannot  afford  to  operate  at  a  loss. 

Independent  nonscheduied  airlines  between  Burbank  and  east  coast  cities  have 
recently  been  the  victims  of  attack  through  the  federal  Civil  Aeronautics  Board, 
not  to  be  confused  with  the  CAA. 

These  efforts  to  keep  flying  out  of  the  range  of  the  average  man's  iwcketbook 
are  clearly  for  the  benefit  of  a  few  large  companies,  which  evidently  do  not  stop 
at  anything  including  political  means  to  achieve  profits. 

It  is  high  time  that  the  airline  lobbyists  realize  what  they  are  doing.  They  will 
eventually  legislate  themselves  into  unprofitable  operation,  just  as  the  railroad 
lobbyists  of  anocher  day  succeeded  in  doing. 

Certainly,  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission,  which  is  responsible  for 
rail,  streetcar,  and  buslines  in  this  state,  does  not  have  a  record  of  encouraging  or 
providing  the  public  with  excellent  transportation  of  any  type.  If  existing  facili- 
ties prove  anything,  the  opposite  has  been  the  case.  We  would  hate  to  see  the 
commission  obtain  control  of  air  travel  in  this  state  also. 

What  can  be  done  to  protect  the  public's  interest  in  aviation?  The  public 
certainly  deserves  more  consideration  from  state  and  federal  goveinment  than 
do  the  private  interests  of  the  large  corporate  interests. 


Appendix  C. — Valley  Air  Service 
[From  the  Valley  Times.  Editorial  page  (n.d.)] 

Intrastate  flights  originating  at  Lockheed  Air  Terminal  and  serving  the  Bay 
area,  primarily,  are  being  threatened  with  "grounding  tactics"  by  the  pro- 
visions of  Senate  Bill  1624,  sponsored  by  Senator  Hatfield. 

These  regular  flights  constitute  practically  the  whole  of  intrastate  passenger 
business  originating  in  the  Valley  for  the  convenience  of  the  thousands  of  air- 
minded  citizens  w^ho  daily  use  these  lines  to  the  north. 

Most  of  the  commercial  lines  come  into  the  Municipal  Field,  many  miles  from 
the  Valley,  except  when  fog  drives  them  to  Lockheed  Air  Terminal. 

The  importance  of  having  air  passenger  service  available  to  the  more  than 
7,000  persons,  who,  during  the  period  from  March  15  through  April  30,  this  year, 
were  carried  by  Robin  Airways,  Inc.  between  Burbank  and  Oakland,  and  to  the 
7,012  passengers  flown  by  Central  Airlines  during  the  month  of  April  from  Bur- 
bank to  San  Francisco,  is  evident. 

In  the  light  of  these  phenomenal  passenger  figures  which  established  the  need 
/or  flights  into  and  out  of  the  Valley,  it  would  appear  that  Senator  Hatfield 
should  withhold  action  on  his  bill  pending  completion  of  a  survey  of  nonscheduied 
flights  being  prepared  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

It  also  appears  that,  with  the  coach-type,  average-man-priced  service  these 
local  lines  are  rendering,  a  complete  study  of  their  activities  is  warranted  before 
they  are  subjected  to  an  unnecessarily  quick  decision  on  their  fate  made  without 
reference  to  actual  factual  data. 

This  unheralded  bill  was  scheduled  to  come  before  the  Senate  for  reading  on 
May  11.  However,  when  these  affected  companies  found  out  about  the  impending 
legislation,  they  were  able  to  delay  this  Teading  and  to  secure,  instead,  a  public 
hearing  on  Ma.v  16. 

Adequate  discussion  with  full  deliberation  upon  this  imi>ortant  matter  must 
result  in  continuing  this  service  so  important  to  valleyites. 

The  valley,  which  is  a  cradle  of  aviation  industries  and  air  enthusiasts,  cer- 
tainly justifies  passenger  service  from  the  Lockheed  Air  Terminal  to  the  Bay  area 
and  to  other  states  in  the  nation. 

We  feel  that  Senator  Hatfield,  when  apprised  of  these  facts  at  the  public  hear- 
ing, will  deem  it  wise  to  proceed  cautiously  and  await  the  important  CAB  report 
before  acting  on  his  bill. 

Response  of   Continental  Airlines,   Inc.   to   Supplementary  Testimony   os 
Dr.   William   A.   Jordan 

On  April  21,  1975,  Professor  Jordan  submitted  a  39-page  "supplementary 
testimony"  which,  in  essence,  is  a  rebuttal  to  the  supplementary  statement  filed 


618 

with  the  subcommittee  by  James  L.  Mitchell,  vice  president  of  regulatory  proceed- 
ings of  Continental  Airlines. 

Although  we  find  many  of  Professor  Jordan's  statements  to  be  misleading,^ 
we  will  not  engage  in  a  point-by-point  rejoinder.  A  far  better  purpose  can  be 
served  at  this  juncture  by  directing  utteiitiou  to  the  critical  issue  which  confronts 
the  subcommittee.  That  issue,  simply  stated,  is  what  conclusions  can  be  drawn 
from  the  California  intrastate  experience,  and  can  that  experience  be  reliably 
projected  to  a  national  system. 

As  Mr.  Mitchell  pointed  out  in  his  statement,  there  are  "some  limitations  on 
generalizing  too  much  from  this  [the  California]  exi>erience."  (Statement,  p.  5.) 
Professor  Jordan  apparently  agrees,  when  he  states  that  "[tjhere  are  indeed 
limitations  to  generalizing  from  the  California  (and  Texas)  experience.  .  .  ." 
(Supplementary  Testimony,  p.  15.)  However,  after  making  this  statement. 
Professor  Jordan  goes  on  to  generalize  with  the  assertion  that : 

"With  open  entry  nationwide,  airlines  could  operate  more  efl5ciently  and 
enjoy  lower  operating  costs  than  experienced  in  constrained  intrastate  areas, 
demand  for  their  services  would  be  far  greater,  and  there  would  probably 
be  proportionally  fewer  failures  than  what  occurred  within  California" 
{Id.). 
At  a  later  point  in  his  testimony,  Professor  Jordan  argues  that : 

"The  specialized  California  intrastate  carriers  geared  their  services  to  the 
air  transportation  preferences  of  the  California  public,  and  the  majority  of 
these  passengers  responded  by  utilizing  those  more  convenient  services.  The 
same  would  occur  were  all  U.S.  city  pairs  open  to  any  carrier  meeting  FAA 
operating  standards  (Id.,  p.  30,  emphasis  supplied.) 
We  disagree  with   Professor  Jordan  that   such   broad  generalizations  can   be 
projected  from  the  California  experience.  The  California  exj^erience,  as  Professor 
Jordan  now  seems  to  realize  is  characterized  by  a  stable  base  of  service  required 
to  be  provided  by  the  CAB-certificated  carriers  coupled  with  strong  price  and 
service  competition  from  aggressive  intrastate  carriers  who  had  to  be  aggressive 
in  order  to  make  inroads  into  the  marketplace.  The  two  classes  of  airlines  com- 
plemented one  another,  and  the  public  benefited  by  this  blend. 

Notwithstanding  the  financial  failures  of  various  intrastate  carriers,  the 
major  California  markets  continued  to  receive  good  basic  service,  because  they 
were  served  by  CAB-certificated  air  carriers.  Even  Professor  Jordan  makes  this 
point  by  naming  the  CAB-certificated  carriers  to  support  his  argument  that  the 
public  received  reliable  service  : 

"Surely,    given    the    continuing   services   of   PSA,    United,    TWA,    Western, 
Pacific  and  other  airlines,  it  is  incorrect  to  say  that  passengers  had  no 
assurance  of  receiving  reliable  air  service"  (Supplementary  testimony  p.  16.) 
In  the  major  markets,  the  people  of  California  have  had  the  best  of  both  worlds — 
stable,   reliable  service   by   the   CAB-certificated  carriers  and  aggressive  price 
competition  stimulated  by  the  intrastate  carriers.  In  Professor  Jordan's  words, 
"Overall,  the  rivalry  between  individual  carriers,  regardless  of  their  regu- 
latory classification,  has  resulted  in  an  outstanding  coverage  and  quality  of 
service  being  provided  by  all  airlines  as  a  group.  As  far  as  the  consumer  is 
concerned  it  is  this  overall  level  of  service  that  counts,  and  the  airline  con- 
sumer has  been  amply  blessed  in  California."  (Id.,  p.  0  emnhasis  supplied.) 
Without  the  presence  of  the  CAB-certificated  air  carriers,  the  people  of  California 
would  not  have  enjoyed  the  benefits  of  the  competitive  rivalry  which  existed 
between  PSA  and  these  airlines.  In  criticizing  Mr.  Mitchell  for  failing  to  mention 
the  CAB-certificated  carriers,  Professor  Jordan  points  to  their  presence  as  having 
prevented  a  "monopoly  situation  :" 

"Was  there  any  airline  monopoly  in  California?  Mr.  Mitchell  states  that  by 
1965  the  period  of  open  entry  in  California  'produced  a  single  carrier 
monopolizing  all  of  the  (major)  California  markets.'  He  fails  to  mention 
that  at  that  time,  in  addition  to  PSA,  service  was  provided  in  major  Cali- 
fornia city-pairs  by  American,  Delta,  National,  TWA.  United,  AVestern  and 
the  three  predecessors  of  Hughes  Airwest  (Bonanza,  Pacific  and  West 
Coast).  This  was  hardly  a  monopoly  situation  (Id.,  p.  19). 


^  An  example  Is  his  criticism  of  Continental  at  pages  8-9  of  his  testimony  for  failing  to 
serve  some  of  the  California  satellites,  which  ignores  the  fact  that  community  opposition  at 
Long  Beacli  and  Orange  County  to  any  new  airline  entry  on  environmental  grounds  forced 
Continental  to  curtail  its  ser.ice  plan." 


619 

It  is  clear  from  the  history  of  the  California  experience  that  the  CAB-certifi- 
cated  carriers  provided  two  signiticant  public  beiietits.  First,  they  provided  a 
stable  base  of  air  service  on  which  the  pnldic  could  rely  when  confronted  by  the 
financial  failures  of  the  intrastate  carriers.  Second,  the  very  presence  of  the 
LAB-certincated  carriers,  as  well  as  their  competitive  response,  spurred  I'SA 
to  otter  low  fares  and  freciueut  schedules  in  the  primary  corridor  markets  be- 
tween San  Diego,  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco.  I'SA  had  to  otter  these  l>enefits 
in  order  to  succeed  in  the  marketplace  in  competition  with  the  CAB  certificated 
carriers. 

Tlie  competitive  battle  between  PSA  and  the  CAB-certificated  carriers  is  de- 
scribed in  a  1966  article  published  in  the  Journal  of  Air  Law  and  Commerce^' 
That  article,  which  is  a  portion  of  a  prize  winning  paper  at  Yale  University, 
describes  PSA's  entry  into  the  Los  Angeles-San  Francisco  market  with  low  fares 
and  frequent  service  and  the  competitive  response  by  TWA,  United  and  Western 
with  similar  fares  and  even  better  service.  For  example,  Western  responded 
to  PSA's  Electra  service  by  undercutting  PSA  on  price  and  using  DC-6B's. 
United  introduced  pure  jet  aircraft  with  a  fare  only  $1.05  higher  than  that 
charged  by  for  Electra  service.  United  and  TWA  both  ottered  commuter  service. 

Tills   varied   competitive   response  by   the  trunklines   reduced  PSA's  market 
share  and  spurred  PSA  to  improve  its  own  service  by  upgrading  its  equipment 
to  pure  jets  and  increasing  its  schedules.  PSA  was  then  able  to  recapture  its 
lost  traflSc.  The  public  was  the  obvious  beneficiary  of  this  comi)etitive  struggle: 
"Thus  PSA,  through  vigorous  competition  in  fares,  equipment,  and  schedul- 
ing, has  been  able  to  succeed  in  this  important  market.  The  trunks  have 
recently   met   the   competition,   and   the  advantages  to  the   consumer  are 
evident  .  .  ."  (Id.,  p.  609.) 
Had  the  trunklines  not  been  serving  the  market,  PSA  would  not  have  felt  the 
pressure  to  improve  its  service,  and  the  public  would  not  have  been  presented 
with  the  variety  and  range  of  service  and  fare  offerings  that  were  made  available. 

Projected  to  a  national  scale,  this  experience  indicates  that  the  public  would 
benefit  by  new  entry  into  air  transix»rtation,  just  as  it  was  benefited  by  PSA's 
entry  into  the  prime  California  corridor  markets.  Indeed,  that  has  been  Conti- 
nental's position,  as  expressed  by  Mr.  Mitchell :  '^ 

"In  fact,  we  believe  that  new  entrants  maintain  vitality  in  the  industry. 
They  bring  innovation,  which  means  public  benefits.  Moreover,  the  threat 
of  new  entrants  being  permitted  into  the  industry  spurs  the  incumbents  to 
better  serve  the  public  ..." 
But,  as  Professor  Jordan  concedes  by  his  own  arguments,  the  California  experi- 
ence also  makes  clear  that  the  public  is  better  .served,  if,  in  addition  to  receiving 
service  and  fare  benefits  from  new  entrants,  it  is  assured  of  continuing,  reliable 
air  service  from  certificated  air  carriers.  The  California  experience  shows  that 
competition  works  in  both   directions — the  new  entrants  spur  the  incumbents 
to  react  with  improved  service  which,  in  turn,  spurs  the  new  entrants  to  improve 
their  own  service.  At  the  same  time,  the  public  can  rely  on  continuing  service  by 
the  certificated  carriers  if  new  entrants  should  fail. 

Viewing  the  California  experience  with  caution — because,  after  all,  that  ex- 
perience is  related  to  very  high  density  commuter  markets — one  nevertheless 
can  conclude  that  the  CAB  should  undertake  to  certificate  qualified  new  entrants 
who  would  provide  new  .service  and  fare  benefits  to  the  public  and  stimulate  a 
competitive  response  by  existing  air  carriers.  However,  one  cannot  use  the  Cali- 
fornia experience  to  leap  to  the  conclusion  that  tliere  should  be  open  entry. 
Indeed,  there  is  no  historic  experience  to  support  the  concept  of  open  entry  in 
nationwide  air  transportation.  The  arguments  for  open  entry,  however  well- 
intentioned,  are  only  arguments  which  reflect  the  proponents'  judgment  that 
open  entry  will  work.  The  implementation  of  open  entry  carries  with  it  the  risk 
that  their  judgment  is  wrong.  Professor  .lordan  is  certainly  entitled  to  his 
opinions,  but  the  subcommittee  .should  consider  these  opinions  in  the  context 
of  what  actually  happened  in  California  and  how  that  experience  can  be  used 
to  improve  what  is  generally  regarded  as  the  best  air  tran.sportation  system  in 
the  world.  Given  the  fact  that  a  good  national  air  transportation  system  does 
exist,  albeit  with  deficiencies,  it  would  seem  a  better  approach  at  this  juncture 
improve  the  system  by  introducing  healthy  doses  of  competition  rather  than  tear- 


2.\twoocl.   JR..  "Intrastate  Carrier-Competitive  Impact-raclfic   Southwest  Airlines,"  32 
J.  Air  I^-iw  &  Comm.  007.  autumn  1906. 
^Supplementary  Statement,  pp.  l.")-]6. 


620 

ing  the  system  apart  and  risking  the  possibility  that  needed  public  service  will 
be  lost. 

Prepared  Statement  of  Edwin  I.  Colodny,  Exect:tive  Vice  President, 
Marketing  and  Legal  Affairs,  Allegheny  Airlines,  Inc. 

Allegheny  Airlines  was  pleased  to  be  included  in  the  list  of  companies  invited 
to  participate  in  these  most  vital  hearings  concerning  the  future  course  of 
regulation  of  the  U.S.  domestic  air  transport  industry. 

My  statement  will  be  directed  primarily  to  the  subcommittee's  interest  in  route 
regulation. 

The  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958  and  its  predecessor  statute  has  been,  by 
and  large,  a  success.  The  ability  to  move  by  scheduled  air  carrier  on  a  convenient 
basis  throughout  the  United  States  speaks  for  itself.  The  safety  record  of  this 
industry  is  remarkable,  and  will  undoubtedly  continue  to  improve. 

But  despite  how  good  we  believe  the  system  to  be,  we  know  it  can  be  improved 
upon.  There  is  opportunity  for  needed  service  improvements,  without  amending 
the  statute.  Before  commenting  on  this,  however,  I  believe  it  would  be  helpful 
for  the  subcommittee  to  know  why  Allegheny  believes  the  basic  statutory 
approach  of  the  P'etleral  Aviation  Act  should  be  left  alone. 

Let  me  use  Allegheny  as  an  example  of  the  growth  and  service  possible  under 
the  existing  statute. 

Since  1964,  Allegheny  has  grown  from  a  small  local  airline  which  served  about 
1.5  million  passengers  in  1965,  to  a  large  regional  carrier  which  served  about  11 
million  passengers  in  1974.  Our  commercial  revenues  grew  from  $27.5  million 
to  .$366  million  in  this  period.  Assets  of  the  company  increased  from  $45  million 
to  $290  million.  Earnings  have  grown  at  a  less  dramatic  rate  though  they  reached 
over  $6  million  in  1974.  Retained  earnings  at  the  end  of  1974  were  minus  $578,000. 
The  shareholders  have  received  only  two  cash  dividends  in  the  company's 
history— 5  cents  i)er  share  in  1965  and  6  cents  per  share  in  1966.  Allegheny 
received  no  federal  subsidy  in  1974.  Management  of  the  company  has  remained 
essentially  unchanged  for  over  20  years. 

This  record  was  made  possible  by  three  key  achievements  sanctioned  by  the 
Act: 

1.  Route  grants  issued  pursuant  to  section  401(a)  of  the  Act; 

2.  Mergers  with  two  other  local  service  airlines,  Lake  Central  in  1968  and 
Mohawk  in  1972,  pursuant  to  section  408  of  the  Act ;  and 

3.  Approval  of  the  Allegheny  commuter  agreements  pursuant  to  which  the 
CAB  permitted  Allegheny  to  suspend  service  at  loss  points  in  favor  of  independent 
commuter  operators  utilizing  smaller  equipment. 

Allegheny  has  exercised  the  authority  resulting  from  the  foregoing  actions  in  a 
vigorous  manner,  providing  service  in  large  and  small,  as  well  as  competitive  and 
monopoly  markets.  The  Allegheny  history  is  the  product  of  the  administration  of 
the  Federal  Aviation  Act  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  (CAB)  which,  as  an 
institution,  has  reflected  a  wide  range  of  philosophies  over  the  years. 

Prior  to  1965,  the  CAB  had  denied  most  applications  by  the  local  service  car- 
riers to  serve  heavily  traveled  short  or  medium-haul  markets  served  by  trunk- 
lines.  Then,  the  Board  shifted  its  policy  and  encouraged  local  carriers  to  improve 
their  route  structures  to  fit  the  jet  age  which  was  then  upon  us.  To  assist  in  this 
transition,  the  CAB  adopted  a  procedure  for  expediting  applications  to  remove 
restrictions  on  local  carriers  to  permit  .service  in  competition  with  trunklines 
in  short-  and  medium-haul  markets,  where  such  services  were  needed  and  could 
be  .shown  to  be  profitable  and  subsidy-reducing. 

Allegheny  applied  for  and  received  authority  in  several  large  markets,  such  as 
New  York-Pitt.sburgh,  Chicago-Pittsburgh  and  St.  Louis-Pittsburgh.  Allegheny's 
share  of  these  markets  in  fiscal  year  1974  was  43,  26  and  55  percent,  respectively. 
We  have  concentrated  our  jet  fleet  on  100  passenger,  twin-engine  DC-9-30  aircraft 
in  single-class  configuration  at  coach  fare  levels.  We  emphasize  convenient  serv- 
ice with  necessary  amenities.  No  first-class  compartments.  No  free  liquor. 

Today,  Allegheny  is  a  strong  competitor  against  large  carriers  .such  as  United, 
TWA,  American  and  Delta. 

We  offer  a  wide  variety  of  discount  fares:  weekend  excur.sion  at  25  percent 
off,  group  10  travel  at  33  percent  off,  tour  basing  fares  at  20  percent  off,  as  well  as 
clergy  and  military  reduced  rates. 

And  we  have  requested  CAB  approval  to  expand  the  new  Bicentennial  excursion 
fares  to  all  markets  on  our  system. 


621 

We  also  have  pending  a  new  group  fare  for  small  groups  between  4  and  9.  This 
new  fare  would  reduce  the  cost  of  travel  to  family  and  other  groups  by  20  percent. 

Because  of  our  strong  discount  fare  program,  we  are  able  to  promote  Allegheny 
as  the  No.  1  moneysaver  in  a  large  number  of  important  markets. 

While  developing  as  a  major  factor  in  the  dense  short-  and  medium-haul  mar- 
kets, Allegheny  was  at  the  same  time  developing  a  new  way  of  providing  better 
service  at  no  cost  to  the  Federal  Government  for  many  small  cities. 

In  1967,  the  CAB  permitted  Allegheny  to  commence  the  first  experiment  with 
a  commuter  replacement  program  at  Hagerstown,  Maryland.  The  success  of  the 
Allegheny  commuter  experiment  is  well-known.  Under  this  program  27  cities  now 
receive  service  from  12  independent  air  carriers  under  contract  to  Allegheny. 
These  carriers  operate  at  a  profit  with  no  Federal  subsidy  support.  In  1974, 
operating  small  aircraft  such  as  Beech  99,  Twin  Otter  and  Nord  262,  these  carriers 
generated  over  one  million  passengers  primarily  to  and  from  smaller  cities  which, 
prior  to  the  Allegheny  commuter,  supported  only  limited  frequency  and  required 
heavy  subsidy  support.  The  consumer  benefits  at  the  small  cities  involved  are 
obvious.  By  and  large,  these  are  the  kinds  of  communities  which  have  received 
limited  benefit  from  a  policy  of  free  entry  which  already  exists  under  part  298 
of  the  CAB'S  regulations. 

The  success  of  the  Allegheny  commuter  story  lies  in  its  integration  of  small 
city  service  to  the  mainline  air  transport  network  of  this  country.  A  prime  exam- 
ple is  Salisbury,  Maryland,  which  enplaned  over  31,000  passengers  in  1974.  These 
passengers  travelled  all  over  the  United  States  and  internationally,  many  of 
them  on  Allegheny  Airlines  through  connections  at  Baltimore/Washington  Inter- 
national Airport  (BWI),  Washington  National  Airport,  and  Philadelphia  Inter- 
national Airport.  This  could  not  be  achieved  without  having  the  benefit  of  an 
integrated  system  to  ease  connecting  travel  and  encourage  use  of  the  local  air- 
ports instead  of  driving  2  hours  to  BWI  to  board  aircraft. 

Furthermore,  these  passengers  have  had  the  benefit  of  a  fare  structure  similar 
to  that  of  the  local  service  industry,  including  joint  rates  to  our  Allegheny  cities 
and  many  offline  cities,  as  well  as  the  discount  fares. 

I  appreciate  the  concern  of  the  subcommittee  as  well  as  the  concern  of  some 
persons  both  within  the  government  and  outside,  with  the  proposition  that  our 
regulatory  scheme,  by  restricting  freedom  of  entry  or  exit,  has  led  to  higher  cost 
air  service  than  need  be  paid  by  the  travelling  public.  As  stated  by  one  of  the 
earlier  witnesses,  the  Chairman  of  the  Federal  Trade  Commission,  we  have  the 
most  comprehensive,  stable  air  transport  network  in  the  world.  In  his  opinion, 
however,  the  co.st  has  been  a  fare  structure  on  many  routes  which  is  higher  than 
would  prevail  if  the  industry  were  characterized  by  price  competition  and  free 
entry. 

In  my  opinion,  freedom  of  entry  would  do  nothing  to  reduce  the  price  of  air 
travel  at  the  small  and  intermediate  cities  in  this  country.  I  also  believe  that 
freedom  of  entry  in  the  larger  markets  would  ultimately  seriously  impair  service 
to  the  small  and  intermediate  cities. 

As  the  subcommittee  knows,  under  part  298  of  the  CAB's  regulations,  any  indi- 
vidual has  been  free  to  start  an  airline  and  operate  at  any  city  in  the  country  on 
an  exempt  basis,  provided  he  utilizes  smaller  aircraft  not  exceeding  a  30  pas- 
senger capacity.  Freedom  of  entry  is  available,  therefore,  at  smaller  and  interme- 
diate size  cities  and  has  been  for  years.  However,  the  fares  charged  by  most 
commuter  carriers  serving  such  points  is  generally  higher  than  certificated  car- 
riers charge. 

The  public  interest  in  markets  of  this  type  is  less  likely  to  be  related  to  the 
price  of  air  transportation  as  it  is  to  the  availability.  The  citizens  of  northern 
New  England — Vermont,  New  Hampshire  and  Maine — have  recently  concluded 
years  of  effort  before  the  CAB  in  an  attempt  not  to  get  cheaper  air  travel,  but  to 
get  adequate  air  service.  Had  freedom  of  entry  been  a  .success  in  northern  New 
England,  it  would  not  have  been  necessary  for  the  CAB  to  certificate  Air  New- 
England  to  provide  new  services  at  the  many  communities  involved,  at  a  sub- 
stantial cost  in  Federal  subsidy. 

I  have  speculated  as  to  what  might  have  been  Allegheny's  policy  toward  small, 
loss  points  had  we  had  freedom  to  exit  without  CAB  approval.  It  is  questionable 
whether  the  Allegheny  commuter  concept  would  have  been  created,  and  most  of 
these  27  points  would  have  simply  disappeared  from  the  scheduled  airline  mac. 

The  CAB  has  permitted  deletion  of  certificated  service  at  many  small  points 
without  replacement  services  being  provided,  where  poor  traffic  generation 


622 

high  subsidy  were  found  to  warrant  such  action.  While  the  Board  has  tended  to 
require  that  service  be  retained  in  some  marginal  situations,  on  balance  we  do 
not  believe  the  present  statute  requires  amendment  to  liberalize  dropping  of 
points. 

Ho  much  for  the  smaller  city  side  of  the  question. 

What  about  the  larger  communities  and  city -pairs  with  greater  traffic  density? 
The  CAB  recently  released  a  staff  study  on  domestic  routes.  This  Study  con- 
tains much  valuable  information  on  the  character  of  the  present  system.  Par- 
ticularly signiticant  is  the  data  which  shows  that  relatively  few  of  ihe  58,000 
city  pair  markets  generate  the  bulk  of  the  traffic.  Of  total  revenue  passenger- 
miles  "tO  percent  are  flown  in  fewer  than  1,000  pairs.  Of  the  revenue  passenger- 
mile  potential  30  percent  is  found  in  only  70  city-pairs. 

Of  Allegheny's  total  system  passengers  50  percent  enplane  and  deplane  on 
just  39  pairs  of  points— 11  percent  of  the  total  of  369  pairs  of  points  served  on 
a  single-plane  basis  (exhibit  1). 

It  seems  to  us  that  a  change  in  direction  which  permitted  freedom  of  entry 
would  in  effect  be  directed  toward  larger  markets  and  not  the  balance  of  the 
system. 

Some  of  these  larger  city-pair  markets  are  served  by  Allegheny.  For  example, 
Pittsburgh-Chicago,  New  York-Indianapolis,  Pittsburgh-Philadelphia,  Boston- 
Philadelphia,  Pittsburgh-New  York,  Buffalo-New  York,  and  Rochester-New  York 
are  all  in  the  top  100  ranked  passenger  markets  over  200  miles  distance.  There 
can  be  no  question  about  the  ability  of  these  markets  to  support  competitive  serv- 
ices. These  markets  are  competitive  on  all  fronts,  including  price  competition. 

Each  of  these  markets  is  not  only  served  by  an  aircraft  schedule  serving  the 
specific  city-pair,  but  is  part  of  a  traffic  flow  on  schedules  which  provide  beyond 
service  to  other  points.  For  example,  Allegheny's  Chicago-Pittsburgh  services  go 
beyond  to  Allegheny  points  such  as  Wilkes-Barre/Scranton,  Harrisburg  and 
Allentown,  Pennsylvania.  The  flights  which  service  the  Philadelphia-Pittsburgh 
segment  also  serve  cities  such  as  Albany,  Hartford  and  Providence  to  the  east, 
Erie,  Columbus,  Dayton,  Louisville  and  Indianapolis  to  the  west. 

In  scheduling  the  system,  flight  evaluation  is  keyed  to  the  profitability  of  the 
flight  as  a  whole,  since  the  traffic  flows  are  made  up  of  a  series  of  individual 
markets.  Thus,  a  flight  serving  the  Pittsburgh-Philadelphia  market  may  well 
serve  four,  five  or  six  other  city-pairs,  e.g.,  a  fiight  from  Providence  to  Hartford. 
Philadelphia,  Pittsburgh  and  Columbus,  would  serve  10  individual  city-pairs. 
The  ability  of  the  flight  to  be  scheduled,  however,  frequently  is  dependent  on  the 
load  factor  on  the  critical  segment  between  Philadelphia  and  Pittsburgh. 

Exhibit  2  reflects  a  profile  of  the  traffic  over  the  Pittsburgh-Philadelphia  seg- 
ment. Of  the  47,391  passengers  carried  over  the  segment  in  July  1974,  33,736  or 
71  percent  were  local  Philadelphia-Pittsburgh  on  and  off,  and  the  remaining  29 
percent  were  through  passengers.  This  263  mile  segment,  which  is  also  served  by 
TWA,  received  29  daily  flights  by  Allegheny  in  July,  1974  at  an  average  load 
factor  of  60  percent  over  the  segment.  It  is  conceivable  that  if  restrictions  were 
eliminated  on  entry,  this  segment  could  be  attractive  to  a  person  investing  in  a 
small  fleet  of  jet  aircraft,  perhaps  two  or  three  units  to  get  into  business,  slash 
the  price,  and  attempt  to  drive  Allegheny  and  TWA  out  of  the  market.  Alle- 
gheny and  TWA  would  then  have  to  choose  between  meeting  the  competition  by 
a  combination  of  price  and/or  service  adjustments. 

Exhibit  3  reflects  a  similar  profile  of  traffic  over  the  Chicago-Pittsburgh  seg- 
ment. In  this  case,  over  50  percent  of  Allegheny's  passengers  come  from  other 
than  the  local  market. 

Without  question  the  availability  of  reasonable,  frequent  air  service  between 
many  other  points  which  are  served  on  a  single-carrier  or  single-plane  basi*? 
because  of  Allegheny's  ability  to  schedule  frequently  over  this  segment,  would 
be  destroyed.  The  benefits  to  local  travelers  between  Philadelphia  and  Pitts- 
burgh are  questionable  when  viewed  against  the  disservice  to  the  large  volume 
of  travelers  which  are  dependent  on  this  segment  to  support  their  services. 
This  subcommittee  should  pause  and  reflect  before  imposing  a  solution  in  an 
effort  to  lower  prices  for  some  consumers  which  will  in  effect  destroy  the  system 
or  tend  to  increase  the  prices  paid  by  others. 

It  is  conceivable  that  a  few  larsre  concentrations  of  traffic  in  this  country 
would  benefit  by  freedom  of  entry.  I  have  no  doubt  that  long-haul  transcontinental 
markets  such  as  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  to  New  York,  or  perhaps  a  few 
of  the  Chicago  markets  could  conceivably  benefit  by  open  entry  and  a  rate  war 


623 

between  competing  carriers.  But  I  do  not  think  we  need  expose  tlie  system  to 
competiiive  destruction  in  order  to  achieve  some  of  the  results  which  are 
desirable. 

We  should  all  be  wondering  whether  under  a  freedom  of  entry  concept  certain 
large  trunk  airlines  would  find  markets  of  other  carriers  sufficiently  inviting  to 
warrant  a  raid. 

And  we  should  ask  ourselves  what  the  "domino"  effect  would  be.  Carriers 
forced  to  withdraw  from  their  markets  would  look  for  other  piaces  to  fly  the 
aircraft  in  which  they  have  invested.  There  is  obviously  no  answer  to  this 
Pandora's  box. 

We  urge  the  subcommittee  to  take  note  of  the  fact  that  a  major  reason  for  the 
recent  increased  demand  for  low  cost  air  service  in  the  domestic  air  travel 
market  has  come  about  because  of  decisions  by  the  Federal  courts  which  forced  the 
CAB  to  review  the  legality  of  the  youth  and  family  plan  fares.^  These  decisions 
ultimately  led  to  a  finding  by  the  CAB  that  youth  fares  and  family  plan  fares 
were  unlawful  under  the  present  statute.  Allegheny  opposed  that  decision  and 
believed  the  CAB  couid  have  found  such  fares  lawful,  but  the  CAB  found 
otherwise. 

A  significant  reduction  in  the  cost  of  air  travel  can  be  made  by  the  reinstate- 
ment of  youth  and  family  plan  fares  under  guidelines  which  would  ensure  their 
being  economically  viable.  This  may  require  legislation  by  the  Congress  to  permit 
the  airlines  to  otter  these  reduced  rate  services.  Hearings  on  the  Low  Cost  Air 
Transportation,  S.  421,  introduced  by  Senators  Cannon  and  Kennedy,  will  pro- 
vide a  forum  for  reviewing  this  subject.  It  will  also  provide  an  opportunity  to 
consider  offering  reduced  rate  travel  to  our  senior  citizens.  Allegheny  supports 
these  objectives. 

A  major  burden  on  the  traveler  is  being  imposed  due  to  the  tremendous 
increase  in  the  cost  of  jet  fuel.  Allegheny's  projected  1975  fuel  costs  per  gallon 
are  approximately  110  percent  higher  than  1973  levels.  Fuel  accounts  for  14  per- 
cent of  our  operating  expenses.  With  the  magnitude  of  increases  now  being 
experienced,  there  is  no  way  to  maintain  the  price  of  air  travel  at  a  lower  level 
by  adding  more  airlines.  The  answer  is  for  the  federal  government  to  control  the 
price  which  is  paid  for  the  fuel.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  we  see  a  rather  serious 
incompatibility  between  the  government's  fuel  conservation  effort  and  the  push 
for  freedom  of  entry  and  exit  in  public  transportation  by  air. 

We  also  understand  that  you  will  be  considering  other  possible  ratemaking 
policy  matters  later  in  this  hearing  which  could  increase  the  ability  of  scheduled 
carriers  to  adjust  fares  to  meet  market  demand. 

Improved  efficiency  at  Federal,  State  and  local  governmental  levels  in  the 
operation  of  the  ground  portion  of  the  air  transport  system  could  be  a  direct 
contributor  to  reducing  the  price  of  air  travel.  Airport  maintenance  and  operating 
costs  as  well  as  capital  plant  costs  have  risen  rapidly  as  a  result  of  inflation 
and  environmental  impact  problems.  The  airlines  are  expected  to  support  these 
increa.sed  costs  through  their  use  fees.  Additionally,  airport  operating  delays 
continue  as  a  result  of  still-to-be-achieved  efficiency  in  the  air  traffic  control 
system  and  this  directly  impacts  airline  operating  costs. 

Obviously,  there  are  things  the  airlines  themselves  must  do  to  control  the  cost 
of  air  travel.  We  must  reexamine  the  technological  side  of  our  business  to  avoid 
premature  obsolescence.  While  unit  cost  improvement  which  came  about  through 
the  jet  development  obviously  has  been  a  tremendous  boon  to  the  country,  future 
development  must  proceed  on  the  theory,  of  improving  the  productivity  of  the 
aircraft  without  necessarily  increasing  the  size  of  the  machine. 

If  the  Congress  adopts  a  program  which  looks  toward  allowing  freedom  of 
entry,  the  airlines  will  be  faced  with  the  impairment  of  the  stability  of  -  its 
invested  capital  and  the  ability  to  raise  long-term  funds  to  permit  orderly  growth. 
Such  financial  instability  would  l)e  totallv  inconsistent  with  the  funding  of  our 
air  transport  system  by  private  canital.  While  those  who  advocate  freedom  of 
entry  are  honing  for  more  free  enterprise,  more  competition  and  lower  prices, 
the  frnit  of  this  effort  could  well  be  a  system  of  nationalized  air  transportation 
funded  bv  the  Government  for  which  the  country  would  pay  an  enormous  price. 
The  Congres*!  should  be  extremely  concerned  that  this  constant  searchmc  for  a 
lower  priced  product  may  have  an  extremely  adverse  impact  on  the  ability  of 


1  T^nvurnvfivptttnl  nim  Sliiifrm .  Tnr  v.  C.A.P..  SS.*?  F.2rl  4fiR  .5*^h  Ctr.,  iQfiT  fvonrti  rnresi  : 
Trnihrnj/s  of  Mew  England,  Inc.,  et  aj.  v.  C.A.B.,  412  F.2d  926,  1st  Clr.,  1969  (family 
fares). 


624 

the  industry  to  plan  its  growth  on  an  orderly  basis  and  to  be  funded  at  reasonable 
costs.  One  of  Allegheny  s  large  expenses  is  for  interest  on  the  debt  which  is 
required  to  finance  modem  equipment.  Last  year's  interest  expense  exceeded  $12 
million.  I  would  think  that  the  degree  of  risk  in  a  system  which  required  airlines 
to  fend  for  themselves  with  no  security  of  profitable  route  services  would  create 
a  tremendous  cost  burden  on  the  system. 

With  regard  to  artificial  restraint  of  competition  by  means  of  the  capacity 
agreements  which  have  been  entered  into  by  some  carriers,  we  understand  the 
motivation  which  has  led  to  approval  of  these  agreements.  However,  Allegheny 
has  opposed  this  philosophy  since  it  was  first  considered  by  the  CAB.  We  think 
it  is  a  proper  matter  for  legislative  review. 

In  summary,  we  at  Allegheny  do  not  believe  that  freedom  of  entry  is  really 
the  issue.  There  are  numerous  certificated  airlines  available  to  do  the  job,  particu- 
larly the  local  service  airlines  and  smaller  trunks.  We  are  willing  to  invest 
money  to  expand  service,  and  at  reasonable  prices.  Since  the  late  sixties,  as  a 
result  of  the  CAB's  route  policy  which  permitted  the  local  service  industry  to 
expand,  the  CAB  has  created,  in  effect,  eight  regional  trunklines  who  ettectively 
compete  in  many  markets  with  the  large  carriers. 

While  urging  that  the  Congress  not  disturb  the  sections  of  the  Act  dealing  with 
route  entry  and  exit,  we  do  so  in  full  recognition  that  there  are  some  things 
which  do  need  attention,  and  in  which  Congressional  interest  can  be  beneficial. 
One  deals  with  the  vexing  problem  of  the  so-called  "route  moritorium"  which  the 
CAB  imposed  by  indirection  commencing  in  1970  and  1971. 

The  downturn  in  the  economy  which  occurred  at  that  time  was  properly  recog- 
Jiized  by  the  CAB  as  requiring  a  slowdown  in  awarding  new  route  authority. 
To  the  extent  there  have  been  excessive  route  awards  in  recent  years,  they  have 
been  in  certain  long-haul  situations,  such  as  the  proliferation  of  carriers  in  the 
Hawaiian  market.  But  at  the  other  end  of  the  spectrum  there  remain  many  short 
and  medium  haul  markets  under  700  miles  where  monopoly  has  been  permitted 
to  remain  even  where  service  has  decline  to  inadequate  levels. 

This  is  not  the  proper  forum  for  arguing  cases  which  are  in  the  CAB's  hands. 
But  I  would  like  to  give  the  subcommittee  some  examples  of  the  type  of  situation 
we  are  concerned  about.  In  December  1971  Allegheny  filed  an  application  under 
the  CAB's  subpart  M  rule  for  removal  of  a  restriction  which  prevented  nonstop 
flights  by  Allegheny  between  Louisville  and  Memphis — an  American  Airlines 
monopoly  where  service  has  declined  to  once  or  twice  a  day.  American  objected 
to  our  entry.  The  Board  has  been  silent  since  1971  on  the  application. 

Since  1972,  the  Board  has  denied  a  hearing  on  three  other  Allegheny  applica- 
tions to  remove  restrictions  which  prevent  Allegheny  from  competing  on  an  equal 
basis  with  American  in  monopoly  situations :  Cleveland-Cincinnati,  Cleveland- 
Louisville,  and  Cleveland-Rochester.  Yet  these  cities  look  to  Allegheny  for  relief 
from  American's  inadequate  service.  And  in  two  of  the  markets — Cleveland- 
Cincinnati  and  Cincinnati-Washington — TWA  sits  on  dormant  rights  which  it  is 
free  to  exercise  at  any  time,  but  neglects  to  do. 

There  are  other  examples  of  this  type  of  situation  which  require  a  shift  in 
CAB  policy  for  correction.  Trunklines  should  not  be  permitted  to  sit  on  dormant 
grandfather  rights  which  another  carrier  could  use  to  the  benefit  of  the  public 
as  well  as  itself. 

The  correction  lies  not  in  a  change  in  the  law,  but  perhaps  in  more  regular 
oversight  hearings  by  the  appropriate  committees  of  Congress.  We  have  today 
a  great  flexibility  in  the  statute  for  changing  the  route  structure  by  new  route 
awards  under  the  broad  umbrella  of  public  convenience  and  necessity,  as  well  as 
through  mergers,  suspensions  and  route  transfers.  Administration  of  the  statute 
has  varied  according  to  the  views  of  the  members  of  the  Board.  But  that  seems 
to  reflect  the  intent  of  Congress  that  there  be  a  5-man  commission  reflecting  a 
variety  of  points  of  view.  The  Congress  wisely  intended  to  leave  a  good  deal  of 
discretion  in  this  commission.  But  the  Congress  did  intend  that  the  commission 
exercise  the  discretion  in  a  way  in  which  the  public  could  challenge  through  the 
administrative  process,  and  the  courts  if  need  be. 

As  I  understand  the  recently  released  route  study  of  the  CAB's  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights,  the  Board  is  considering  new  rules  which  will  deal  with  the 
grant  of  hearing  priorities.  In  addition,  the  Board  is  considering  new  standards 
which  will  deal  with  grant  of  applications.  Allegheny  does  not  necessarily  sub- 
scribe to  the  standards  and  guidelines  which  are  being  suggested  and  we  will  file 
our  comments  in  due  course. 


625 

It  appears  to  us,  therefore,  that  while  the  CAB  has  been  less  than  responsive 
in  the  past  few  years  in  certain  areas  related  to  service  deficincies,  it  is  moving 
to  correct  the  situation  by  appropriate  proposed  rulemaking.  We  believe  the  Con- 
gress should  urge  the  Board  to  utilize  existing  statutory  authority  to  grant  com- 
petitive authorizations  in  the  many  monopoly  markets  which  can  support  service 
by  two  carriers.  In  this  way  the  CAB  would  be  providing  an  opportunity  for  a 
new  carrier  to  improve  the  service  by  adequate  scheduling,  which  is  a  more 
urgent  need  in  many  market  pairs  than  a  need  for  cutrate  service. 

In  conclusion,  we  believe  that  if  the  Congress  were  to  express  its  opinions  with 
regard  to  the  various  matters  which  are  under  consideration  on  a  more  frequent 
basis,  and  were  to  utilize  its  oversight  authority  more  directly,  many  of  the 
problems  which  have  surfaced  in  the  last  few  years  would  be  dissipated  within 
a  reasonable  period  of  time,  and  without  tremendous  distortion  of  the  system. 
Certainly  there  is  no  need  to  disrupt  well-established  means  of  providing  service 
to  the  great  multitude  of  markets  in  this  country  in  order  to  permit  unrestrained 
competitive  influences  in  a  handful  of  markets  which  could  conceivably  benefit 
from  open  entry. 


626 


Exhibit  1 


50%  OF  ALLEGHENY'S  PASSENGERS  ARE  GENERATED 
IN  ONLY  11%  OF  THE  CITY  PAIRS  IT  SERVES 


Allegheny's  On  Flight  0-D  Passengers 
In  Its  Top  39  Markets 


Allegheny's  Total  On  Flight  0-D 
Passengers 


Allegheny's  Total  Or  Flight  0-D 
Markets 


Passengers  In  Allegheny's  Top  39 
On  Flight  0-D  Markets  As  a  Percent 
Of  Total  Allegheny  System  Passengers 

Allegheny's  Top  39  Markets  As  A 
Percent  Of  Its  Total  On  Flight 
O-D  Markets 


Source :   Company  Records 


627 


Exhibit  2 


29%  OF  ALLEGHENY'S  PASSENGERS  ON  ITS 
PITTSBURGH-PHILADELPHIA  NONSTOP  FLIGHTS  COME  FROM  OTHER 

THAN  THE  LOCAL  MARKET 

(Pittsburgh-Philadelphia  Nonstop  Flights  -  Month  Of 
July,  1974) 


Market* 


Percent 
Of  Segment 
Passengers  In 


Segment  Passengers   Passengers  In 
Local   Beyond  Total"  Beyond  Markets 


Local  Market 

Pittsburgh-Philadelphia 


Beyond  Markets 


Pittsburgh-Albany 

1,961 

-Boston 

2,232 

-Hartford/Springfield 

265 

-Providence 

234 

Philadelphia-Columbus 

1,446 

-Dayton 

894 

-Erie 

626 

-Indianapolis 

796 

-Louisville 

2,990 

-Memphis 

176 

-Nashville 

41 

-St.  Louis 

412 

Other  Markets 

(Beyond  Both 
Philadelphia 
And  Pittsburgh) 


Total  33,736    13,655   47,391         28. 

*Those  markets  served  on  a  single-plane  basis  by  flights  operating 
nonstop  over  the  Philadelphia-Pittsburgh  segment. 


SOUliCE:   Company  Records, 


628 


Exhibit  3 


MORE  THAN  HALF  (51%)  OF  ALLEGHENY'S  PASSENGERS  ON 
ITS  CHICAGO-PITTSBURGH  NONSTOP  FLIGHTS  COME  FRCW  OTHER  THAN 

THE  LOCAL  MARKET 

(Chicago-Pittsburgh  Nonstop  Flights  -  Month  of  July,  1974) 


Percent 
Of  Segment 
Segment  Passengers    Passengers  In 
Local  Beyond  Total   Beyond  Markets 


Local  Market 


Chicago-Pittsburgh  14,023 


Beyond  Markets 

Chicago-Harrisburg/York  8,094 

-Wilkes  Barre/Scranton  5,115 

-Allentown/Bethlehem/Easton  1,014 

-Other  305 


Total  14,023  14,528   28,551      50.9% 


*Those  markets  served  on  a  single-plane  basis  by  flights  operating 
nonstop  over  the  Chicago-Pittsburgh  segment. 


Source:   Company  Records 


629 

BlOGBAPHY    OF    EDWIN    I.    COLODNY,    EXECUTIVE    ViCE    PRESIDENT,    MARKETING   AND 

Legal  Affairs,  Allegheny  Airlines 

Edwin  I.  Colodny  joined  Allegheny  in  1957  as  assistant  to  the  president  and 
later  served  as  company  secretary,  vice  president-legal  affairs  and  economic 
research,  senior  vice  president  of  the  same  division,  and  executive  vice  presi- 
dent-legal affairs  and  marketing  services,  prior  to  assuming  his  present  responsi- 
bilities in  1973. 

Colodny  was  formerly  aflBliated  with  the  Office  of  General  Counsel,  General 
Services  Administration ;  OflBce  of  the  Judge  Advocate  General,  while  a  First 
Lieutenant  in  the  U.S.  Army  ;  and  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  as  a  trial  attorney. 
Bureau  of  Air  Operations. 

Active  in  industry  affairs,  Colodny  serves  as  chairman  of  the  route  policy 
committee  of  the  Association  of  Local  Transport  Airlines  and  on  several  Air 
Transport  Association  committees. 

He  is  a  native  of  Burlington,  Vt.,  and  received  his  A.B.  degree  in  1948  from 
the  University  of  Rochester.  He  earned  his  LL.  B.  from  Harvard  Law  School  in 
1951. 


Prepared  Statement  of'  Andrew  de  Voursney 

THE    ISSUE    of    controlled    ENTRY 

United  Air  Lines  welcomes  this  opportunity  to  contribute  its  views  to  the  sub- 
committee's inquiry  into  the  economic  regulation  of  the  airline  industry.  As  the 
nation's  largest  airline  serving  92  airports  with  over  1,400  daily  flight  departures, 
employing  some  49,000  persons,  consuming  nearly  1.5  billion  gallons  of  jet  fuel  per 
year,  carrying  over  31  million  passengers  on  both  scheduled  and  charter  service 
last  year,  and  responsible  for  the  productive  use  of  .$3.5  billion  in  fixed  assets  fi- 
nanced by  lenders,  lessors  and  our  52,000  shareholders.  United  has  an  enormous 
commitment  to  the  nation's  air  transport  needs  and  a  very  large  stake  in  the 
economic  regulation  of  our  industry. 

At  the  outset  we  think  that  any  system  bears  reexamination,  including  the  cur- 
rent inquiry  into  economic  regulation.  In  this  regard,  we  supported  the  creation  of 
a  nationarcommission  on  regulatory  reform.  We  also  recognize  that  there  are 
areas  in  which  less  regulation  would  be  both  helpful  and  desirable.  These  should 
be  carefully  explored  on  a  step-by-step  basis. 

At  the  same  time,  we  wish  to  emphasize  that  the  issues  addressed  by  the  sub- 
committee, especially  (he  is.«ue  of  regulation  of  entry  and  exit,  should  not  be 
treated  merely  as  academic  issues  in  a  purely  theoretical  context.  We  cannot 
turn  back  the  calendar  to  1938  in  order  to  speculate  on  how  the  airline  industry 
might  operate  today  had  we  chosen  differently  in  writing  the  original  Act  which 
has  governed  our  economic  regulation  in  the  past  37  years. 

ACHIEVEMENTS  OF  THE  EXISTING  U.S.   DOMESTIC   SYSTEM  OF  REGULATION 

We  must  look  to  the  present  and  to  the  future,  recognizing  the  billions  of  dol- 
lars (f  iiive-rme't  sr  '  ady  in  pace  and  the  hundreds  of  thou'-'ands  of  persons 
whose  livelihood  is  dependent  on  the  existing  airline  system  which  today  provides 
the  best  air  transportation  service  in  the  world— by  any  standard  of  measure- 
ment one  may  choose.  Above  all  we  must  look  at  the  national  interest  served 
by  the  air  transport  industry— the  primary  mode  of  intercity  common  carrier 
passenger  travel. 

Consider  the  following  major  economic  characteristics  of  our  existing  system : 

1.  All  parts  of  the  nation  (over  500  airports)  receive  convenient,  safe,  and 
reliable  scheduled  air  service.  Equipment  maintenance  standards  are  high  ;  flights 
generally  operate  on  time,  except  for  severe  weather  problems ;  complicated  itin- 
eraries are  handled  routinely,  and  airline  passengers  expect  and  usually  receive 
friendly,  courteous  attention  from  airline  employees. 

2.  Airline  fares  and  rates  for  scheduled  passenger  and  cargo  service,  have 
tended  to  rise  much  less  than  other  prices  over  the  long  run,  although  they  have 
had  to  be  increased  significantly  in  the  past  year  to  offset  the  rapid  rise  in  fuel 
and  labor  costs.  The  average  domestic  fare  per  mile  flown  rose  23  percent  from 
1964  to  1974  while  the  consumer  price  index  rose  59  percent.  During  this  same 
period,  per  capita  disposable  personal  income  rose  102  percent  and  ability  to 
purchase  air  travel  increased  significantly.  Furthermore,  domestic  air  fares  in 
the  U.S.  are  significantly  lower  than  fares  for  service  in  other  parts  of  the  world. 


630 

For  example,  the  coach  fare  from  London  to  Rome,  a  distance  of  892  miles  is 
$178.10.  A  comparable  trip  in  the  U.S.  from  Chicago  to  Denver  costs  only  $85.00 
for  a  you-mile  trip.  Other  examples  inciude :  BaugKok-Siugapore  (o97  miies)  — 
$125;   Beirut-Teheran    (908  miles)— $128;  and  Buenos  Aires-Sao  Paulo   (1052 

3.  The  direct  subsidy  cost  to  the  taxpayer  is  quite  modest— under  $70  million  a 
year,  and  confined  to  eight  regional  airlines  and  three  Alaskan  carriers.  These 
payments  insure  that  many  small  or  remote  communities  are  connected  to  the 
national  airline  network.  This  airline  subsidy  is  only  about  20  percent  of  the 
$350  million  federal  subsidy  proposed  for  Amtrak  rail  passenger  service  m  the 
coming  fiscal  year.  The  emergency  aid  to  the  Penn  Central  may  also  approxi- 
mate $350  million,  while  the  maritime  operating  and  construction  subsidy  will 
be  $500  million  per  year. 

4.  The  existing  system  retains  an  opportunity  for  individual  small  entre- 
preneurs to  enter  the  air  transportation  business  as  air  taxi  operators  and  third- 
level  commuter  airlines  which  fill  the  role  of  broadening  the  scope  of  smaller  city 
services  available  to  air  travelers.  One  such  airline,  Air  New  England,  recently 
"graduated"  to  the  status  of  a  fully  certificated  carrier. 

5.  Alongside  regular  scheduled  services,  specialized  services  have  grown  up 
for  the  price  sensitive  pleasure  traveler  who  doesn't  want  all  of  the  service  fea- 
tures designed  into  the  basic  system  and  can  thus  take  advantage  of  the  econ- 
omies possible  in  group  or  charter  travel.  Uuiteu  in  the  largest  domestic  charter 
operator  with  53  percent  of  domestic  charter  traffic.  United  has  consistently  en- 
couraged the  development  of  this  market  segment,  including  liberalizing  of 
charter  regulations  to  make  charter  service  even  more  widely  available.  Spe- 
cifically, United  is  on  record  in  support  of  the  CAB's  recent  efforts  to  liberalize 
travel  group  charter  rules  and  establish  special  event  charters  and  one-stop  in- 
clusive charters.  United  also  favors  a  one-year  extension  of  affinity  charters,  less 
restrictive  travel  limitations  and  payment  of  commissions  to  travel  agents  for 
sales  of  the  new  form  of  charters  under  consideration. 

THE    FUTURE    AIRLINE    ENVIRONMENT 

In  considering  regulatory  reform,  we  must  evaluate  the  changed  economic  en- 
vironment in  order  to  determine  what  changes  are  needed.  United' s  planning  for 
the  next  5  years  recognizes  a  number  of  changing  conditions  which  will  aftect  our 
operations  and  services.  Briefly,  these  are  as  follows  : 

1.  The  economy  will  continue  to  experience  a  higher  level  of  inflation  than  in 
most  of  the  postwar  era,  while  also  suffering  greater  unemployment  and  slower 
economic  growth.  The  inevitable  consequence  for  the  airline  industry  will  be 
relatively  slow  growth  of  demand  for  air  travel.  In  1974,  scheduled  air  travel 
rose  only  2.4  percent,  in  good  part  because  of  diversion  of  auto  travel  to  airlines 
during  the  gasoline  shortage.  We  now  expect  a  decline  in  traffic  in  1975  and 
modest  growth  of  some  5  to  6  percent  per  year  in  the  1976-1980  period. 

2.  Although  the  control  mechanisms  to  be  used  are  not  yet  designed,  we  are 
certain  that  energy  conservation  will  be  a  dominant  factor  in  airline  planning 
for  at  least  the  next  five  years.  A  variety  of  steps  have  already  been  taken  by  the 
airlines  to  conserve  fuel;  for  example,  Uniteds  1974  fuel  consumption  was  11 
percent  less  than  in  1972  and  13  percent  less  than  in  1973.  We  expect  to  continue 
our  fuel  conservation  program  both  by  operational  procedures  and  by  restraint  in 
adding  scheduled  fiights. 

3.  Several  major  hub  airports  and  sectors  of  the  airways  system  are  so  near  to 
their  practical  capacity  as  to  constitute  significant  constraints  on  future  airline 
growth.  They  include  the  New  York,  Chicago,  Washington  and  Atlanta  terminal 
areas.  The  costs  of  new  airports  and  facilities  are  so  high  that  utmost  caution 
must  be  used  in  planning  and  making  financial  commitments  to  construction  pro- 
grams. We  must  be  certain  that  we  avoid  the  costly  waste  of  prematurely  ex- 
panding the  system  before  we  are  fully  utilizing  the  capacity  of  the  existing  air- 
port-airway system. 

4.  Finally,  United's  planning  reflects  the  need  for  maximizing  operational  effi- 
ciency which  is  so  necessary  if  we  are  both  to  hold  down  the  level  of  airline 
prices  and  to  continue  to  provide  an  adequate  level  of  service  despite  constraints 
on  fuel  availability  and  airport  capacity.  Specifically,  we  anticipate  a  need  to 
increase  use  of  larger  airplanes,  to  increase  seating  capacity  of  all  airplanes,  to 
increase  average  daily  hours  of  u.se  of  airplanes,  and  to  increase  the  load  factor, 
or  seat  occupancy  percentage.  These  changes  will  directly  benefit  the  public  by 


631 

providing  a  continued  higli  standard  of  service  at  lower  prices  than  would  other- 
wise be  possible.  It  will  be  extremely  difficult  to  accomplish  such  changes  in  the 
existing  competitive  environment  without  the  active  leadership  and  support  of 
government.  Stimulating  a  flood  of  new  capacity  by  relaxing  regulation  of  entry 
could  make  these  productivity  gains  impossible  to  achieve. 

PROBABLE   CONSEQUENCES    OF   DEREGULATION 

It  is  recognized  that  air  transportation  is  not  a  so-called  "natural  monopoly" 
which  requires  economic  regulation  in  the  sense  of  a  monopoly  public  power 
utility.  Air  transportation  initially  was  placed  under  regulation  to  insure  that  air 
service  would  be  provided  which  was  adequate  to  meet  the  needs  of  a  modern 
economy  and  to  be  certain  that  all  sections  of  the  nation  would  receive  the  bene- 
fits of  air  service.  It  also  was  important  to  prevent  destructive  competition 
among  the  carriers,  a  consideration  amply  supported  by  history.  Such  destructive 
competition  would  pose  problems  in  the  areas  of  safety,  public  convenience, 
financial  stability  and  continuity  of  service.  The  Federal  Aviation  Act  specifically 
directs  the  CAB  to  consider  "as  being  in  the  public  interest  *  *  *  the  encourage- 
ment and  development  of  an  air-transportation  system  properly  adapted  to  the 
present  and  future  needs  of  the  foreign  and  domestic  commerce  of  the  United 
States,  of  the  Postal  Service,  and  of  the  national  defense"  *  *  *  and  "competition 
to  the  extent  necessary"  to  assure  such  a  system. 

There  are  now  numerous  propsals  to  scrap  this  system  and  permit  free  entry 
and  exit  into  and  out  of  the  industry.  It  is  alleged  that  the  increased  competi- 
tion which  would  result  would  lead  to  a  more  eflScient  system  with  lower  fares 
and  rates  for  travelers  and  shippers.  It  is  assumed  that  pricing  freedom  would 
necessarily  accompany  freedom  of  entry  and  exit. 

In  examining  the  question  of  regulation  we  should  try  to  foresee  what  would 
actually  occur  if  deregulation  were  to  take  place.  It  is  difficult  to  do  since  there 
is  no  nation  in  the  world  which  has  an  unregulated  domestic  public  transport 
system.  Indeed,  the  prevailing  pattern  is  for  outright  nationalization,  partial 
public  ownership,  or  much  more  restricted  competition  than  exists  in  the  U.S. 
However,  a  generalized  projection  of  the  results  of  deregulation  can  be  made. 

In  our  view  the  first  development  would  be  greater  concentration  of  service 
and  intensified  competition  in  large,  high-density  markets.  Existing  airlines  and 
operators  would  seek  to  gain  po>~itions  in  the  largest  markets ;  many  would  be 
tempted  to  offer  service  at  prices  below  cost  in  order  to  obtain  a  foothold  in  these 
markets.  Initially,  frequency  of  service  would  increase  and  fares  might  be 
lower — but  carrier  profits  surely  would  vanish. 

We  can  draw  a  parallel  between  freedom  of  entry  and  the  history  which  sur- 
rounds the  transpacific  route  ca'-e.  Prior  to  the  final  decision  in  this  route  case  in 
the  summer  of  1969,  three  scheduled  carriers  had  served  the  route  between  the 
Mainia'Hl  and  Hawaii.  Thry  had  provided  high  qualitv  service  at  very  low 
fares.  United's  average  coach  rate  per  mile  between  the  West  Coast  and  Hawaii 
in  1968  was  3.8  cents:  the  lowest  promotional  fare  was  2.2  cents  per  mile. 
United's  operating  profits  were  reasonable,  aggregating  ,$24.9  million  on  revenues 
of  $121.3  million.  Following  the  award  and  the  initiation  of  new  competing  serv- 
ices, United's  profit  history  is  as  follows  : 

1969— still  a  profit  of  $25.6  million. 

1970— loss  of  .$6.7  mi"ion. 

1971— a  very  substantial  loss  of  $18.0  inillion. 

1972— continued  loss— $14.6  million. 

1973— a  profit  of  $13.3  million  on  revenues  of  $159.4  million. 

Results  for  1974  are  not  yet  available.  In  the  transpacific  case,  we  have  a  very 
good  preview  of  what  would  happen  if  freedom  of  entry  were  permitted. 

A  second  immediate  effect  wouM  be  the  neslert  or  abandonment  of  economically 
marginal  routes :  smaller  cities,  low  traffic  density  sectors,  etc.  If  subsidies  to  re- 
gional carriers  were  abandoned  along  with  freedom  of  exist,  many  communities 
would  risk  immediate  loss  of  service,  or  at  least  a  major  downgrading  of  quality 
of  service.  To  retain  service,  some  new  system  would  need  to  be  devised  such 
as  the  contract  concept  advanced  by  former  CAB  chairman  Secor  Browne.  But  it 
would  have  to  be  in  place  immediately  to  prevent  abandonment  of  the  small  com- 
munities. It  is  questionable  whether  such  a  system  is  better  or  more  economical 
than  that  we  now  have.  Airport-airway  congestion  problems  would  be  severely 
impacted  by  deregulation.  Increased  competition  in  major  markets  would  take 


632 

the  form  of  higher  frequency  of  scheduled  flights,  using  smaller  less  fuel  efficient 
and  less  economic  airplanes  crowded  into  periods  of  peak  demand.  Until  addi- 
tional airports  could  be  built  to  handle  the  increased  frequency  of  schedules,  local 
allocation  systems  would  be  needed  to  ration  the  limited  number  of  landing  and 
takeoff  times.  Such  allocation  programs  are  in  use  today  at  O'Hare,  La  Guardia, 
Kennedy  and  AVashington  National  airports  with  overall  ceilings  on  the  number 
of  operations  per  hour.  A  proliferation  of  new  carriers  and  new  gate  and  airway 
demands  would  greatly  expand  the  rationing  process  and  place  life  or  death  regu 
latory  power  in  the  hands  of  local  airport  authorities.  The  construction  of  new 
and  very  costly  duplicate  airports  to  serve  major  hubs  would  be  needed  to  handle 
the  added  flights.  The  resulting  economic  waste  would  eventually  lead  to  higher 
fares,  since  passengers  ultimately  must  pay  for  the  expen.'^ive  new  facilities  and 
the  wasteful,  excessive  flight  schedules. 

Indeed,  there  is  no  certainty  that  costs  could  be  reduced  or  average  fares 
lowered  significantly  even  in  the  short  run.  Existing  airlines  have  high  fixed 
costs:  airplanes,  computer  systems,  terminals,  maintenance  facilities,  training 
centers,  and  heavily  unionized  work  forces  with  restrictive  work  rules.  It  is  con- 
ceivable that  new  operators  could  enter  the  business  with  lower  fares  based  on 
use  of  older  aircraft  and  nonunion  employees  earning  lower  salaries  and  with 
greater  flexibility  in  work  assignments.  Assuming  some  could  gain  access  to  ma- 
jor markets  and  survive,  it  is  reasonable  to  expect  that  they  would  soon  become 
unionized  and  would  move  to  upgrade  equipment.  For  example,  PSA  has  followed 
this  path  of  unionization  and  acquisition  of  larger  equipment ;  it  is  vigorously 
trying  to  raise  the  level  of  California  intrastate  fares  to  offset  rapidly  rising 
costs.  The  intrastate  economy  fare  between  Los  Angeles  and  San  Francisco  has 
risen  21.7  percent  since  1969  and  PSA  has  a  pending  application  for  a  further  13 
percent  increase. 

Meanwhile,  the  present  carriers  either  would  have  to  meet  the  fares  of  cutrate 
operators  at  a  loss  or  puUback  service  and  abandon  the  market.  The  public  would 
lose  long  established  services  and  airline  employees  their  jobs. 

The  matter  of  safety  standards  cannot  be  treated  lightly.  Despite  some  recent 
criticism,  the  scheduled  airline  industry  has  a  genuine  dedication  to  safety 
which  transcends  economic  concerns.  Safety  is  a  prerequisite  to  lasting  com- 
mercial success.  Frankly,  the  experience  of  other,  less  regulated  sectors  of  avia- 
tion does  not  provide  much  comfort  as  to  the  pos.^ible  safety  consequences  of  de- 
regulation. A  recent  study  of  1974  worldwide  accident  rates  indicats  that  the 
accident  rate  per  departure  for  the  largely  unregulated  nonscheduled  airlines 
was  seven  times  the  rate  for  scheduled  carriers.  Historically,  both  .scheduled  and 
supplemental  U.S.  airlines  have  enjoyed  superior  safety  records  compared  with 
the  rest  of  the  world.  History  teaches  us  that  marginal,  or  cutrate,  operators 
may  be  tempted  to  cut  corners  on  safety  when  under  economic  pressure. 

The  nature  of  the  air  transportation  industry  which  would  finally  evolve  from 
deregulation  is  highly  uncertain.  However,  it  is  clear  that  the  certain  short  run 
result  would  be  a  protracted  period  of  great  instability.  Weak  carriers  would 
fail  or  be  forced  to  shrink  the  scope  of  their  operations.  Many  airline  workers 
would  lose  their  jobs.  Many  mature  U.S.  industries  are  dominated  by  a  few  firms  ; 
this  could  well  be  the  long  run  pattern  for  a  deregulated  airline  industry. 

Under  these  circumstances,  economic  regulation  probably  would  not  di.«appear. 
Rather  than  being  centralized  under  the  CAB,  it  would  pass  into  other  hands. 
For  example,  there  would  be  de  facto  regulation  by  airport  operators  through 
the  allocation  of  airport  gates,  leases  and  landing  rights.  The  FAA  would  allocate 
available  airspace.  Under  today's  conditions,  FEA  would  be  establishing  policy 
through  allocation  of  scarce  fuel  supplies.  Finally,  the  Antitrust  Division  of  the 
Department  of  Justice  would  be  concerned  with  increased  concentration  of 
economic  power  which  might  result.  We  could  evolve  into  a  system  of  regulation 
by  litigation. 

PROBLEMS   UNDER   DEREGULATION 

The  lack  of  central  regulation  and  resulting  instability  would  have  a  number 
of  unfavorable  consequences.  These  problems  would  require  an  enormous  effort 
to  replace  existing  efticient  systems  which  have  produced  the  industry  we  have 
today  with  new  methods  applicable  to  a  changed  environment. 

Of  paramount  importance  would  be  the  future  of  the  highly  efficient  busines^s 
systems  created  by  the  regulated  airline  industry  under  CAB  authority.  All  ele- 
ments of  transacting  airline  business :  reservations,  ticketing,  connecting  service, 
and  baggage  handling,  would  be  affected  by  deregulation.  What  would  happen  to 
tariffs  and  the  tariff  system?  The  potential  for  price  discrimination,  now  illegal, 


633 

would  be  introduced.  With  constantly  changing  prices,  great  variation  among 
carriers,  price  deals,  and  possibly  no  tariffs — what  would  happen  to  the  thou- 
sands of  independent  travel  agents  who  now  sell  nearly  half  of  U.S.  air  travel? 
How  could  they  construct  a  ciienfs  itinerary  in  advance  with  any  confidence? 
How  could  they  quote  fares  with  confidence?  Could  these  small  entrepreneurs 
survive  or  would  they  be  overwhelmed  by  larger  firms  with  many  branches  who 
could  create  close  ties  with  individual  carriers  in  the  absence  of  restrictive 
regulation. 

Frequent  fiyers  place  great  importance  on  the  convenience  and  efficiency  of- 
fered by  the  existing  system.  The  ability  to  write  a  ticket  to  any  location  on 
earth,  to  check  baggage  through  the  final  destination,  to  change  complex  plans 
with  a  single  telephone  call  is  essential  and  would  need  to  be  retained  somehow 
under  a  deregulated  system.  Under  a  situation  of  considerable  carrier  turnover, 
this  could   be   difficult. 

We  believe  the  subcommittee  is  aware  that  through  the  air  traffic  conference, 
a  subsidiary  organization  of  the  Air  Transport  Association  created  to  coordi- 
nate the  complex  elements  of  travel  arrangements  by  cooperative  action  of  the 
carriers,  the  domestic  airlines  have  entered  into  hundreds  of  technical  agree- 
ments on  trade  practices  which  are  filed  with  the  CAB  covering  such  diverse  sub- 
jects as  tariff  filing,  tariff  enforcement,  interline  connecting  times,  timetable  pub- 
lication, interline  ticketing,  carriage  of  physically  handicapped  persons,  stand- 
ardized public  address  announcements,  educational  familiarization  programs  for 
travel  agents,  tax  collection,  control  of  ticket  stock,  baggage  handling  and  trac- 
ing, reservations  procedures,  travel  agency  agreements,  and  computer 
applications. 

The  same  requirement  for  efficient  coordination  applies  to  the  postal  service 
and  air  freight  shippers.  At  this  time  it  is  inconceivable  that  international  air 
service  could  be  deregulated  ;  the  complex  interface  of  domestic  and  international 
services  would  need  to  be  preserved.  By  its  very  nature,  the  airline  industry 
requires  a  high  degree  of  cooperation  among  its  participants ;  such  cooperation 
would  appear  to  require  some  degree  of  regulatory  supervision  and  support. 

Aside  from  these  operational  efficiency  problems,  a  deregulated  system  would 
impose  severe  difficulties  in  planning  for  those  activities  and  resources  with  long 
lead  times.  The  stability  and  continuity  of  the  existing  system  provides  a  reason- 
ably reliable  basis  for  forecasting  future  needs  for  airports  and  other  facilities 
with  long  planning  lead  times  and  high-capital  costs.  Airline  staffs  now  play 
an  important  role  in  forecasting  volume  data  for  this  planning  effort  and  airlines 
provide  guarantees  for  the  financing  of  many  airport  improvements.  With  an 
uncertain  environment,  could  forecasts  be  made  with  any  confidence  and  would 
such  guarantees  be  feasible? 

Similar  planning  difficulties  would  affect  the  aircraft  and  engine  manufacturers. 
Most  major  new  technological  developments  and  new  aircraft  models  have  been 
launched  with  the  support  of  substantial  purchase  commitments  by  the  major 
airlines.  Today  United  is  working  closely  with  Boeing  and  United  Aircraft  in 
the  design  specifications  of  a  new  version  of  the  highly  successful  727  jet,  the 
dash  300,  which  promises  greater  fuel  efficiency  and  quieter  operations — both 
clearly  in  the  interest  of  airline  passengers  and  communities.  Who  could  afford 
the  sort  of  long  range  study  effort  and  massive  capital  commitment  associated 
with  this  sort  of  activity  if  the  air  transportation  industry  is  placed  in  a  highly 
uncertain  transitional  posture  by  deregulation?  Would  aerospace  manufacturers 
invest  in  R&D  efforts  to  sell  to  a  fragmented  and  unstable  market? 

The  possibility  of  the  development  of  capacity  shortages  under  a  policy  of  free- 
dom of  entry  and  exit  also  is  significant.  The  Federal  Aviation  Act  provides  for 
an  adequate  supply  of  air  service  regardless  of  economic  conditions.  If  carriers 
were  unwilling  or  unable  to  make  lasting  service  commitments,  vital  services 
could  disapi>ear  during  recessions  and  return  very  slowly  during  recovery.  Serious 
service  imbalances  could  occur  at  times.  If  a  carrier  were  to  fail  for  any  reason, 
communities  would  face  serious  service  disruptions  and  potential  economic  hard- 
ships from  which  they  now  are  protected. 

The  problems  of  uncertainty  and  instability  raise  the  difficult  question  of  how 
the  industry  would  be  able  to  finance  future  growth.  Would  it  be  forced  to  rely 
on  banks  and  other  financial  institutions  to  acquire  the  bulk  of  airline  equipment 
and  bear  a.ssociated  financial  risks,  and  then  lease  aircraft  to  airline  operators? 
Perhaps,  this  solution  would  be  feasible:  however,  it  raises  questions  in  a  very 
sensitive  area  concerning  the  proper  role  of  such  financial  entities  in  the  control 
of  other  businesses,  particularly  one  so  vested  with  public  interest  considerations. 


634 

In  summary,  we  foresee  many  risks  and  new  problems  resulting  from  any 
abrupt  deregulation  of  the  airline  industry.  We  ask  the  subcommittee  to  place 
these  considerations  on  the  other  side  of  the  scale  to  compare  them  with  any 
prospective  benefits  which  might  be  gained.  If  we  take  into  account  the  indis- 
putable fact  that  our  present  system  is  superior  to  any  exij^ting  alternative  sys- 
tem, is  it  in  the  public  interest  to  abolish  regulation  of  entry  and  exit  for  the 
uncertain  promise  of  lower  fares?  Might  we  develop  a  new  system  which  would 
not  only  be  ineffiective  in  improving  the  domestic  airline  system  but  which, 
through  developments  which  cannot  be  clearly  foreseen,  could  cause  a  deterior- 
ation in  tliat  system  ? 

BUREAU    OF    OPERATING    BIGHTS    ROUTE    POLICY    STUDY 

In  addition  to  a  general  discussion  of  freedom  of  entry,  the  subcommittee  has 
requested  United's  views  on  two  specific  matters :  the  CAB  Bureau  of  Operating 
Righf.s  study  of  domestic  route  policy,  and  the  Boards  po'icy  of  rcstiai.it  in 
route  matters  which  has  been  followed  in  recent  years.  With  respect  to  the 
former.  United  is  now  in  the  process  of  preparing  its  formal  response  to  the 
CAB  which  will  be  submitted  by  March  1,  1975.  Copies  of  our  response  will  be 
furnished  to  the  subcommittee.  As  a  matter  of  principle,  United  supports  the 
concept  of  guidelines  governing  route  proceedings  analogous  to  the  guidelines 
recently  established  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation.  We  also  believe 
it  advisable  from  a  policy  viewpoint  to  establish  some  type  of  public  forum  to 
permit  complete,  open  discussion  of  the  issues  associated  with  such  standards. 
Several  precedents  exist  for  public  hearings  on  major  policy  considerations  in- 
cluding fact-finding  hearings  related  to  the  desirability  of  establishing  local 
service  airlines  and  the  preliminary  investigation  of  large  irregular  air  carriers. 
We  believe  it  will  not  be  necessary  to  have  a  prolonged  litigated  proceeding  but 
we  believe  something  broader  than  normal  ru'eniaking  is  needed  to  exj)lore 
adequately  the  policy  issues.  We  commend  the  CAB  for  starting  the  process  by 
making  the  study  and  we  expect  it  will  proceed  expeditiously. 

CAB   POLICY    OF    RESTRAINT 

Regarding  the  CAB's  policy  of  route  restraint,  it  is  clear  that  the  Board  has 
been  acting  in  the  best  interest  of  both  the  public  and  the  carriers.  In  its  treat- 
ment of  individual  cases,  the  Board  openly  stated  its  views  on  the  need  for 
restraint  and  pointed  to  a  variety  of  reasons  related  to  the  economic  health  of 
the  industry  and  the  uncertain  national  economic  outlook.  To  our  knowledge,  this 
policy  has  never  been  formally  challenged  as  a  policy.  While  questions  have  been 
raised  with  respect  to  specific  cases  in  question,  subsequent  economic  develop- 
ments certainly  have  confirmed  the  wisdom  of  this  policy  from  an  economic 
standpoint.  Absent  this  policy,  either  the  carriers  would  suffer  staggering  losses 
resulting  from  the  intrusion  of  new  carriers,  or  fare  levels  would  have  to  increase 
substantially. 

UNITED' S   PROPOSALS    FOR   IMPROVEMENT    OF    REGULATION 

We  recognize  the  system  is  not  perfect.  But  we  suggest  that  we  seek  means  by 
which  the  quality  of  regulation  under  the  CAB  may  be  improved  rather  than 
scrapping  the  entire  system.  United  favors  evolutionary  changes  and  reforms  to 
achieve  the  goals  set  forth  in  the  original  Act  in  1938.  We  believe,  for  example, 
that  the  airlines  need  more  freedom  within  the  boundaries  of  the  regulated 
system  to  exercise  their  business  judgment.  A  case  in  point  is  the  recent  estab- 
lishment of  a  mileage  limitation  on  the  bicentennial  fare ;  we  feel  that  this  is  a 
case  where  the  CAB  substituted  its  business  judgment  for  our  own,  and  we 
favored  no  limit  on  the  applicability  of  the  fare  in  order  to  provide  maximum 
benefit  to  the  traveling  ijublic. 

For  many  years  we  have  felt  that  the  public  deserves  a  higher  quality  of  pro- 
fessionalism on  the  part  of  government  regulators.  Is  it  possible  to  devise  a  set 
of  objective  standards  for  membership  on  regulatory  commissions?  Could  the 
Senate  expand  the  "advise"  portion  of  its  "advise  and  consent"  responsibilities? 

In  response  to  question  39  of  the  subcommittee's  questionnaire  we  suggested 
some  procedural  improvements  which  United  believes  should  be  implemented. 
Briefly,  these  were  as  follows  : 

1.  Reduce  the  size  and  scope  of  information  requests  from  bureaus  of  CAB 
in  formal  proceedings.  Preparation  of  responses  is  burdensome  and  time- 
consuming. 


635 

2.  Reduce  the  length  of  hearings  by  cutting  down  on  excessively  detailed  cross- 
examination. 

3.  Provide  greater  time  for  filing  responses  to  applications,  petitions,  motions, 
etc.  Time  now  available  is  ordinarily  inadequate  to  permit  reasonable  evalua- 
tion of  issues  and  preparation  of  answers.  The  CAB  is  thus  deprived  of  the  best 
possible  arguments  and  evidence. 

4.  Expedite  the  hearing  process  and  try  to  avoid  hearings  where  possible  with- 
out prejudice  to  parties'  rights  to  due  process. 

5.  Change  the  tariff  filing  procedure  by  statute  to  require  45-day  notice  and 
CAB  action  within  30  days  to  provide  15  days  for  orderly  implementation. 

United  also  is  supporting  a  number  of  significant  changes  related  to  the  regu- 
lation of  charter  service  which  will  expand  the  potential  benefits  to  the  public 
without  impairing  the  quality  of  scheduled  service.  United  strongly  believes  that 
charter  service  should  be  encouraged  to  serve  that  segment  of  the  market  whose 
requirements  are  different  from  scheduled  service — and  thus  to  offer  safe,  reli- 
able service  to  the  public  at  the  lowest  possible  cost.  However,  we  do  not  believe 
the  proper  path  to  this  goal  is  the  legislative  one.  CAB  regulation  now  permits 
experimentation  to  test  the  feasibility  of  new  concepts  such  as  more  liberal 
one-stop  inclusive  tour  charters  without  the  inflexibility  involved  if  such  changes 
were  legislated.  That  freedom  should  be  used  before  the  rigidities  of  a  legislative 
concept  are  imposed. 

In  conclusion,  we  wi.sh  to  reemphasize  United's  vital  interest  in  the  proceed- 
ings of  this  subcommittee  as  well  as  other  investigations  of  a  similar  vein.  We 
also  wish  to  stress  our  willingness  to  cooperate  in  bringing  about  changes  which 
will  produce  genuine  public  benefits ;  our  record  is  clear  in  this  regard.  United 
is  not  an  implacable  defender  of  the  status  quo.  However,  we  believe  it  would  be 
unwise  to  endanger  the  quality  of  an  excellent  system  in  the  pursuit  of  hypo- 
thetical gains  which  may  be  unattainable  in  actual  practice.  The  overall  record  of 
the  airlines  under  CAB  regulation  is  one  of  which  the  country  can  be  proud.  It 
represents  a  solid  ha.se  for  future  improvement  of  the  system.  It  should  not  be 
discarded  without  a  great  deal  of  careful  weighing  of  the  potential  benefits 
against  the  apparent  risks. 

United  Aib  Lines, 
Chicago,  III.,  Fel.  28, 1975. 
Hon.  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
U.S.  Senate, 
Wa.^hington,  D.C. 

Dear  Senator  :  During  my  testimony  on  February  18,  we  discussed  the  subject 
of  internal  cross-subsidization  of  unprofitable  routes.  I  indicated  that  we  would 
provide  additional  information  on  the  scope  of  such  subsidization  which  existed 
on  United's  route  system  in  1974 — a  year  of  relatively  good  earnings  for  the 
company.  We  have  compiled  the  information  below  from  internal  company 
records  using  planning  standard  cost  rates  and  average  revenue  rates,  which 
closely  approximate  actual  results. 

All  regular  scheduled  passenger  operations  of  the  company  have  been  separated 
into  two  categories  :  those  airport  pairs  on  which  we  failed  to  earn  a  profit  before 
federal  income  tax.  and  those  on  which  we  did  earn  a  pretax  profit.  This  analysis 
compiled  the  results  for  all  nonstop  flights  between  a  given  pair  of  airports,  in 
l)i)th  directions,  to  determine  the  profitability  category ;  some  of  the  individual 
flights  serving  an  ain>ort  pair  might  be  unprofitable  even  though  the  total  of 
all  flights  was  profitable,  and  vice  versa".  Similarly,  some  airport  pairs  are  un- 
profitable in  certain  months  of  the  year  and  profitable  in  others.  The  breakdown 
shown  below  reflects  full  year  results  of  the  sum  of  all  flights  operated  in  a 
given  market. 

1974  RESULTS  OF  SCHEDULED  PASSENGER  OPERATIONS 

Unprofitable  Profitable  System 

city-pairs  city-pairs  total 

Number  of  airport  pairs 163  164  327 

Revenue  (in  millions) .._ $462.7  $1,556.9  $2,019.6 

Expense  (in  millions) $604.7  $1,226.0  $819.7 

Profit  before  tax  (loss) ($142.0)  $330.9  $188.9 

On-board  passengers  (in  millions) 13.8  20.0  33.8 


Each  of  the  20  million  passengers  in  the  profitable  markets  provided  an  inter- 
nal sub  idy  of  $7.10  to  offset  the  $142  million  loss  on  the  unprofitable  routes.  This 
is  equivalent  to  approximately  9  percent  of  the  average  revenue  per  passenger 
on  the  profitable  routes.  In  order  for  the  unprofitable  routes  to  reach  the  break- 
even level,  a  revenue  increase  of  30.7  percent  would  be  necessary.  A  fare  increase 
of  this  magnitude  would  almost  certainly  depress  the  level  of  traffic  in  those 
markets.  The  existence  of  a  substantial  level  of  internal  cross-subsidization 
clearly  and  directly  benefits  approximately  half  of  the  markets  served  by  United. 

Further  analysis  revealed  that  75  of  the  163  unprofitable  airport  pairs  involv- 
ing 3.2  million  passengers  failed  to  produce  sufiicient  revenue  to  cover  their  direct 
variable  cash  costs.  These  markets  consist  largely  of  short  haul  feeding  or 
connecting  segments  which  provide  important  support  for  the  longer  haul  flights 
but  are  not  credited  with  this  support  revenue  by  the  accounting  system.  How- 
ever, if  these  segments  were  not  an  integral  part  of  a  larger  system,  they  would 
probably  receive  little  or  no  scheduled  airline  service  since  the  purely  local 
traflic  demand  is  too  small  to  support  such  service. 

I  hope  this  simple  analysis  helps  shed  added  light  on  the  subject  of  internal 
cross-subsidization  of  unprofitable  route  segments.  We  recognize  that  implemen- 
tation of  phase  9  of  the  CAB  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation  decision  will 
help  alleviate  this  situation  but  will  not  end  it. 

We  would  be  pleased  to  cooperate  further  with  the  subcommittee  on  this  vital 
subject  which  is  of  great  interest  to  the  management,  employees  and  share- 
holders of  UAL,  Inc.,  as  well  as  to  the  public. 
Sincerely, 

Andrew  M.  ue  Voursney, 
Oroup  Vice  President  of  Finance  and  Planning. 

[Note. — The  following  letter  was  submitted  to  the  subcommittee  by 
United  Air  Lines  to  update  and/or  replace  the  data  submitted  in  the 
letter  of  February  28, 1975,  as  printed  above.] 

United  Air  Lines, 
Chicago,  III.,  Apr.  29, 1915. 
Mr.  Stephen  M.  Breyer, 

Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure, 
Washington,  D.C. 

Dear  Mr.  Breyer  :  I  am  enclosing  a  detailed  listing  of  our  analysis  of  United's 
unprofitable  routes  in  1974  as  we  discussed  by  telephone.  Section  1  covers  58 
city-pairs  on  which  revenue  failed  to  cover  incremental  operating  costs ;  this  list 
corresponds  to  the  75  city-pair  list  with  which  you  were  working  originally.  The 
17  markets  which  we  excluded  from  our  analysis  were  not  scheduled  on  a  year- 
round  basis  and,  in  most  cases,  received  sparse  or  sporadic  service.  We  believe  it 
is  more  reasonable  to  look  only  at  those  markets  which  receive  regular  scheduled 
service  for  most  or  all  of  the  year.  Incidentally,  three  markets  you  included  in 
vour  "retain  service"  category  should  be  listed  among  those  where  service  has 
i)een  discontinued;  these  are  Baltimore-Philadelphia,  Birmingham-Knoxville, 
and  Honolulu-Hilo. 

Section  II  of  the  analvsis  covers  those  city  pairs  where  revenue  exceeded  in- 
cremental costs  but  did  not  cover  fully  allocated  costs.  These  markets  are  certainly 
those  which  would  come  under  close  scrutiny  as  to  the  wisdom  of  continuing  serv- 
ice if  exit  were  permitted,  inasmuch  as  it  w^ould  not  appear  economically  justified 
to  purchase  replacement  equipment  on  which  an  adequate  return  was  not  being 
earned.  It  is  our  working  assumption  that  long  run  incremental  costs  (the  theo- 
retical basis  for  capital  investment  decisions)  are  equal  to  or  greater  than  current 
fully  allocated  operating  costs  including  overheads.  Our  internal  cost  studies  indi- 
cate that  overhead  cost^  tend  to  vary  in  the  long  run  in  the  same  way  as  short 
run  incremental  costs. 

Some  technical  definitions  may  assist  you  in  interpreting  the  attached  table. 

Contribution— Total  revenue  less  incremental  cash  costs  (based  on  system 
average  costs).  .     ,    ,. 

PBT  (Profit  Before  Tax)— Total  revenue  less  fully  allocated  costs  including 
interest  but  excluding  income  taxes. 

Retained  for  Traflic  Control  Purposes— City-pairs  where  feed  traflSc  to  other 
segments  is  significant  but  is  not  reflected  in  market  profitability. 

Retained  to  Combine  Market.s— City-pairs  where  aircraft  are  routed  to  com- 
bine two  cities  on  a  single  flight  but  where  local  traflic  is  not  significant. 


637 

Retained  for  Operational  Routings — City-pairs  where  primary  purpose  of 
fligtits  Is  equipment  positioning. 

Retained  for  Future  Profit  Potential  (or  Policy)— City-pairs  which  are  judged 
to  have  good  future  profit  potential  but  are  current  losses  due  to  temporary  prob- 
lems or  unusual  circumstances ;  or,  where  the  market  is  of  such  strategic  signifi- 
cance that  company  policy  dictates  continued  operation  despite  unsatisfactory 
economic  results. 

I  am  certain  you  understand  that  this  classification  exercise  is  a  judgmental 
process  and  reflects  a  conscientious  effort  by  United's  scheduling  experts  but  is 
by  no  means  based  on  the  sort  of  exhaustive  economic  studies  which  we  would 
pursue  in  the  event  we  were  faced  with  an  actual  decision.  I  am  satisfied  that  it 
also  represents  our  unbiased  opinion,  not  slanted  for  political  impact.  Because  of 
the  sensitive  nature  of  these  data,  we  are  requesting  that  no  details  regarding 
specific  city-pairs  be  released  to  the  public. 

In  summary,  the  attached  analysis  is  our  approach  to  answering  the  question, 
"What  United  markets  would  not  be  served  if  you  were  free  to  abandon  unde- 
sired  routes?"  We  agree  that  in  some  cases,  such  as  Atlanta-Birmingham,  other 
carriers  would  continue  service.  In  other  instances,  new  carriers  might  replace 
United's  service.  This  list  is  also  not  complete  in  the  sense  that  we  may  find  it 
desirable  to  withdraw  service  from  some  nominally  profitable  markets  under  a 
condition  of  free  exit  and  entry.  The  statistical  results  are  summarized  as 
follows : 

CLASSIFICATION  OF  LOSS  MARKETS 
(United  Airlines,  1974] 


Number  of 
city-pairs 


Annual 

Percent      contribution 

of  (in 

market       thousands) 


Profits 

(PBT) 

(in 

thousands) 


Markets  with  negative  contribution 
Retained: 

Traffic  control 

Combine  markets.. 

Operational 

Consider  for  deletion 

Subtotal. 

Markets  with  positive  contribution: 
Retained: 

Traffic  control 

Future  profit  or  policy 

Consider  for  deletion 

Subtotal 

Grand  total : 

Retained 

Considered  for  deletion , 

Total 


17.2 
12.1 
6.9 


($992)  ($12, 433) 

(2, 927)  (6, 654) 

(2,  445)  (10,  718) 


21 
37 

36.2 
63.8 

(6,364) 
(8,096) 

(29,805) 
(25, 172) 

58 

100.0 

(14,460) 

(54,977) 

43 

48.3 
16.9 

31,054 
23,  746 

(26,  495) 
(14,216) 

15 

58 
31 

65.2 
34.8 

54,  800 
12,672 

(40,711) 
(13,242) 

89 

100.0 

67,472 

(53,953) 

79 

54.0 
46.0 

48.436 
4,576 

(70,  516) 

68 

(38,  414) 

(108,  930) 


We  look  forward  to  an  opportunity  to  read  your  draft  report  and  we  hope  we 
can  continue  to  enjoy  a  mutually  constructive  relationship. 
Sincerely, 

William  R.  Nesbit, 
Corporate  Economist. 


Prepared  Statement  of  Stuart  G.  Tipton 

I  am  Stuart  G.  Tipton,  Pan  Am  senior  vice  president  for  Federal  affairs.  I  am 
here  today  with  Stanley  Gewirtz,  Pan  Am  special  adviser  on  public  policy,  to  tell 
you  about  some  of  our  widely-publicized  problems.  But  in  the  context,  essentially, 
of  the  effectiveness  of  regulation,  of  route  awards  and  the  requirements  of  entry 
into  the  business  of  international  air  transportation. 


638 

At  your  hearing  on  February  6,  you  heard  from  some  very  thoughtful  people. 
The  representatives  of  the  industry's  trade  association  quite  properly,  and 
proudly,  recited  the  progress  which  has  characterized  domestic  commercial  avia- 
tion in  the  36  years  since  the  passage  of  the  Civil  Aviation  Act  of  1938. 

Some  Government  and  some  academic  experts  suggested  that  the  progress 
could  have  been  greater,  and  the  growth  more  beneficial  in  the  public  interest,  if 
the  rules  had  been  different  and  if,  in  fact,  there  were  no  rules  governing  entry 
and  relaxed  rules  controlling  rates. 

There  may  be  much  wisdom  in  the  recommendations  made  to  you.  But  they 
relate  to  the  domestic  system.  They  are  neither  appropriate  nor  applicable  to 
our  U.S.-flag  system.  Few  of  the  recommendations  you  have  heard  atypically 
embrace  of  our  international  flag  system.  You  are  concerned,  and  quite  prop- 
erly, with  the  efficacy  of  the  practices  and  procedures  of  federal  regulation  of  the 
airline  industry.  And  whether  they  have  been  "designed  and  implemented  (to  pro- 
vide) .  .  .  the  consumer  with  adequate  service  at  reasonable  prices."  This  is 
praiseworthy.  Your  contribution  to  air  transport  regulation  would  be  enhanced 
were  you  to  examine,  also,  whether  those  practices  and  procedures  have  been 
administered,  over  the  last  36  years,  to  insure  a  healthy  climate  in  which  the 
U.S.-flag  system  could  be  sustained.  And,  indeed,  to  inquire  whether  the  practices 
and  procedures  applicable  to  the  domestic  industry  are  equally  appropriate  to 
the  totally  different  nature  of  international  air  transportation.  Also,  in  that  light, 
you  should  examine  whether  the  nostrums  advanced  to  save  the  domestic  air 
transport  system  are  not  totally  unsuited  as  solutions  to  the  problems  of  Pan  Am, 
a  somewhat  different  U.S.  airline  whose  operations  constitute  close  to  50  percent 
of  the  U.S.-flag  operation  outside  the  United  States  and  which  performs  less  than 
10  percent  of  its  operations  domestically— and  all  of  those  outside  the  U.S. 
mainland. 

Since  no  one  else  yet  has,  let  us  look  at  the  differences  between  the  U.S.  com- 
panies that  operate  air  transportation  services  internationally  and  those  who 
concentrate  on  domestic  serrices. 

At  the  outset,  we'd  like  to  explain  what  we  propose  to  tell  you  and  why  we 
feel  that  to  be  necessary.  The  Federal  Aviation  Act  requires  the  CAB  to  con- 
sider "*  *  *  as  being  in  the  public  interest,  and  in  accordance  with  the  public 
convenience  and  necessity ;  the  encouragement  and  development  of  an  air  trans- 
portation system  properly  adapted  to  the  present  and  future  needs  of  the  fed- 
eral and  domestic  commerce  of  the  United  States,  of  the  Postal  Service,  and  of 
the  national  defense  *  *  *."  The  statute  also  directs  the  Board  to  consider 
"*  *  *  competition  to  the  extent  necessary  to  assure  the  sound  development  of 
an  air  transportation  system  *  *  *"  also  consonant  with  the  trinity  of  require- 
ments respecting  the  commerce,  the  Postal  Service  and  the  national  defense  of 
the  United  States.  As  a  result  of  these  statutory  directives  the  same  procedures 
and  practices,  and  to  a  very  great  extent  the  same  philosophic  determinations, 
have  been  developed  with  respect  to  both  domestic  and  foreign  commerce.  This 
is  understandable  as  a  matter  of  statutory  interpretation.  It  was  also  under- 
standable at  the  time  the  Act  was  written  that  the  regulatory  approach  would 
treat  similarly  the  basic  economic  determinants  for  certification  whether  it  be 
in  the  domestic  or  the  international  field.  However,  we  feel  it  important  that 
we  differentiate  the  two  systems  of  air  transportation.  In  addition  to  that,  it 
seems  useful  to  explore  the  structure  of  our  .systems  generally,  and  of  Pan  Am 
more  specifically.  Pan  Am  is  the  principal  U.S.  international  carrier  and,  as  a 
carrier  without  mainland  domestic  routes,  may  suggest  a  pretty  good  example 
of  the  need  for  such  differentiation. 

We  hasten  to  point  out  that  the  problems  of  Pan  Am  are  related  against  this 
background  and  not  for  the  purpose  of  complaining  about  our  condition.  After 
we  have  given  you  the  facts  and  old  you  wha  we've  aemped  to  remedy  our 
problems,  we  feel  you'll  agree  that  management  has  done  an  effective  job  in  the 
face  of  some  very  awesome  challenges. 

So,  le's  take  a  look,  at  the  outset,  at  the  two  airline  systems  of  the  United 
States  and  wherein  they  inherently  differ. 

I.    THE   TWO   AIKLINE    SYSTEMS   OF   THE    UNITED    STATES 

The  United  States  has  two  airline  systems,  both  essential  to  the  country :  the 
domestic  system,  which  operates  within  the  United  States ;  the  flag  system,  which 
operates  beyond  the  borders  of  the  50  states. 


Many  U.S.  airlines  take  part  in  both  systems.  The  impression  is  thus  sometimes 
given  that  the  two  systems  are  similar.  They  are  not. 

There  are  basic  distinctions  between  the  U.S.-flag  system  and  the  U.S.  domestic 
system,  and  the  tw^o  systems  must  be  treated  accordingly. 

1.  The  Two  Environments:  U.S. -Domestic  and  U.S.-Flag 

The  domestic  system  operates  in  a  single  environment  within  the  U.S.  The  flag 
system  operates  in  each  of  the  separate  environments  of  the  numerous  countries 
which  it  serves.  The  multitude  of  political  and  economic  environments  in  which 
the  flag  system  operates,  as  compared  with  the  single  political  and  economic  en- 
tity in  whi  h  the  domestic  system  functions,  emphasizes  the  dissimilarity  between 
the  two  systems. 

The  economic  impact  on  the  flag  system  of  marketing  a  product  in  numerous 
foreign  nation  environments  is  dissimilar  to  the  domestic  system.  The  domestic 
system  operates  in  a  free  market  economy.  The  flag  system,  in  most  cases,  oper- 
ates in  the  world  of  cartels  and  pools  and  government-owned  and  subsidized 
corporations. 

Labor  laws  are  but  another  example  of  dissimilarity.  The  domestic  system  op- 
erates under  a  xmiform  set  of  U.S.  government-regulated  labor  laws.  The  flag 
system  is  immersed  in  environments  of  numerous  foreign  nations,  each  with  sep- 
arate laws. 

The  divergence  in  economic  environments  in  which  the  two  systems  operate  is 
illustrated  by  airport/airway  costs.  The  domestic  system  operates  with  a  pro- 
gram administered  and  paid  for  through  a  single  government  controlled  airport 
development  air  program  fund  supported  by  the  consumer  of  airline  services.  The 
flag  system  supports  airport/airways  costs  around  the  world  by  mandated  user 
charges  of  the  multiple  nations  which  it  serves  and  such  costs  are  borne  by  the 
carrier.  In  1974,  these  charges  to  Pan  Am  came  to  $46  million. 

There  are  many  other  obvious  basic  distinctions  between  the  two  systems  in  the 
areas  of  markets,  competition,  competitive  opportunity,  fares  and  rates,  wage 
levels,  cost  of  capital,  and  price  control.  They  relate  to  the  separate  environments 
of  the  flag  system  and  the  domestic  system  and  effect  every  element  of  their 
different  operations. 

2.  Markets 

The  markets  of  the  domestic  system  are  protected  against  competition  from 
foreign-flag  airlines.  The  question  of  w^hich  airlines  shall  serve  which  geographic 
markets  is  determined  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  The  determination  is  iuade 
on  the  basis  of  public  convenience  and  necessity. 

The  markets  of  the  flag  system  are  by  definition  subject  to  competition  by 
foreign-flag  airlines.  The  question  of  which  airline  shall  serve  which  geographic 
markets  is  determined  by  international  negotiation  between  governments.  The 
determination  is  made  on  the  basis  of  various  national  interests  including,  among 
others,  prestige  and  political  considerations  and  tourism. 

3.  Amount  of  Competition 

The  amount  of  competition  within  the  domestic  system  is  determined  and  con- 
trolled by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  Decisions  as  to  the  amount  of  competi- 
tion are  based  on  concepts  of  what  represents  good  service  for  the  public  and 
sound  economics  for  the  airlines. 

The  amount  of  competition  faced  by  the  flag  system  is  decided  by  foreign  gov- 
ernments as  well  as  by  the  U.S.  Government.  Decisions  are  made  on  the  basis  of 
various  national  interests  and  political  considerations. 

A  number  of  examples  will  illustrate  this  difference.  The  U.S.  government  de- 
creed that  only  three  carriers  (Delta,  Eastern  and  National)  are  needed  between 
New  York  and  the  Miami  area,  and  they  carried  3  million  passengers  in  1972. 
Ten  carriers  competed  for  less  than  1  million  passengers  in  1972  in  the  New 
York-London  market.  Our  government  apparently  felt  that  only  three  carriers 
(American,  TWA  and  United)  were  required  to  provide  healthy  competition  and 
they  served  1  million  passengers  between  New  York  and  Los  Angeles  in  1972. 
Eight  airlines  vied  for  the  business  of  about  half  a  million  passengers  in  the  New 
York-Paris  market  in  1972. 

4-  Competitive  Opportunity 

Within  the  domestic  system  the  principle  is  that  airlines  .shall  have  equality  of 
competitive  opportunity.  Restrictions  on  competitive  opportunity,  when  they 
exist,  are  intended  to  balance  the  interests  of  one  airline  fairly  against  anotb"' 


640 

The  flag  system  does  not  have  equality  of  competitive  opportunity  with  foreign- 
flag  airlines.  Foreign-flag  airlines  have  the  right  of  access  to  the  U.S.  market  on 
equal  terms  with  the  U.S.-nag  system.  But  the  U.S.-flag  system  is  severely 
discriminated  against  a  foreign  markets  by  foreign  governments.  This  discrimina- 
tion was  a  fundamental  reason  for  the  enactment  of  the  Internaional  Air  Trans- 
portation Fair  Competitive  Practices  Act.  (It  is  thoughtful  legislation  which  can 
be  effective  only  if  properly  and  vigorously  administered. ) 

5.  Fares  and  Rates 

For  the  domestic  system,  the  level  of  fares  and  rates  is  set  by  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board,  and  action  can  be  rapid  when  speed  is  required.  The  Board  acts 
in  accordance  with  the  concept  that  the  public  interest  requires  that  airlines 
receive  a  reasonable  rate  of  return. 

For  the  flag  system,  the  level  of  fares  and  rates  is  set  through  international 
negotiation  between  airlines,  and  these  agreements  are  subject  to  approval  by 
governments.  Rapid  action  is  virtually  impossible.  In  making  the  decisions,  the 
subject  of  airline  economics  plays  a  relatively  minor  role  with  the  major  factors 
being  such  issues  as  how  the  various  foreign-flag  air  services  can  best  serve  their 
country's  economic  and  other  national  objectives. 

No  international  mechanism  has  been  as  non-constructively  maligned  as 
lATA.  The  word  itself  has  become  fashionable  opprobrium  in  the  halls  of  acad- 
eme. We  don't  like  a  good  deal  about  it.  We  would,  however,  suggest  that  instead 
of  condemning  the  lATA  machinery  that  some  one  suggest  a  better  alternative 
for  how  a  hundred  countries  can  agree  on  the  exercise  of  their  inherent  sovereign 
power. 

6.  Cost  of  Capital 

Within  the  domestic  system,  the  companies  compete  on  relatively  equal  terms 
for  capital,  and  the  cost  of  capital  depends  on  a  company's  rating  and  on  its 
negotiating  skill. 

The  cost  of  capital  is  higher  for  the  U.S.-flag  system  than  for  the  foreign-flag 
airlines.  Capital  is  made  available  to  foreign-flag  airlines  free  of  charge  or  at 
low  cost  by  their  own  governments,  and  certain  low-cost  capital  is  also  provided 
foreign-flag  airlines  through  the  United  States  Government,  which  does  not  pro- 
vide similar  capital  for  the  U.S.-flag  system.^ 

7.  Price  Control 

The  price  of  most  supplies,  including  fuel,  used  by  the  domestic  system  can  be 
controlled  by  the  U.S.  Government.  A  significant  portion  of  the  supplies,  notably 
fuel,  used  by  the  U.S.-flag  system,  and  purchased  abroad  cannot  be  price-con- 
trolled by  the  U.S.  Government. 
S.  Political  and  Economic  Environment 

The  domestic  system  functions  within  the  relatively  stable  domestic  political 
and  economic  environment  of  the  United  States.  The  U.S.-flag  system  is  subject 
to  the  effects  of  foreign  political  and  economic  turmoil  (as  when  a  war  or  a 
national  strike  forces  suspension  of  service  to  some  markets  and  also  causes 
costly  circuitous  routing  of  flights  in  order  to  avoid  war  zones). 

.9.  Subsidized  Competition 

Within  the  domestic  system,  trunklines  do  not  face  competition  from  other 
trunklines  that  are  subsidized.  With  few  exceptions,  the  U.S.-flag  system  com- 
petes again  subsidized  government-owned  or  government-support  foreign-flag 
airlines — subsidized  not  only  to  cover  the  operations  of  airline  systems  I)ut  also 
the  manufacture  of  aircraft  as  well  as  other  associated  elements  of  a  transpor- 
tation complex. 
10.  The  Flag  System's  Basic  Economic  and  Policy  Problems 

The  basic  economic  and  policy  problems  of  the  U.S.-flag  system  can  be  simply 
^nd  compactly  stated : 

(a)  Competition  against  the  U.S.-flag  system  has  been  established  on  a  scale 
that  is  destructive  of  the  U.S.  interest,  particularly  since  much  of  the  foreign- 
flag  competition  receives  subsidy  and  other  special  support  and  since  virtually 
all  foreign-flag  systems  are  fed  by  extensive  domestic  operations. 


iln  fiscal  year  1974,  Ex  Im  credits  for  aviation  purchases  granted  to  foreign  airlines 
totaled  $918  million,  at  interest  rates  of  6  and  7  percent,  characteristically  far  lower  than 
the  rates  then  being  charged  by  commercial  lenders. 


641 

(&)  The  U.S. -flag  system  today  does  not  have  equal  treatment  with  foreign- 
flag  airlines.  The  interests  of  the  foreign-flag  airlines  are  generally  advanced  in 
a  more  coordinated  and  systematic  fashion  by  foreign  governments  than  are  the 
interests  of  the  U.S.-flag  system  by  the  U.S.  Government.  The  U.S.-flag  system 
does  not  in  fact  have  equality  of  competitive  opportunity. 

(c)  For  a  large  portion  of  the  world's  air  network,  fares  and  rates  had  been 
set  at  levels  that  are  not  compensatory. 

It  can  be  seen  that  Pan  Am's  problems  are  unique,  for  Pan  Am  is  unlike 
any  other  U.S.  airline. 

Pan  American's  greatest  special  problem,  however,  is  the  long  history  of  reg- 
ulatory actions  which,  bit  by  bit,  sapped  away  at  the  strength  of  a  strong  carrier. 
There  was  no  deliberate  government  policy  to  cripple  us.  Rather,  on  the  basis  of 
uncoordinated  case-by-case  review,  it  was  decided  in  each  case  that  that  particu- 
lar straw  would  not  break  our  back. 

Pan  Am's  problems  cannot  be  adequately  comprehended  without  relating  them 
to  a  broad  view  of  the  entire  airline  industry,  both  domestic  and  international, 
and  to  the  regulatory  steps  which  in  the  past  preceded  the  present  critical 
situation. 

II.    HISTORY   OF    OUR   U.S.-FLAG   SYSTEM 

What  impact  have  these  differences  in  systems,  but  comparability  of  certifica- 
tion and  entry  criteria,  had  on  our  U.S.-flag  systems?  Pan  Am  had  initiated 
Caribbean  services  in  1928,  Latin  America  service  in  1930,  inaugurated  trans- 
pacific services  in  October  of  1936  before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  was  passed 
in  1938,  and  was  certificated  across  the  Atlantic  in  1939. 

World  War  II,  at  one  and  the  same  time,  immobilized  air  commerce  yet  ulti- 
mately became  its  greatest  stimulant.  At  the  close  of  the  war,  the  transatlantic 
market  appeared  the  most  immediately  promising.  In  1945,  three  basic  routes  to 
Europe  were  designed :  across  the  Atlantic  to  Scandinavia  and  Russia ;  to  India 
via  the  United  Kingdom,  Germany,  east  Europe  and  Turkey ;  and  a  southern 
route  by  way  of  France,  Iberia  and  the  Mediterranean  basin  to  southern  India. 
In  1950,  Pan  Am's  acquisition  of  American  Overseas  Airlines'  northern  route 
precipitated  a  redesign  of  the  competitive  map  which  resulted  in  U.S.  competition 
in  foreign  markets  for  the  first  time. 

This  looked  good  and  sound  because  the  tired  world  had  not  yet  developed,  with 
U.S.  assistance,  its  economic  muscle.  The  illusion  of  healthy  and  necessary  U.S. 
competition  provoked,  over  the  next  two  decades,  the  grant  of  competition  among 
U.S.  airlines  in  almost  every  major  international  market.  Over  the  years,  since 
1950,  the  principal  airline  components  of  the  uouiestic  system  have  been  granted 
international  or  overseas  routes  regardless  of  the  growth  and  strength  and 
strength  and  government  nourishment  of  the  scores  of  foreign-flag  competitors. 

m.    PAN   AM  :    THE   CUEBENT   CRISIS 

i.  A  Brief  Background 

Pan  Am  will  be  50  years  old  in  1977.  Pan  Am  was  the  first  U.S.  international 
carrier  when  the  Act  was  passed  in  Vd6H.  Notwithstanding  its  efforts  over  the 
years  to  improve  its  competitive  position,  its  basic  route  system  has  remained 
virtually  the  same  since  1950,  by  government  order. 

At  the  same  time,  every  other  major  U.S.  trunkline  has  been  granted  regula- 
tory permission  to  grow  significantly  over  the  last  20  years,  often  by  diluting 
Pan  Am's  international  route  potential. 

Every  major  "domestic"  U.S.  air  carrier  has  been  given  the  right  to  expand 
into  international  or  overseas  services  while  Pan  Am  still  is  not  permitted  to  fly  at 
home  in  equitable  comj^etition  and  is  rigidly  confined  by  U.S.  regulation  basically 
to  international  and  overseas  routes.  (Pan  Am's  "domestic"  operations  date  from 
the  period  when  Alaska  and  Hawaii  were  still  territories  of  the  United  States.) 

2.  Pan  Am  has  teen  An  Innovator 

From  the  outset  in  1927,  Pan  Am  has  been  recognized  as  the  pioneer  of  the 
industry,  worldwide.  Virtually  all  overseas  routes  in  the  world  were  first  opened^ 
by  Pan  Am.  But  Pan  Am  has  pioneered  in  every  other  phase  of  the  airline  in- 
dustry's development,  as  well. 

Despite  the  rigidity  of  regulations  circumscribing  Pan  Am's  efforts  to  expand 
its  operations  in  order  to  compete  evenly.  Pan  Am  has  an  unparalleled  record 
of  innovating  fare  reductions.  This  unique  record,  beginning  in  1946,  extended 


642 

to  all  Pan  Am  routes  and  comprehended  every  type  of  fare.  Only  recently,  in  the 
autumn  of  1970,  Pan  Am's  attempt  to  introduce  a  $99  standby  student  fare  to 
Europe  was  rejected  by  lATA.  the  international  governing  body. 

Pan  Am  was  the  first  airline  to  recognize  that  air  transportation  was  not  the 
only  necessity  for  tourism.  Pan  Am  s  wholly  owned  subsidiary,  the  Interconti- 
nental Hotel  Corporation,  opened  its  first  hotel  in  1946.  It  now  owns,  manages  or 
franchises  66  hotels  in  46  countries.  Some  of  these  establishment  were  de- 
veloped in  the  national  interest  in  conjunction  with  the  government's  policy  of 
assisting  the  emerging  economics  of  the  then  underdeveloped  nations. 

Pan  Am  has  been  the  industry's  technological  leader.  It  introduced  the  jets  in 
1958 ;  the  Boeing  747's,  the  first  of  the  widebodied  jets,  early  in  1970.  Pan  Am's 
initial  order  enabled  Boeing  to  go  ahead  with  production  of  the  747,  and  Pratt 
&  Whitney  to  proceed  with  the  JT9D  engine.  Pan  Am's  initial  order  encouraged 
other  U.S.  and  foreign-fiag  carriers  to  order  the  747.  Pan  Am's  leadership  in 
jet  procurement  has  led  to  orders  amounting  to  $4.14  billion  by  mid-1971,  includ- 
ing $1.78  billion  by  foreign  airlines. 

3.  Pan  Am's  Competitive  Situation  in  the  Air  Markets  of  the  World 

Pan  Am  is  subject  to  more  competition  and  to  more  restrictions  than  any  other 
airline  in  the  world.  Pan  Am  is  the  only  U.S.  major  airline  without  a  domestic 
network.  As  if  it  were  a  foreign  airline.  Pan  Am  is  prohibited  from  passenger- 
cargo  service  between  cities  within  the  continental  U.S.  Pan  Am's  foreign-flag 
competitors  are  not  so  restricted  in  their  own  countries. 

Pan  Am's  overseas  routes  have  continuously  been  diluted  through  the  years 
by  awards  to  its  U.S.  competitors  without  compensatory  authorizations  to  balance 
and  to  maintain  its  competitive  position. 

Gradually  over  the  years.  Pan  Am  has  been  subjected  to  dilution  of  its  profit 
potential  by  more  unsound  and  excessive  competition — both  U.S.  and  foreign, 
scheduled  and  charter — than  any  other  airline.  This  has  seriously  affected  its 
profitability. 

Competing  with  Pan  Am  in  the  world's  travel  market  are :  49  airlines  across 
the  Atlantic;  27  to  Caribbean  points:  31  to  cities  in  South  America;  21  U.S. 
carriers  to  Hawaii ;  12  to  the  Orient  and  9  to  the  South  Pacific. 

U.S.  and  foreign  carriers  now  provide  what  clearly  is  excessive  competition  on 
virtually  all  of  Pan  Am's  routes.  This  unsound  and  uneconomic  competition  is 
largely  the  result  of  U.S.  governmental  edict. 

One  of  the  major  causes  of  Pan  Am's  unique  and  distressed  competitive  position 
in  the  world's  international  markets  is  the  fact  that  all  of  its  U.S.  competitors 
may  also  operate  domestically,  have  strong  U.S.  continental  traflic  centers  to  feed 
and  support  their  international  operations.  And,  by  reason  of  those  U.S.  domestic 
operations,  they  maintain  a  degree  of  influence  over  domestic  passengers  for 
routing  over  their  own  international  routes.  None  of  this  is  available  to  Pan  Am. 

Foreign  airlines  enjoy  certain  distinct  advantages.  Their  own  nationals  under- 
standably generally  use  their  own  airlines.  Usually,  they  offer  the  U.S.  airlines 
one  or  two  major  traflSc  points  in  their  own  nation  in  return  for  many  more  that 
they  serve  in  the  United  States  and  beyond.  They  are  government-supported 
airlines.  They,  too,  have  a  domestic  feed  within  their  countries  and  extra-terri- 
torial access  to  their  Commonwealth  and  territorial  associates. 

The  supplemental  problem  underscores  a  basic  ru'e  of  physics,  applicable,  with 
devastating  results  to  U.S.-flag  competition :  for  every  action  there  is  an  equal 
and  opposite  reaction.  Without  aruging  the  emotional  problem  of  supplemental 
versus  scheduled  carriers,  it  is  obvious  that  an  increased  .share  of  the  trans- 
atlantic passenger  market  from  about  2  percent  in  1964  to  over  17  percent  in  1971 
is  not  insubstantial  competition. 
4.  The  Classic  Example  of  Hawaii 

In  1936,  Pan  Am  pioneered  the  flights  from  the  mainland  to  Hawaii.  After 
World  War  II,  two  more  airlines,  Northwest  and  United,  were  authorized  to 
provide  what  was  balanced  competition  under  regulation. 

The  public  interest  was  served.  All  three  were  able  to  exist.  All  three  were 
able  to  follow  Pan  Am's  traditional  policy  of  offering  lower  prices  as  traflSc  in- 
creased and  profits  developed. 

In  1969.  five  more  U.S.  arlines  were  granted  the  rights  to  compete  for  the 
Hawaiian  air  travel  business.  All  had  mid-American  rights  and  access  to  the 
vast  and  mid-continental  population  markets,  as  had  the  original  two  competi- 
tors, Northwest  and  United. 


643 

This  is  a  classic  example  of  reasonable  and  sound  competition  being  cast  aside 
in  favor  of  unsound  and  excessive  competition,  without  understandable  rhyme, 
reason  or  principle.  Although  in  this  case,  as  in  others.  Pan  Ani's  long-standing 
routes  have  been  the  constant  targets,  there  have  been  no  balancing  or  compensa- 
tory awards  to  Pan  Am. 

In  fact,  despite  Pan  Am's  development  of  the  Hawaiian  market  and  with  the 
advent  of  new  long-range  aircraft  which  allowed  for  nonstop  flights  to  and  from 
New  York  only  two  of  the  three  original  airlines.  Northwest  and  United,  received 
this  award.  Pan  Am  was  denied  the  right.  American,  a  newcomer  to  this  route 
was  chosen  over  Pan  Am.  (The  Pan  Am/ American  route  swap  corrects  this.) 

Denied  those  nonstop  rights,  later  that  same  year.  Pan  Am  petitioned  unsuc- 
cessfully for  the  right  of  "fill-up"  traflBc  between  New  York  and  California.  No 
domestic  passengers  or  cargo  were  allowed.  "Fill-up"  traffic  would  have  meant 
an  opportunity  to  carry  a  small  number  of  domestic-bound  pas.sengers  between 
the  two  coasts.  At  most,  it  would  have  resulted  in  one  or  two  flights  a  day — an 
additional  public  service  w'ith  little,  if  any  effect  on  the  U.S.  airlines  already 
with  those  rights. 

5.  The  Caribbean 

Four  U.S.  airlines  presently  serve  the  Caribbean  region — Pan  Am,  American, 
Eastern,  Delta.  In  addition,  12  foreign  scheduled  carriers  and  9  U.S.  supple- 
mentals  are  authorized  to  operate  in  that  area. 

This  abundance  of  competition  has  made  it  virtually  impossible  for  any  sched- 
uled airline  to  make  its  Caribbean  routes  profitable.  One  previously-authorized 
scheduled  airline,  Trans-Caribbean,  on  the  threshold  of  insolvency  by  the  end  of 
1969,  was  acquired  by  American.  This  permitted  American  Airlines  to  expand 
its  far-flung  domestic  and  international  route  structure  into  this  already  over- 
burdened air  travel  sector. 

An  example  of  this  impact  w^as  to  further  erode  Pan  Am's  limited  domestic 
market  since  prior  to  this  new  government  authorization  of  American  into  the 
Caribbean  by  acquisition,  domestic  passengers  enroute  to  that  region  were  gen- 
erally routed  by  American  to  fly  on  Pan  Am. 

And  the  domestic  sources  of  Eastern,  as  w^ell  as  those  of  Delta  give  them  an 
obvious  advantage  in  strengthening  their  traffic  opportunities  to  the  Caribbean 
versus  Pan  Am's  domestic  gap. 

6.  The  South  Pacific 

In  1969,  the  government  also  authorized  American  to  compete  with  Pan  Am  in 
the  South  Pacific,  with  a  number  of  competitive  intermediate  resort  island  stops 
to  New  Zealand  and  Australia. 

On  flights  to  the  South  Pacific,  four  foreign  scheduled  carriers  and  three  U.S. 
supplementals  had  also  been  authorized  to  operate  on  this  long-distance  route 
which  is  necessary  in  the  public  interest  but  is  far  from  being  profitable. 

While  one  U.S.  airline  might  continue  to  be  able  to  exist  economically  against 
this  competition,  it  did  not  appear  probable  that  two  U.S.  scheduled  airlines 
could  do  so.  American  and  Pan  Am  have  wisely  proposed  to  swap  South  Pacific 
and  Caribbean  routes  to  correct,  by  these  self-help  resources,  an  unhealthy  com- 
petitive situation. 

7.  The  U.S.-Orient 

In  1948,  Northwest  Airlines  was  granted  rights  to  fly  from  New  York  and 
Seattle  to  the  Orient.  In  1969,  in  the  far-reaching  Transpacific  Case  decision. 
Northwest  was  granted  a  new  competitive  route  to  the  Orient  via  Hawaii  and 
the  Central  Pacific.  Once  again,  Pan  Am's  competitor  had  access  to  interior  U.S. 
with  its  vast  population  centers  as  a  source  of  increasing  overseas  traflSc.  And 
in  addition.  Northwest  had  been  granted  the  added  advantage  of  nonstop  flights 
between  New  Y^ork  and  Hawaii  of  obvious  importance  to  Central  Pacific-Oriental 
travel. 

That  same  1969  decision  also  closed  TWA's  round-the-world  gap  by  allowing 
TWA  to  fly  from  Hong  Kong  to  Los  Angeles  via  Taiwan,  Okinawa,  Guam  and 
Hawaii.  Here,  again.  Pan  Am  enlisted  TWA  in  its  self-help  campaign  trading 
certain  European  points  for  TWA's  Pacific  rights. 

That  same  1069  decision  for  the  first  time  also  certificated  a  U.S.  all-cargo 
carrier.  Flying  Tigers,  across  the  Central  Pacific  to  Tokyo,  Bangkok,  Southeast 
Asia  and  other  Far  East  points. 


644 

8.  Pan  Aril's  Domestic  Gap:  An  Important  Element  of  the  Problem 

Pan  Am  pioneered  round-the-world  flights.  But  Pan  Am  has  been  limited  by 

U.S.  Government  edict  to    U.S.  gateway  cities,  primarily  on  the  nation's  two 

coasts. 

The  possession  of  a  domestic  network  was  to  remain  as  the  preserve  for  the 

domestic  airlines.  At  the  outset,  overseas  and  international  passengers  from  U.S. 

continental  cities  were  transferred  to  and  thus  were  able  to  support  the  traflSc 

needs  of  Pan  Am  and  the  other  purely  international  air  carriers. 

But  when,  in  1945,  the  purely  domestic  airlines,  American  and  TWA,  were  also 

authorized  to  become  international  carriers  across  the  Atlantic  and  beyond,  the 

die  was  cast.  The  criteria  of  regulated  competition  were  applied  in  equal  measure 

to  U.S.  domestic  and  international  competition  without  regard  to  their  basic 

differences. 

IV.  THE  IMPACT  OF  THE  FUEL  CRISIS 

From  1966's  peak  of  profitability — at  $86  million  noninflated  dollars — to 
six  years  of  mounting  losses,  Pan  Am's  trouble  has  been  well-recorded.  But  there 
was  near  success  in  1973,  but  not  quite  enough  of  a  cushion  of  a  comfortable, 
healthy  competitive  flavor  to  compensate  for  increased  fuel  prices  further  exac- 
erbated by  the  impact  of  a  combined  inflation/recession  in  the  predominantly 
vacation/pleasure  market  Pan  Am  serves. 

We  had  felt  in  1973  that  we  would  enjoy  our  first  profitable  years  since  1968. 
But,  first  the  scarcity  of  fuel,  then  its  escalated  price  shattered  that  hope.  Even 
so,  in  1973  we  recorded  a  sharply  increased  operating  profit  of  $6.7  million 
compared  to  $188,000  in  1972. 

In  1974,  our  preliminary  estimate  of  operating  loss  is  about  $98  million. 

Our  fuel  bill  in  1974  was  $333  million.  Our  fuel  bill  in  1973  was  $170  million— 
about  100  percent  increase  over  1973.  And  this  despite  12  percent  less  flying. 
Fuel  costs  represented  over  21  percent  of  our  total  operating  expenses  whereas 
in  1972,  the  last  complete  calendar  year  before  the  fuel  crisis,  it  represented 
about  10  percent. 

In  1974,  compared  to  1973,  Pan  Am's  operating  expenses  increased  only  1.7  per- 
cent exclusive  of  fuel  costs. 

The  cost,  per  gallon,  of  fuel  to  Pan  Am  rose  from  19.6  cents  at  the  beginning  of 
1974  to  38.6  cents  by  December.  This  compares  to  cost  increa.<;es,  to  domestic  car- 
riers, of  from  about  15  cents  per  gallon  at  the  beginning  of  the  year  to  about  24 
cents  by  the  end  of  1974.  Since  each  penny  per  gallon  increase  means  approxi- 
mately $10  million  per  year  to  Pan  Am,  you  can  calculate  what  Pan  Am's  burden 
of  close  to  an  additional  14  cents  over  the  average  domestic  price  would  have 
meant  to  the  profit  picture  of  the  principal  U.S.  domestic  trunks  who  each  burned 
in  excess  of  IV2  billion  gallons  of  fuel  in  1974. 

First,  the  fuel  crunch  and  then  the  fuel  punch  sent  Pan  Am  reeling. 

V.  PAN  am's  efforts  TO  HELP  ITSELF 

So  much  has  been  written  about  Pan  Am's  problems  and  its  efforts  to  have  the 
government  bail  it  out  that  there  has  been  an  insuflicient  focus  on  the  efforts  that 
Pan  Am  has  made  to  help  itself.  These  efforts  have  been  vigorous  and  effective. 
They  can  be  briefly  described  as  follows  : 

1.  Pan  Am  reduced  personnel  by  4,750  employees.  At  the  beginning  of  1972, 
Pan  Am's  total  payroll  was  36,084.  By  February  of  1974,  this  has  been  reduced  to 
31,334.  Reduction  is  continuing. 

2.  Pan  Am  reduced  its  capital  expenditure  program  for  1974  from  $100  million 
to  approximately  $70  million.  Capital  expenditures  were  limited  to  those  for 
which  previous  commitments  had  been  made  or  were  necessary  in  the  interest  of 
safety,  efliciency,  or  environmental  improvement. 

3.  Capacity  in  terms  of  scheduled  available  seat-miles  operated  was  reduced  by 
10.4  percent  from  1973.  In  1973,  Pan  Am  operated  36.2  billion  available  seat-miles 
in  scheduled  service  and  operated  32.3  billion  available  seat-miles  in  the  full  year 
of  1974. 

4.  In  order  to  protect  itself  from  dangerous  erosion  of  its  scheduled  traffic  by 
foreign  and  U.S.  charter  operators,  Pan  Am  decreased  its  charter  operations  con- 
siderably less  than  its  scheduled  operations.  In  1973,  it  operated  4.263  billion 
available  seat-miles  in  charter  operations.  In  1974,  it  operated  4.212  billion  in 
this  service,  a  decrease  of  only  1.2  percent.  Pan  Am  is  the  largest  passenger 
charter  operator  in  the  world. 


645 

5.  Pan  Am  entered  into  the  following  agreements  to  improve  the  strength  of 
its  route  system  : 

(a)  TWA/PAA. — By  this  agreement  Pan  Am  withdrew  from  Ireland  and  TWA 
withdrew  from  certain  of  its  routes  in  Africa.  The  agreement  has  been  approved 
by  the  CAB  and  is  in  effect. 

(&)  AA/I'AA. — By  this  agreement,  the  approval  of  which  is  pending  before 
the  CAB,  American  withdrew  from  the  South  Pacific  (south  of  Honolulu)  and 
Pan  Am  undertook  to  transfer  to  American  certain  of  its  routes  in  the  Caribbean. 
When  this  agreement  is  approved.  Pan  Am  will  also  oi>erate  American's  present 
route  from  New  York,  Chicago  and  Dallas/Fort  Worth  to  Honolulu. 

(o)  Western/PAA. — By  this  agreement  Pan  Am  transferred  a  Boeing  707  and 
its  route  from  Seattle  to  Fairbanks  to  Western  for  $0.3  million  in  cash.  This 
agreement  is  pending  before  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

(d)  TWA/PAA. — By  this  agreement,  recently  approved  by  the  CAB,  TWA  and 
Pan  Am  seeks  to  eliminate  part  of  the  head-to-head  competition  between  the  two 
carriers  in  the  Pacific  and  in  Europe. 

G.  Pan  Am  suspended  service  at  15  points  on  its  worldwide  system  and  if  it 
could  secure  CAB  approval  for  the  agreements  referred  to  above,  it  would  be 
prepared  to  suspend  additional  services. 

7.  With  the  approval  of  the  CAB,  Pan  Am  has  entered  into  capacity  reduction 
agreements  as  follows : 

(a)  New  York/San  Juan. 

(b)  Miami /San  Juan — Miami/ Virgin  Islands. 

(c)  US/UK. 

(d)  US/Italy. 

(e)  US/Venezuela. 

8.  It  has  vigorously  pursued  its  application  for  authority  to  operate  between 
Los  Angeles  and  Miami,  to  operate  between  New  York  and  Johannesburg  via 
Rio  de  Janeiro,  and  to  improve  its  Pacific  system  by  operating  between  Saipan 
and  Tokyo. 

9.  Pan  Am  has  reduced  its  fleet  size  from  161  in  1970  to  144  in  1972  and  134  in 

1974.  During  1974,  used  aircraft  were  sold  for  $22  million. 

10.  Pan  Am  has  developed  and  carried  into  effect  a  fuel  conservation  program 
which  saved  40  million  gallons  for  the  first  9-months  of  1974. 

By  reason  of  the  improvements  in  eflBciency  set  out  above.  Pan  Am  in  1973 
incurred  operating  expenses  per  revenue  ton-mile  of  40.1  cents,  the  lowest  in 
the  trunkline  industry.  It  incurred  available  ton-mile  costs  of  19.6  cents,  the 
third  lowest  in  the  industry.  In  1974,  Pan  Am's  operating  expenses,  excluding 
fuel  which  is  virtually  uncontrollable,  have  increased  only  1.7  percent  notwith- 
standing U.S.  inflation  of  over  10  percent  and  even  higher  inflation  rates  in  the 
countries  in  which  it  operates.  Pan  Am's  fuel  cost  increase  for  1974  was  approxi- 
mately $170  million.  Its  1974  net  loss  was  $81.8  million.  Thus,  it  was  able  to 
swallow  close  to  $90  million  of  uncontrollable  cost  increases. 

Pan  Am's  efforts  have  increased  its  overall  productivity  dramatically.  Using 
1967  as  a  base  of  100,  the  1973  inflation  index  for  the  trunklines  and  Pan  Am 
as  a  group,  has  increased  to  142.7  and  productivity  up  117..5.  Through  the  second 
C]uarter  of  1974,  the  inflation  index  for  Pan  Am  is  158.9,  and  productivity  is 
130.9.  Thus,  Pan  Am  has  been  faced  with  inflation  more  severe  than  the  industry 
as  a  whole,  and  its  productivity  increase  has  been  considerably  higher. 

As  part  of  the  continuing  program  to  help  itself,  the  following  additional  steps 
are  being  taken : 

1.  In  order  to  meet  a  severe  cash  shortage  during  the  low  traflBc  months  of  the 
winter  and  early  spring.  Pan  Am  negotiated  a  $125  million  line  of  credit.  To 
secure  this  line  of  credit,  Pan  Am  had  to  agree  to  its  termination  on  September  30, 

1975,  and  to  pledge  to  long-  and  short-term  lenders  virtually  all  of  its  assets. 

2.  Further  overall  cost  reduction  programs,  the  continuation  of  the  present 
policy  on  capital  exi>enditures.  and  new  and  drastic  measures  designed  to  mobi- 
lize cash  resources  are  expected  to  improve  the  Company's  cash  position. 

3.  Further  sale  of  used  aircraft  and  surplus  property  is  expected  to  provide 
substantial  additional  cash  during  1975. 

4.  It  has  entered  into  negotiations  with  the  Government  of  Iran  seeking  to 
secure  a  long-term  loan  of  approximately  $300  million  and  has  vigorously  pur- 
sued these  negotiations  to  the  point  where  there  is  every  reason  to  anticipate 
success  if  our  Government  does  not  introduce  insurmountable  obstacles. 

As  we  have  noted,  our  efforts  at  self-help  have  been  dislocated  by  the  extra- 
ordinary cost  of  fuel— a  cost  far  greater  for  us  than  that  of  the  domestic  air- 


646 

lines  who  enjoy  some  measure  of  price  control.  Since  over  50  percent  of  our  fuel 
is  loaded  overseas,  our  cost  is  substantially  greater. 

CONCLUSION 

This  testimony,  along  with  the  answers  submitted  to  your  questions,  just 
begins  to  tell  the  Pan  Am  story. 

In  1961,  the  President's  Task  Force  on  National  Aviation  Goals  noted: 

"Continued  U.S.  preeminence  in  international  air  transport  is  unquestionably 
in  the  national  interest.  Our  extensive  economic  and  political  interests  abroad 
require  the  special  advantages  which  economical  and  technically  sound  air 
air  transportation  provides. 

"A  second  reason  for  maintaining  an  aggressive  and  expanding  international 
air  transport  system  is  its  present  and  prospective  national  security  value  in 
terms  of  auxiliary  military  airlift  capability  and  political  contact  with  foreign 
countries. 

"For  these  reasons,  the  decline  of  U.S. -flag  carrier  participation  in  the  world 
air  travel  market — particularly  significant  and  worrisome  across  the  North 
Atlantic — deserves  the  most  concentrated  attention  of  the  Government  and  the 
most  aflirmative  effort  of  our  airlines." 

The  need  for  U.S.  preeminence  still  persists.  Pan  Am's  presence  as  a  United 
States  aviation  symbol  around  the  world  is  still  vital. 

"We  feel  that  in  the  last  years  some  greater  understanding  of  the  problem  has 
manifested  itself  in  affirmative  action.  The  Congress  has  acted  wisely  to  correct 
foreign  restrictive  and  discriminatory  practice.^.  The  Administration  has  pro- 
posed action  to  balance  the  competitive  opportunity  of  Pan  Am  and  TWA  with 
foreign-flag  airlines.  The  CAR  has  appeared  constructively  the  self-help  meas- 
ures developed  to  redress  some  of  the  imbalance  resultant  from  unsound 
competition. 

We  know  that  this  subcommittee,  to  the  extent  that  it  can.  will  recommend 
further  corrective  action. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  want  to  welcome  the  members  of  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board.  I  am  pleased  to  see  Chairman  O'Melia  afjain,  and  I  am 
happy  to  welcome  members  Minetti  and  West,  here  for  the  first  time 
before  us.  Mr.  O'Melia  will  present  a  statement.  I  would  welcome  com- 
ments from  other  meml:>ers  after  the  statement,  or  in  response  to  ques- 
tions. Chairman  O'Melia,  would  you  please  present  your  testimony. 

STATEMENTS  OE  RICHARD  J.  O'MELIA,  ACTING  CHAIRMAN,  CIVIL 
AERONAUTICS  BOARD;  G.  JOSEPH  MINETTI,  MEMBER,  CAB;  AND 
LEE  R.  WEST,  MEMBER,  CAB;  ACCOMPANIED  BY  FREDERIC  D. 
HOUGHTLING,  ASSISTANT  TO  MEMBER  MINETTI;  WILLIAM  B. 
CALDWELL,  JR.,  DIRECTOR,  BUREAU  OE  OPERATING  RIGHTS, 
CAB;  ARTHUR  H.  SIMMS,  ACTING  DEPUTY  DIRECTOR,  BUREAU 
OF  ECONOMICS,  CAB;  AND  STEVEN  J.  GROSS,  ASSOCIATE  GENERAL 
COUNSEL,  CAB 

Mr.  O'Melta.  First  I  would  like  to  introduce  on  my  left  Judge  West, 
member  of  the  CAB ;  Mr.  Minetti  of  the  CAB,  and  Mr.  Houghtling, 
Mr.  Minetti's  assistant.  On  my  right,  :Mr.  Caldwell,  head  of  the  Bureau 
of  Operating  Rights,  and  next  to  liim  Mr.  Simms,  acting  deputy  di- 
rector. Bureau  of  Economics,  and  Mr.  Gross,  acting  general  counsel, 
who  is  in  place  of  Mr.  Tom  Ueye  whose  good  friend  and  .<i-ood  friend 
of  ours  died  tragically  over  the  weekend.  We  are  deeply  sad  that  Mr. 
Gingery  died. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  want  to  indicate  at  this  point  we  are  very  much 
saddened  as  well.  We  understand  he  was  going  to  be  of  some  help  to 


647 

the  subcommittee.  "VVe  understand  that  he  was  a  very  highly  regarded 
and  distinguished  public  servant  on  the  Board.  Although  I  have  never 
had  the  opportunity  to  meet  him,  from  what  I  have  known  he  has  a 
reputation  of  dedicated  public  service  to  the  Board,  many  years  of 
public  service,  and  we  extend  our  sentiments  to  the  members  of  the 
family,  both  on  the  record  and  obviously  in  a  personal  sense  as  well. 
1  can  understand  the  sense  of  loss  that  the  members  of  the  Board  and 
the  people  who  knew  him  and  worked  with  him  must  feel.  I  appreciate 
your  mentioning  it. 

[Mr.  William  Gingery,  Director,  Bureau  of  Enforcement,  CAB,  was 
scheduled  to  testify  before  the  subcommittee  this  day.  He  committed 
suicide  during  the  night  preceding  this  hearing.  These  matters  are 
discussed  further  in  the  hearing  before  this  subcommittee  on  March  21, 
1975.  See,  especially,  pp.  2300-03,  below.] 

OVERALL  CAB  POLICY  OX   EXTRY  IXTO  IXDUSTRY  AND  ROUTES   SINCE   1938 

Mr.  O'^SIelia,  Thank  you,  Senator. 

I  have  a  summarized  statement  that  I  have  submitted  to  the  sub- 
committee and  I  will  briefly  highlight  some  of  the  points. 

A  reading  of  the  Board's  major  route  decisions  will  show  that  the 
Board's  overall  route  policy  since  1938  has  had  two  distinct  but  related 
goals :  first,  to  expand  the  number  of  markets  in  which  air  service  is 
provided ;  and  second,  to  promote  the  expansion  of  competition  among 
air  carriers.  In  general,  the  expansion  of  competition  in  an  expanding 
market  has  been  a  primary  underpinning  of  the  Board's  route  policy 
since  1938.  It  has  long  been  recognized  that  the  competitive  environ- 
ment that  exists  in  our  aviation  industry  has  been  responsible  for  the 
development  of  the  high  level  and  quality  of  service  enjoyed  by  the 
traveling  public  in  this  country,  which  service  constitutes  the  most 
extensive,  convenient,  efficient  and  least  costly  air  transport  system 
anywhere  in  the  world.  A  very  important  secondary  result  of  the 
Board's  competitive  route  awards  has  been  the  expansion  of  first  air 
service  opportunities  to  many  city-pair  markets  as  a  result  of  the  tack- 
m<r  on  of  vpv:  points  ^o  th^  existing  system  of  a  successful  applicant. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Would  you  just  hold.  We  want  to  welcome  Sen- 
ator Thurmond  who  is  an  active  member  of  this  subcommittee.  Of 
course,  we  are  delighted  to  have  him  here.  We  have  the  members  of 
the  Board  here,  the  Chairman,  Mr.  O'Melia,  making  his  presentation. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Since  the  midsixties,  the  Board  has  been  permitting 
the  local  service  carriers  to  enter  markets  served  by  trunkline  car- 
riers. The  result  is  that  in  a  very  real  sense  man}^  of  these  carriers 
have  evolved  into  small  trunkline  carriers.  The  expansion  of  local 
service  carriers  accomplished  several  important  objectives.  By 
strengthening  the  carriers'  route  systems  the  Board  accelerated  the 
time  when  Government  subsidy  may  no  longer  be  required.  And,  by 
increasing  market  opportunities,  the  regional  carriers  were  enabled 
to  modernize  their  fleets  and  enjoy  other  technological  improvements. 

As  you  know,  Mr.  Chairman,  tlie  Board's  route  award  policies  were 
not  limited  to  the  tnmk  and  local-service  carriers.  In  addition,  var- 
ious specialist  carriers  were  authorized  to  provide  service  in  com- 
petition with  trunkline  carriers.  These  include  all -cargo  specialists 
that  compete  ior  cargo  over  routes  served  by  the  trunks'  the  supple- 


648 

mental  carriers  that  compete  for  charter  traffic  with  the  trunks ;  var- 
ious Alaskan  and  Hawaiian  operators;  and  certificated  helicopter 
carriers.  A  new  trunkline  carrier,  Trans  Caribbean  Airways  (now 
merged  with  American)  was  awarded  a  certificate,  and  certificates 
authorizing  service  over  limited  routes  were  awarded  to  Aspen  Air- 
ways and  Wright  Airlines.  In  addition,  in  the  midfifties  the  Board 
authorized  26  supplementals  to  provide  individually  ticketed  service 
in  competition  with  the  trunks.  I  would  also  note  that  in  July  1974 
the  Board  established  in  the  New  England  service  investigation  a 
new  regional  airline,  Air  New  England,  to  provide  service  between 
New  York  and  Boston  and  at  least  12  other  New  England  points. 

REASONS  FOR  LACK  OF  CERTIFICATIOX  OF  NEW  ENTRANTS  INTO  INDUSTRY 

One  of  the  issues  that  concerns  this  subcommittee,  the  administra- 
tion, and  a  broad  segment  of  the  public  is  how  the  Board  views  com- 
petitive service.  There  is  no  question  that  in  its  history  of  route 
awards  the  Board  has  affirmed  its  recognition  of  the  merits  that  can 
flow,  in  appropriate  situations,  from  competitive  service. 

If  it  has  determined  that  competitive  authority  is  required  to  im- 
prove the  efficiency  and  quality  of  the  service,  an  equally  difficult  task 
for  the  Board  is  that  of  carrier  selection.  Carrier  selection  criteria 
include  the  question  of  which  carrier  can  provide  the  most  service 
bentfits  to  passengers  in  the  particular  city-pair  market  under  ex- 
amination as  well  as  in  beyond-area  markets;  the  need  for  carrier 
strengthening,  which  includes  an  examination  of  individual  carrier 
profitability  over  the  proposed  route;  the  degree  of  historic  identity 
in  the  market  in  issue ;  the  extent  of  diversion  from  the  incumbent, 
which  varies  by  individual  applicant,  depending  upon  its  route 
structure. 

Thus,  in  any  case  involving  a  choice  between  an  existing  carrier 
and  a  would-be  entrant,  the  existing  carrier  can  virtually  always  show 
that  it  will  be  able  to  provide  substantial  public  benefits  in  the  form 
of  through  service  to  numerous  points,  in  addition  to  those  at  issue 
in  the  proceeding,  whereas  the  new  entrant  cannot  make  such  a  show- 
ing. In  view  of  this  and  in  light  of  the  capital  outlay  required  to 
serve  a  scheduled  route,  it  is  not  surprising  that  applications  by  new 
entrants  into  the  trunkline  field  have  been  relatively  few.  The  degree 
of  competitive  expansion  authorized  by  the  Board  has  varied  from 
time  to  time  depending  upon  the  state  of  the  general  economy  and 
the  airline  industry. 

"route    moratorium"    1969-74 

This  practice  of  the  Board  has  been  subject  to  severe  criticism,  to 
the  point  that  it  has  been  characterized  by  its  critics  as  a  "route 
moratorium."  I  think  you  will  find,  Mr.  Chairman,  if  you  examine 
the  Board's  decisions,  and  the  public  remarks  made  by  Board  mem- 
bers and  by  its  senior  staff  officials,  that  this  characterization  does 
not  truly  reflect  the  Board's  policy.  On  the  contrary,  the  Board  is 
keenly  aware  of  its  statuatory  mandate  to  be  responsive  to  route  ap- 
plications and  to  act  upon  them  as  speedily  as  possible  in  keeping 
with  the  circumstances  of  each  such  application  and  with  the  judg- 
mental decisions,  with  which  it  is  also  entrusted. 


649 

Senator  Kennedy.  On  that  point,  Mr.  O'Melia,  how  can  you  say 
there  has  been  no  route  moratorium?  How  many  competitive  route 
applications  were  actually  set  for  hearings  in  1973  or  1974? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Well,  there  are  several  points  I  would  like  to  make. 
During  the  sixties,  as  you  heard  this  morning,  there  were  a  lot  of 
route  cases.  In  early  1970  there  was  a  downturn  in  the  economy.  The 
cases  that  came  before  the  Board  were  very  few.  There  was  no  Board 
policy  stating  that  there  was  to  be  a  moratorium.  In  1973  we  experi- 
enced the  fuel  shortage  from  the  fall  of  1973  until  the  summer  of 
1974  the  carriers  were  trying  to  find  fuel,  not  trying  to  find  new  routes 
to  operate. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Were  there  applications  during  this  period  of 
time? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  am  not  sure.  There  probably  were.  Normally  there 
are  aWit  a  thousand  docketed  cases  a  year  of  which  300  or  400  of 
them  are  route  cases.  Of  those  I  am  not  sure  how  many  are  normally 
filed  for  expedited  consideration,  which  would  then  bring  them 
before  the  Board. 

Senator  Kennedy.  As  I  understand  it,  even  though  there  were  no 
hearings  that  were  set  during  this  period  of  time,  and  even  though 
you  have  claimed  there  was  no  moratorium,  the  staff  study  itself  opens 
by  saying  that  since  approximately  1970,  the  cases  involving  new 
domestic  route  authority  were  generally  not  being  set  for  hearing. 
[Bureau  of  Operatino;  Rio:hts,  CAB.  the  Domestic  Route  System, 
foreward  at  i-ii  (Oct.  1974).]  How  else  would  you  characterize  the 
policy  of  the  CAB?  Isn't  that  really  a  moratorium— are  we  just 
fencing  on  words  here  ? 

CAB    WILL    BE    INCLINED    TO    HEAR    ROUTE    ENTRY    APPLICATIONS    IN    THE 

FUTURE 

Mr.  O'Melia.  As  one  Board  member,  let  me  give  you  as  straight  an 
answer  as  I  can,  Senator.  During  my  hearings  before  Senator  Can- 
non when  consideration  was  being  given  to  my  nomination  as  a  mem- 
ber of  the  Board.  I  answered  the  question  of  the  route  moratorium 
two  or  three  times.  I  said  I  was  not  in  favor  of  a  moratorium,  that 
I  felt  that  if  cases  are  filed,  and  if  the  applicants  ask  for  expeditious 
hearing,  that  they  should  be  heard.  Now  this  is  in  the  record  of  those 
two  hearing. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  your  view? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  That  is  my  view.  In  fact,  as  far  as  I  am  concerned, 
there  is  no  route  moratorium  as  of  now. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let  me  just  say,  I  think  that  is  a  very  positive 
statement. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Thank  you.  Senator. 

Now,  this  probablv  has"^not  been  read  but  Board  order  75-2-33  came 
out  February  7,  1975,  Eastern  airlines  exemptions,  dockets  24626  and 
27075.  Let  me  read  just  two  sentences: 

During  the  past  few  years  the  Board  has  acted  with  caution  in  setting  for 
hearing  certificate  amendment  applications,  where  it  appeared  that  granting 
the  application  would  increase  or  intensify  competition  among  the  domestic 
air  carriers.  This  course  has  been  occasioned  by  depressed  economc  conditions 
in  air  transportation  following  a  period  of  rapid  expansion,  and  more  recently 
by  scarcity  of  fuel.  It  has  also  to  some  extent  been  influenced  by  unusual  de- 


650 

mands  on  the  time  of  the  Board's  staff  in  fare  and  rate  matters,  for  example, 
the  recently  completed  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation.  Undoubtedly  this 
course  can  be  expected  to  change  as  the  relevant  circumstances  change,  and 
it  goes  without  saying  that  the  Board  has  a  continuing  duty  to  address  those 
situations  where  it  becomes  apparent  that  there  are  legitimate  needs  for 
additional  and  improved  air  service  which  are  not  being  met. 

Now,  that  is  a  five  to  nothing  vote  by  the  Board  on  the  7th  of 
February, 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  reviewed  with  the  earlier  witnesses  the  pro- 
visions of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  as  well  as  the  Administrative 
Procedures  Act,  which  would  appear  to  require  at  least  a  timely  dis- 
position of  matters  which  are  brought  before  the  respective  agencies. 
Then  we  heard  from  some  of  the  witnesses,  who  characterized  the 
inaction  during  this  period  of  time  as  being  a  moratorium,  for 
whatever  reasons. 

Do  I  understand  your  testimony  now,  that  you  believe  that  any 
applications  that  come  through  to  the  Board  are  going  to  at  least 
get  a  timely  disposition,  and  that  at  least  there  will  be  the  possibility 
of  hearings  before  the  Board  on  those  that  meet  certain  criteria  ?  The 
problem  is  we  don't  knoAv  what  those  criteria  are,  as  I  understand  it. 
You  can  correct  me  at  any  time.  It  is  awfully  difficult,  I  would  think, 
for  any  applicant  to  really  know  whether  they  will  get  a  hearing  or 
not  because  they  don't  know  what  the  criteria  are.  The  criterion  of 
public  interest  is  sufficiently  vao-ue,  I  would  think,  to  permit  what  I 
think  fair-minded  people  would  feel  is  simply  a  policy  of  nonhearing 
by  the  Board. 

We  are  interested,  as  I  am  sure  you  are,  in  having  the  Board  be 
responsive  to  these  legitimate  requests.  I  am  interested  in  the  extent 
you  feel  you  can  make  any  kind  of  a  statement  which  would  indicate 
what  the  Board's  policy  is?  I  might  ask  the  other  members  of  the 
Board  what  they  feel  to  be  the  policy  of  hearing  those  cases  that 
were  set  for  hearing  some  time  ago,  but  have  never  been  heard :  for 
example,  the  Ohio/Indiana  ponstop  investi^i-ation;  the  Spokane- 
Montana  points  investigation;  the  Louisville- Washinfrton/Baltimore 
service  investigation,  and  there  are  others.  What  kind  of  assurance 
can  you  give  us  as  to  when  these  cases  will  be  heard?  What  is  the 
Board's  attitude  with  rearard  to  these  cases  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  First,  before  I  turn  your  question  over  to  the  other 
members,  let  me  say  that  the  standards  for  determining  priority  of 
hearings  are  in  section  899.60  of  the  regulations.  I  won't  go  over 
them,  but  they  are  the  standards  that  the  carriers  need  to  measure 
up  to  in  their  annlication  where  thev  want  prio^-itv  of  hearin^^. 

[The  regulation  referred  to,  14  CFR  sec.  399.60  (1974),  follows:] 

§  399.60     Standards  for  determining:  priorities  of  hearing:. 

(a)  General.  This  policy  statement  describes  the  general  stnu'^arris  whi>h  "-'"ll 
be  used  by  the  Board  in  determining  the  order  in  which  it  will  designate  for 
hearing  those  matters  on  its  docket  which  are  to  be  decided  after  notice  and 
hearing.  Among  such  matters  are  applications  for  certificates  of  public  con- 
venience and  necessity  or  for  foreign  air  carrier  permits ;  applications  under 
section  408  of  the  Act  for  approval  of  consolidations  or  acquisitions  of  control ; 
complaint  cases  ;  and  various  ratemaking  proceedings. 

(b)  Standards.  Matters  will  be  assigned  for  hearing  in  accordance  with  the 
degree  of  relative  priority  which  each  matter  is  entitled  to  on  the  basis  of  the 
comparative  public  interest  involved  therein.  Among  other  things,  the  Board 
will  take  into  account : 


651 

(1)  statutory  requirements  for  preference  or  statutory  limitations  on  the 
time  witliin  which  the  Board  shall  act ; 

(2)  The  impact  of  delay  on  the  public  or  particular  persons; 

(3)  The  need  for  promptly  securing  compliance  with  the  provisions  of  the 
Act  ■ 

(4)  The  time  for  which  the  matter  has  already  been  pending  and  which  would 
be  required  to  dispose  of  it ; 

(5)  Whether  the  application  requests  renewal  of  an  existing  temporary  au- 
thorization ;  and 

(6)  In  matters  relating  to  operating  authority — 

(i)  Whether  a  proposal  might  reduce  subsidy  or  increase  economy  of 
operations ; 

(ii)  Whether  an  application  proposes  new  service  ; 

(iii)  The  volume  of  traffic  that  might  be  affected  by  the  grant  or  denial  of 
the  proposal ; 

(iv)  The  period  that  has  elapsed  since  the  Board  considered  the  service  needs 
of  the  places  or  areas  involved  ;  and 

(v)  The  relative  availability  of  necessary  staff  members  of  the  carriers,  com- 
munities and  the  Board,  in  the  light  of  other  proceedings  already  in  progress, 
to  handle  the  processing  of  the  case. 

Interested  persons  may  urge  upon  the  Board  such  considerations  as  they  believe 
should  lead  it  to  accord  a  particular  application  a  priority  different  from  that 
which  the  Board  has  given  it. 

As  I  said,  I  can  speak  only  for  myself,  but  as  one  Board  member, 
I  have  given  yoii  my  opinion.  Now,  if  you  want  to  ask  the  other 
Board  members  the  same  question,  go  ahead. 

LEGALITY  OF  THE  "rOUTE  MORATORIUM" 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  are  aware,  before  we  leave,  Mr.  Chairman, 
that  there  is  a  substantial  body  of  lawyers  who  feel  that  CAB  orders 
have  been  at  some  variance  with  what  is  in  the  regulations 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  think  you  are  referring  to  section  399.60. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Section  401  [of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of 
1958,  72  Stat.  754,  49  USC  §  1371]  and  the  regulations  thereunder. 

Let's  hear  other  points. 

Mr.  Minetti.  I  have  prepared  some  comments  here  on  the  question 
on  the  legality  of  a  route  moratorium. 

I  do  not  believe  the  Board  could  simply  announce  it  was  not  going 
to  hear  any  more  new  route  applications  either  for  a  period  of  years 
or  an  indefinite  time.  If  the  Board  had  ever  announced  such  a  policy 
I  would  certainly  have  dissented.  I  think  section  401  of  the  act  clearly 
contemplates  that  route  applications  are  to  be  set  for  hearing,  that 
they  are  to  be  granted  if  the  Board  finds  after  notice  and  hearing  that 
the  public  convenience  and  need  so  requires ;  otherwise,  they  are  to  be 
denied. 

At  the  same  time,  I  think  the  Board  has  to  have  control  over  the 
order  in  which  applications  are  heard.  If  we  heard  them  in  strict 
order  of  filing  most  of  our  time  might  easily  be  spent  hearing  appli- 
cations which   promise  very  little  benefit  to  the  traveling  public. 


652 

Applications  for  service  critically  and  uro;ently  needed  by  the  travel- 
ing public  might  take  many  years  in  coming  to  the  top  of  the  list. 

I  recall,  for  instance,  that  soon  after  the  first  successful  moon  shot 
one  major  carrier  got  publicity  by  filing  an  application  with  the 
Board  for  a  route  to  the  moon.  Now  should  the  Board  have  set  that 
application  for  hearing  ? 

It  is  my  understanding  that  the  Board  at  first  tried  to  hear  appli- 
cations in  order  of  filing,  and  the  result  was  that  certain  carriers 
flooded  the  docket  with  applications  for  every  new  route  they  hoped 
to  acquire  in  the  next  10  years. 

So  we  have  to  have  some  preliminar}^  method,  before  actually  set- 
ting an  application  for  hearing,  of  deciding  where  it  ought  to  go  in  a 
rational  order  of  priorities,  based  on  the  factoi-s  of  the  public  interest 
and  not  simply  when  it  was  filed. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  do  not  think  there  is  any  dispute  whatsoever 
about  what  you  mentioned  concerning  setting  the  order  of  agenda. 
I  do  not  think  any  of  us  could  possibly  dispute  that  you 
have  the  responsibility  and  authority  to  work  that  kind  of  will, 
but  that  is  not  what  we  are  talking  about.  We  are  talking  about  the 
fact  there  were  not  any  hearings,  not  the  question  of  whether  you  have 
the  authority  and  responsibility  to  set  them  in  a  particular  order. 

Mr.  MixETTi.  As  you  know,'^Senator,  I  did  dissent  in  many,  many 
cases  in  which  the  Board  refused  to  set  cases  for  hearing. 

Senator  Kennedy.  As  much  as  you  may  or  may  not  be  interested  in 
the  merits  of  a  particular  situation,  that  is  out  of  our  particular  area 
of  interest.  What  we  are  interested  in  is  what  I  think  has  been  charac- 
terized as  a  moratorium.  Different  words  have  been  used.  We  are 
interested  in  the  substance  of  the  situation  :  that  no  hearings  were  held. 
What  we  are  trying  to  find  out — and  I  would  be  interested  in  what- 
ever comments  you  make  on  the  rationale  from  the  legal  and  policy 
point  of  view — is  what  you  are  going  to  do  in  the  future.  I  am  inter- 
ested in  what  happened  in  the  past  and  reasons  for  it,  but  I  am  most 
interested  in  what  the  attitude  will  be  now. 

Mr.  O'Melia  has  very  constructively  commented  that  he  believes 
there  should  be  a  timely  hearing  in  those  matters. 

Mr.  MiNETTi.  That  is  what  I  am  interested  in,  too. 

HISTORY  OF  CAB  DE^-ELOPMENT  OF  THE  "rOUTE  MORATORHrM" 

Senator  Kennedy.  Perhaps  you  could  develop,  since  you  were  on 
the  board  from  the  beginning  of  the  moratorium,  or  whatever  word 
you  want  to  use 

Mr.  MiNNETTi.  The  phrase  route  moratorium  came  up  in  1969  after 
the  Board  had  decided  a  number  of  cases.  I  think  at  that  time  some  of 
the  carriers  came  in  and  suggested  to  the  Board  that  we  have  a  route 
moratorium  to  "-ive  them  an  opportunity  to  digest  the  new  routes  they 
had  received.  This  was  not  shared  by  all  the  carriere,  but  some  of  them 
felt  we  should  have  a  route  moratorium.  That  is  how  the  phrase  route 
moratorium  came  up. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  did  you  respond  to  some  of  the  applicants 
who  pointed  out  that  under  the  various  legislation  there  was  a  re- 
sponsibility by  the  Board  for  timely  consideration  of  the  various  route 
applications?' When  someone  raised  that  point  to  you  how  did  you 
respond  to  that? 


653 

Mr.  MiXETTi.  Well,  as  I  said  in  one  dissent.  Senator,  several  years 
ago.  I  have  no  problem  with  a  policy  of  caution  in  setting  down  "route 
cases  during  time  of  financial  difficulty.  What  I  disagree  with  is  carry- 
ing the  policy  of  caution  to  the  extreme  of  refusing  to  hear  any  route 
cases.  I  still  tJiinic  hearing  no  such  cases  at  all  is  inconsistent  with  the 
mandate  of  the  statute. 

Senator  Ivexxedy.  Could  you  tell  us  just  a  little  bit  about  the  meet- 
ing that  you  had  with  the  carriers,  in  which  it  was  suggested  that  there 
be  a  moratorium?  Was  that  an  open  hearing  or  were  there  any  notes 
kept  on  that  ? 

Mr.  MixETTi.  I  do  not  know  whether  there  were  any  notes  kept  on 
that  one. 

Senator  Kexxedy.  You  can  see  the  point — I  think  it  was  suggested 
that  the  major  carriers  get  new  routes  and,  in  order  to  solidify  their 
positions,  that  there  be  a  moratorium.  They  used  those  words.  Sub- 
sequenth".  there  was  in  effect  a  moratorium,  and  I  suppose  what  we  are 
interested  in  is  how  that  policy  was  made.  Was  it  made  openly,  if  it 
was,  Jiow  v.as  i^  cojisnlerecl.  and  who  said  what,  and  what  other  inter- 
ests were  considered? 

Sh:  Mixi-Tii.  \\  ell.  I  think  that  just  developed  as  cases  came  before 
the  Board.  The  Board  stated  the  position  was  that  there  was  a  policy 
of  caution. 

Senator  Kexxedy.  It  does  not  appear  that  every  time  it  came  up  the 
merits  of  the  particular  case  just  happened  to  be  consistent  with  the 
policy  of  caution  during  that  period  of  time.  That  is  not  quite  what 
you  said  earlier.  As  i  understand  what  you  said  in  response  to  an 
earlier  question,  a  number  of  the  major  carriers  came  to  members  of 
the  Board  and  indicated  they  needed  some  time  to  solidify  their  posi- 
tion. There  was  no  announced  policy,  but  at  least  an  implied  one.  that 
there  were  not  going  to  be  any  more  new  routes  granted.  I  do  not  want 
to  put  words  in  your  mouth,  but  it  seems  that  is  really  the  sequence  of 
events. 

What  our  subcommittee  is  interested  in  is  what  are  the  procedures 
developed  resulting  in  some  major  policy  considerations.  Could  you 
give  me  your  view  on  this  point,  Mr.  West  ?  What  I  am  interested  in 
is  moving  from  the  current  situation:  Where  we  are  going  in  the 
future. 

Mr.  West.  I  gave  Senator  Stevenson  the  same  comment  out  in 
Peoria.  I  had  no  part,  since  I  am  newly  on  the  Board,  in  the  develop- 
ment of  route  moratorium,  philosophy,  of  course.  I  am  not  in  favor  of 
it.  I  do  not  feel  inclined  to  defend  it. 

I  am  in  favor,  and  have  so  recommended  to  the  Board,  that  we  do 
conduct  hearings  in  regard  to  applications.  Xow.  there  has  to  be  some 
priority  considerations  and  I  think  you  recognize  that.  I  think  the 
Board  is  evolving  a  policy  of  trying  to  determine  those  and  pass  on 
them  at  the  Board  level  rather  than  all  together  at  the  staff  level,  and 
I  am  active  in  the  effort  and  will  be  in  the  future. 

I  do  not  think  there  is  an  official  moratorium.  I  think  that  was  a 
majority  philosophy  at  the  time. 

I  do  not  question  the  motives  of  the  members  involved  in  that  so- 
called  philosophy.  I  just  do  not  agree  with  it. 

Senator  Kexxedy.  I  suppose  the  point  is  in  that  reaching  a  poUcy 
of  this  importance  and  magnitude,  informal  discussions,  whether  they 


654 

are  right  or  wrong,  will  certainly  impact  major  industries  of  this 
country.  It  seems  to  me  that  there  should  be  at  least  some  kind  of  a 
proceeding  or  hearing  in  which  various  interested  groups  are  able  to 
participate.  As  I  understand  it,  there  was  at  least  some  kind  of 
informal  understanding.  It  is  not  clear  how  the  understanding  was 
reached.  Mr.  Minnetti  has  indicated  some  of  those  who  have  been 
awarded  the  routes  after  being  in  touch  with  Board  members.  There 
appears  to  have  been  some  understanding  within  the  Board  that  this 
was  going  to  be  the  policy,  and  then  it  was  strengthened  in  the  refusal 
to  have  any  hearings,  in  the  way  that  applications  were  disposed  of 
before  the  Board,  and  I  suppose  our  question  is  really  whether  this  is 
the  best  and  most  effective  way  of  implementing  a  policy. 

Mr.  West.  I  think  not,  Senator.  I  think  Mr.  Minetti  has  been  most 
interested  and  most  active  in  attempting  to  articulate  some  standards 
by  which  we  can  determine  which  cases  should  come  up  for  hearing  and 
which  should  not  be  passed  on.  From  my  personal  knowledge,  I  know 
he  is  very  active  in  that  area. 

CAB  STAFF  STUDY  ON  ROUTE  EXTRY,  THE  DOIHESTIC  ROUTE  SYSTEM  (197  4) 

I  think  we  are  also  susceptible  to  the  charge  that  we  conduct  our 
business  in  a  way  that  no  one  knows  what  factors  we  take  into  consid- 
eration. Judge  Friendly  has  been  complaining  about  this  for  years  and 
years.  I  think  that  out  of  the  route  study— and  I  think  we  have  to  be 
very  careful  not  to  make  this  too  restrictive— but  we  have  to  develop 
standards  that  can  not  only  be  determined  within  our  staff  and  passed 
on  to  the  Board,  but  provide  a  basis  for  judicial  review  of  our  failures. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  that  would  be  helpful.  I  would  like  to 
finish  this  point  and  then  yield  to  Senator  Thurmond. 

We  usually  follow  a  rough  rule  of  about  15  minutes  or  so.  Senator 
Thurmond  has  been  here  and  I  would  like  for  him  to  cover  additional 
areas.  The  principal  point  concerns  the  criteria  that  has  been  outlined 
by  the  staff  report.  It  is,  I  would  think,  a  fair  characterization  to  say 
that  they  are  extremely  restrictive. 

Mr.  West.  That  is  not  a  Board  release.  That  was  a  staff  release,  and 
I  think  you  will  recognize  that  I  have  to  be  extremely  careful  in  com- 
menting with  regard  to  that  because  that  is  a  matter  out  for  comment 
pending  before  the  Board  which  we  will  pass  on  in  the  future.  I  am 
aware  of  a  number  of  criticisms  of  the  staff  release. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  all  of  us  are  familiar  enough  with  various 
reports  are  prepared  at  that  level.  They  do  not  necessarily  represent 
the  view  of  the  Board,  and  we  do  not  want  to  view  them  as  a  character- 
ization of  the  attitude  of  the  members  of  the  Board  if  they  are  not. 
I  would  like  to  yield. 

first-class  service  and  the  need  for  LOW-FARE  TRANSPORTATION 

Senator  Thurmond.  Thank  you.  I  will  ask  a  few  questions  and  then 
turn  back.  Mr.  O'^Ielia,  in  view  of  the  time  required  and  the  appropria- 
tion limitations  of  CAB,  would  you  recommend  that  the  CAB  no 
longer  have  authority  to  assign  new  routes?  Could  your  resources  be 
more  effectively  used  if 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Senator,  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  would  have  to  be 
amended  to  allow  the  Board  to  have  freer  entry  into  the  industry  by 


655 

other  carriers.  The  present  policy  of  entry  is  in  fact  set  forth  in  section 
401  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act. 

Senator  Thurmond.  Whatever  is  necessary  to  give  the  public  better 
rates,  because  air  travel  now  is  a  mass  form  of  travel,  of  course,  as  you 
know,  and  that  should  be  encouraged  over  automobiles.  I  live  about 
9  hours  from  Washington  down  in  South  Carolina,  and  it  costs,  if  I 
take  my  family,  four  or  five  people  at  $45  apiece  and  maybe  a  little 
more,  you  can  see  what  it  costs.  With  an  automobile  you  can  go  down 
there  a  lot  cheaper. 

Well,  now,  it  seems  to  me  for  the  average  family  there  ought  to  be 
some  way  a  man  could  travel  by  air  and  save  a  lot  of  money.  I  am  won- 
dering, too,  is  it  necessary  to  have  a  first-class  fare  now  ?  "Wliat  is  the 
purpose  in  having  a  fii-st-class  fare  ? 

Mr.  O'Mfxia.  Well,  there  are  a  lot  of  businessmen  who  I  presume 
want  to  travel  in  connection  with  this  business  and  cost  is  not  a  real 
obstacle,  so  they  go  first  class. 

Senator  Kexnedy.  It  is  not  the  real  object  because  the  taxpayers  are 
paying  for  it ;  they  are  subsidizing  first  class. 

Senator  Thurmond.  You  carry  very  few  people  on  the  plane.  If  you 
take  more  on  the  plane,  that  ought  to  reduce  the  cost  to  the  rest  of  the 
passengers,  should  it  not  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Let  me  have  our  rate  expert  answer  your  questions. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  In  the  recently  concluded  domestic  passenger  fare  inves- 
tigation, one  of  the  issues  concerned  the  lawfulness  of  first-class  fares. 
The  Board,  after  a  very  extensive  evidentiary  hearing,  concluded  that 
the  first-class  fares  have  historically  been  too  low,  that  they  have  bur- 
dened the  coach-fare  level.  In  other  words,  the  carriers  have  in  the  long 
run  lost  money  on  the  service  and  the  Board  as  a  consequence  directed 
that  the  first-class  fares  be  increased  in  stages  over  a  2-year  period  up 
to  the  level  of  the  full  costs. 

Now,  there  are  substantial  questions  as  to  the  extent,  as  to  whether 
first-class  service  will  continue  to  be  attractive  at  the  much  higher 
levels  that  will  be  in  effect  after  the  phase-in— the  complete  phase-m  is 
completed.  But  experience  with  fairly  high  differentials  in,  for  ex- 
ample, in  the  international  markets,  indicates  there  is  a  market  for  a 
first-class  service  at  verv  sizable  premiums. 

Senator  Thurmond.  *You  can  get  three  seats  to  the  row  if  you  have 
tourists  and  only  two  to  first  class. 

Mr.  Simms.  Yes. 

Senator  Thurmond.  xVnd  the  airline  would  make  more  money  ]f  it 
Avas  all  tourists,  would  it  not  ? 

]Mr.  SiMMS.  It  depends  upon  the  price  the  airline  gets  for  it.  In  the 
past  the  price  has  not  fully  reflected  the  cost  differential.  It  costs  more 
per  seat  if  vour  seat  is  larger.  . 

Senator  Thurihond.  I  will  give  you  my  illustration  of  going  to  Co- 
lumbia, S.C,  from  Washington.  It  costs  more,  about  $10  more,  to  travel 
first  class.  If  I  travel  fii-st  class,  two  seats  to  the  row,  it  will  be  double 
that  amount,  probably  $55,  two  of  us  $110,  whereas  if  you  have  three 
seats,  ^5,  that  is  $135  the  airline  will  get,  is  it  not  ? 

Mr.  Simms.  Yes. 

Senator  Thurmond.  And  were  your  first-class  passengers  not  costing 
the  public  more  to  travel  ? 

Mr.  Simms.  The  answer  to  that  is  at  the  present  time,  yes. 


656 

Senator  Thurmond.  Well,  then,  why  do  you  not  raise  them? 

Mr.  SiMMs.  We  have. 

Senator  Thurmond.  The  airlines  I  travel  on  still  have  first  class. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  The  Board  has  just  completed  its  investigation  and  the 
order  is  effective  April  29.  Beginning  April  29  the  first-class  fares  will 
be  higher. 

Senator  Thurmond.  I  travel  tourist  all  the  time.  I  see  a  lot  of  little 
government  employees  here  up  in  the  front  section  traveling  first  class. 
They  do  not  have  to  pay  it.  It  is  a  different  thing.  But  I  think  service 
ought  to  be  for  the  masses  of  the  people,  not  for  the  rich  and  not  for 
the  high  and  mighty,  but  to  give  the  lowest  rate  possible  to  serve  the 
people.  I  think  it  is  your  duty  to  provide  that. 

]Nir.  SiMMS.  Sir,  the  statute  quite  clearly  precludes  the  Board  from 
dictating  to  the  carriers  the  type  of  service  which  the  carriers  provide. 
In  other  words,  the  carriers  are  free  under  the  law  to  provide  a  first- 
class  service  if  they  wish,  and  there  is  no  way  the  Board  can  directly 
interfere  with  that  discretion. 

What  the  Board  can  do  and  has  done  is  ensure  that  the  carriers  make 
a  proper  charge  for  those  services  so  that  the  more  luxurious  service  is 
not  conducted  in  a  manner  which  burdens  the  mass  traveler. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Could  the  Senator  yield  just  on  that  point? 

Senator  Thurmond.  Yes ;  I  will  be  glad  to. 

Senator  Kennedy.  On  Senator  Thurmond's  point,  there  is  no  reason 
why  you  could  not  permit  World  Airways  to  provide  that  same  service 
on  a  given  route,  is  there  ? 

Mr.  SiMMS.  That  raises  a  whole  new,  quite  a  different  set  of  questions. 

Senator  Kennedy.  To  provide  what  Senator  Thurmond  so  elo- 
quently stated  here  this  morning,  you  cannot  require,  as  I  understand 
it,  that  an  airline  perform  a  certain  kind  of  service,  but  there  is  no 
reason  why  you  cannot  give  a  particular  carrier  authority  to  fly  a 
given  route  down  to  South  Carolina.  You  could  do  that,  could  you  not  ? 
If  some  carriers  were  to  take  out  all  the  first-class  seats,  if  some  of  them 
wanted  to  do  that  and  provide  service  at  lower  fares,  you  have  the 
poAver  to  do  that  ? 

Mr.  SiMMS.  We  have  the  power  to  certificate  a  carrier  who,  in  his 
application,  represents  that  he  Avill  provide  that  type  of  service,  yes. 

Senator  Thurmond.  And  not  only  that,  but  first-class  people  get  a 
little  better  meals  and  get  wine  with  their  meal,  and  who  is  paying  for 
that? 

Mr.  SiMMS.  Under  the  Board  order  all  of  those  costs  will  be  borne  by 
the  first-class  user. 

Senator  Thurmond.  For  an  hour  or  two,  even  up  to  5  hours,  is  it 
necessary  to  serve  meals?  Cannot  people  eat  before  they  f^et  on  the  plane 
and  eat  when  they  set  there?  Would  that  not  reduce  a  whole  lot  having 
all  tliose  meals  and  the  weight  of  those  meals,  and  the  service  of  those 
meals  requires  more  stewardes'-es  to  serve  those  mea^s  ^  T  <^'^ink  ve  l^nve 
to  in  this  country  recognize  that  people  want  the  safest  form  of  air 
travel  possible,  and  if  you  have  all  these  fringe  benefits  let  them  charter 
a  plane  or  go  some  other  way.  We  have  to  provide  for  the  masses  of 
people  the  most  economical  transportation  possible. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  I  think  the  Board.  Senator,  has  been  moving  in  various 
directions  to  meet  those  needs.  One  way  is  through  the  development 
of  charter  policies.  After  all,  charters  represent  the  most  efficient  form 


657 

of  transportation  possible,  because  the  cost  of  charter  service  does  not 
minimize  the  operation  of  empty  seats. 

FULL   FARES   FOR   CHILDREN   WHO    ARE   CARRIED 

Senator  Tpiurmond.  I  want  to  ask  you  another  question  that  affects 
me.  and  I  see  it  does  other  people  with  children.  Is  there  any  reason  why 
a  3-year-old  child  has  to  have  a  ticket  if  the  parents  hold  him  on 
their  lap  ? 

Mr.  SiMMs.  Senator,  the  airlines  have  historically  offered  free  trans- 
portation to  what  are  essentially  babies  in  arms,  persons 

Senator  Thurmond.  Do  the  airlines  do  it  or  does  the  CAB  require 
that  ? 

Mr.  SiMMS.  No;  the  airlines.  Under  the  tariffs  that  are  filed  by  the 
airlines  from  time  immemorial,  children  under  2  years  have  been 
carried  free  if  they  do  not  occupy  a  seat  of  their  own.  From  2  through 
12  there  is  a  discount  for  children.  The  Board  has  never  had  occasion 
to  consider  whether  the  2-year  cutoff  is  the  right  point  at  which  to  cut 
it  off.  The  matter  has  not  come  before  the  Board. 

Senator  Thurmond.  You  have  made  it  too  costly  for  me  to  travel 
with  these  young  babies  I  have  got.  I  do  not  see  why  a  3-year-old  child 
could  not  sit  in  the  parents  lap, 

]Mr.  SiMMS.  I  suppose  the  next  problem  will  be  what  about  the  31^- 
or  4-year-old.  You  have  to  draw  the  line  somewhere. 

Senator  Thurmond.  Well,  why  not  draw  it  up  to  3  instead  of  2,  just 
increasing  it  a  year?  Now,  Eastern  tells  me  they  would  not  object  if  I 
hold  this  little  fellow  on  my  lap,  but  they  say  that  CAB  requires  that. 

Mr.  SiMMS.  The  Federal  Aviation  Act  requires  that  Eastern  adhere 
to  its  tariff.  The  Federal  Aviation  Act  gives  Eastern  the  right  to  file 
any  tariff  it  pleases  and  the  Board  can  suspend  it  and  investigate  it  if 
the  Board  finds  it  is  unlawful.  I  am  not  aware  that  Eastern  has  filed  a 
tariff  to  authorize  it  to  carry  a  3-year-old  without  charge. 

Senator  Thurmond.  At  any  rate,  these  are  just  things  that  have  come 
to  my  attention  as  a  man  who  rides  the  airlines  every  week,  but  it  is 
getting  very  difficult.  I  will  have  to  drive  my  automobile  and  take  a 
lot  longer  time  rather  than  to  have  to  pay  for  all  these  children.  It 
seems  to  me  up  imtil  a  child  is  4  years  old  if  the  parent  is  holding  him 
in  his  lap  you  ought  to  make  some  arrangement — in  fact  you  ought 
to  be  encouraging  them  rather  than  riding  in  automobiles  where  they 
are  more  likely  to  get  killed.  I  do  not  want  to  take  much  time  on  this, 
Mr.  Chairman. 

NEW   ENTRY   INTO   THE   INDUSTRY 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you,  very  much.  Could  I  ask  you,  Mr. 
Chairman,  how  many  new  trunk  carriers  have  been  granted  certifica- 
tion since  1950  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Well,  I  listed  all  of  them  in  my  prepared  testimony, 
Senator. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  think  since  1950  there  have  not  been  any  new 
trun]v  carriers,  have  there  ? 

[In  answer  to  question  19  of  an  extensive  subcommittee  question- 
naire, directed  to  the  CAB  in  preparation  for  these  hearings,  the  CAB 
indicated  tliat  between  1950  and  1974,  94  applications  for  new  trunk- 
line  authority  (of  which  79  were  for  domestic  authority)  have  been 


658 

made  to  the  CAB,  and  none  had  been  granted.  The  CAB's  complete 
answer  is  reprinted  in  the  separately  bound  appendix  to  these 
hearings.] 

Mr.  O'Melia.  I  do  not  think  so,  Senator.  However,  some  of  the 
smaller  carriers  reached  the  statute  of  trunk  during  that  time. 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  reason  that  I  raise  this  point  is  that  it  raises 
serious  questions  about  the  original  intent  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Act.  When  the  Aviation  Act  was  being  considered  in  1938,  I  note, 
looking  through  the  legislative  history,  that  Senator  Truman  was  the 
floor  manager  of  the  bill.  Senator  King  of  Utah,  I  believe,  said  that 
he  was  concerned  to  know  just  how  far  the  bill  would  freeze  existing 
routes  and  corporations.  He  felt  that  if  it  would  exclude  others  who 
might  desire  to  enter  this  great  field,  that  there  should  be  some  amend- 
ments. Senator  Truman  assured  Senator  King  no  such  development 
was  likely  under  the  act  as  drafted.  Yet  we  have  seen  that  this  has 
not,  in  fact,  been  the  policy  of  the  Board — speaking  not  of  your  Board 
in  particular,  but  of  the  Board  over  the  period  of  its  past.  The  fact  is 
that  they  have  turned  down  some  94  applications  by  firms  outside  the 
industry.  I  am  wondering  whether  this  doesn't  create  at  least  a  pre- 
sumptive case  that  the  Board  doesn't  want  any  new  blood  in  the  in- 
dustry itself. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  On  the  contrary,  I  think  that  in  1938  there  were  just 
four  so-called  trunk  carriers.  Today,  if  you  will  look  at  some  of  the  air- 
taxi  operators  we  have  in  the  United  States,  they  are  bigger  than  the 
four  trunk  carriers  which  were  called  trunk  carriers  in  1938.  I  think 
the  Board  in  its  history  has  probably  moved  in  the  direction  of  creat- 
ing better  service  by  extending  the  routes  for  the  so-called  smaller 
carriers,  now  the  local  service  carriers  by  certificating  all  cargo 
carriers  and  by  authorizing  helicopter  carriers,  and  other  specialist 
types.  It  doesn't  mean  that  if  you  wanted  to  come  into  the  industry 
and  had  enough  money  to  try  for  a  401  certificate  under  the  Aviation 
Act,  that  you  would  be  precluded.  That  possibility  is  still  there.  Until 
that  is  changed  you  have  to  follow  the  law. 

Senator  Kennedy.  It  would  appear  by  the  way  the  statute  is 
drafted,  it  is  still  there,  but  as  a  practical  matter  it  doesn't  appear  to 
be. 

As  I  understand  it,  the  four  or  five  major  trunk  carriers  operating 
in  1938  have  just  about  the  same  percent  of  the  market  today  as  they 
had  in  1938,  except  for  American,  which  has  gone  from  28  to  15  per- 
cent. All  the  others  remained  just  about  the  saine.  Also,  in  1938  there 
were  16  trunk  carriers,  and  today  there  are  10.  What  is  the  reaction  of 
the  Board,  in  terms  of  any  new  carriers?  What  will  be  the  attitude  of 
the  Board  in  considering  any  requests  for  certification  ? 

INIr.  O'Melia.  Well,  any  carrier  that  applies  certainly  has  the  right 
to  be  heard.  In  my  testimony  I  try  to  point  out  that  a  new  carrier  who 
seeks  entry  is  at  a  great  disadvantage  against  an  existing,  competing 
carrier,  because  a  new  carrier  will  probably  only  apply  to  operate  be- 
tween points  a  and  b  and  probably  has  no  beyond  authority  and 
couldn't  compete  with  the  existing  carriers.  That  is  on  page  7  of  my 
prepared  testimony  that  I  didn't  go  into. 

Senator  Kennedy.  It  took,  actually,  an  act  of  Congress  to  get  the 
local  service  carriers  permanently  certificated,  did  it  not  ? 


659 

Mr.  O'Melia.  It  did. 

Senator  Kennedy.  In  1955.  And  still  we  have  no  new  trunk  carriers. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  That  is  right.  . 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  have  had  an  application.  We  heard  World 
Airways  indicate  what  they  were  prepared  to  do,  and  I  think  that 
ought  to  be  noted. 

CAB   willingness    TO   HEAR  FUTURE   ROUTE   CASES 

On  the  subject  of  the  route  moratorium,  we  heard  a  little  bit  earlier 
that  some  carriers  came  down  in  1969  and  proposed  a  moratorium,  and 
basically  this  policv  was  adopted  on  an  ad  hoc  case-by-case  basis,  al- 
though there  was  no  formal  comment  by  the  Board,  or  any  oppor- 
tunity for  challenge  to  that  idea.  Now  we  have  had  the  staff  domestic 
route  study,  and  again  it  hasn't  been  adopted  by  the  Board.  I  am  just 
wondering  whether  we  can  expect  that  the  Board  is  going  to  face  the 
situation  in  the  future  on  an  ad  hoc  case-by-case  adoption,  by  the  pro- 
posals in  this  study  or  whether  there  will  be  some  formal  procedure 
to  allow  for  public  input  and  challenges.  What  kind  of  assurances  can 
you  give  us  ? 

Mr.  O'jNIelia.  We  will  be  dealing  with  new  route  cases  on  an  ad  hoc 
basis  until  the  new  route  study  has  been  completed.  This  means  that 
with  the  input  from  all  sources,  we  will  decide  each  case  that  has 
requested  a  expeditious  hearing  as  it  comes  along.  This,  I  hope,  will 
work  up  to  the  time  that  the  route  study  is  completed.  The  study  has 
a  May  1,  deadline  for  comments  by  the  industry  and  by  airport  oper- 
ators and  carriers  and  whoever  wants  to  comment.  Once  those  com- 
ments are  in,  the  staff  study  will  be  considered  by  the  Board.  I  hope, 
down  the  road,  that  through  that  study  standards  will  be  set  out  as 
guidelines  to  give  the  Board  in  the  future  the  same  type  of  guidance 
that  the  domestic  passenger  fare  case  gave  it  as  far  as  fares  are  con- 
cerned. I  think  this  is  a  big  step  forward. 

I  understand  that  you  want  to  know  whether  there  would  be  public 
hearings.  I  think  that  the  public  can  certainly  be  heard  in  any  case 
before  the  Board. 

Senator  Kennedy.  When  will  that  be  resolved  as  far  as  the  Board 
is  concerned,  the  reactions  to  the  staff  study  ? 

Mr.  O'Melia.  We  extended  the  dates  for  comment  to  the  first  of 
I^Iay,  Senator,  so  that  we  would  get  good  constructive  comments.  Hope- 
fully from  these  hearings  also  we  would  benefit  by  the  results  of  study- 
ing the  views  expressed  at  these  hearings. 

Senator  Kennedy.  One  of  the  questions  that  was  raised  earlier  m 
defense  of  the  route  freeze  or  moratorium,  was  the  question  of  the  via- 
bility of  airline  profits.  I  would  imagine  that  with  the  increase  in 
profits  this  past  year,  that  if  this  has  been  a  consideration,  as  has  been 
suggested,  that  it  might  lead  you  to  give  some  additional  consideration 
to  the  possibility  of  additional  route  entries. 

:Mr.  O'Melia'.  I  am  not  sure  I  am  following  your  question.  Senator. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  believe  it  was  World  Airways  that  said  they 
had  applied  for  route  stractures  in  the  past  and  that  they  would  again 
if  they  thought  that  there  was  an  opportunity  for  a  return  which  made 
some  sense  financially,  and  if  there  Avere  some  likelihood  of  a  hearing. 


660 

I  gather  from  your  testimony  that  you  will  consider  giving  a  hearing 
to  any  legitimate  or  meritorious  carrier.  Given  the  increase  in  the 
profit  structure  over  the  past  year,  I  would  imagine  there  may  be  a 
number  of  applications  for  different  routes.  You  have  indicated  that 
you  would  consider  the  applications  as  they  came  along. 

I  think  you  did  indicate,  in  response  to  a  question  I  had  asked  you 
up  in  Boston  February  14th,  that  if  there  was  an  application  by  some 
carrier  that  wanted  to  provide  PSA  types  of  service  in  the  North- 
east you  would  at  least  be  willing  to  give  that  a  review. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  That  is  correct,  Senator. 

Senator,  I  forgot  in  my  opening  remarks  to  say  that  Mr.  Timm 
is  out  of  the  country  and  that  is  why  he  is  not  here  today.  Judge 
Gillilland  is  home  with  the  flu.  If  you  have  any  written  questions, 
they  will  be  happy  to  answer  them. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  would  like  to  submit  questions  to  the  members 
of  the  Board,  if  I  could,  on  price  and  entiy  policy,  which  is  covered  in 
your  testimony,  and  also  other  areas  as  well. 

Mr.  O'Melia.  Fine. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  West  or  Mr.  Minetti,  is  there  any  further 
comment  ? 

Mr.  West.  No. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  recess  and  reconvene  at  2:15  p.m. 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  O'Melia  follows.  See  also  the  ma- 
terials on  the  topic  of  certification  in  the  separately  bound  appendix  to 
these  hearings.] 

Prepared  Statemeint  of  Richard  J.  O'Melia,  Acting  Chairman, 
Civil    Aeronautics    Board 

cab's  route  policies 

Mr.  Chairman,  the  topic  your  subcommittee  is  examining  today  is  clearly  one  of 
the  major  facets  of  the  Board's  work.  My  testimony  will  cover  the  Board's  prac- 
tices and  policies  on  routes,  on  entry  into  the  air  transportation  system,  and  on 
the  decisional  factors  involved  in  route  awards. 

In  considering  at  the  Board  how  we  might  be  most  responsive  and  contribute 
usefully  to  the  purpose  of  these  hearings,  we  had  in  mind  your  remarks  last 
December  when  you  announced  the  convening  of  these  hearings.  We  have  also 
received  the  opinions  expressed  before  this  Committee  during  its  session  on  Feb- 
ruary 6  by  representatives  of  various  federal  entities  on  possible  approaches  to 
regulatory  reform  and  on  the  principal  Board  activities  that  could  be  usefully 
reexamined.  With  these  thoughts  in  mind,  I  would  like,  first  of  all,  to  present  a 
brief  description  of  the  statutory  framework  within  which  we  operate.  Then  I 
will  seek  to  set  forth  as  succinctly  as  I  can  where  we  stand  today  on  the  question 
of  route  authority  and  how  we  plan  to  ensure  that  our  route  practices  and  pro- 
cedures are  truly  responsive  to  the  public's  best  interests  in  air  transportation. 

By  enacting  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  in  1938— the  predecessor  to  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act  of  1958— Congress  determined  that  the  play  of  free  market  forces 
alone  was  not  sufficient  to  assure  the  long-term  stability  required  for  the  develop- 
ment of  a  sound  national  air  transportation  system.  As  a  result  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board  was  created  and  vested  by  Congress  with  extensive  powers  to 
regulate  the  air  carrier  competitive  environment.  Specifically,  the  Board  was 
granted,  among  other  things,  the  exclusive  power  to  control  entry  into  and  exit 
from  the  air  transportation  system.  v,     t>       .^i- 

A  reading  of  the  Board's  major  route  decisions  will  show  that  the  Board  s 
overall  route  policy  since  1938  has  had  two  distinct  but  related  goals :  first,  to 
expand  the  number  of  markets  in  which  air  service  is  provided ;  and  second,  to 
promote  the  expansion  of  competition  among  air  carriers.  In  general,  the  expan- 
sion of  competition  in  an  expanding  market  has  been  a  primary  underpinning  of 


661 

the  Board's  route  policy  since  1938.  It  has  long  been  recognized  that  the  competi- 
tive environment  that  exists  in  our  aviation  industry  has  been  responsible  for  the 
development  of  the  high  level  and  quality  of  service  enjoyed  by  the  traveling  pub- 
lic in  this  country,  which  service  constitutes  the  most  extensive,  convenient,  eflS- 
oient  and  least  costly  air  transport  system  anywhere  in  the  world.  A  very 
important  secondary  result  of  the  Boards  competitive  route  awards  has  been  the 
expansion  of  first  air  service  opportunities  to  many  city-pair  markets  as  a  result 
of  the  tacking  on  of  new  points  to  the  existing  system  of  a  successful  applicant. 

With  these  primary  goals  of  the  Board  as  our  premise,  it  is  useful  to  take  a 
look  at  how  our  present  system  of  trunk  carriers  and  local  service  carriers  came 
into  being. 

The  original  domestic  air  transport  system  of  nineteen  carriers  were  established 
in  1938  under  "grandfather"  rights  by  Congress.  This  initial  nucleus  presented 
the  Board  with  a  fairly  competitive  route  structure  relative  to  the  infant  size 
of  the  industry.  Only  four  carriers  at  that  time  had  what  we  now  consider  to  be 
trunkline  type  route  structures :  American,  Eastern,  TWA  and  United.  The  other 
carriers,  such  as  Continental,  Delta,  Northwest  and  Braniff,  were  small  regional 
operators  performing  feeder-type  services  similar  in  many  respects  to  the  subsid- 
ized services  now  performed  by  local  service  carriers.  These  other  carriers  were 
in  some  cases  considerably  smaller  than  many  of  today's  air  taxis.  Competition 
was  fostered  by  expanding  the  operating  rights  of  the  smaller  trunks  into  markets 
served  by  larger  trunks,  thereby  strengthening  the  smaller  carriers  and  equalizing 
traflSc  opportunities.  At  the  same  time,  the  routes  of  the  larger  trunks  were  also 
enlarged.  I  should  note  that  during  that  entire  period,  the  industry's  traffic  growth 
averaged  16  percent  per  year. 

Since  the  mid-sixties  the  Board  has  been  permitting  the  local  service  carriers 
to  enter  markets  served  by  trunkline  carriers.  The  result  is  that  in  a  very  real 
sense  many  of  these  carriers  have  evolved  into  small  trunkline  carriers.  The  ex- 
pansion of  local  service  carriers  accomplished  several  important  objectives.  By 
strengthening  the  carriers'  route  systems  the  Board  accelerated  the  time  when 
government  subsidy  may  no  longer  be  required.  And,  by  increasing  market  op- 
portunities, the  regional  carriers  were  enabled  to  modernize  their  fleets  and  enjoy 
other  technological  improvements. 

As  you  know,  Mr.  Chairman,  the  Board's  route  award  policies  were  not  limited 
to  the  trunk  and  local  service  carriers.  In  addition,  various  specialist  carriers 
were  authorized  to  provide  service  in  competition  with  trunkline  carriers.  These 
include  all-cargo  specialists  that  compete  for  cargo  over  routes  served  by  trunks  : 
the  supplemental  carriers  that  compete  for  charter  traffic  with  the  trunks  ;  various 
Alaskan  and  Hawaiian  operators ;  and  certificated  helicopter  carriers.  A  new 
trunkline  carrier,  Trans  Caribbean  Airways  (now  merged  with  American)  was 
awarded  a  certificate,  and  certificates  authorizing  service  over  limited  routes 
were  awarded  to  Aspen  Airways  and  Wright  Air  Lines.  In  addition,  in  the 
midfifties  the  Board  authorized  26  supplementals  to  provide  individually  ticketed 
service  in  competition  with  the  trunks.  The  courts,  however,  ruled  that  this  action 
was  not  authorized  by  the  Act.  Congress  subsequently  authorized  the  award  of 
supplemental  air  carrier  certificates,  but  precluded  such  carriers  from  perform- 
ing individually  ticketed  service  except  under  very  limited  circumstances. 

I  would  also  note  that  in  July,  1974  the  Board  established  in  the  New  England 
Service  Investigation  a  new  regional  airline,  Air  New  England,  to  provide  service 
between  New  York  and  Boston  and  at  least  12  other  New  England  points  in 
Maine,  Vermont,  New  Hampshire,  and  Massachusetts,  That  carrier  is  now  in 
certificated  operation.  I  believe  that  the"  Board's  action  in  that  case  highlighted 
that  the  Board  can  respond,  as  the  circumstances  permit,  to  demonstrable  service 
inadequacies  with  a  bold  exercise  of  its  statutory  authority  and  mandate. 

Before  proceeding  to  the  matter  of  competitive  service,  I  think  it  should  be 
noted  that  the  Board  authorizes  air  service  by  the  exemption  process  as  well  as 
by  certificate  award.  I  am  sure  everyone  is  familiar  with  the  commuter  carriers 
which  use  relatively  small  aircraft  to  provide  feeder  service  to  hundreds  of  the 
nation's  small  communities  and  sometimes  serve  high  density,  short  haul,  markets 
such  as  Washington-Philadelphia,  or  San  Juan-St.  Thomas.  In  addition,  the 
Board  frequently  issues  a  more  specialized  type  of  exemption  which  we  refer 
to  as  a  large  aircraft  exemption — that  is,  an  authorization  to  use  equipment 
larger  than  that  used  by  air  taxis — where  there  is  a  showing  that  a  relatively 
limited  or  specialized  type  of  service  is  required. 

One  of  the  issues  that  concerns  this  subcommittee,  the  administration,  and  a 
broad  segment  of  the  public  is  how  the  Board  views  competitive  service.  There 


662 

is  no  question  that  in  its  liistory  of  route  awards  the  Board  has  affirmed  its 
recognition  of  the  merits  that  can  flow,  in  appropriate  situations,  from  competi- 
tive service.  A  recent  Board  opinion  said,  in  fact,  and  I  quote,  "We  also  bear 
in  mind  that  the  need  of  the  traveling  public  for  air  transportation  service  is  a 
paramount  element  of  public  interest,  and  the  competition  ultimately  holds  the 
greatest  prospect  for  vigorous  development  of  air  transportation.  .  .  ."  ^ 

Over  the  years  and  as  a  result  of  several  hundred  cases  the  Board  has  developed 
standards  for  considering  awards  of  competitive  authority.  These  standards 
break  down  into  two  broad  decisional  categories — first,  need  for  service,  and 
secondary,  carrier  selection.  Under  the  need  for  service  category,  the  Board 
evaluates,  based  upon  the  evidentiary  record,  the  extent  to  which  the  existing 
services  of  the  incumbent  are  deficient  and  whether  the  markets  are  large  enough 
to  support  additional  service  immediately  or  in  the  near  future.  Factors  con- 
sidered in  determining  "service  deficiency"  include  to  greater  or  lesser  degrees, 
the  number  and  timing  of  the  incumbent  carrier's  flights;  the  quality  of  such 
flights  (nonstop,  1-stop,  multistop)  ;  the  load  factors  on  the  flights  ;  the  particular 
patterns  of  service  provided  (i.e.,  the  additional  points  served  on  the  flights)  ;  the 
service  amenities,  etc. 

If  it  has  determined  that  competitive  authority  is  required  to  improve  the 
efficiency  and  quality  of  the  service,  an  equally  difficult  task  for  the  Board 
is  that  of  carrier  selection.  Carrier  selection  criteria  include  the  question  of 
which  carrier  can  provide  the  most  service  benefits  to  passengers  in  the  particular 
city-pair  market  under  examination  as  well  as  in  "beyond-area"  markets;  the 
need  for  carrier  strengthening,  which  includes  an  examination  of  individual 
carrier  profitability  over  the  proposed  route;  the  degree  of  historic  identity 
in  the  market  in  issue ;  the  extent  of  diversion  from  the  incumbent,  which  varies 
by  individual  applicant,  depending  upon  its  route  structure. 

Furthermore,  in  weighing  the  application  of  any  new  entrant,  the  Board  has 
historically  considered  the  probable  diversion  of  revenues  from  existing  carriers, 
the  effect  of  that  diversion  on  Federal  subsidy  payments,  and  the  possible  impair- 
ment of  the  ability  of  existing  carriers  to  continue  to  serve  their  own  routes, 
including  those  cities  on  their  routes  which  they  may  serve  at  a  loss.  I  want 
to  say  in  this  connection  that  the  Board  has  no  policy  which  precludes  the  entry 
of  a  new  carrier.  Nonetheless,  it  must  be  acknowledged  that  an  applicant  who  is 
not  an  existing  carrier  is  at  a  substantial  disadvantage  vis-a-vis  existing  carriers. 
This  is  because  such  an  applicant,  by  definition,  is  unable  to  provide  service  to 
"beyond  area"  markets,  which,  as  previously  mentioned,  is  an  important  stand- 
ard in  determining  carrier  selection. 

Thus,  in  any  case  involving  a  choice  between  an  existing  carrier  and  a  would 
be  new  entrant,  the  existing  carrier  can  virtually  always  show  that  it  will  be 
able  to  provide  substantial  public  benefits  in  the  form  of  through  service  to 
numerous  points,  in  addition  to  those  at  issue  in  the  proceeding,  whereas  the 
new  entrant  cannot  make  such  a  showing.  In  view  of  this  and  in  light  of  the 
capital  outlay  required  to  serve  a  scheduled  route,  it  is  not  surprising  that  appli- 
cations by  new  entrants  into  the  trunkline  field  have  been  relatively  few. 

The  degree  of  competitive  expansion  authorized  by  the  Board  has  varied  from 
time  to  time  depending  upon  the  state  of  the  general  economy  and  of  the  airline 
industry,  as  well  as  the  rate  of  traffic  growth.  These  are  all  factors  which  are 
inextricably  interwined.  On  top  of  that,  the  Board  has  recently  had  to  focus  on 
fuel  supply  considerations  and  environmental  matters. 

The  earnings  of  the  airline  industry  are  extremely  erratic.  They  are  far  more 
cyclical  than  is  the  case  with  most  other  industries  or  the  economy  as  a  whole. 
During  the  depressed  phases  of  the  cycle,  when  traffic  declines  and  carrier  losses 
increase— such  as  in  the  early  seventies,  the  Board  has  accorded  applications 
for  competitive  route  authority  low  priority  in  order  to  allow  the  carriers  to 
adjust  their  systems  to  take  into  account  the  routes  they  and  their  competitors 
acquired  during  the  previous  up-cycle  and  to  permit  lagging  traffic  demand  to 
once  again  catch  up  to  the  capacity  increases  that  seem  inevitably  to  flow  from 
route  awards. 

This  practice  of  the  Board  has  been  subject  to  severe  criticism,  to  the  point 
that  it  has  been  characterized  by  its  critics  as  a  "route  moratorium."  I  think 
you  will  find,  Mr.  Chairman,  if  you  examine  the  Board's  decisions,  and  the  public 


Order  72-12-29. 


remarks  made  by  Board  Members  and  by  its  senior  staff  officials,  that  this  char- 
acterization does  not  truly  reflect  the  Board's  policy.  On  the  contrary,  the  Board 
is  keenly  aware  of  its  statutory  mandate  to  be  responsive  to  route  applications 
and  to  act  upon  them  as  speedily  as  possible  in  keeping  with  the  circumstances 
of  each  such  application  and  with  the  judgmental  decisions,  with  which  it  is  also 
entrusted,  to  assign  necessary  priorities  for  its  work.  The  Board's  activities  indi- 
cate that  as  carrier  earnings  and  the  general  economy  improve  the  Board's  route 
programs  have  kept  pace  with  the  rise  in  traffic  demand  and  carrier  health.  In 
orders  setting  an  application  for  hearing,  or  refusing  to  do  so,  you  will  find 
discussion  of  traffic  levels,  load  factors,  the  timing  and  frequency  of  existing 
flights,  fuel  availability  and  of  all  other  factors  relevant  to  the  question  of  the 
priority  to  be  accorded  to  the  application. 

Finally,  the  Board's  policies  on  exit  can  be  just  as  important  as  its  policies  on 
entry  in  insuring  that  the  American  public  gets  the  kind  of  air  transportation 
they  need,  and  that  the  system  remains  healthy.  As  in  the  case  of  route  awards, 
the  Act  requires  the  Board  to  balance  the  needs  of  individual  travelers  and  com- 
munities, on  the  one  hand,  with  the  overall  economic  efficiency  of  the  system,  on 
the  other.  Thus,  the  decision  on  a  carrier's  deletion  or  suspension  request  has  to 
be  based  on  a  weighing  process.  In  one  recent  deletion  case,  for  example,  the 
historic  traffic  levels  at  the  communities  in  question  were  as  low  as  those  of  many 
points  that  we  had  in  the  past  agreed  to  delete  from  a  carrier's  system.^  In  this 
instance,  however,  the  communities  made  a  strong  showing  regarding  the  pos- 
sible impact  of  deletion  on  their  future.  Accordingly,  the  Board  decided  that  the 
communities  should  be  given  at  least  another  year  of  air  service  during  which 
time  they  would  have  to  show  their  willingness  to  use  and  promote  the  service. 

In  other  circumstances,  where  air  transportation  economics  warrant,  the  Board 
has  encouraged  the  switch  from  large  aircraft  service  by  certificated  carriers  to 
small  aircraft  service  provided  by  air  taxis  pursuant  to  agreements  between  the 
carriers  involved.  In  fact,  in  the  case  of  one  experimental  situation  of  this  kind, 
the  Board  provided  for  a  "flow-through"  of  the  certificated  carrier's  subsidy  funds 
to  the  replacement  air  taxi,  thereby  providing  for  air  service  to  a  small  com- 
munity at  a  considerable  savings  in  subsidy  for  the  taxpayer.^ 

In  concluding  these  remarks,  Mr.  Chairman,  I  want  to  note  that  in  December 
1974,  the  Board's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  issued  a  study  of  the  domestic 
route  system  on  which  industry  comments  are  due  on  May  1,  1975.  The  study 
was  undertaken  to  accomplish  three  objectives :  1 )  to  assess  the  existing  system, 
analyze  its  development  and  to  determine  the  effect  and  extent  of  service  com- 
petition ;  2 )  to  construct  a  model  for  the  development  of  traffic  projections  to  the 
year  1985  for  the  domestic  system  and  individual  city-pair  markets,  and  projec- 
tions of  probable  service  requirements  ;  and,  3)  to  set  forth  recommendations  with 
respect  to  going  forward  with  a  new  route  program.  The  Bureau  recommends  in 
this  study  that  the  Board  promulgate  new  rules  to  define  the  standard  for  priority 
hearing  of  applications  involving  first  effective  air  service  as  well  as  other  im- 
proved and  competitive  service.  Secondly,  the  rule  would  define  standards  for 
determining  the  priority  of  hearing  cases  on  service  adequacy  and  other  defi- 
ciencies in  service,  as  well  as  excessive  service.  I  would  urge  that  this  subcom- 
mittee take  cognizance  of  the  historical  analyses  contained  in  this  staff  study 
in  the  course  of  its  deliberations. 

Let  me  finally  say,  Mr.  Chairman,  that  the  Board  recognizes  that  the  system 
can  always  be  improved  and,  as  illustrated  by  the  route  study  referred  to  above, 
the  Board's  attempt  to  fine-tune  the  system  to  meet  the  changing  times  in  a  con- 
tinuing process.  It  is  difficult  in  this  short  space  to  comment  on  the  many  sug- 
gestions tliat  have  been  made  that  the  time  has  come  to  deregulate  air 
transportation  in  this  country.  I  anticipate  that  these  hearings  and  the  questions 
generated  by  the  Chairman  and  the  subcommittee  staff  will  provide  an  adequate 
forum  to  explore  these  complex  and  important  issues. 

My  colleagues  and  I,  Mr.  Chairman,  are  at  your  disposal  for  any  questions  you 
may  care  to  ask. 

[Wliereupon,  at  12 :45  p.m.  the  subcommittee  recessed  to  reconvene 
at  2 :15  p.m.  the  same  day.] 


2  Order  74-11-19. 
'  Order  74-4-77. 


664 

AITERNOON    SESSION 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  will  come  to  order.  Our  first  two  witnesses 
this  afternoon  will  be  Mr.  Donald  Baker  and  Mr.  William  Kutzke. 
Mr.  Donald  Baker  is  a  Deputy  Assistant  Attorney  General  in  the 
Antitrust  Division.  Mr.  Kutzke  is  an  attorney  at  the  Department  of 
Transportation  who  has  represented  the  Department  in  many  CAB 
proceedings.  He  will  present  the  testimony  of  Mr.  John  Snow,  the 
Deputy  Assistant  Secretary  of  the  Department  of  Transportation  for 
Policy,  Plans  and  International  Affairs. 

The  staff  had  the  chance  to  review  the  statement  of  Mr.  Baker  and 
we  would  like  to  thank  you  for  the  detailed  comments  concerning 
entry  policy  and  route  awards.  Perhaps  you  could  just  summarize 
briefly  and  then  we  could  get  to  questions.  I  want  to  thank  you 
for  coming. 

STATEMENTS  OF  DONALD  I.  BAKER,  DEPUTY  ASSISTANT  ATTORNEY 
GENERAL,  ANTITRUST  DIVISION,  DEPARTMENT  OF  JUSTICE,  AND 
WILLIAM  A.  KUTZKE,  OFFICE  OF  THE  GENERAL  COUNSEL,  DE- 
PARTMENT OF  TRANSPORTATION;  ACCOMPANIED  BY  DONALD 
FARMER,  SPECIAL  ASSISTANT  TO  THE  ASSISTANT  ATTORNEY 
GENERL,  DOJ 

Mr.  Baker.  Thank  you,  Mr.  Chairman.  I  would  like  to  introduce  my 
colleague,  Don  Farmer,  who  has  worked  extensively  on  airline  matters 
over  a  period  of  time.  He  is  special  assistant  to  the  Assistant  Attorney 
General  and  a  resident  expert. 

Let  me  just  summarize  very  briefly  what  I  have  got  in  my  statement. 

I  would  make  about  five  or  six  key  points.  First  of  all,  entry  and 
pricing  are  very  closely  related.  The  entry  threat  is  a  vital  considera- 
tion if  you  are  going  to  have  pricing  flexibility.  Moreover,  an  open 
entry  policy  without  pricing  flexibility  tends  to  just  produce  waste.ful 
service  competition  and  is  really  not  a  very  useful  alternative. 

My  second  general  point  would  be  that  route  policy  is  really  con- 
cerned with  two  kinds  of  competition :  First,  the  city-pair  competition 
for  actual  passengers;  and,  second  is  industry-wide  potential  com- 
petition between  carriers  to  get  on  different  routes. 

INITIAL  FINANCING  OF  AN  AIRLINE  ( ECONOMIC  BARRIERS  TO  ENTRY  I 

Third,  the  CAB  has  been  very  restrictive  in  its  approach  to  these 
entry  questions  and  particularly  its  approach  to  new  entry  into  the 
industry.  What  it  has  done,  and  the  statement  details  it,  is  basically 
confine  the  trunk  route  awards  to  the  firms  that  were  in  the  industry 
in  1938,  the  grandfather  carriers.  The  result  has  been  a  lack  of  new 
blood  in  the  industry ;  we  have  a  set  way  of  doing  things. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  do  you  respond  that  new  airlines  cannot 
get  the  necessary  initial  financing.  These  trunk  carriers  are  going  to 
need  enormous  amounts  of  capital  to  get  started,  so  this  is  really  as 
much  a  process  of  market  forces  as  a  CAB  decision. 

Mr.  Baker.  I  would  respond  by  saying  I  do  not  think  it  is  so.  I 
would  say  that  for  several  reasons.  For  example,  the  innovative  Cali- 


665 

fomia  carriers,  the  PSA's  and  the  Air  California's,  have  gotten  ab- 
solutely no  encouragement  from  the  CAB  potential  tninkline  carriers. 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  have  heard  that  California  and  Texas  are 
really  specialized. 

Mr.  Baker.  I  understand  their  arguments  and  I  have  heard  them 
as  often  as  you  have. 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  is  right.  Probably  more. 

Mr.  Baker.  But,  no,  the  point  is,  if  I  recall  correctly  in  the  early 
sixties,  PSA  and  Air  California  tried  to  get  interstate  authority  to 
go  into  the  Northwest  and  there  was  absolutely  no  Board  interest 
whatever  in  allowing  that  kind  of  thing.  Second,  the  witness  this 
morning  from  United  Air  Lines  pointed  out  the  fact  that  a  new  entrant 
was,  in  fact,  quite  likely  to  be  able  to  put  the  thing  together,  leasing 
planes  and  crews;  and,  therefore,  the  vast  scale,  the  vast  capital  argu- 
ment, really  did  not  hold  water. 

So  I  think  that  the  argument  that  nobody  else  has  gotten  in  be- 
cause they  were  not  around  and  did  not  want  to  get  in  and  did  not 
have  the  capability  is  just  plain  not  true. 

Obviously,  we  will  look  carefully  at  any  evidence  to  the  contrary, 
in  terms  of  hard  facts.  But,  of  course,  it  is  very  hard  to  pin  down. 
Coming  down  from  the  Board's  generally  restrictive  policy  on  entry 
into  the  industry  to  their  particular  route  award  policy,  here  it  seems 
to  me  that— and  this  has  been  the  question  of  passing  out  routes  among 
the  existing  carriers  within  the  club — ^the  Board  has  made  at  least 
two  errors  that  are  outlined  in  my  testimony.  First  of  all,  the  Board 
has  emphasized  service  competition  over  price  competition.  It  has 
just  simply  allowed  people  on  with  no  real  opportunity  for  fully  com- 
peting, as  you  and  Senator  Thurmond  were  talking  about  this  morning 
in  terms  of  offering  different  mixes  of  quality  and  service. 

And  second,  the  Board  and  the  staff  proposals  have  emphasized  rates 
of  return  and  so  forth  excessively,  indeed,  this  has  been  their  main 
preoccupation.  . 

Now  I  would  draw  from  this  history  of  both  the  entry  mto  the  in- 
dustry and  the  particular  route  awards  some  conclusions.  First  of 
all,  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  has  not  required  the  CAB  to  behave 
in  this  way.  The  Act  lets  them 

NEED  FOR  LEGISLATION 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  heard  Mr.  O'Melia  indicate  this  morning, 
in  response  to  Senator  Thurmond,  that  to  really  open  up  the  entry 
process  might  very  well  require  changes  in  the  statute  itself,  that 
they  are  under  mandate  by  the  Congress  to  promote  a  certain  kind  of 
air  transportation  system,  and  that  if  Congress  wants  to  do  otherwise— 
and  this  is  implied  time  after  time  in  responses  by  members  of  the 
Board — will  require  revision  of  the  congressional  mandate. 

They  are  ready  to  do  it  if  Congress  wants  it.  And  if  Congress  does 
not  act,  they  know  the  wav  the  act  has  been  enforced  in  the  past. 

Mr.  Baker.  Well  I  heard  that  and  I  also  heard  Acting  Secretary 
Barnum  last  week  say  the  opposite,  namely  that  the  Board  could  do 
it  if  it  wanted  to.  And  with  all  due  respect,  I  agree  with  Mr.  Barnum. 
The  Board  has,  on  pricing  and  entry,  the  legal  authority  to  adopt  very 
open  rules  and  very  open  price  indexes. 


666 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  are  satisfied  from  the  legislative  history 
and  your  reading  of  the  statute  that  this  power  exists  within  the 
Board  itself. 

Mr.  Baker.  Yes.  I  think  that  the  power  really  does  exist.  In  a  sense, 
what  the  acting  chairman  said  this  morning  was  that  we  have  ad- 
ministered the  statute  in  one  way  for  a  long  time  and,  unless  the 
Congress  gives  us  a  new  set  of  orders,  we  are  going  to  go  on  doing 
it  that  way,  which  leads  me 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  is  your  answer  to  that  ? 

Mr.  Baker.  That  you  ought  to  change  the  statute.  And,  basically, 
the  fault  lies  with  the  discretion  the  agency  has  and  the  use  of  it.  Now 
this  is  not  a  unique  situation  with  the  CAB.  In  fact,  the  history  of 
regulatory  agencies  generally  has  been  that  they  have  been  granted 
'broad  discretion,  they  have  generally  been  influenced  heavily  by  the 
people  they  were  supposed  to  regulate,  and  they  have  generally  ex- 
ercised the  discretion  in  favor  of  the  people  who  they  were  supposed 
to  regulate. 

And  this  is  what  Jordan  calls  the  cartel  theory  of  regulation,  and 
it  is  not  surprising  that  here  we  have  this  system  of  regulation,  which 
is  supposed  to  protect  the  traveling  public,  but  its  leading  champions, 
who  sit  around  these  tables,  are  not  the  traveling  public,  but  the  car- 
riers. This  could  be  repeated  industry  after  industry — banking,  se- 
curities, whatever. 

And  I  have  dealt 

Senator  Kennedy.  So  you  are  satisfied  it  is  really  a  question  of  the 
Board's  implementation  of  the  act.  And  as  I  understand,  in  terms  of 
the  history  of  the  CAB,  there  have  been  times  when  the  Board  ac- 
tually has  had  a  more  liberal  policy  in  terms  of  entry. 

Mr.  Baker.  That  is  correct. 

Senator  Kennedy.  And  you  can  call  upon  that  as  being  a  sufficient 
precedent.  How  do  you  respond  to  the  fact  that  most  of  the  people 
that  have  spoken  on  this  issue  are  from  industry?  You  have  heard 
the  gentleman  from  United  Air  Lines,  Mr.  De  Voursney,  who  indi- 
cated that  if  the  CAB  is,  in  fact,  a  captive  agency,  look  after  us  if 
they  ever  turn  against  us. 

IF   THE   CAB   PROTECTS   THE   AHILINES,   WHY   AREN't   THEY   RICH? 

How  do  you  respond  to  the  point  that  is  made  again,  time  and  time 
again,  that  the  airlines  really  have  not  experienced  good  times  ?  This 
point  is  made  frequently,  but  it  really  has  not  got  a  basis  of  fact, 
because  if  it  did,  the  airlines  would  have  shown  a  good  deal  more 
lucrative  profits  than  they  have  been  permitted  over  the  period  when 
they  have  had  a  restrictive  policy  of  entry  and  when  they  have  kept 
up  price. 

Mr.  Baker.  I  see  this  a  little  differently.  What  they  have  had  all  the 
way  through  is  a  restrictive  policy  on  price  and  a  varying  policy  on 
entry  by  firms  already  in  the  industry.  And  the  result  has  been  that, 
while  established  carriers  are  allowed  on  particular  routes,  they  are 
tied  down  by  a  fixed  price  scheme.  They  are  allowed  to  put  on  as  many 
seats  as  they  want.  And,  basically,  what  you  have  had  is  the  rates 
set  to  earn  a  monopoly  profit  and  then  the  carriers  have  proceeded 
to  compete  away  the  monopoly  profits  in  empty  seats.  And  this  is  not, 


667 

again,  unique  to  this  industry.  The  securities  industry,  which  has  the 
same  kind  of  price  regulated  scheme  with  no  particular  control  over 
entry  and  facilities,  the  securities  firms  have  competed  away  monopoly 
profits  in  the  same  way. 

So  I  do  not  see  regulation  as  a  guarantee.  Senator  Kennedy,  of 
a  comfortable  life.  I  see  it  as  a  guarantee  that  they  will  be  allowed 
to  compete  in  a  way  they  prefer  to  compete  rather  than  through  price 
competition. 

Anyway,  to  finish  off  the  points  in  my  statement,  this  leads  us  to 
recommend  that  the  agency  discretion  must  be  changed.  It  must  be 
limited  or  eliminated.  And  we  suggest  a  range  of  possibilities  that 
are  under  consideration,  including  some  form  of  clear  statutory  com- 
mand to  the  Board  that  it  allow  entry  unless  it  is  able  to  make  specific 
findings  that  there  would  be  harm  from  allowing  new  entry.  In  the 
parallel  surface  transportation  area,  the  administration  suggested  in 
1971  that  entry  be  allowed  unless  there  is  a  showing  that  new  entry 
is  likely  to  result  in  less  service  rather  than  more  in  a  reasonable 
period. 

The  other  broad  alternative  mentioned  was  the  possibility  of  just 
eliminating  CAB  control  over  rates  and  entry  as  a  part  of  a  general 
deregulation  scheme.  And  again,  we  say  that  is  one  of  the  things  that 
is  under  consideration. 

Senator  Kennedy.  ^^Tien  will  we  know  what  the  Department  posi- 
tion is  ? 

Mr.  Baker.  Two  weeks  ago,  acting  Secretary  Barnum  said  6  Aveeks. 
Last  week  he  said  5  weeks  to  another  committee.  Therefore,  this  week 
I  will  say  4  weeks.  I  do  not  know  anything  going  on  that  has  put  us  off 
our  schedule,  and  we  are  actively  at  work. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  want  to  reduce  it  to  March  4,  when  you 
are  coming  back  ?  You  can  make  a  note  of  that. 

Mr.  Baker.  March  4  does  not  sound  right  to  me,  especially  since  I  am 
going  to  be  out  of  town  half  the  time  between  now  and  then,  except  for 
your  hearings. 

EFFECT    OF    OPEN    COMPETITION    ON    SMALL-TOWN    SERVICE 

This  is  my  last  point.  Any  proposal  like  this  tends  to  lead  to  the 
argument  that  there  will  be  no  service,  or  service  will  greatly  go  down 
in  thin  markets.  You  have  heard  that  this  morning,  and  basically,  the 
testimony  suggests  several  answers  to  this. 

First  of  all,  that  the  efficiencies,  the  incentives  to  efficiency  in  run- 
ning a  route  system  remain  under  freer  entry^,  and  indeed,  the  manu- 
agement  has  greater  discretion  in  how  it  uses  its  planes  to  optimize  the 
route  operation  in  a  freer  entry  situation. 

We  offered  you  the  Bar  Harbor  example  because  we  thought  we 
ought  to  have  some  example  from  New  England.  There  an  unregulated, 
open-entry  kind  of  situation  resulted  in  regular  year-round  service 
from  Bar  Harbor  to  Boston,  which  had  not  been  available  before. 

It  is  possible,  it  seems  to  us,  that  a  more  competitive  environment 
would  lead  to  more  efficient  operations  and,  therefore,  would  lead  to 
lower  levels  of  subsidies  being  needed.  If  there  are  to  be  subsidies,  we 
think  that  they  should  be  spelled  out  as  clearly  as  possible,  as  indeed, 
you  said  this  morning.  We  should  all  know  who  is  getting  paid  what 


668 

and  how  much  it  is  costing  the  rest  of  us.  We  feel  very  strongly  that 
the  cross-subsidy  approach  is  inequitable  and  inefficient — that  it 
basically  flows  from  a  premise  that  'Svhat  the  public  does  not  know 
does  not  matter."  A  person  who  is  flying  on  the  Birmingham-to-Boston 
route  does  not  know  that  he  is  being  subsidized  by  you  on  your  trips 
from  Washington  to  Boston,  and  it  is  not  clear  that  he  would  vote  for 
it  if  he  did  know  about  it.  Cross-subsidy  is  a  completely  subterranean- 
type  of  thing. 

Moreover,  if  you  set  up  a  scheme  that  is  based  on  cross-subsidies,  you 
then  have  to  erect  all  kinds  of  very  special  barriers  to  make  sure  that 
the  profits  are  not  completed  away  in  a  monopoly  market,  and  hence, 
not  available  to  cross-subsidize  the  high-cost,  low-volume  markets.  This 
has  just  been  a  persistent  problem  throughout  regulation. 

We  feel  that  the  air  experience  is  not  significantly  different  from  the 
communications  industry  and  other  areas  of  transportation,  and  the 
cross-subsidy  argument  should  be  scrutinized  carefully. 

DEPENDENCE    OF   SMALL-TOWN    SERVICE   ON    CROSS   SUBSIDY 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  you  working  on  the  cross-subsidy  question  as 
well,  to  determine  the  magnitude  of  it  ?  We  have  asked  the  airlines  for 

this  kind  of  information  and 

Mr.  Baker.  I  would  honestly  have  to  say  that  we  have  not  seen 
good  data— at  least  I  personally  have  not  seen  good  data  on  the  cross 

subsidies,  and 

Senator  Kennedy.  Is  there  any  reason  why  you  could  not  work  with 
the  DOT  on  that  particular  issue? 

Mr.  Baker.  We  can  use  the  same  telephone  system  and  so  forth. 
And  I  will  say  quickly  that  the  Department  of  Transportation  has 
been  concerned  over  a  period  of  time  with  cross  subsidies,  and  this 
is  not  a  situation  where  I  have  been  beating  on  their  door  and  they 
have  not  been  providing  data.  It  is  simply  the  fact  that  I  have  been 
doing  other  things  and  not  perhaps  doing  what  I  should  be  doing. 
That  completes  the  presentation. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  would  like  to  know  how  you  respond  to  a 
number  of  questions  ?  United  Air  Lines  appeared  to  indicate  that  145 
nonstop  segments  will  be  lost,  that  will  not  be  served  unless  they  have 
this  kind  of  a  cross-subsidy. 

What  kind  of  assurance  can  you  give  us  that,  if  we  have  policies 
of  freer  entry  and  more  price  competition,  that  people  in  Binghamton 
are  going  to  get  any  kind  of  air  service?  They  are  getting  some  now. 
They  might  even  be  getting  it  at  a  reasonable  price. 

United  Air  Lines  indicates  that  all  of  these  other  Binghamton's 
around  the  country  will  not  be  served  if  we  permit  freer  entry  and 
lower  prices.  What  do  you  say  about  that  ? 

Mr.  Baker.  Well,  what  I  say  is  that  clearly  we  want  to  look  at  the 
facts  very  carefully  because,  in  fact,  people  are  serving  these  thin 
markets  which,  by  and  large,  are  monopoly  markets.  They  are  doing 
so  because  they  have  applied  for  routes  on  which  they  thought  they 
could  make  a  profit  and  are  serving  on  them.  When  they  do  not 
think  they  can  make  a  profit  they  have  sought  to  suspend,  and  in 
many  cases  been  able  to  suspend. 

Indeed,  the  Bar  Harbor  example  is  a  situation  which  flows  out  of 
Northeast  moving  to  suspend,  someone  else  being  brought  in  with  sub- 


stitute  service  which  was  relatively  infrequent ;  and  Bar  Harbor  Air- 
ways coming  back  and  offering  more  frequent  substitute  service.  There 
is  a  lot  of  flexibility  on  different  kinds  of  equipment.  You  may  find 
that  a  DC-9,  for  instance,  is  not  economic  on  a  market  where  a  smaller 
plane  would  be.  And  anyone  who  has  spent  time,  as  I  am  sure  you 
have  and  I  have,  flying  around  New  England  on  Air  New  England 
and  so  forth,  has  seen  a  variety  of  smaller  planes  on  routes  that  used 
to  have  larger  planes.  There  is  still  service.  And  so  I  am  not  convinced 
that  route  security  is  the  key  to  service  in  these  markets. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  do  you  make  a  decision  whether  competi- 
tion is  going  to  be  beneficial  or  whether  it  is  going  to  be  destructive  ? 

We  hear  both  sides.  We  are  hearing  from  World  Airways  that  it 
would  be  beneficial,  and  from  United  that  it  would  be  destructive.  How 
are  we  going  to  really  know,  and  how  do  you  make  your  judgments? 

Mr.  Baker.  What  is  involved,  what  destructive  competition  involves 
is  somebody  pricing  something  down  below  his  variable  cost  of  pro- 
viding it  for  the  purpose  of  driving  other  people  out.  Now,  as  I  indi- 
cated in  my  testimony,  this  is  not  a  very  frequent  occurrence  in  the 
real,  the  unregulated  world.  We  do  not  find  in  antitrust  investigations 
that  this  occurs  very  often.  It  occurs  much  more  frequently  in  a  regu- 
lated environment  because  in  order  for  it  to  work,  new  entry  has  to  be 
held  out.  AVhat  you  have  to  do  is  to  cut  your  price  down  below  your 
variable  cost,  which  means  you  lose  your  shirt  for  awhile,  and  then 
somehow  or  other,  to  make  it  rational  conduct,  you  have  got  to  be  able 
to  get  your  shirt  back.  And  the  way  you  get  your  shirt  back  is  by 
charging  monopoly  prices  and  not  having  anyone  come  in. 

Now  in  the  real,  unregulated  world,  that  does  not  happen.  Other 
people  come  back  in.  In  the  regulated  environment,  I  have  seen  situa- 
tions where  a  carrier  expected  to  knock  someone  off  a  route  or  put  them 
in  the  corner,  and  then  afterwards  clean  up  at  regulated  price  levels. 

THE   INTERLINE   NETWORK   AND   OPE!N   COMPETITION 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  are  satisfied  that  this  national  network 
concept,  which  I  think  is  almost  the  sacred  cow  of  the  airlines  in- 
dustry, would  not  be  so  altered  as  to  create  a  jungle  of  difficulty  for 
the  traveling  public,  were  we  to  go  to  a  competitive  situation. 

Mr.  Baker.  The  national  network  is  essentially  a  set  of  interchange 
arrangements,  interchanges  of  baggage,  and  tickets,  and  facilities, 
and  so  forth,  and  there  is  no  reason  why  that  kind  of  interchange 
arrangement  should  not  go  forward.  And  in  the  hearings  last  week — 
and  we  will  come  back  to  this,  I  assume,  in  the  hearings  2  weeks  hence 
on  antitrust  immunities — there  are  all  kinds  of  cooperative  endeavors 
in  order  to  make  the  system  work  that  are  perfectly  fine  from  the 
antitrust  standpoint.  I  do  not  see  having  freer  entry  in  anyway  affect- 
ing the  national  network  concept.  Less  regulated  carriers  have  an 
equal  incentive  to  be  able  to  interchange  traffic  and  baggage. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  happens  when  you  want  to  go  from  Boston 
to  Detroit  and  you  can  only  get  as  far  as  Binghamton?  Are  there 
not  going  to  be  gaps  that  are  created  in  the  system  that  are  avoided 
now?  We  hear  this  talked  about. 

Mr.  Baker.  Well,  my  colleague,  Don  Farmer,  says  you  might  rather 
get  to  Binghamton  than  Detroit  anyway.  But  I  do  not  know  that 
that  is  the  answer  to  the  question. 


670 

Senator  Kennedy.  The  point  is  that  perhaps  gaps  would  be  created 
in  the  network. 

Mr.  Baker.  It  would  seem  to  me  that,  to  the  extent  that  there  is 
business  to  support  a  nonstop  service  from  Boston  to  Detroit,  it  is 
going  to  be  carried.  To  the  extent  that  there  is  not  business,  then  you 
are  going  to  have  to  go  via  some  intermediate  point. 

But  the  carrier,  the  Allegheny  or  whatever,  that  takes  you  to  Bing- 
hamton  or  that  takes  you  out  of  Boston,  even  if  it  does  not  go  to 
Detroit,  has  every  incentive  to  try  to  work  up  some  way  that  you  are 
going  to  get  through  service  to  Detroit,  or  Chicago,  or  Seattle.  It 
would  just  encourage  you  to  use  a  plane. 

ANALOGY   TO   OTHER  UNREGULATED   INDUSTREBS 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  there  any  other  kind  of  systems,  analogous 
to  the  airline  system,  which  are  not  regulated  and  yet  which  provide 
for  interchangeability  and  integration?  Are  there  such  systems  that 
work  well? 

Mr.  Baker.  Yes,  certainly.  I  will  give  you  some  examples.  One  is 
the  whole  bank  credit  card  authorization  and  clearance  system  which 
is  entirely  private,  entirely  outside  the  regulatory  realm  and  is  going 
to  an  automatic  online  basis. 

There  are  a  variety  of  large,  complicated  systems  which  really  do  not 
involve  this  kind  of  regulation.  And  indeed,  we  threw  into  the  testi- 
mony the  example  of  a  national  hotel  authority  on  the  grounds  that  if 
you  had  for  30  yeare  a  central  reservation  system  Government  admin- 
istered and  so  forth  for  hotel  reservations,  you  would  immediately  be 
greeted  with  claims  of  chaos  if  it  was  suggested  it  should  be  abolished. 

cab   staff   study   on   route  entry,   THE   DOMESTIC   ROUTE 
SYSTEM    (1974) 

Senator  Kennedy.  Have  you  reviewed  the  staff  proposal  that  was 
mentioned  ? 

Mr.  Baker.  I  have  looked  at  it.  Senator.  I  cannot  honestly  say  that  I 
have  reviewed  it  in  detail.  I  can  make  some  general  cormnent. 

Senator  Kennedy.  As  I  understand  it,  in  the  first  place,  it  requires 
a  showing  that  the  proposed  operations  will  earn  12-percent  rate  of 
return  on  investment  the  first  year.  Second,  it  requires  a  showing  that 
no  incumbent  is  making  less  than  6  percent  in  that  market.  And  third, 
it  requires  a  showing  that  the  new  entrant  will  not  divert  more  than  35 
percent  of  the  incumbent's  traffic. 

Now  I  suppose  the  question  is  the  competitive  effect  of  these  require- 
ments, and  how  they  would  ultimately  translate  into  entry  or  price  of 
travel  in  the  airline  industry. 

Mr.  Baker.  Well,  clearly,  they  are  highly  restrictive  and  designed  to 
reduce  potential  competition  to  a  minimum ;  the  requirement  of  earn- 
ing 12  percent  the  first  year  really  almost  eliminates  it,  even  where  the 
market  is  being  badly  served.  The  new  entrant  has  to  set  up  stations, 
pay  its  promotional  costs,  to  pay  your  promotional  costs  and  still  make 
this  high  return  in  the  first  year. 

As  one  of  the  witnesses  this  morning,  I  think  the  representative  from 
Continental  Airlines,  said  that  the  6-percent  standard  for  every  carrier 


671 

that  has  to  be  earning  at  least  6  percent  on  the  market,  could  mean 
that  you  are  supporting  awful  inefficiency  where  some  carrier  on  the 
route  was  not  earning  it  because  they  were  an  airborne  equivalent  of 
the  telegraph  company. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Of  course,  even  the  airlines  that  have  been  func- 
tioning have  not  been  able  to  meet  that  requirement  over  the  past  20 
years. 

Mr.  Baker.  That  is  right.  This  is  a  route-by- route  probability.  And 
it  just,  you  know  it  seems  to  me  that,  taken  as  a  group,  those  three 
standards  represent  a  very  strong  example  of  what  I  was  talking  about, 
an  overconcern  about  the  carriers  on  routes,  about  the  welfare  of  the 
established  group  and  not  enough  concern  about  the  level  of  passenger 
convenience  and  the  threat  of  new  entry. 

VIABILITY  OF  "REGULATION"  BY  ANTITRUST  LAW 

Senator  Kennedy.  AMiat  is  your  reaction  to  what  was  said  this 
morning.  We  heard  from  United  Air  Lines  that  substituting  antitrust 
policy  for  regulation  is  just  substituting  litigation  for  regulation?  It  is 
not  a  very  high  endorsement  for  the  antitrust  division. 

Mr.  Baker.  It  is  a  troublesome  fact  that  antitrust  cases  often  do  take 
a  long  time,  but  they  do  not  take  longer  than  the  route  cases  we  have 
been  talking  about.  And  so,  I  do  not  feel  it  is  a  devastating  criticism  of 
antitrust.  And  second — to  stress  an  important  point  that  we  will  come 
back  to  this  a  couple  weeks  from  now — when  you  get  a  decision  from 
antitrust  court,  you  are  getting  a  decision  by  a  forum  that  is  completely 
outside  the  traditional  bilateral  relationships  between  the  industry  and 
the  agency.  You  are  out  of  that  closed-circuit  situation.  And  this  is  the 
thing,  I  think,  that  is  most  troublesome  to  people  in  the  industry :  That 
suddenly  competitive  policy  questions  are  going  to  be  made  by  judges, 
not  by  our  regulators.  I  think  that  is  their  concern,  not  the  delays  and 
the  uncertainties. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Mr.  Kutzke  ? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  appear.  Mr.  Snow 
expresses  his  regret  that  he  could  not  be  here  to  testify.  If  you  would 
like,  I  v.'ill  summarize  Mr.  Snow's  testimony  for  the  record.  As  ex- 
pressed in  Acting  Secretary  Barnum's  statement  to  this  subcommittee 
on  February  6,  1975,  the  Department  has  been  a  strong  advocate  of 
improving  the  economic  preformance  of  the  air  transportation  indus- 
try through  increased  reliance  on  competitive  market  forces.  The  eco- 
nomic performance  of  the  industry  must  be  improved  if  we  are  to 
restrain  the  rapidly  escalating  prices  of  air  transportation  and  preserve 
the  use  of  air  transportation  for  large  numbers  of  travelers.  One  vital 
aspect  of  this  problem  is  entry  and  route  awards.  As  a  result  of  the 
Board's  current  route  moratorium,  the  American  consumer  is  not  af- 
forded the  range  of  price  and  service  options  that  an  efficient  market 
would  provide  and  often  must  purchase  more  service  than  he  wants  or 
needs. 

open  entry  will  hold  down  fares 

Wliat  we  need,  in  terms  of  entry,  is  a  two-pronged  approach.  First : 
We  need  to  weigh  the  entry  standard  more  heavily  in  favor  of  compe- 
tition and  efficiency.  Second :  We  need  a  requirement  that  cases  before 


672 

the  Board  be  decided  promptly.  The  Board  must  focus  upon  the  needs 
of  the  public  and  the  need  for  competition  and  innovation,  and  place 
less  emphasis  on  the  impact  upon  the  existing  carriers.  Adoption  of  this 
approach  would  not  necessarily  lead  to  the  addition  of  new  carriers  on 
each  domestic  route,  nor  even  the  addition  of  new  carriers  to  the  ma- 
jority of  domestic  routes.  Rather,  the  basic  result  of  this  new  approach 
will  be  the  introduction  of  potential  competition  to  ensure  that  the 
domestic  air  markets  operate  efficiently  and  that  the  consumer  obtains 
the  price  and  service  option  of  his  choice.  The  threat  of  potential  entry 
will  police  and  discipline  market  behavior  and  ensure  competitive  mar- 
ket results.  Liberalized  entry  will  place  firms  on  the  edge  of  the  mar- 
ket, able  and  ready  to  step  into  that  market  when  the  consumer  is  dis- 
satisfied with  the  existing  service  and  price.  This  dissatisfaction  wall 
attract  entrants.  But  we  think  that  the  existing  firms  will  act  as  intelli- 
gent businessmen,  improve  their  efficiency,  and  keep  their  prices  low 
enough  to  keep  new  firms  out.  This  is  the  concept  of  threshold  pricing. 
Prices  are  kept  high  enough  to  make  reasonable  profits,  and  low 
enough  to  keep  new  competition  out.  The  consumer  benefits. 

Occasionally,  an  outsider  will  be  able  to  enter  the  market  because 
he  will  be  an*^innovator  and  offer  a  new  service,  or  be  more  efficient. 
Because  of  the  costs  associated  with  entry,  however,  he  will  be  the 
exception  to  the  rule.  But  the  fear  of  his  competition  will  spur  the 
existing  carriers  to  even  greater  efficiency  and  to  their  own  innovation. 
We  are  confident  the  result  will  be  a  more  efficient  and  innovative  air- 
line industry,  providing  the  public  with  better  service  and  more  price 
and  service  options. 

Even  though  this  hearing  deals  with  entry,  it  is  important  to  con- 
sider entry  in  the  context  of  price  flexibility.  As  you  will  remember, 
Acting  Secretary  Barnum  testified  in  favor  of  the  need  for  more 
pricing  flexibility  before  this  subcommittee.  One  criticism  of  pricing 
flexibilty  is  that' only  the  strong  firms  will  take  advantage  of  it,  and 
they  will  either  drive  prices  up  or,  in  the  alternative,  drive  prices  down 
temporarily  to  destroy  competition,  and  then  increase  price  when  the 
competition  is  gone.  Liberalized  entry  and  the  threat  of  potential  entry 
is  the  regulator  and  enforcer  which  assures  that  pricing  flexibility  will 
not  be  misused.  With  liberalized  entry,  strong  firms  will  not  be  able 
to  drive  the  price  up  because  of  the  threat  of  competition.  With  liber- 
alized entry,  strong  firms  will  have  little  incentive  to  underprice  their 
services  to  drive  out  old  competitors  because  there  is  always  the  threat 
of  new  competitors.  Thank  you.  Senator. 

CROSS  subsidy:  insubstantial  and  inefficient 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much. 

What  is  your  interest  in  this  cross-subsidy  issue  ?  Wliat,  if  anything, 
are  you  doing? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  Our  interest  in  it  is  to  make  sure  that  the  transporta- 
tion system  functions  effectively  and  efficiently.  It  has  been  our  view 
that  a  transportation  system  which  incorporates  large  elements  of 
cross-subsidy  is  not  operating  as  efficiently  as  it  ou^ht  to,  and  not  pro- 
viding the  types  of  service  the  market  actually  desires.  We  have  ex- 
amined at  the  cross-subsidy  issue  as  part  of  our  presentation  in  the 
domestic  passenger  fare  investigation.  Our  research  convinced  us  that 


673 

cross-subsidies  were  not  efficient,  and  that  there  was  very  little  cross- 
subsidy  in  the  fare  structure,  in  terms  of  the  actual  way  the  carriers 
actually  operated.  The  final  decision  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare 
investigation  sets  a  fare  tapes  which  is  very  close  to  what  is  perceived 
to  be  the  cross-taper  of  airline  costs  with  distance,  leaving  very  little 
room  for  cross-subsidy. 

FAILURE     or     cab's   ATTEMPT   TO   CROSS-SUBSIDIZE   LOCAL   SERVICE 
CARRIERS    IN    LATE    SIXTIES 

Our  v-iew  has  been  that  carriers  generally,  in  markets  where  they 
are  supposed  to  be  earning  losses  and  cross-subsidizing  these  losses 
with  other  profitable  services,  have  an  incentive  to  reduce  service  to  a 
minimum  level  consistent  with  minimizing  losses.  The  Board,  in  its 
staff  study  of  service  to  small  communities,  looked  at  the  question 
of  whether  its  route  policy  for  local  service  carriers  produced  cross^ 
subsidy  dollars  to  finance  low-denstiy  routes.  The  study  found  that, 
while  there  was  a  benefit  to  the  public,  in  terms  of  expanding  local 
service  carrier  opportunities,  local  service  carriers  were  not  earning 
cross-subsidy  dollars  in  the  new  markets  to  subsidize  low-density 
routes. 

[In  answer  to  an  inquiry  by  the  subcommittee  staff,  Mr.  Kutzke 
identified  the  study  referred  to  here  as  CAB,  Bureau  of  Operating 
Rights,  Service  to  Small  Communities  (March  1972),  and  recom- 
mended inclusion  in  the  record  of  the  following  passage  from  pt.  Ill, 
pp.  25-27,  of  that  study.  The  passage  referred  to,  follows :] 

******* 

♦  *  *  The  principal  specific  policy  for  achieving  the  seemingly  contradictory 
goals  of  reducing  subsidy  and  retaining  service  to  small  communities  was  cross- 
subsidization  under  the  now  abated  route-strengthening  program.  This  approach 
appeared  promising  in  the  high  tide  period  of  route  cases  in  the  middle  and  late 
sixties.  Under  the  revenue  sharing  and  ad  hoc  provisions  of  class  rate  IV,  subsidy 
was  declining,  and  applications  to  cease  operations  at  small  communities  were  at 
a  low  ebb.  However,  in  retrospect,  the  route  expansion  program  and  the  cross- 
subsidization  of  existing  routes  appear  to  be  counterproductive.  The  route- 
strengthening  policy  has  not  resulted  in  discemable  cross-subsidization  for  most 
of  the  locals.  It  has,  in  fact,  put  them  into  two  distinct  markets  requiring  two 
distinct  types  of  operations  and  equipment.  The  one  market  clearly  requires 
subsidization,  while  the  other  market  is  unable  to  provide  sufficient  funds  for  such 
subsidization.  . 

If  the  more  dense  markets  were  open  to  local  carriers  on  a  monopoly  basis, 
they  might  then  have  some  cliance  to  earn  sufficient  funds  for  cross-subsidization 
of  marginal  markets.'  Many  objections  could  be  raised  to  such  a  policy  of  cross- 
subsidization.  In  the  first  place,  such  a  policy  merely  shifts  the  burden  of  low- 
density  loss  points  from  Federal  taxpayers  to  airline  customers  travehng  on 
routes  which  generate  the  funds  for  subsidy.  Second,  higher  air  fares  in  monopoly 
markets  will  restrict  the  quantity  of  services  demanded  in  these  profitable  areas 
and  divert  potential  air  passengers  to  competitive  modes  of  travel. 

Although  the  government  may  wish  to  change  the  allocation  of  economic  re- 
sources, changing  the  allocation  through  cross-subsidization  is  an  inefficient 
means,  since  the  governiiunt  has  litrlc  assurance  that  its  desired  pattern  of  allo- 
cation will  result  from  the  actions  of  private  firms.  Cross-subsidization  ties  the 
amount  of  subsidized  service  to  the  level  of  profits  in  another  market.  There  is  no 


1  Monopoly  In  an  air  transportation  market  Is  a  neressarv  but  rot  a  ""^^^nt  conrlltlon 
for  cross-subsldlzatlon  policies.  The  market  must  also  be  isolated  from  meaningful  surface 
competition.  Otherwise,  an  airline  attempting  to  charge  higher  than  a  competitive  fare 
would  simply  drive  more  passengers  to  surface  modes. 


674 

assurance  that  this  method  will  lead  to  the  government's  desired  pattern  of 
service/  Further,  if  such  a  policy  of  cross-subsidization  were  to  work,  there  is 
reason  to  believe  that  carriers  no  longer  dependent  upon  government  subsidy 
payments  would  make  every  effort  to  shed  their  unprofitable  routes  and  points  of 
service  in  order  to  increase  business  profits.  The  incentive  to  perform  loss  services 
would  be  gone  and  they  would  retain  such  services  only  insofar  as  they  were 
forced  to  do  so.  This  would  likely  result  in  deteriorating  service  to  small  com- 
munities and  demands  for  a  new  class  of  subsidized  carriers  more  devoted  to  the 
provision  of  small  community  air  services. 

However,  the  local  service  carriers  have  not  been  moving  into  more  dense, 
profitable  routes  on  a  monopoly  basis.  Rather,  they  are  entering  markets  in 
competition  with  trunklines  earning  normal  (currently  below  normal)  profits. 
One  need  not  assume  predatory  competitive  practices  to  conclude  that  the 
amounts  needed  for  extensive  cross-subsidization  of  unprofitable  routes  will  not 
be  forthcoming  from  such  markets.  Since  there  is  a  taper  in  air  fares,  with  higher 
per  mile  fares  in  short-haul  markets  served  by  local  carriers  and  lower  per  mile 
fares  in  longer-haul  markets  of  trunklines,  a  fare  sufficient  to  generate  revenues 
for  cross-subsidization  of  low-density  short-haul  routes  would  yield  abnormally 
high  returns  to  the  trunklines.  This  would  also  interfere  with  the  relative  pricing 
in  long-haul  markets  not  involving  local  service  carriers.  As  a  complementary 
policy  to  assist  in  low-loss  situations,  cross-subsidization  can  and  will  work.  But 
as  a  solution  to  the  long  term  problem  of  service  to  small  communities,  cross- 
subsidization  is  uneconomic  and  can  make  only  a  minimal  contribution  to  the 
solution  of  the  basic  problems  of  air  service  to  small  communities. 


AIRLINES'   CLAIMS   OF   CROSS-SUBSIDY 

Senator  Kennedy.  Of  course,  there  was  clear  testimony  this  morn- 
ing from  some  of  the  airlines  that  the  cross-subsidy  still  exist,  and  is 
a  rather  important  aspect  of  this  network  of  air  transportation ;  this 
is  certainly,  the  testimony  of  United  Air  Lines. 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  Yes;  what  is  uncertain  about  United's  testimony — 
it  is  very  interesting  testimony — is  that  we  do  not  know  what  kind 
of  costing  they  were  using  in  their  description  to  you.  Were  they  talk- 
ing about  the  fare  calculation  methodology  used  the  domestic  pas- 
senger fare  investigation?  Were  they  talking  about  internal  costing? 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  thought  they  said  variable  costs. 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  They  said  variable  costs,  but  I  do  not  know  how  they 
calculated  variable  costs.  Are  they  using  United's  internal  cost  sys- 
tem, or  are  they  using  the  kind  of  regulatory  costing  system  the  Board 
uses.  Also,  we  do  not  know  how  important  those  markets  are  from  the 
description  given  this  morning.  Are  they  markets  that  are  operated  on 
an  entry-mileage  basis,  where  the  aircraft  is  being  routed  from  one 
city  to  another  for  an  operational  purpose,  or  are  they  markets  that 
even  in  a  competitive  system  the  carrier  would  desire  to  operate  for 
some  reason?  What  percentage  of  United  total  revenue  passenger- 
miles  were  produced  in  those  markets?  They  are  also  talking  in  terms 
of  segments,  but  they  certainly  are  not  the  most  important  segments 
in  the  United  system. 


Senator  Kennedy.  So,  what  is  your  feeling  about  whether  those 
kind  of  routes  would  be  abandoned  under  a  competitive  system? 


*  See  Luclen  Foldes,  "Domestic  Air  Transport  Policy,"  Part  II,  Economlca,  vol.  XXVIII 
(August  1961),  page  272. 


675 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  I  think  you  would  have  to  look  at  those  on  a  segment- 
by-segment  basis.  It  is  quite  possible  that  United  might  not  be  able 
to  serve  them,  but  it  is  possible  another  trunk  can-ier  rnight. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  consideration  should  be  given  to  an  appli- 
cant wlio  came  before  the  CAB  and  indicated  it  can  provide  service 
at  less  cost  to  the  traveling  consumer?  Should  that  be  given  a  very  high 
consideration,  or  a  low  consideration,  or  should  it  indeed  be  given  any 
consideration  ?  What  do  your  studies  show  ? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  Senator,  we  think  that  should  be  given  important  con- 
sideration, particularly  for  applicants  who  are  offering  a  new  type  of 
service  in  the  market,  for  example,  a  new  type  of  shuttle  service,  a  type 
of  very  high-density,  turnaround  service.  All  those  things  should  be 
given  consideration.  Under  existing  Board  procedure,  there  is  not 
much  opportunity  to  make  a  case  for  lower  fares  in  a  route  case,  be- 
cause at  the  present  time,  all  fares  are  calculated  according  to  proce- 
dures used  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation.  An  applicant 
would  not  norm. ally  be  filing  a  lower  fare  proposal.  The  Board  has 
not  indicated  they  are  going  to  give  decisional  significance  to  that, 
and  because  of  that,  the  carriers  do  not  propose  lower  rates  in  route 
cases.  They  do  not  make  them  a  key  element  of  their  service  proposal. 

Senator  Kennedy.  What  was  your  reaction  ?  Was  there  really  a 
moratorium  for  a  couple  of  years,  or  are  we  just  wrestling  with  words? 
And  whatever  you  want  to  classify  it,  do  you  think  it  was  legal  or 
illegal? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  Well,  you  may  wrestle  with  words,  but  the  fact  is,  in 
the  last.  5  years,  the  Board  simply  has  not  been  granting  very  many 
new  route  awards.  Applications  have  been  filed  and  the  Board  has  not 
heard  them,  or  they  dismissed  them  on  grounds  which,  in  earlier  cases, 
almost  would  have  certainly  gotten  the  carrier  a  hearing.  North  Cen- 
tral offered  a  list  of  such  cases  in  its  testimony  this  morning.  These 
cases  would  almost  certainly  have  been  set  for  a  hearing  and  new 
authorizations  would  have  been  granted  to  carriers.  Our  feeling  is  that 
a  carrier  that  files  an  application  with  the  Board  has  a  right  to  get  a 
speedy  hearing  on  that  application.  It  should  be  decided  pro  or  con. 

DESTRUCTI\TE   COMPETITION 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  have  important  responsibilities,  obviously, 
in  the  Department  of  Transportation  system.  Do  you  not  think  that 
if  there  were  more  route  entries,  that  you  might  have  destructive  com- 
petition, and  get  a  breakdown  in  the  whole  national  network  system? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  I  do  not  think  that  would  happen.  Senator.  At  least, 
our  information  does  not  suggest  it  would  happen.  The  economic 
studies  that  have  been  done  of  the  industry  do  not  suggest  this  is  the 
type  of  industry  which  would  produce  destructive  competition.  The 
experience  of  commuter  carriers  suggests  that  there  is  little  likelihood 
of  destructive  competition.  In  situations  of  freer  entry,  such  as  in 
California  and  in  Texas,  the  results  have  not  suggested  that  destruc- 
tive competition  has  resulted.  And,  finally,  the  Board  is  still  in  place 
to  monitor  what  is  happening  on  routes  and  it  can  police  any  potential 
destructive  competition. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Do  you  not  have  a  responsibility,  though,  in 
terms  of  the  development  of  automobile  or  bus,  air,  sea  transportation. 


676 

rail ;  and  how  does  all  of  that  fit  together  with  what  we  hear  in  terms 
of  air  transportation?  If  you  recognize  the  importance  of  the  develop- 
ment of  an  integrated  system,  perhaps  we  should  not  have  air  trans- 
portation in  some  areas,  and  people  ought  to  be  getting  there  by  rail- 
road or  by  bus,  saving  the  public  a  good  deal  of  money.  How  does  all 
of  that  funnel  through  your  office  in  coming  up  with  an  integrated 
system? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  It  actually  funnels  through  the  Assistant  Secretary 
for  policy.  He  makes  these  balancing  decisions.  Basically,  in  looking 
at  markets,  we  do  try  to  see  that  there  is  a  balanced  transportation 
system  in  place.  In  looking  at  subsidy  issues  particularly,  where  you 
have  conmiunities,  for  example  in  New  England,  who  have  sought  air 
service,  DOT  looked  very  hard  at  the  alternate  transportation  sys- 
tems available — buses  and  trains  and  the  kind  of  interstate  system  was 
provided — in  making  a  decision  as  to  whether  to  recommend  to  the 
Board  that  these  communities  should  receive  subsidized  air  service. 

Senator  Kennedy.  I  am  going  to  vield  to  Mr.  Breyer  for  just  a  few 
minutes  for  some  questions,  and  I  will  be  right  back. 

COURT    CHALLENGE    TO    "rOUTE    MORATORIUM" 

Mr.  Breyer.  Has  the  Department  of  Transportation  ever  considered 
taking  the  Board  to  court  on  the  route  moratorium  ? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  No,  sir.  We  have  not.  We  have  been  in  a  number  of 
CAB  cases.  We  have  not  been  in  many  domestic  route  cases  recently. 
We  just  have  not  focused  our  efforts  in  that  area.  I  understand  there 
is  at  least  one  case  pending  in  the  court  of  appeals  now  dealing  with 
this  issue.  I  believe,  it  is  the  San  Diego-Denver  case.  The  Department 
of  Justice  will  be  representing  the  United  States. 

STUDIES    ON    CROSS-SUBSIDY 

Mr.  Breyer.  I  would  like  to  get  back  to  the  question  of  cross-subsidy 
for  a  minute.  Do  you  have  studies  on  the  cross-subsidy  problem  ?  Have 
you  prepared  any  papers  ?  It  is  a  major  arjrument,  obviously,  and  we 
are  trying  to  find  out  from  the  industry  the  extent  to  which  routes  if 
any  are  cross-subsidized.  And,  as  you  point  out,  the  accounting 
problems  are  enormous.  How  do  you  figure  it  out  ? 

The  ultimate  question  was  pretty  clear.  The  ultimate  question  we 
would  like  to  know  is,  if  you  did  move  to  a  more  liberal  entry  system, 
a  more  liberal  rate  system,  along  some  kind  of  zone  reasonableness 
in  pricing  which  I  think  you  have  advocated,  what  routes  would  be 
lost  ?  Are  there  a  lot  of  them  ?  Will  those  people  not  get  service  ?  Where 
are  they  ?  How  many  are  there  ? 

Now,  I  think  you  and  the  Council  of  Economic  Advisers  believe 
there  are  not  many  that  will  not  get  service.  Is  that  right  ? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  That  is  right. 

Mr.  Breyer.  But  is  there  a  way  that  we  can  actually  get  into  this 
problem,  to  make  a  sensible  judgment  about  it?  We  have  asked  the 
ATA  to  produce  data  for  us,  and  we  have  asked  the  airlines  to  do  the 
same.  Could  you  try  to  provide  us  with  some  information,  some  back- 
up information,  to  help  us  answer  that  question  ? 


677 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  We  would  be  happy  to  submit  the  same  materials  to 
you  that  we  have  submitted  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investiga- 
tion already  and  anything  else  that  we  have  in-house. 

Mr.  Breyer.  You  might  check  and  see  if  it  woidd  be  all  right,  for 
example,  to  show  your  materials  to  the  airlines ;  and  perhaps  we  will 
try  to  ask  them  if  *it  is  all  right  to  the  same  extent  to  show  them  your 
materials,  so  we  can  perhaps 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  I  should  say  this.  In  the  domestic  passenger  fare  in- 
vestigation, where  you  would  have  thought  there  would  be  a  good 
hearing  record  on  the  cross-subsidy  issue  and  evidence  regarding 
what  routes  are  being  cross-subsidized,  by  which  routes  and  by  which 
carriers,  there  is  very  little  hard  factual  information.  Most  of  it  comes 
by  separating  carrier  costs  into  mileage  blocks  and  then  looking  at 
some  mileage  blocks  as  supposedly  providing  cross-subsidy  to  other 
mileage  blocks,  there  is  very  little  on  the  markets  themselves.  In  fact, 
I  suspect  that  you  would  almost  have  to  look  at  the  traffic  moving  m 
each  market  and  figure  out  independently  whether  that  route  could 
sustain  a  viable  operation  in  conjunction  with  other  routes. 

Mr.  Breyer.  One  thing  that  would  help  very  much  is,  could  you 
suggest  questions  we  might  ask  the  ATA  and  the  carriers?  We  are 
trying  to  create  a  dialog  that  might  actually  end  up  with  productive 
results.  Do  you  think  that  is  a  feasible  thing? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  It  certainly  is. 

TRANSITION    TO    COMPETITION 

Mr.  Breyer.  There  is  another  question  that  I  think  honestly  worries 
a  lot  of  carriers,  in  the  policies  that  you  and  the  Justice  Department 
have  suggested.  Are  the  new  liberal  entry  policy  and  zone  competition 
going  to  come  about  all  at  once,  or  is  there  going  to  be  some  kind 
of  an  interim  period,  if  we  are  moving  to  a  new  world  in  the  airline 
industry?  Is  it  possible  to  work  out  transitional  arrangements,  so 
that  people  are  not  hurt  too  severely,  people  who  have  relied  upon  the 
old  world  ?  Have  you  gone  into  that  at  all  ? 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  Yes;  I  will  comment  on  that.  First  of  all,  in  the  pas- 
senger fare  investigation,  the  Board  for  the  first  time  imposed  load 
factor  standards.  In  recognition  of  the  fact  the  carriers  needed  tran- 
sition time  to  begin  living  with  this  new  world,  the  Board  permitted 
several  years  of  transition.  They  established  a  52V2-percent  load  factor 
to  give  the  carriers  time  to  change.  That  standard  is  now  55  percent. 
Our  original  pricing  flexibility  proposal  in  the  DPFI  was  15  percent 
above  and  below  an  average  cost  curve.  We  felt  that  the  zone  could 
be  placed  in  operation  immediately  because  it  was  within  the  range 
that  reasonable  movements  of  price  could  be  expected,  without  causing 
dislocations. 

Mr.  Breyer.  If  there  has  been  thought  given  to  this  transitional 
problem,  we  would  certainly  appreciate  the  benefit  of  whatever 
thought  you  have  given  to  it. 

Mr.  KuTZKE.  The  notion  of  transition,  of  course,  is  ultimately 
dependent  upon  what  kind  of  a  legislative  proposal  we  make. 

Mr.  Brei-er.  Yes.  of  course  it  is,  and  what  I  am  really  saying  is, 
regardless  of  whether  the  system  is  a  good  one.  a  bad  one,  or  an  indif- 


678 

ferent  once,  people  have  relied  on  it,  and  they  have  built  up  a  tre- 
mendous amount  of  investment  on  it.  How  can  they  be  protected,  or 
not  hurt  too  badly  ? 

Another  question  that  I  think  concerns  quite  a  number  of  people, 
and  if  Mr.  Baker  has  any  comments  on  these  additions,  I  would 
appreciate  them  very  much. 

Mr.  Baker.  I  always  feel  free  to  volunteer,  sir. 

SAFETY   AND    COMPETITION 

Mr.  Breyer.  Another  issue  that  is  vei-y  worrying  to  a  number  of 
people,  and  perhaps  seriously  so,  is  if  we  move  to  this  more  com- 
petitive world,  what  about  airline  safety?  I  know  the  argument  is 
sometimes  treated  lightly,  but  1  think  there  are  people  who  are  wor- 
ried that,  in  this  new  world  of,  say,  a  hundred  carriers,  there  might 
be  such  tremendous  competition  that  inevitably,  management  would 
begin  to  skimp.  And  that  would  mean  less  safe  airplanes.  I  think 
that  was  mentioned  this  morning,  in  fact,  in  Mr.  de  Voursney's 
testimony.  It  is  a  very  interesting  point,  and  an  important  one.  Have 
you  given  thought  to  that  ? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  We  do  not  have  any  doubt  that  the  Federal  Aviation 
Administration  has  adequate  authority  to  police  airline  safety.  Sec- 
ond, I  think  that  the  kinds  of  operations  you  are  talking  about  are 
improbable.  We  are  not  talking  about  people  operating  on  shoestrings. 
We  are  talking  about  entry  by  well-financed,  soundly  managed  firms. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Have  you  put  the  question  to  the  Federal  Aviation 
Agency?  Have  they  been  forced  to  think  about  the  safety  problems 
that  might  exist  if  we  really  were  going  to  move  to  this  real  world? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  I  do  not  know  the  extent  they  have  studied  the  issue. 

Mr.  Breyer.  Could  you  check  on  that  ? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  Certainly. 

possibility  of  chaos 

Mr.  Breyer.  Another  thing  that  I  think,  again,  is  a  serious  prob- 
lem that  some  people  have  brought  up  is,  is  it  all  going  to  be  terribly 
confusing  ?  Will  it  be  possible  to  make  reservations  with  a  large  num- 
ber of  airlines?  Maybe  some  are  going  out  of  business  tomorrow, 
and  there  are  new  ones  coming  in  the  next  day.  The  competitive  idea 
sounds  all  right  on  paper,  and  then  you  think,  well,  there  are  all  these 
different  airlines  flying  around.  How  do  we  get  reservations?  How 
do  we  know  which  ones  are  in  business  today?  Is  that  a  serious 
problem  ? 

Mr.  Kutzke.  Not  in  our  judgment. 

Mr.  Breyer.  You  think  that  is  not  a  serious  problem?  Why  not? 

Mr,  Kutzke.  Either  Mr.  Baker  or  I  can  answer  it.  In  our  view, 
the  firms  that  are  going  to  be  in  the  airline  business  are  large,  well- 
financed  operations.  The  entry  that  we  have  had  in  the  last  couple 
of  years  demonstrates  this.  One  such  firm  is  Southwest  Airlines  in 
Texas.  I  do  not  know  that  anyone  has  ever  suggested  they  are  not  a 
well-financed,  well-managed,  safe  operation. 

The  last  time  the  Board  allowed  a  significant  amount  of  entry  in 
the  industry  was  the  certification  of  supplemental  carriers.  Ihey 


679 

operate  large  aircraft,  particularly  the  big  supplementals.  They 
operate  as  safely  as  any  other  carrier. 

Mr.  Baker.  I  would  like  to  amplify  on  that,  from  a  sort  of  legal 
standpoint ;  and  that  is,  I  do  not  think  anyone  contemplates  that  the 
carriers  are  going  to  operate  on  what  you  might  call  a  complete  free- 
for-all  basis.  You  do  not  have  to  have  detailed  economic  regulation 
in  order  to  impose  upon  a  carrier  various  common  carriage  opera- 
tions, if  that  is  what  you  want.  In  other  words,  you  can  say,  you 
have  got  to  have  tariffs,  you  have  got  to  have  schedules,  you  have 
got  to  fly  people  based  on  those  tariffs,  you  have  got  to  fly  your 
schedules  even  if  only  one  person  shows  up.  And  that,  basically,  would 
say  that  any  consistent  failure  to  perform  common  carriage  types  of 
obligations  would  be  grounds  for  not  allowing  you  to  fly  at  all ;  and 
the  notion  that  you  have  to  tie  together  common  carrier  obligations 
to  serve  everyone  in  equal  and  nondiscriminatory  terms  with  economic 
entry  is  just  a  mistake. 

Mr.  Breyer.  All  right. 

I  have  nothing  more,  and  I  think  we  will  ask  for  the  last  witness 
to  come  to  the  table,  and  then  I  think  we  will  recess  for  a  few  minutes. 
Mr.  James  Gagnon,  of  the  Airport  Operators  Council  ? 

We  will  stand  in  recess  for  5  minutes. 

fA  brief  recess  was  taken.] 

[The  prepared  statements  submitted  by  Mr.  Baker  and  Mr.  Kutzke 
follow.  A  followup  letter  from  DOT  pertaining  primarily  to  this 
day's  hearing  is  also  included.] 

Pbepaked   Statement  of  Donald  I.   Bakeb 

I  am  pleased  to  present  the  views  of  the  Department  of  Justice  on  the  nature 
and  effects  of  regulation  of  routes  and  entry  in  the  airline  industry,  and  to 
offer  some  tentative  proposals  for  reform. 

Two  weeks  ago,  Assistant  Attorney  General  Kauper  gave  this  subcommittise 
a  broad  overview  of  the  problems  associated  with  Federal  economic  regulation 
of  the  air  transportation  industry.  He  pointed  out  that  route  regulation  actually 
has  had  a  detrimental  effect  on  the  public  by  denying  the  American  people  the 
type  and  price  of  transportation  services  they  could  purchase  in  a  free  market- 
place. My  testimony  will  expand  upon  those  observations  as  they  relate  to  routes 
and  entry. 

At  the  outset,  however,  I  want  to  make  clear  that  these  questions  are  insepar- 
ably intertwined  with  the  question  of  airline  pricing  rules  to  be  discussed  next 
week.  In  other  words,  if  the  present  fixed  price  system  were  liberalized,  to  allow 
carriers  to  raise  or  lower  their  prices,  the  threat  of  new  entry  would  be  an 
important  factor  in  determining  whether  in  fact  those  prices  were  lower  rather 
than  higher.  Conversely,  if  entry  were  liberalized  (as  we  believe  it  should  be), 
but  nothing  were  done  about  pricing,  the  traveling  public  would  gain  little  in 
the  way  of  greater  benefits :  having  mor§  competitors  does  not  insure  better 
competition  for  the  public,  if  regulators  (or  statutes)  prevent  those  competitors 
from  competing.  Thus,  as  we  review  the  history  of  procompetitive  policy  in 
California  and  Texas  we  should  firmly  have  in  mind  the  fact  that  pricing  flexi- 
bility has  been  combined  with  essentially  open  entry  policy.  The  history  of  CAB 
entry  regulation  is  familiar,  but  quite  different. 

The  existing  statutory  standard  has  not  required  the  Board  to  operate  the 
way  it  has  in  fact  operated.  The  Board  must  consider  competition,  among  other 
things,  and  it  has  done  so — always  with  an  eye  to  the  existing  industry.  The 
statutory  standards  should  be  revised  to  deal  with  this  issue.  Not  only  must  the 
Board  be  required  to  give  greater  weight  to  the  competitive  process,  but  this  will 
only  prove  meaningful  if  combined  with  measures  that  deprive  the  Board  of 
authority  to  turn  down  a  route  and  entry  proposal  on  protectionist  grounds. 
Stated  another  way,  the  problem  has  not  been  with  the  Board's  authority,  but 


with  its  exercise  of  discretion.  Any  reform  has  got  to  look  toward  switching 
discretion  from  the  Board  to  the  managements  of  air  carriers  and  new  entrants. 

Nobody  contemplates  that  all  entry  regulation  would  be  eliminated.  We  and 
the  Administration  recognize  that  it  is  important  that  those  who  fly  do  so  in 
safe  planes,  and  that  they  be  flown  by  qualified  crews.  However,  these  particular 
factors  are  capable  of  being  quite  objective,  so  that  entry  can  be  tied  to  the 
necessary  Federal  Aviation  Administration  certificates.  Beyond  that,  entry  into 
common  carrier  fields  must  be  tied  to  ability  and  willingness  to  meet  common 
carrier  obligations.  In  other  words,  a  common  carrier  would  be  obliged  to  have 
published  tariffs  and  schedules  and  to  fly  in  accordance  with  them.  Any  sustained 
pattern  of  failure  to  comply  would  provide  a  basis  for  a  finding  that  the  carrier 
was  in  fact  unfit. 

We  intend,  whatever  form  our  proposals  ultimately  take,  to  insure  that  air 
service  will  continue  to  be  a  highly  dependable  means  of  travel.  Liberalized  entry 
need  not — and  indeed  is  not  likely  to — lead  to  "fly  by  night"  operators  coming 
into  the  business.  In  this  connection,  it  is  worth  realizing  that  the  whole  "com- 
mon carrier"  legal  concept  arose  at  common  law  in  what  was  very  often  an 
"open  entry"  environment  for  such  operations  as  stage  coaching  and  innkeeping. 

I.    ADVERSE   CONSEQUENCES   OF   ECONOMIC   BEGULATION 

In  enacting  the  Civil  Aviation  Act,  predecessor  to  today's  Federal  Aviation 
Act,  Congress  in  1938  believe  it  was  dealing  with  two  problems.  The  first  was 
the  need  to  bring  stability  to  the  government-subsidized  system  of  air  mail 
carriers  which  had  originated  in  the  late  twenties  and  had  been  regulated  on  a 
piecemeal  basis  since  that  time.  The  second  was  to  encourage  the  development 
of  the  infant  scheduled  air  transport  industry  in  the  chaotic  economic  conditions 
that  characterized  the  Depression.  Today,  mail  revenue  has  become  a  very  small 
proportion  of  total  airline  revenues,  and  the  major  trunk  carriers  no  longer 
receive  subsidy.  The  airline  industry  has  matured  and  attained  a  level  of  tech- 
nological sophistication  and  size  unimaginable  at  the  time  economic  regulation 
was  established.  Today  the  short  run  economic  prospects  that  confront  the  nation 
are  not  bright,  but  conditions  are  nowhere  near  the  "chaotic  and  destructive" 
conditions  that  were  perceived  as  threatening  the  very  existence  of  commercial 
aviation  in  1938. 

Although  the  conditions  that  led  to  the  institution  of  the  economic  regulation 
of  airlines  are  now  history,  the  regulatory  system  spawned  by  the  Depression 
still  is  very  much  with  us.  Consequently,  the  discussion  of  the  current  need  for 
regulation  must  center  on  an  evaluation  of  what  would  happen  to  the  aviation 
industry  if  regulation  were  substantially  reduced. 

The  economic  evidence  accumulated  over  the  past  several  years  convincingly 
demonstrates  that  under  regulation  passengers  have  been  compelled  to  pay 
higher  air  fares  and  suffer  unresponsive  service,  and  scarce  capital,  energy 
and  other  resources  have  been  wasted  by  the  airline  industry  through  over- 
investment in  aircraft  and  excessive  service  competition.^ 

In  exercising  the  regulatory  authority  over  routes  granted  to  it  by  Congress, 
the  CAB  has  restricted  the  number  of  carriers  permitted  to  perform  scheduled 
air  service,  and  also  has  restricted  the  ability  of  those  few  authorized  carriers 
to  enter  new  markets.  Today,  the  number  of  certificated  trunklines  is  half  as 
many  as  the  19  which  existed  in  1938,  though  the  number  of  revenue  passenger 
miles  flown  has  increased  238  times  since  that  year,  and  over  70  percent  of  the 
revenue  passenger  miles  flown  by  the  trunk  carriers  in  1972  were  flown  in 
markets  in  which  only  one  or  two  carriers  were  certificated.^  Carriers  who 
already  have  route  certificates  can  expect  that  additional  entry  into  their 
markets  will  be  restricted.  It  is  not  surprising,  then,  that  there  has  been  a  lack 
of  pricing  competition  in  the  airline  industry,  and  several  studies  have  demon- 
strated that  these  noncompetitive  prices  are  higher  than  they  would  be  in  the 
absence  of  competition.  Of  course,  the  lack  of  price  competition  is  aided  and 
abetted  by  the  CAB's  regulation  of  prices,  and  the  anticompetitive  incentives 
built  into  the  tariff  mechanism.  Regulatory  protection  from  the  threat  of  entry 
by  cari-iers  who  could  do  a  better  job  at  a  lower  price  is  surely  a  major  factor 
in  the  maintainance  of  high  prices. 


1  For  a  more  extensive  discussion  of  the  following  points  and  the  evidence  related  to 
them,  see  testimony  of  Assistant  Attorney  General  Thomas  E.  Kauper  before  this  sub- 
committee, Feb.  6,  1975. 

a  The  Domestic  Route  System,  CAB  1974,  appendix  A,  table  10. 


681 

Perverse  as  it  may  seem,  the  existence  of  route  regulation  actually  increases 
the  incentive  for  airlines  to  engage  in  predatory  pricing  or  other  anticompeti- 
tive measures.  An  airline  knows  that  if  it  manages  to  drive  a  competitor  out 
of  a  market  with  regulated  entry,  it  may  obtain  increased  profits  to  cover  earlier 
losses. 

This  observation  leads  to  an  important  point:  contrary  to  charges  made  by 
proponents  of  continued  route  regulation,  it  is  not  competition  that  leads  to 
waste  in  the  airline  industry.  Rather,  waste  results  from  the  attempts  of  business- 
men to  fulfill  their  normal  desire  to  compete  in  a  regulatory  environment  which 
precludes  meaningful  entry  and  price  competition.  Consequently,  airlines  engage 
in  capacity  competition,  give  away  alcoholic  beverages,  and  offer  other  "frills" 
which  probably  would  not  be  provided  if  free  entry  and  price  competition  were 
permitted.  Thus,  regulation  has  not  led  to  high  industry  profits;  it  has  led  to 
higher  costs  which  dissipate  the  excess  revenue  generated  by  the  industry's 
noncompetitive  prices. 

Excess  capacity  which  may  exist  in  markets  where  there  is  more  than  one 
carrier,  result  not  from  the  existence  of  increased  carrier  entry  and  the  resultant 
competition,  but  from  the  fact  that  the  regulatory  structure  prevents  carriers 
from  competing  in  price  and  forces  them  to  compete  through  the  provision  of 
services  which  might  not  be  as  important  to  passengers  as  a  price  cut.  Intra- 
state carriers  in  California  and  Texas  operating  on  a  competitive,  unregulated 
environment,  have  offered  higher  load  factors  and  lower  prices  than  route- 
regulated  carriers.^ 

Supporters  of  the  current  regulatory  scheme  make  the  charge  that  without 
regulation  of  entry,  service  would  be  undependable.  Experience,  however,  does 
not  demonstrate  that  this  would  be  the  case.  First,  without  regulation,  the 
profit  motive  would  return  to  its  normal  governing  role:  Businessmen  would 
recognize  that  if  they  fail  to  provide  dependable  service,  they  soon  lose  their 
customers.  Second,  in  the  CAB's  own  New  England  service  investigation,  the 
Administrative  Law  Judge  found  that  while  individual  air  taxis  which  are 
not  regulated  by  the  Board  might  enter  and  leave  particular  markets,  service 
continued  to  be  provided  by  new  operators,  and  the  turnover  on  identity  of 
firms  providing  that  service  did  not  inconvenience  the  public,  as  opposed  to  the 
carriers  themselves. 

It  is  not  really  all  that  surprising  that  private  businesses  not  subject  to 
economic  regulation  of  entry  and  exit  can  provide  a  dependable,  widespread 
service  network.  For  instance,  there  is  no  Federal  Hotel  and  Motel  Administra- 
tion, but  the  large  chains  do  provide  nationwide  reservations  so  a  traveler  may 
arrange  for  lodging  in  a  distant  city  and  expect  to  find  the  hotel  in  business 
and  his  room  awaiting  him  upon  his  arrival.  But  you  can  be  assured,  had  a 
Motel  Administration  been  established  in  the  thirties,  any  attempt  to  abolish 
it  today  would  be  met  by  widely  publicized  fears  of  the  collapse  of  the  American 
economy  due  to  the  inability  of  business  travelers  to  make  dependable  hotel 
and  motel  reservations. 

Proponents  of  existing  route  regulation  contend  that  without  government  regu- 
lation of  entry  and  exit,  our  present  air  route  system  would  severely  contract, 
leaving  numerous  small  communities  without  the  air  service  they  now  enjoy  under 
regulation.  Whether  this  is  likely  or  not  is  a  highly  complex  issue,  but  it  is  a 
crucial  one  which  must  be  resolved,  because  passengers  on  less  heavily  traveled 
routes  should  neither  suffer  unnecessarily  in  order  to  reform  the  system,  nor 
receive  hidden  and  quite  expensive  subsidies  without  an  explicit  and  convincing 
justification. 

This  country's  domestic  air  route  system  is  a  complicated,  extensive  netvvork 
served  by  trunk  air  carriers,  local  service  air  carriers,  intrastate  air  carriers, 
small  carriers  exempt  from  regulation  under  part  298  of  the  Board's  regulation,' 
supplemental  carriers,  and  ^eve^•al  other  small  specialist  carriers  regulated  by  the 
Board.  There  are  approximately  817  airports  in  the  United  States  which  provide 
service  by  certificated  airlines.^  Simple  arithmetic  indicates  that  there  are  thus 
over  a  half  million  domestic  city-pairs'  in  which  airline  travel  is  theoretically 


'Testimony  of  William  A.  Jordan  before  this  subcommittee,  Feb.  14,  1975,  p.  33.  The 
intrastate  carriers  also  have  experienced  markedly  lower  costs.  Id. 

*  14  CFR  pt.  298.  ,  „  .  ^      , 
5  Civil  Aviation  Research  and  Development  Policy  Study,  Department  of  Transportation/ 

National  Aeronautics  and  Space  Administration,  1971,  supporting  papers,  p.  4-34. 

•  A  city-pair  is  a  routing  between  two  cities.  It  is  more  precise,  though  not  as  conven- 
tional, to  refer  to  individual  routings  as  airport  pairs,  thus  reflecting  actual  passenger 
routings  when  more  than  one  airport  serves  one  city  or  one  airport  serves  more  than  one 
city.  Because  traffic  information  is  not  usually  available  for  airport  pairs,  the  term  city- 
pair  is  used  in  this  testimony. 


682 

possible.  But  alternative  transportation  is  available  in  many  city-pairs,  convenient 
air  service  is  not  available  in  many  of  them,  and  many  of  them  simply  do  not 
have  any  passengers  who  wish  to  fly  them.  As  a  result,  most  air  travel  actually 
takes  place  over  a  very  small  percentage  of  these  theoretical  city-pair  routings. 
As  the  Air  Transport  Association  has  stated  earlier  in  these  hearings,  30  percent 
of  domestic  traffic  is  produced  in  the  70  largest  city-pairs,  40  percent  in  the  840 
next  largest,  and  another  30  percent  in  the  remaining  city-pairs. 

Apart  from  basic  .«upply  and  demand  considerations,  there  are  primarily  three 
influences  on  the  number  of  city-pairs  which  receive  service :  subsidy,  cross-sub- 
sidy, and  the  advantages  of  an  integrated  route  system.  In  order  to  examine  the 
influence  of  regulation  on  the  pattern  of  service,  it  is  necessary  to  look  at  each 
of  these  factors. 

Section  406  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  empowers  the  Board  to  grant  subsidy 
to  air  carriers,  and  9  local  service  carriers  and  several  Alaskan  carriers  presently 
receive  subsidy  of  approximately  $70  million  per  year.  This  statutory  provision 
would  allow  the  Board  to  insure  the  provision  of  air  service  to  remote  com- 
munities even  if  there  were  no  economic  regulation  of  air  carriers  at  all.  There 
is  considerable  agreement  that  the  present  method  of  awarding  subsidy  is  back- 
ward and  inefficient,'  but  the  history  of  the  airline  subsidy  program  shows  that 
the  Congress  can  insure  service  to  remote  points  if  it  wants  to  pay  the  price.  The 
present  low  level  of  subsidy  compared  to  the  total  air  transportation  system  in- 
dicates that  subsidy,  though  expensive,  is  not  a  staggering  problem. 

Some  defenders  of  the  status  quo  argue  that  if  the  government  does  not  limit 
entry  and  exit,  it  will  be  unable  to  require  air  carriers  to  serve  the  bad  markets 
with  the  good.  Without  government  regulation,  the  argument  goes,  airlines  would 
all  serve  exclusively  the  largest  markets,  and  small  markets  would  go  unserved. 
In  order  to  deal  with  these  arguments,  it  is  necessary  to  distinguish  between  the 
next  two  quite  different  factors  which  lead  carriers  to  serve  "bad"  markets  with 
the  "good"  ones :  cross-subsidization  and  route  system  integration. 

Each  of  these  two  factors  allows  an  air  carrier  which  serves  more  than  a  single 
city-pair  to  serve  as  part  of  that  system  city-pair  which  would  not  be  served  in 
isolation.  System  integration  may  allow  this  for  a  number  of  reasons :  the  small 
city -pairs  may  be  one  segment  in  a  larger  city  pair,  as  when  service  from  A  to  B 
is  not  economically  viable,  but  service  from  A  to  B  to  C  is  viable.  The  smaller 
market  may  simply  be  "entry  mileage"  on  the  way  to  one  larger  market  from 
another,  or  from  a  maintenance  base.  Or  the  incremental  cost  of  adding  a  small 
city-pair  to  a  given  aircraft  routing  may  be  low  because  there  is  otherwise  un- 
usable aircraft  time  which  can  be  used  in  that  city-pair.  This  latter  factor  is 
important,  because  many  city-pairs  do  not  have  enough  traffic  potential  by  them- 
selves to  use  all  the  capacity  generated  by  a  modern  aircraft  used  full  time  in 
that  city-pair.* 

These  efficiencies  from  more  extensive  operations  are  offset  by  the  increased 
costs  of  managing  a  complex  and  far-flung  route  network  with  diverse  operational 
characteristics,  so  that  above  a  very  small  minimum  size,  air  carriers  do  not 
experience  any  substantial  economies  of  scale."  But  where  potential  route  system 
economies  exist,  they  can  result  in  increased  service  and  lower  cost  to  consumers, 
and  the  regulatory  system  should  encourage  operations  which  capitalize  on  them. 

It  seems  clear,  however,  that  route  regulation  is  not  necessary  for  the  full  ex- 
ploitation of  the  advantages  of  route  system  integration.  Without  regulation, 
carriers  have  an  incentive  to  be  efficient  and  expand  their  business  operations,  and 
they  can  be  expected  to  do  so.  Indeed,  route  certification  decreases  an  air  carrier's 
ability  to  adapt  and  expand  its  route  system  in  response  to  changing  conditions, 
and  this  inflexibility  undoubtedly  explains  a  substantial  portion  of  the  higher 
costs  and  prices  which  are  associated  with  regulated  air  carriers. 

The  absence  of  economies  of  scale  in  the  airline  industry  also  indicates  that 
addition  of  another  city-pair  to  a  carrier's  route  system  does  not  always  mean 
increased  efficiency  or  lower  costs.  Costs  can  actually  be  increased  by  route 
Rjstems  which  are  unduly  complex,  do  not  allow  efficient  gathering  of  traffic, 
or  require  the  operation  of  too  many  different  aircraft  types.  Under  regulation, 


'  See,  Service  to  Small  Commnnltles.  CAB  staff  study.  1972  ;  Eads  :  The  Local  Service 
Airline  Experiment,  1972.  The  Board  itself  requested  introduction  of  legislation  in  the 
93d  Congress  which  would  have  authorized  it  to  conduct  a  limited  experiment  in  procuring 
subsidized  service  on  a  competitive  bidding  contract  basis. 

8  See,  Testimony  of  Willi5(m  A.  Jordan,  supra. 

*  Testimony  of  Thomas  Kauper,  supra,  pp.  15-17. 


683 

a  carrier  has  incentives  to  keep  inefficient  routes  on  its  system  because  if  it 
drops  them,  the  route  authority  might  be  hard  to  get  back  from  the  government, 
and  another  carrier  might  obtain  a  certificate  for  the  route,  making  reentry  even 
more  difficult  or  impossible.  The  increased  costs  of  retention  of  uneconomic 
routes  because  of  regulation  increases  the  overall  level  of  air  earner  costs,  which 
may  well  decrease  their  ability  to  offer  profitable  service  in  smaller  markets. 
Thus  the  result  of  route  regulation  is  to  introduce  costly  rigidity  which  de- 
creases, rather  than  increases,  the  air  carriers'  ability  to  exploit  the  economic 
efficiencies  of  an  integrated  route  system. 

Government  regulation  of  market  exit  is  often  advocated  as  a  means  of  pre- 
venting disruptive  service  terminations  to  small  communities.  There  appears 
to  be  no  evidence  that  free  exit,  subject  to  notice  provisions,  would  create  any 
serious  inconvenience  to  the  public.  But  more  importantly,  regulation  of  exit, 
rather  than  increasing  the  amount  of  service  to  small  markets,  probably  de- 
creases it.  When  air  carriers  are  not  free  to  leave  markets  which  prove  to  be 
unprofitable,  they  will  be  more  conservative  in  entering  doubtful  markets, 
and  fewer  of  those  markets  will  actually  receive  service. 

In  contrast  to  actual  efficiencies  from  route  system  integration,  cross-subsidy 
is  an  expensive,  inequitable,  and  unreliable  means  of  including  service  in  lightly 
traveled  city-pairs.  Regulation  of  entry  to  extract  monopoly  profits  from  pas- 
sengers on  some  routes  so  that  those  profits  can -theoretically  be  used  to  subsi- 
dize service  to  passengers  on  other  routes  is  a  sub  rosa  tax  which  Congress  prob- 
ably would  not  explicitly  allow. 

Finally,  leaving  aside  the  extreme  undesirability  of  cross-subsidization  through 
route  regulation,  there  is  considerable  economic  evidence  that  it  simply  does 
not  work  in  the  regulated  airline  system.'"  Increased  revenues  resulting  from 
restrictions  on  entry  in  highly  traveled  markets  are  utilized  to  support  exces- 
sive service  competition  rather  than  to  subsidize  otherwise  unprofitable  markets. 
The  inflated  level  of  service  and  atteuaant  costs  thus  make  it  more  difficult 
for  carriers  to  serve  lightly  traveled  markets  at  all. 

In  summary,  there  is  little  to  Indicate  that  regulation  brings  air  service  to 
small  communities  which  otherwise  would  not  have  service.  Cross-subsidization 
is  theoretically  possible  under  route  regulation,  but  it  doesn't  work  and  should 
not  be  attempted.  Route  system  efficiencies,  which  are  a  real  source  of  other- 
wise unavailable  service,  are  more  available  without  route  regulation.  Accord- 
ingly, we  question  the  need  for  continuation  of  the  present  close  regulation  of 
individual  routes. 

While  it  is  true  that  a  liberalized  entry  policy  may  cause  replacement  of 
carriers  serving  particular  markets,  such  an  occurrence  need  not  be  detrimental 
to  the  public,  or  adversely  affect  the  level  of  service  to  smaller  communities 
which  is  now  rendered  by  certificated  carriers.  For  instance,  Executive  Air- 
lines entered  the  Boston-Bar  Harbor  market  in  the  summer  of  1968  and  pro- 
vided substitute  service  for  Northeast  Airlines  during  the  4-month  summer 
season.  In  1970,  Executive  was  ousted  from  the  market  by  Bar  Harbor  Airways, 
another  commuter  carrier,  after  Bar  Harbor  had  begun  to  offer  year-round 
non-stop  service  between  Boston  and  Bar  Harbor.  As  a  result.  Bar  Harbor  re- 
ceived a  level  of  service  to  Boston  for  in  excess  of  that  which  it  had  been  receiv- 
ing. While  Executive  may  have  left  the  market  because  it  was  operating  at  a 
loss,  the  public  was  benefited  by  the  substitution  of  a  carrier  willing  to  offer 
year  round  service  responsive  to  the  needs  of  that  community.  Hence,  the  basic 
reason  for  Executive's  ouster  was  the  superior  service  offered  by  Bar  Harbor 
Airways,  and  not  "destructive  competition"  resulting  from  free  entry.  If  a  CAB 
route  proceeding  were  necessary,  I  suspect  that  Bar  Harbor  Airways  would  be 
still  trying  (or  have  long  since  given  up  trying)  to  get  on  the  route;  and  Bar 
Harbor  passengers  would  still  be  waiting  for  year-round  non-stop  service  to 
Boston. 

Improved  and  more  responsive  service  is  not  the  only  public  benefit  from 
restoring  the  airline  industry  to  the  relatively  "free  entry"  conditions  it  experi- 
ences when  there  is  no  extensive  economic  regulation.  For  years,  studies  have 
been  noting  that  when  entry  into  intrastate  air  transportation  in  California 
and  Texas  was  relatively  free  of  regulatory  barriers  to  entry,  intrastate  air 


">  Statement  of  Gary  L.  Seevers,  and  James  C.  Miller  III,  Council  of  Economic  Advisers, 
Feb.  6,  1975  ;  Statement  of  William  Jordan,  supra  ;  G.  Douglas  and  J.  Miller,  Regulation 
of  Domestic  Air  Transport,  pp.  97-103,  162,  174. 


684 

carriers  offered  dramatically  lower  prices  than  CAB-regulated  carriers  and 
made  profits  doing  so."  Professor  Jordan's  testimony  before  this  subcommittee 
last  week  indicates  that  the  great  fare  differences  between  regulated  and  un- 
regulated carriers  are  not  freak  results  accounted  for  by  peculiar  factors  other 
than  economic  regulation.  If  there  were  any  reasons  for  these  dramatic  price 
differences  other  than  regulation,  surely  they  would  have  been  demonstrated 
by  now.  The  Board's  response  to  this  situation  has  been  to  allow  its  regulatees 
to  parallel  the  intrastate  routes  of  the  low-price  intrastate  carriers,  charging  low 
prices  to  intrastate  passengers  and  high  prices  to  interstate  passengers.  The 
difference  in  price  is  not  based  on  any  peculiar  route  characteristic,  just 
competition. 

The  airline  industry,  like  any  closed  system,  can  use  new  blood.  The  evidence 
is  clear  that  when  new  competitors  are  able  to  enter  the  airline  industry,  they 
bring  with  them  new  talent  and  new  ideas  in  operations,  marketing  and  service. 

U.    SUBSTANTIVE    8TATUTOBY   PROBLEMS 

The  substantive  provisions  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  which  govern  entry 
are  themselves  the  heart  of  the  problem,  for  they  provide  the  Board  with  vague 
guidance  as  to  the  policies  it  should  follow  and  allow  restriction  of  competition. 

Under  the  Act,  the  Board  is  empowered  to  issue  route  certificates  to  applicants 
who  are  "fit,  willing,  and  able"  to  i^erform  the  service  they  wish  to  provide,  but 
such  a  certificate  may  only  be  granted  if  "such  transportation  is  required  by  the 
public  convenience  and  necessity ;"  otherwise  the  application  is  to  be  denied.^ 
The  Act  also  requires  that  the  Board,  in  exercising  its  authority,  must  consider 
"competition  to  the  extent  necessary  to  assure  the  sound  development  of  an  air 
transportation  system.  .  .  ."  ^'  With  directives  this  broad,  it  is  not  surprising 
that  CAB  regulation  of  the  air  transportation  system  exhibits  a  confusing  pattern 
of  "regulated  competition"  which  has  resulted  in  waste  and  high  prices. 

Through  its  power  to  issue  certificates,  and  to  subject  them  to  "reasonable 
terms,  conditions,  and  limitations"  as  required  by  the  public  interest,"  the  CAB 
has  wide  discretion  to  determine  the  extent  of  competition  in  commercial  avia- 
tion. The  Board,  however,  was  not  left  entirely  free  to  adapt  the  domestic  route 
structure  to  meet  the  changing  conditions  of  the  airline  industry  during  its  rapid 
growth  from  the  passage  of  the  Act  in  1938  to  the  present. 

First,  Congress  embodied  in  the  Act  a  concept  of  "security  of  route."  In  gen- 
eral, the  CAB  may  not  revoke  a  certificate  unless  it  finds  an  "intentional  failure" 
by  a  carrier  to  comply  with  the  Act  or  a  Board  order,  and  only  if  the  carrier 
thereafter  refuses  to  correct  the  failure  after  notice  by  the  Board."^  Temporary 
suspensions,  as  opposed  to  revocations,  may  be  ordered  upon  a  mere  finding  that 
the  "public  convenience  and  necessity"  so  require.'*  Any  significant  reduction  in 
an  existing  carrier's  operating  authority  could  only  come  about  through  the 
permanent  deletion  of  that  carrier's  authorization  to  serve  a  particular  point, 
with  the  consequence  that  airlines  and  the  Board  look  upon  route  certificates  as 
important  assets,  giving  holders  the  perpetual  right  to  do  business  in  a  particular 
market.  Carriers,  though,  may  sometimes  agree  to  suspend  unprofitable  routes, 
or  two  or  more  carriers  may  agree,  if  the  Board  approves,  to  reduce  competition 
through  mutual  suspensions  of  authorities. 

Second,  the  1938  Civil  Aviation  Act  "grandfathered"  the  operating  rights  which 
the  then-existing  19  major  carriers  had  under  airmail  contracts  awarded  in  the 
late  twenties  and  the  thirties."  These  mail  routes,  having  their  genesis  in  the 
Hoover  Administration,  thus  became  the  nucleus  of  the  domestic  route  structure, 
with,  for  example,  TWA  and  United  being  the  major  transcontinental  carriers, 
and  Eastern  having  the  Eastern  Seaboard  routes. 


n  Testimony  of  William  A.  Jordan  before  this  subcommittee,  Feb.  14,  1975  ;  Testimony  of 
Gary  Seevers  and  James  C.  Miller  III  before  this  subcommittee,  Feb.  6,  1975. 

iM9  U.S.C.  sec.  1371(d). 

«49  U.S.C.  sec.  1302(d). 

"49  U.S.C.  sec.  1371(e)(1). 

15  49  U.S.C.  sec.  1371(g).  .  ^   .  .x.     t>       ^   ^ 

"  Id.  This  power  is  rarely  exercised  without  carrier  acquiescence  but  the  Board  nas 
been  found  empowered  to  suspend  one  carrier  so  as  to  grant  service  to  another,  though 
the  incumbent  desires  to  perform  the  service.  Western  Airlines  v  CAB,  495  F.2d  145  (D.C. 
Cir.  1974). 

"  Civil  Aeronautics  Act  of  1938.  sec.  401(e)  (1),  525  Stat.  973. 


685 

Third,  applications  for  new  route  authiority,  or  modifications  to  existing  author- 
ity, can  be  granted  only  after  notice  and  hearing,^**  and  under  the  Ashbacker 
doctrine,^*  the  Board  must  hold  a  full  evidentiary  hearing  when  there  are  mul- 
tiple applications  for  the  same  authority.  Thus,  when  a  carrier  seeks  authority 
in  an  important  market,  it  is  certain  to  face  the  prospect  of  long,  complex  proceed- 
ings, with  the  possibility  that  the  losing  party  will  petition  for  juaicial  review. 

Lastly,  once  a  carrier  is  granted  a  certificate,  it  is  free  to  use  whatever  equip- 
ment it  wishes,  or  establish  whatever  schedules  it  pleases,  as  long  as  it  operates 
a  minimum  amount  of  service.'"  As  a  result,  carriers  remain  free  to  engage  in 
schedule  competition,  though  protected  against  new  entry  by  the  need  for  a 
potential  entrant  to  get  a  certificate,  and  against  rate  competition  by  rate 
regulation. 

In  administering  the  authority  thus  granted  it,  the  Board  has  developed  an 
elaborate  system  of  restrictions  which  prevent  carriers  from  actually  competing 
on  routes  where  both  have  certificate  authority.  Certificates  granted  by  the  Board 
are  of  a  "linear"  nature  in  that  they  authorize  service  among  city-pair  markets 
with  a  terminal  or  terminals,  sometimes  several  intermediate  points,  and  another 
terminal  or  terminals  on  the  other  end.  Airlines  can  operate  among  the  various 
points  on  the  routes  by  various  combinations  of  nonstop,  multistop,  and  connecting 
service.  The  Board,  however,  may  condition  these  otherwise  flexible  route  awards 
with  several  types  of  restrictions.  By  means  of  a  single  plane  restriction,  the 
Board  may  require  that  service  between  two  points  on  a  route  not  be  by  a  single 
plane,  but  only  by  connecting  flights.  Thus,  an  airline  having  such  a  restriction 
may  be  put  at  a  disadvantage  because  it  must  force  passengers  to  change  planes 
at  the  intermediate  city  while  its  competitor's  passengers  may  stay  on  the  same 
aircraft.  The  Board  also  may  require  carriers  to  make  one  or  more  intermediate 
stops,  preventing  nonstop  service,  and  it  may  require  a  carrier  travelling  to  a 
city  to  continue  beyond  that  city  to  another  destination.  Such  a  "long-haul"  re- 
striction limits  an  airline's  ability  to  provide  schedule  competition  in  high- 
density  markets  by  forcing  aircraft  added  to  serve  just  the  major  city-pair  to 
continue  onward  to  the  next  destination. 

In  deciding  whether  to  permit  a  carrier  to  enter  a  particular  market,  the  CAB 
uses  criteria  which  limit  the  ability  of  carriers  to  enter  and  compete  with  each 
other.  The  existence  of  restrictive  standards  means  that  procedural  reform  can 
have  only  a  limited  ability  to  increase  the  amount  of  competitive  entry  in  the  air- 
travel  network.  Procedural  reform  can  insure  that  entrants  are  not  discouraged 
by  the  prospect  of  delay  in  handling  their  applications,  insure  that  they  will  be 
able  to  fully  present  their  case,  and  enable  them  to  meet  claims  raised  by  chail- 
lengers.  But  even  assuming  good  procedures,  one  can  expect  that  the  certification 
process,  as  presently  constituted,  will  result  in  an  unjustifledly  low  amount  of 
competition  in  the  industry. 

The  first  step  the  Board  .reaches  in  deciding  whether  the  "public  convenience 
and  necessity"  requires  new  competitive  service,  or  the  removal  of  a  certificate 
restriction  so  as  to  permit  more  effective  competition,  is  the  decision  of  whether 
there  is  "room"  for  an  additional  carrier  in  the  market.  This  consideration  focuses 
on  whether  the  current  traffic  or  traffic  in  a  forecast  period  would  profitably  sup- 
port the  additional  service  contemplated  by  the  applicant.  Particularly  in  a  less- 
expansive  economic  climate,  the  Board  also  may  look  at  the  effect  of  new  entry 
on  existing  carriers,  that  is,  the  amount  of  traffic  which  would  be  diverted  from 
the  existing  carrier  to  the  new  entrant.  Almost  always,  the  issue  of  whether  there 
is  room  for  a  new  competitor  becomes  the  key  issue. 

Once  the  decision  is  made  to  authorize  entry,  the  next  step  is  to  select  the  car- 
rier, if  more  than  one  carrier  is  proposing  to  serve  the  market.  Such  a  decision  is 
diflScult,  for  many  carriers  are  able  to  offer  ireasonably  similar  services.  The  Board 
may  take  into  consideration  the  "service"  benefits  that  may  flow  from  a  grant  of 
new  authority  to  a  carrier,  that  is,  the  extent  to  which  the  addition  of  the  route 
to  the  carrier's  svstem  will  enable  it  to  improve  or  increase  service  throughout  its 
system,  or  offer  more  connecting  flights  or  through  plane  service  to  the  newly 
authorized  market.  However,  carrier  selection  will  often  depend  on  the  Board's 
desire  to  strengthen  a  paTticular  carrier,  by  giving  a  financially  weak  carrier  a 
profitable  route,  or  its  desire  to  minimize  the  amount  of  diversion  from  incumbent 


«49  U.S.C.  sec.  1371(c). 

i»  Ashbacker  Rndio  Coro.  v  FCC,  326  U.S.  327  (1946). 

10  40  TT  S  O    SAC     1S71  ( o\ 


U.S.C.  sec.  1371(e)'. 


carriers,  if  the  new  service  would  siphon  off  connecting  traffic  from  an  incumbent 
carrier  to  other  routes  on  the  new  entrant's  system.  Hence,  the  selection  of  the 
carrier  to  receive  new  authority  may  consciously  or  unconsciously  depend  on 
"political"  factors  involving  the  attitude  of  the  Board  toward  a  particular  car- 
rier and  its  management.  As  long  as  the  Board  has  the  discretion  to  choose  among 
competing  applicants  on  the  basis  of  rather  subjective  criteria,  such  influences 
may  remain  regardless  of  the  procedures  involved. 

The  result  of  the  Board's  restrictive  entry  policies,  coupled  with  the  permanent 
nature  of  domestic  route  authority,  has  been  the  creation  of  a  static  route  struc- 
ture. With  the  exception  of  the  recent  certification  of  Air  New  England  as  a  local 
service  carrier,  there  has  been  no  certification  of  a  new  domestic  scheduled  car- 
rier since  local  service  carriers  were  certificated  following  World  War  II.  The 
only  trunk  carriers  serving  the  public  are  those  which  received  grandfather  rights 
in  1938.  What  the  Board  seems  to  have  done  is  to  create  and  perpetuate  a  -tier" 
system  of  carriers  with  fouir  levels.  First  are  the  large  trunks,  smaller  trunks,  the 
local  serivce  carriers,  and  on  the  bottom,  the  part  298  "commuter  carriers." 

The  Board  has  resisted  the  entry  of  new  groups  into  the  aviation  business,  and 
Congress  has  sometimes  seen  fit  to  .require  the  Board  to  certify  new  carriers.  For 
instance,  in  1962,  Congress  required  the  certification  of  supplemental  carriers 
which  engage  in  charter  only  service.'^  Similarly,  throughout  the  tremendous  ex- 
pansion of  air  travel  since  1938,  and  the  disappearance  through  merger  of  several 
smaller  trunks.  United,  American,  and  Trans  World  remained  the  largest  carriers, 
with  Delta  only  recently  edging  out  Eastern,  the  other  of  the  Big  Four  carriers 
receiving  grandfather  rights  in  1938.^^ 

Through  Board-approved  mergers,  the  number  of  trunk  carriers  has  declined 
from  19  to  10,  and  with  the  addition  of  the  9  local-service  carriers,  the  total 
number  of  significant  carriers  remains  the  same  as  it  was  in  1938.  In  1972  the 
original  10  trunks  carried  approximately  92  percent  of  all  revenue  passenger 
miles,  with  the  local  service  carriers  having  only  about  8  percent  of  the  traffic." 
While  the  percentage  of  traffic  carried  by  the  Big  Four  has  declined,  concentra- 
tion remains  high.  In  1938,  these  airlines  carried  82.5  percent  of  all  domestic 
revenue  passenger  miles,  and  by  1972  this  amount  had  dropped  to  only  60.5  per- 
cent,^ at  a  time  when  the  total  number  of  passenger  miles  flown  increased  from 
476  million  to  over  114  billion. 

The  expansion  of  route  authority  within  this  tiered  system  has  been  ad  hoc : 
while  the  Board  has  occasionally  established  formal  priorities  for  hearing  route 
cases,'*  it  has  never  systematically  examined  the  overall  route  system  or  followed 
a  comprehensive  plan  in  authorizing  new  authority.  As  a  recent  CAB  study  put 
it :  "The  only  occasion  upon  which  the  Government  has  determined  or  influenced 
the  development  of  the  route  system  on  other  than  an  incremental  basis  was 
under  the  Hoover  Administration  mail  contract  program.  .  .  ."  ^ 

This  situation  is  all  the  more  unfortunate  because  change  under  the  present 
system  is  slow  and  costly.  The  typical  route  proceeding,  which  may  involve 
lengthy  trial-type  hearings,  takes  at  least  one  to  2  years  to  process."  The  CAB 
does  not  even  permit  a  carrier  to  escape  this  restricted  route  network  when  it 
engages  in  charters,  for  the  Board  has  limited  carriers  engaging  in  off-route 
charters,  those  not  between  city -pairs  on  the  carrier's  certificate,  to  a  tiny  per- 
centage of  the  total  revenue  plane  miles  flown  by  the  carrier  in  the  calendar 
year.'" 

The  present  inquiry  in  route  proceedings  into  whether  entry  onto  a  specific 
route  would  be  "economically  viable"  should  be  eliminated.  Whatever  the  pro- 
cedures or  standards  applied  to  this  inquiry,  it  still  amounts  to  a  substitution  of 
government  decisionmaking  for  market  processes  in  a  way  which  inevitably  to 
one  degree  or  another  brings  unnecessary  costs  and  inefficiencies  which  we  can- 
not afford.  The  Board's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  has  recently  proposed  ™  that 
the  Board  require  an  advance  forecast  of  profitability  for  all  carriers  in  a  market 
before  a  route  application  will  be  set  for  priority  handling  which  in  practice  is 


2149  D.S.C.  sees.  401(e)  (3).  401(n)  (1),  417. 

22  The  Domestic  Route  System.  CAB  1974,  appendix  A,  table  1. 

23  Id.,  appendix  A,  table  1. 
2*  Id.  100. 

2s  For  example,  14  CFR  sec.  399.60. 

2»  Domestic  Route  System,  supra. 

2'  Domestic  Route  System,  supra. 

28  14  CFR  sec.  2C7.5 

2»  The  Domestic  Route  System,  CAB  1974. 


687 

a  necessary  prerequisite  to,  if  not  complete  assurance  that,  the  application  wiU 
be  granted.  This  proposal  represents  a  valiant  attempt  to  rationalize  a  route 
investigation  procedure  on  the  part  of  the  Board  which  in  recent  years  has 
effectively  eliminated  new  competitive  route  awards  in  an  attempt  to  improve 
profiitability.™ 

The  BOR's  proposals  no  doubt  would  be  quite  damaging  to  competition  and 
efficiency  in  the  air  transportation  industry.  But  the  BOR  proposal  only  makes 
explicit  and  perhaps  intensifies  the  undesirability  of  the  Board's  characteristic 
conduct  under  its  substantive  statutory  standards. 

The  Board  has  very  candidly  admitted  that  under  its  procedural  practices  of 
the  past  few  years,  the  vast  bulk  of  new  route  applications  have  not  even  been 
set  for  hearing  because  of  the  Board's  exclusive  preoccupation  with  enhancing 
the  profitability  of  existing  carriers.^'  This  refusal  even  to  hear  cases  raises  seri- 
ous questions  under  statutory  procedural  requirements.  But  the  problem  is  far 
more  serious  than  bad  procedures.  The  Board's  recent  de  facto  moratorium  on 
new  route  awards  represents  merely  intensification  of  its  characteristic  use  of 
a  vague  statutory  mandate  to  extend  unnecessary  and  costly  protection  to  exist- 
ing air  carriers. 

Whether  service  on  a  specific  route  is  "required  by  the  public  convenience  and 
necessity"  is  a  similarly  unnecessary  inquiry  in  view  of  the  economic  character- 
istics of  air  transportation.  Who  needs  to  be  protected  from  "unnecessary"  serv- 
ice? Not  consumers,  who  if  given  a  choice  will  simply  not  pay  for  service  they 
don't  need.  Not  the  Postal  Service  or  the  Treasury,  for  airmail  and  subsidized 
service  are  very  small  portions  of  the  modern  air  transportation  system,  and 
route  regulation  for  the  entire  system  is  not  necessary  for  either  of  them  to  func- 
tion efficiently.  The  answer  is  the  existing  certificated  air  carrier  themselves,  who 
naturally  regard  any  new  competition  as  "unnecessary."  Government  determina- 
tions of  whether  there  is  a  need  for  service  that  a  private  air  carrier  proposes 
to  offer  on  an  unsubsidized  basis  are  archaic,  unnecessary  and  expensive. 

What  changes  are  necessary  to  narrow  route  regulation  to  reasonable  scope? 
To  begin  with,  procedural  reform  could  improve,  but  not  completely  remedy,  the 
problem.  Route  proceedings  are  extremely  slow,  when  they  take  place  at  all,  and 
the  ability  of  innovators  and  competitors  to  present  their  case  undoubtedly  could 
be  improved  by  procedural  reform.  If  the  substantive  statutory  standards  were 
not  narrowed  along  the  lines  indicated  above,  however,  the  improvements  would 
be  marginal,  and  in  our  view,  insuflSeient.  The  regulator  would  still  retain  a 
broad  and  vague  set  of  directives  and  standards,  and  would  be  able  to  make 
factual  judgments  with  quite  anticompetitive  and  harmful  results  without  re- 
versal by  the  courts. 

There  is  a  wide  range  of  possibilities  for  narrowing  the  fact-finding  discretion 
of  the  regulator.  One  of  the  most  modest  would  be  simply  to  add  to  the  long  list 
of  public  interest  considerations  in  section  102  of  the  Act  specific  language  about 
maintaining  competition  and  efficiency  in  air  transportation.  The  problem  with 
this  approach  is  that  the  vague  and  inclusive  section  102  I'eferences  to  "encourage- 
ment and  development,"  "promotion,"  and  fostering  of  "sound  economic  condi- 
tions in"  air  transportation  would  remain,  and  the  Board  would  at  best  have 
to  balance  past  anticompetitive  and  inefficiency-producing  interpretations  of  these 
provisions  against  the  newer,  narrower  standards,  with  considerable  deference 
still  being  accorded  to  its  factual  judgment. 

It  is  not  clear  to  us  that  this  would  represent  even  a  marginal  improvement 
over  the  present  legal  standards,  because  even  under  the  existing  Act,  as  under 
numerous  other  vague  and  inclusive  regulatory  statutes,  the  courts  have  required 
agencies  to  make  specific  findings  on,  and  pay  specific  attention  to,  competitive 
consideration,^-  along  with  other  public  interest  considerations. 

Another  possibility  would  be  to  eliminate  the  rather  vague  statutory  exhorta- 
tions mentioned  above  and  insert  in  their  place  a  requirement  to  preserve  com- 
petition and  promote  efficiency.  This  would  be  an  improvement,  but  it  simply 
asks  the  regulator  to  do  what  the  Congress  could  do  itself :  examine  the  need  for 
economic  regulation  of  air  routes,  and  decide  how  extensively  it  is  to  be  applied. 


sold.  9,  150. 

31  Domestic  Route  System,  supra,  pp.  i-ii ;  CAB  annual  report  to  Congress,  1973.  p.  4. 

32  For  example,  Gulf  States  Utility  Co.  v.  Federal  Power  Commission,  411  U.S.  747 
(1973)  :  Federal  Maritime  Commission  v.  Svenslva  Amerika  Linien.  .S90  U.S.  238.  24.3-46 
(1968)  ;  Denver  &  R.G.W.R.  Co.  v.  United  States,  387  U.S.  485,  492-93  (1967)  ;  Northern 
Natural  Gas  Co.  v.  Federal  Power  Commission,  399  F.2d  953,  958-61  D.C.  Cir.   (1968). 


still  further  marginal  improvement  could  be  achieved  by  changing  the  section 
401  requirement  that  a  route  must  be  proved  "required"  by  the  public  convenience 
and  necessity  to  a  requirement  that  it  simply  be  proved  "consistent"  with  the 
public  convenience  and  necessity.  This  of  course  would  be  little  improvement  at 
all  if  there  were  no  narrowing  of  the  factual  judgments  the  Board  is  allowed  to 
make  in  finding  anticompetitive  regulation  to  be  so  "required"  or  "consistent." 
And  even  with  such  a  narrowing  along  the  lines  suggested  above,  the  difference 
would  only  be  marginal,  because  in  past  cases,  once  the  Board  has  passed  the 
question  of  detrimental  impact  on  other  carriers,  it  has  not  imposed  a  very  heavy 
burden  on  parties  seeking  to  show  that  their  service  is  "required."  Instead,  it 
frequently  has  found  that  the  provision  of  new  competitive  service  in  itself  con- 
stitutes such  a  need.*^ 

One  last  refinement  to  this  phrase-by-phrase  approach  to  improvement  of  the 
route  provisions  of  the  Act  would  be  to  specifically  eliminate  the  Board's  ability 
to  limit  entry  in  order  to  protect  existing  air  carriers.  This  could  take  the  form 
of  a  provision  that  the  Board  may  not  consider  economic  effects  on  other  air 
carriers  in  acting  on  route  applications,  or  a  provision  that  route  applications 
could  be  denied  only  if  the  Board  found  that  the  result  would  be  a  decline  in 
the  quantity  or  quality  of  service  in  the  market.  This  kind  of  amendment,  along 
with  other  narrowing  of  the  standards  and  substantial  procedural  reform,  would 
remove  the  biggest  historical  impediment  to  a  competitive  airline  system,  but 
it  still  would  leave  the  Board  with  a  fairly  broad  range  of  factual  judgments 
to  make,  and  accordingly  would  leave  the  possibility  of  characteristically  pro- 
tectionist decisions. 

In  our  view,  the  solution  should  get  back  to  basics,  and  insure  that  route 
regulation  does  not  exceed  the  level  which  has  been  justified  in  the  public  interest, 
because  even  at  its  best,  regulation  is  an  intrinsically  expensive,  time-consuming, 
and  unproductive  exercise.  Thus  the  best  approach  to  reform  of  the  entry  pro- 
visions would  be  to  allow  carriers  into  the  industry  if  they  can  demonstrate 
that  they  would  operate  the  service  they  undertake  in  a  safe  and  reliable 
manner.  Protection  of  these  essentially  noneconomic  interests  would  not  seem 
to  require  detailed  entry  or  exit  control  on  specific  city-pair  routes. 


Prepared  Statement  of  John  Snow  (Submitted  by  Mr.  Kutzke) 

Thank  you  for  this  opportunity  to  submit  a  statement  for  the  record  concern- 
ing the  regulation  of  route  awards  and  entry.  I  hope  my  statement  will  be  of 
some  assistance  to  your  proceedings  and  I  will  be  happy  to  answer  any  questions 
that  you  or  the  members  of  your  subcommittee  may  have  about  the  statement  at 
a  later  date. 

As  expressed  in  Acting  Secretary  Barnum's  statement  to  this  subcommittee  on 
February  G,  1975,  the  Department  has  been  a  strong  advocate  of  improving  the 
economic  performance  of  the  air  transportation  industry  through  the  increased 
reliance  on  competitive  market  forces.  The  economic  performance  of  the  industry 
must  be  improved  if  we  are  to  restrain  the  rapidly  escalating  prices  of  air  trans- 
portation and  preserve  the  use  of  air  transportation  for  large  numbers  of 
travelers.  One  vital  aspect  of  this  problem  is  entry  and  route  awards. 

The  present  policy  of  the  Board  is  restrictive  in  terms  of  certificating  new 
trunk  carriers.  Under  the  Act  of  1938,  16  domestic  trunk  carriers  received  operat- 
ing certificates.  No  new  certificates  have  been  awarded  since  that  time,  and,  in 
fact,  because  of  mergers,  there  are  now  only  10  trunk  carriers.  The  Board  has 
allowed  new  carrier  groups  and  classes  of  carriers,  such  as  local  service  and  sup- 
plemental carriers.  But  these  types  of  carriers  do  not  approach  the  trunks  in 
terms  of  scope  of  operation  or  market  penetration. 


33  See,  for  example.  Northeast  Airlines,  et  al..  North  Atlantic  Route  Case,  6  CAB  319, 
325-326  (1945)  ;  TATA  Traffic  Conference  Resolution,  6  CAB  639,  643-644  (1946)  ;  Florida 
Case.  6  CAB  765.  773-774  (1946)  ;  Hawaiian  Case,  7  CAB  83.  103-104  (1946)  ;  Milwaukee- 
Chicago-New  York  Restriction  Case,  11  CAB  310  330  (1950)  ;  TATA  Agency  Resolutions. 
12  CAB  493,  508-509  (1951)  ;  Trans-Pacific  Airlines,  Ltd.,  Certificate  Amendment,  12 
CAB  900,  901  (1951)  :  Southern  Service  to  the  West  Case,  Reopened,  18  CAB  790.  799-800 
(1954)  :  Reopened  New  York-Balboa  Through-Service  Proceeding,  20  CAB  106,  109 
(1954)  ;  Denver  Service  Case,  22  CAB  1178.  1184.  1273  (1955)  ;  New  York-Florida  Case, 
24  CAB  94,  99  (1956)  ;  Seaboard  &  Western  Airlines.  Mail  Authorization,  29  CAB  49,  85 
(1959).  The  Board's  apparent  departure  from  this  attitude  toward  the  values  of  competi- 
tion in  recent  cases  is  currently  being  challenged  in  Continental  Airlines,  Inc.  v.  CAB, 
D.C.  Cir.  74-1651. 


The  Board  is  also  very  restrictive  with  respect  to  route  awards.  During  the 
past  5  years,  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  has  enforced  a  de  facto  route  mora- 
torium, pursuant  to  which  it  has  virtually  refused  to  set  for  hearing  applications 
for  new  route  authority  and  has  generally  denied  applications  for  new  competi- 
tive authority  in  cases  already  in  progress. 

The  Federal  Aviation  Act  grants  the  Board  wide  discretion  in  determining 
entry  and  route  awards.  This  discretion  has  been  inappropriately  exercised  to 
restrain  entry  and  frustrate  the  operations  of  the  market.  Under  the  Act  the 
Board  is  required  to  set  applications  for  new  route  authority  for  public  hearing 
and  to  dispose  of  all  such  applications  "as  speedily  as  possible"  (Section  401  (c) ). 
In  spite  of  that  mandate,  few  route  applications  have  been  set  for  hearing  over 
the  last  5  years.  For  example,  the  Board  declined  to  set  for  hearing  an  application 
by  North  Central  Airlines  to  provide  first  competitive  service  (with  American 
Airlines)  in  the  Boston-Detroit  market  and  refused  as  well  to  hear  an  applica- 
tion by  North  Central  to  provide  competitive  service  between  Philidelphia  and 
Milwaukee  even  though  the  two  carriers  authorized  in  that  market  had  virtually 
eliminated  nonstop  service.  The  Board's  rationale  has  been  that  the  new  service 
offered  limited  public  benefits  which  were  outweighed  by  the  harm  which  com- 
petition would  have  on  the  entrenched  carrier. 

Under  Board  procedures  applicants  for  operating  authority  are  placed  on  the 
horns  of  a  serious  dilemma.  In  spite  of  the  fact  that  the  Board  is  required  by  law 
to  hear  all  applications  filed,  the  application  often  sits  in  the  docket  without  any 
action  taken  unless  the  applicant  also  files  a  petition  for  expedited  hearing.  By  a 
new  regidation  adopted  in  the  fall  of  1973,  the  Board  now  dismisses  all  applica- 
tions which  are  the  subject  of  such  a  petition  for  an  expedited  hearing  upon 
denial  of  that  petition.  And  the  Board  most  always  denies  such  petitions.  Thus,  a 
carrier  has  the  grim  choice  of  requesting  expedited  hearing,  which  will  probably 
be  dismissed,  or  having  no  action  taken  at  all.  As  a  result,  the  number  of  new- 
route  applications  being  filed  has  slowed  to  a  mere  trickle. 

During  the  route  moratorium,  those  cases  already  in  progress  have  advanced 
slowly  with  final  Board  decision  still  pending  in  some  cases  originally  instituted 
in  the  sixties,  such  as  the  additional  service  to  Omaha  and  Des  Moines  case  and 
the  Reno-Portland/Seattle  nonstop  investigation.  The  Atlanta-Detroit/Cleveland 
and  Cincinnati  investigation  was  before  the  Board  over  5  years  (February  1969  to 
May  1974 )  before  being  decided,  and  its  decision  was  based  on  an  issue  not  in  the 
case  when  initially  filed — the  national  fuel  shortage.  The  delay  of  the  proceedings 
has  cast  a  heavy  burden  upon  the  industry. 

A  few  route  cases  have  been  decided  during  the  moratorium  period,  but  with  the 
general  result  that  applications  for  competitive  route  authority  have  been  denied. 
In  reaching  these  decisions  the  Board  has  placed  little  emphasis  on  competition 
and  on  the  needs  of  the  public  for  additional  service.  Instead,  it  has  placed  major 
emphasis  on  the  financial  impact  which  the  services  of  new  carriers  would  have 
on  the  incumbent  carriers.  For  example,  the  Board  denied  an  application  for 
competitive  service  in  the  San  Diego-Denver  market  on  the  ground  that  such  an 
award  would  cause  revenue  diversion  from  Western  Air  Lines.  (That  case  is  now 
before  the  U.S.  Court  of  Appeals.)  Even  where  the  Board  does  consider  competi- 
tion, it  views  it  in  the  narrow  perspective  of  service  adfHjuacy  in  terms  of  capacity, 
rather  than  the  potential  for  lower  prices.  Potential  applicants  have  learned  that 
it  Is  bad  strategy  to  base  their  case  on  lower  prices.  Failure  of  the  Board  to  con- 
sider lower  prices  is  a  serious  deficiency  in  the  Board's  decision  making  process. 

The  result  of  Board's  entry  policy  is  that  the  American  consumer  is  not  afforded 
the  range  of  price  and  service  options  that  an  efficient  market  would  provide  and 
often  must  purchase  more  service  than  he  wants  or  needs. 

What  we  need  in  terms  of  entry  is  a  2-pronged  approach.  First  we  need  to 
weigh  the  entry  standard  more  heavily  in  favor  of  competition  and  efficiency. 
Second,  we  need  a  requirement  that  cases  before  the  Board  be  decided  promptly. 
The  Board  must  focus  upon  the  needs  of  the  public  and  the  need  for  competition 
and  innovation,  and  place  less  emphasis  on  the  impact  upon  the  existing  carrier. 

Adoption  of  this  approach  would  not  necessarily  lead  to  the  addition  of  new 
carriers  on  each  domestic  route  nor  even  the  addition  of  new  carriers  to  the 
majority  of  domestic  routes.  Rather  the  basic  result  of  this  new  approach  will 
be  the  "introduction  of  potential  competition  to  ensure  that  the  domestic  air 
markets  operate  efficiently  and  that  the  consumer  obtains  the  price  and  service 
option  of  his  choice.  The  threat  of  potential  entry  will  police  and  discipline  market 
behavior  and  ensure  competitive  market  results.  Liberalized  entry  will  place  firms 


690 

on  the  edge  of  the  market,  able  and  ready  to  step  into  that  market  when  the 
consumer  is  dissatisfied  with  the  existing  service  and  price.  This  dissatisfaction 
will  attract  entrants.  But  we  think  that  the  existing  firms  will  act  as  an  intelligent 
businessman,  improve  their  efiiciency  and  keep  their  prices  low  enough  to  keep 
new  firms  out.  This  is  the  concept  of  threshold  pricing.  Prices  are  kept  high  enough 
to  make  reasonable  profits,  and  low  enough  to  keep  new  competition  out.  The  con- 
sumer benefits.  Occasionally,  an  outsider  will  be  able  to  enter  the  market  because 
he  will  be  an  innovator  and  offer  a  new  service  or  be  more  efficient.  Because  of 
the  costs  associated  with  entry,  however,  he  will  be  the  exception  to  the  rule,  but 
the  fear  of  his  presence  will  spur  the  existing  carriers  to  even  greater  eflSciency 
and  to  their  own  innovation.  We  are  confident  the  result  will  be  a  more  efficient 
and  innovative  airline  industry,  providing  the  public  with  better  service  and  more 
price-service  options. 

Even  though  this  hearing  deals  with  entry,  it  is  important  to  consider  entry 
in  the  context  of  price  flexibility.  As  you  will  remember,  Acting  Secretary  Barnum 
testified  in  favor  of  the  need  for  more  pricing  fiexibility  before  this  subcommittee. 
One  criticism  of  pricing  flexibility  is  that  only  the  strong  firms  will  take  advan- 
tage of  it,  and  they  will  either  drive  the  prices  up  or,  in  the  alternative,  drive  the 
prices  down  temporarily  to  destroy  competition,  and  then  increase  the  price  when 
the  competition  is  gone.  Liberalized  entry  and  the  threat  of  potential  entry  is  the 
regulator  and  the  enforcer  which  assures  that  pricing  flexibility  will  not  be  mis- 
used. With  liberalized  entry,  the  strong  firms  will  not  be  able  to  drive  the  price 
up  because  of  the  threat  of  competition.  With  liberalized  entry,  the  strong  firms 
will  have  little  incentive  to  underprice  their  services  to  drive  out  old  competitors, 
because  there  is  always  the  threat  of  new  competition. 

There  is  another  aspect  of  this  connection  between  pricing  flexibility  and  entry 
that  must  be  mentioned.  Many  would  ask  why  in  an  industry  where  there  is 
existing  overcapacity,  and  where  the  predictions  indicate  that  future  growth  will 
be  somewhat  slower  than  in  the  past,  do  we  want  more  entry.  We  have  already 
indicated  that  we  do  not  believe  that  easing  entry  will  necessarily  increase  the 
number  of  carriers  in  the  market.  But  the  essential  answer  to  this  question  is 
that  liberalized  entry  is  the  other  side  of  the  coin  to  increased  pricing  flexibility. 
Because  prices  are  rigid,  competition  has  concentrated  on  service  and  over- 
capacitv  has  been  the  result.  Only  through  pricing  flexibility  will  there  be  a 
reductio!)  in  this  overcapacity,  and  as  indicated  above,  pricing  flexibility  without 
liberalized  entry  would  not  achieve  the  full  benefits  of  regulatory  change. 

In  summary,  the  Board  has  pursued  a  restrictive  entry  and  route  award  policy 
which  has  denied  the  American  consumer  the  full  benefits  of  an  efficient  air 
industry  that  offers  him  the  range  of  services  and  prices  that  it  should.  We 
intend  to  introduce  legislation  which  will  turn  the  focus  of  the  Board  away 
from  the  protection  of  existing  carriers  to  the  interests  of  competition,  innova- 
tion, and  the  consumer. 

Office  of  the  Secretary  of  Transportation, 

Washington,  D.C.,  Apr.  25,  1975. 
Hon.  EnwARD  M.  Kennedy, 
U.S.  Sen  life, 
Washington,  B.C. 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy  :  In  the  course  of  our  participation  in  the  recent  hear- 
ings held  by  your  subcommittee  on  economic  regulation  of  aviation,  a  number  of 
questions  were  asked  of  the  Department  which  required  supplementary  written 
response.  Our  answers  to  your  questions  follow. 

Question  1.  What  is  the  Department's  response  to  the  subcommittee's  recent 
staff  report  on  minimum  charter  air  fares? 

Answer.  Among  the  procedural  suggestions  which  the  staff  report  discusses 
are:  providing  public  hearings  prior  to  major  Department  policy  decisions; 
allowing  for  public  comment  in  the  context  of  a  rulemaking  proceeding ;  estab- 
lishing an  agency  official  to  represent  consumer  views;  requiring  that  all  meetings 
be  held  in  public;  making  public  transcripts  of  meetings;  providing  Federal 
Register  notices  of  all  meetings  and  hearings ;  appointing  a  Department  official 
to  decide  which  decisions  require  consumer  representation  or  public  hearings; 
institutionalizing  methods  for  soliciting  public  and  consumer  views;  establih- 
ing  mechanisms  for  monitoring  compliance  with  agency  orders  designed  to  pro- 
tect the  public;  and  providing  consumer-oriented,  in-house  antitrust  expertise 
to  insure  that  agency  action  will  further  the  policies  behind  antitrust  laws. 


The  general  objective  of  these  procedural  suggestions — to  protect  consumer 
interests  from  the  "vagaries  of  'informal'  decisionmaking" — are  worthy,  espe- 
cially if  one  accepts  the  premise  that  those  views  are  not  already  adequately 
considered.  The  suggestions  are  innovative.  Taken  as  a  group,  they  represent  a 
departure  from  traditional  policymaking  approaches.  We  believe  that  some  are 
already  effectively  being  accomplished,  others  would  be  difficult  or  infeasible  to 
administer,  and  still  others  have  merit  and  are  being  discussed,  in  some  form, 
within  the  Department. 

I  think  the  record  of  this  Department's  performance  confirms  that  we  are 
mindful  of  consumer  interests.  As  public  officials,  we  act  in  accordance  with 
what  we  believe  to  be  the  public  interest.  In  determining  public  interest,  we 
recognize  the  importance  of  creating  a  strong  national  transportation  system, 
of  providing  an  economic  climate  in  which  carriers  can  provide  quality  service 
at  reasonable  profits,  of  healthy  competition,  and  of  consumer  needs  for  safe, 
reliable,  energy-efficient  and  low-cost  transportation.  We  do  not  believe  that  the 
present  system  of  transport  regulations  is  adequately  meeting  these  objectives 
and,  therefore,  we  have  sought  to  bring  about  changes  in  regulatory  policy.  The 
basic  thrust  of  our  approach  has  been  to  allow  wider  scope  for  the  operation 
of  market  forces  in  transportation. 

Of  necessity,  in  fulfilling  our  statutory  charge,  we  must  take  into  consideration 
not  only  consumer  interest  but  also  other  national  policies  which  require  a 
healthy  transportation  system,  energy  conservation,  travel  safety,  and  environ- 
mental quality,  among  other  goals.  Weighing  these  sometimes  competing  con- 
siderations is  a  challenging  process. 

Reasonable  men  may  differ  in  judging  the  degree  of  our  success.  But  any  im- 
plication that  consumer  views  are  not  among  the  most  important  of  those 
factors  considered  in  making  policy  in  the  Department  would  not  square  with 
the  facts. 

In  general,  we  believe  the  administrative  burdens  of  opening  to  public  hear- 
ings all  Department  policy  decisions  or  of  requiring  that  all  meetings  be  public 
would  outweigh  the  benefits.  Allowing  public  comment  in  the  context  of  rule- 
making proceedings,  or  having  periodic  policy  conferences  which  are  open  to  all 
interested  parties,  on  the  other  hand,  may  have  more  merit.  At  present,  the 
Department  has  an  official  specifically  charged  with  representation  of  consumer 
interests  who  is  involved  in  many,  although  certainly  not  all,  policy  decisions. 
Public  comments  are  always  welcomed  and  are  considered.  Department  officials 
speak  to  industry  and  consumer  groups  and  meet  with  each  to  explain  our 
programs  and  to  solicit  comments.  The  interchange  is  productive. 

To  further  ensure  adequate  representation  of  consumer  views,  the  Depart- 
ment is  effecting  some  changes  along  lines  of  the  subcommittee  staff's  sugges- 
tions. With  respect  to  determining  the  level  of  compensatory  charter  rates,  for 
example,  the  Department  has  developed  proposed  criteria  which  have  been  circu- 
lated to  other  interested  executive  branch  agencies,  air  carriers  and  consumer 
groups.  The  Department  invited  interested  consumer  groups,  carriers  and  other 
government  agencies  to  participate  in  an  open  meeting  at  the  Department  on 
April  11  to  discuss  our  proposed  criteria.  A  member  of  your  staff  and  consumer 
representatives  were  present.  To  increase  consideration  of  consumer  views  in  our 
decisionmaking  process,  we  recently  published  a  notice  in  the  Federal  Register 
asking  for  comments  on  various  specific  areas  of  the  present  review  of  inter- 
national aviation  policy.  The  Department  intends  to  hold  a  hearing  on  that 
review  when  the  work  is  further  along  and  we  welcome  consumer,  government 
agency.  Congressional  and  carrier  comments  throughout  the  review.  These  com- 
ments will  be  placed  in  a  public  docket.  We  are  also  considering  holding  an 
open  meeting  to  discuss  proposed  aviation  regulatory  reform  legislation. 

We  will  continue  to  review  our  procedures  for  public  participation  and  will 
continue  to  make  every  effort  to  ensure  that  consumer  views  are  fully  considered 
in  all  the  Department's  policy  decisions. 

Question  2.  Does  the  Department  have  any  studies  on  the  extent  to  which 
cross-subsidy  exists  in  the  current  air  system? 

Answer.  As  part  of  our  preparation  for  the  Domestic  Passenger  Fare  Investi- 
gation (DPFI),  the  Department  extensively  studied  air  carrier  operations  in 
many  markets  and  examined  carrier  load  factors,  relevant  carrier  costs  and 
levels  of  operations.  On  the  basis  of  that  examination,  the  Department  concluded 
that  carriers  are  continuously  adjusting  operations  in  individual  markets  so  as 
to  achieve  a  "break-even"  level  (including  profit),  but  some  relatively  few 
city-pair  markets  probably  do  not  cover  fully  allocated  costs  (including  profits). 


692 

However  in  those  markets,  the  carriers  normally  covered  variable  costs,  thus 
making  a  positive  contribution  to  the  carriers'  overall  operation. 

Markets  which  make  a  positive  contribution  will  undoubtedly  be  retained 
by  the  carrier,  regardless  of  the  level  of  federal  regulation.  The  existing  CAB 
accounting  system  and  the  costing  procedure?  developed  in  the  DPFI  do  not 
recognize  that  many  markets  cover  the  relevant  carrier  costs  if  revenue  Is 
properly  assigned.  The  analysis  which  I  have  described  was  not  embodied  in  a 
formal  report,  study  or  memorandum. 

A  theoretical  discussion  of  the  cross-subsidy  issue  was  offered  as  part  of  the 
Department's  direct  case  in  phase  9  of  the  DPFI  and  a  copy  of  our  presentation 
is  included.  This  theoretical  analysis  was  confirmed  by  our  review  of  carrier 
costs,  load  factors  and  market  data. 

Other  studies  of  the  cross-subsidy  issue  have  been  made.  They  include  "Eco- 
nomic Regulation  of  Domestic  Air  Transportation :  Theory  and  Policy,"  by 
George  W.  Douglas  and  James  C.  Miller  III  (see,  e.g.,  pp.  53-54,  87-94)  ;  "The 
Local  Service  Airline  Experiment,"  by  George  Eads ;  and  the  CAB  staff  study  of 
"Service  to  Small  Communities."  With  the  exception  of  United's  testimony  at 
your  hearings,  we  are  not  aware  of  any  evidence  on  cross-subsidy  offered  by 
the  carriers,  although  carriers  often  say  there  is  cross-subsidy.  We  have  not 
examined  the  raw  data  on  which  United's  study  is  based,  but  would  be  pleased 
to  do  so  if  we  had  access  to  the  data,  and  make  the  results  of  our  analysis 
available  to  you. 

Practical  experience  over  the  last  10  years  suggests  that  there  is  little  if  any 
real  cross-subsidy  in  the  domestic  trunk  system.  Trunk  carriers  have  been  with- 
drawing from  markets  which  they  do  not  consider  economic.  Most  of  these 
markets  are  now  served  either  by  local  service  carriers  or  commuter  air  carriers. 
In  recent  years,  trunk  carriers  have  not  sought  to  eliminate  service  in  many 
markets,  even  in  unprofitable  years.  This  provides  some  valuable  evidence  that 
they  do  not  perceive  these  markets  as  uneconomic. 

Question  3.  If  we  move  to  more  liberal  entry  and  pricing,  what  routes  will  be 
affected?  How  many  are  there'.'  Where  are  they?  Will  people  on  those  routes 
get  service? 

Answer.  Every  route  may  be  affected  to  some  extent.  Service  should  increase 
on  some  routes  and  decrease  on  certain  other  routes.  In  some  few  cases,  carriers 
may  suspend  service,  in  which  event  local  service  or  commuter  carriers  would 
probably  institute  service.  In  a  few  cases,  direct  subsidies  from  the  local  com- 
munities might  be  necessary  to  insure  continued  service.  In  some  instances,  alter- 
nate forms  of  transportation  may  become  relatively  more  attractive. 

We  expect  that  service  will  be  rationalized  on  grounds  of  economic  justification 
and  that  carriers  will  not  serve  routes  on  which  they  cannot  cover  their  vaxiable 
costs.  It  is  not  possible  to  do  a  route-by-route  analysis  indicating  which  low- 
density  routes  would  be  eliminated  without  specific  carrier  co.st  and  revenue  data 
for  the  routes  in  question. 

Qursfion  J/.  Can  we  submit  questions  on  cross  subsidy  which  the  subcommittee 
could  address  to  the  ATA  and  carriers? 

Answer.  Our  General  Counsc  I's  office  has  already  provided  certain  questions  for 
your  staff.  One  reason  for  the  difficulty  in  assessing  the  extent  to  which  one  route 
supposedly  sub.sidizos  another  route  is  that  it  depends  upon  which  accounting 
system  is  used.  Also,  accounting  systems  do  not  properly  measure  the  economic 
costs.  Each  trunk  carri;  r  should  be  requested  to  identify  both  profitable  and  un- 
profitable routes,  the  routes  they  <  laim  are  cross  subsidized,  and  the  accounting 
methods  used  to  arrive  at  the  conclusion. 

Question  5.  What  comments  do  we  have  on  problems  of  transition  to  liberalized 
entry  and  pricing?  How  can  establi  hed  carriers  be  protected  or  not  hurt  too 
badly? 

Answer.  Transition  will  depend  upon  the  extent  of  deregulation.  Phased  transi- 
tion is  being  discussed.  If  the  industry  were  to  be  totally  deregulated  (which  the 
Administration  has  not  advocated),  a  transition  period  would  certainly  be 
required. 

The  airline  industry  has  shown  considerable  ability  to  adapt  to  changing  con- 
ditions and  to  meet  competitive  .service  innovations.  We  expect  that  they  will 
prove  similarly  resilient  and  that,  far  from  being  injured,  their  overall  economic 
health  will  improve  as  the  result  of  our  proposals. 

Question  6.  Will  airline  safety  be  affected  by  increased  competition? 


Answer.  Regardless  of  the  degree  of  regulatory  reform  we  propose,  we  do  not 
have  any  intention  of  permitting  any  deterioration  in  aviation  safety.  The  De- 
partment considers  that  supervision  of  aircraft  safety  standards  should  be  en- 
tirely independent  of  economic  regulation.  The  FAA  will  continue  to  maintain 
high  standards.  We  have  discus.sed  the  matter  of  airline  safety  within  the  Office 
of  the  Secretary  and  with  the  FAA.  Many  changes  in  the  Act  which  would  im- 
prove Board  procedures  and  encourage  the  Board  to  foster  more  competition 
would  not  require  any  changes  in  the  existing  FAA  safety  programs  or  under- 
lying statutes.  On  the  other  hand,  if  complete  deregulation  of  air  carriers  were 
envi.-ioned,  some  statutory  changes  in  the  FAA  safety  authority  would  be  re- 
quired. As  a  practical  matter,  if  a  number  of  new  carriers  were  authorized  to 
enter,  the  FAA  workload  would  be  increased  in  the  short  run  as  the  carriers  went 
through  necessary  steps  to  secure  the  requisite  safety  authority  from  the  FAA. 
Also,  the  FAA  would  almost  certainly  have  to  increase  its  inspection  activities 
to  ensure  that  each  new  carrier  was  meeting  all  applicable  safety  standards.  In- 
spection would  be  particularly  important  for  carriers  that  do  not  appear  to  have 
the  requisite  financial  backing  to  mount  .sound  economic  operations. 

You  are  aware  that  there  are  a  number  of  carriers  which  do  not  operate  pur- 
suant to  CAB  authority  which  are  also  required  to  meet  the  same  safety  standards 
as  CAB-regulated  carriers.  These  include  Pacific  Southwest  Airlines  in  California 
and  Southwest  Airlines  in  Texas.  The  FAA  resources  necessary  to  meet  the  re- 
quirements for  increased  safety  supervision  which  would  accompany  any  regula- 
tory reform  proposal  will  depend  on  the  specific  proposal.  We  do  not  anticipate 
a  large  increase  in  FAA  safety  staff,  absent  complete  deregulation.  We  will  not 
permit  any  diminution  in  strict  enforcement  of  safety  standards. 

In  addition,  a  number  of  questions  were  submitted  by  Senator  Thurmond.  Our 
response  to  those  questions  follow. 

Question  7.  Are  you  aware  of  any  reliable  figures,  from  any  source,  which  will 
enable  the  subcommittee  to  get  some  idea  on  the  extent  to  which  price  determines 
the  consumer's  choice  between  airlines,  trains,  buses,  or  some  other  public 
transportation? 

Answer.  For  the  most  part,  the  studies  which  have  been  completed  regarding  the 
effect  of  price  (or  other  factors)  and  the  choice  of  transportation  mode  have  not 
been  conclusive  or  reliable.  The  primary  reason  for  this  is  the  lack  of  information 
which  describes  how  many  people  are  traveling  by  all  of  the  available  transporta- 
tion modes  in  individual  city-pair  markets.  There  have  been  several  studies  com- 
pleted in  particular  markets  which  do  provide  some  insight.  These  studies  show 
that  the  sensitivity  of  mode  choice  to  price  is  very  much  dependent  upon  the  pur- 
pose of  the  trip,  its  distance  and  the  socioeconomic  status  of  the  traveler.  For 
example,  business  travelers  are  far  less  sensitive  to  price  than  are  individuals 
traveling  for  recreation  purposes.  Similarly,  higher  income  people  exhibit  less 
concern  about  trip  cost  than  do  lower  income  travelers.  Frequency  of  service  is 
also  an  important  factor,  especially  for  the  business  traveler.  Additionally,  the 
comparative  trip  times,  including  both  time  spent  on  the  line-liaul  part  of  the 
trip  and  the  time  needed  to  get  to  and  from  the  terminals,  affect  an  individual's 
choice  of  travel  mode.  The  sensitivity  of  modal  choice  to  any  of  the.se  factors  is 
further  affected  by  the  range  of  choice  which  the  traveler  has  in  choosing  among 
competing  modes.  The  greater  the  competition,  the  more  sensitive  is  the  individ- 
ual's decision  with  respect  to  price. 

Quefition  8.  (a)  What  percentage  of  tourist  travel  in  the  United  States  is  by 
means  of  passenger  aircraft?  (b)  What  percentage  of  tourist  travel  in  California 
is  by  means  of  passenger  aircraft?  (c)  In  Texas? 

Answer.  Statistics  from  the  1970  U.S.  Census  indicate  that  approximately  7 
percent  of  personal  trips  for  nonbusiness  purposes  of  100  miles  or  greater  in  length 
are  made  by  air.  Of  all  such  trips  having  at  least  one  end  in  California,  some  14 
percent  are  made  by  air.  This  latter  figure  includes  travel  leaving  or  entering 
California,  subject  to  CAB-regulated  rates,  and  travel  within  California  subject 
to  the  lower  PUC  rates.  If  it  is  assumed  that  trips  entering  or  leaving  California 
have  percentages  of  travelers  using  air  transportation  similar  to  those  reported 
by  the  U.S.  Census  for  the  nation  as  a  whole,  then  the  overall  14  percent  figure 
may  suggest  that  one  reason  for  the  higher  percentage  of  California  air  travel  is 
tlie  lower  PUC  rates.  The  similar  figure  for  Texas  is  7.5  percent. 

Question  9.  What  costs  enter  into  the  consumer's  decision  to  elect  air  travel  over 
some  other  method  of  transportation?  Compare  the  percentages  among  Los 
Angeles-Oakland,  Ln<-  Anedes-San  Jose  (where  somewhat  lower  fares  are  in 
effect),  and  Boston-Washington  or  Montreal-Toronto. 


694 

Answer.  1970  statistics  on  intermetropolitan  travel  between  the  San  Francisco 
Bay  Area  and  otlier  cities  show  the  following : 


Percent  trip  1  by- 

Air         Rail/bus 

Auto 

36.2                1.2 

62.6 

42.4                1.8 

55.  7 

>  Total  trips,  business  and  nonbusiness. 

Results  from  the  Northeast  Corridor  Study  on  1968  intercity  travel  show  the 
following  distribution  of  nonbusiness  person  trips  (exclusive  of  rail  trips)  : 

Percent  of  nonbusiness  person  trips  by  ' 


Bus  Highway 


New  York-Boston 23                   6  70 

New  Yorl<-Washington,  D.C 16                  15  69 

Boston-Washington,  D.C 60                   5  35 

Philadelphia-Boston 43                   6  51 

>  Excludes  trips  by  rail.  Therefore,  each  of  these  entries  would  somewhat  lower  if  rail  trips  were  included. 

Additional  Northeast  Corridor  Study  on  1968  intercity  travel  shows  the  fol- 
lowing distribution  of  total  person  trips  for  given  city  pairs: 


Percent  of  total  person  trips  by 


Air 

Bus 

Highway 

Rail 

46 

7 

42 

5 

36 

10 

45 

9 

51 

4 

42 

3 

34 

3 

61 

2 

New  York-Boston 

New  York-Washington. 

Boston-Washington 

Philadelphia-Boston... 


The  above  statistics  do  not  come  from  directly  comparable  surveys  which  may 
account  for  the  rather  high  air  travel  levels  on  the  East  coast  as  compared  to 
California.  Further,  it  is  imix»rtant  to  understand  that  there  are  major  differ- 
ences in  the  transportation  environment  between  the  Northeast  and  the  San 
Francisco-Southern  California  corridor.  California  is  more  auto  oriented,  with 
far  higher  levels  of  automobile  ownership  per  capita.  Also,  auto  travel  between 
Boston  and  Washington  is  both  much  more  expensive,  with  many  toll  roads  and 
bridges  over  the  route,  and  slower,  inasmuch  as  the  traveler  has  to  pass  around 
the  New  Yorli  metropolitan  area.  These  factors  may  explain  the  high  percentage 
of  air  travel  in  the  Northeast  despite  its  high  cost  relative  to  the  California 
corridor. 

Question  10.  To  my  way  of  thinking,  the  traveling  consumer  in  this  Country 
would  be  better  off  if  he  had  more  choices.  Present  regulations  permit  airlines 
to  compete  with  each  other  in  terms  of  quality — that  is,  they  can  offer  better 
food,  more  food,  better  liquor,  prettier  stewardesses,  or  more  frequent  flights 
in  more  modern  aircraft,  etc.,  but  that  entry  restrictions  and  rate  setting  virtu- 
ally eliminate  price  competition.  I  would  prefer  to  be  able  to  fly  from  here  jto 
Columbia  or  Charleston  for  $10  or  $15  less,  doing  without  some  of  these  frills. 
As  one  who  is  supposed  to  speak  for  consumers,  do  you  think  this  is  an  uncommon 
preference  ? 

Answer.  Not  at  all.  We  agree  that  many  consumers  would  prefer,  and  would 
benefit  from,  price  competition  as  well  as  service  competition.  As  you  know, 
several  airlines  have  recently  received  approval  for  "no-frills"  service  from  the 
CAB,  a  concept  which  we  support.  In  addition,  we  are  preparing  legislation  to 
end  some  of  the  current  practices  which  may  tend  to  prevent  price  competition. 
The  success  of  the  "no-frills"  fare  experiment  may  provide  some  indication  of 
consumer  preferences  in  support  of  our  view. 


Question  11.  Do  you  think  the  consumer  would  be  better  off  if  the  CAB  were 
empowered  to  regulate  all  asi^ects  of  commercial  aviation — or  do  you  think  the 
consumer  would  be  better  off  if  free  competition  were  expanded,  thus  allowing 
potentially  cheaper  and  more  efficient  carriers  to  offer  their  services  over  a  cer- 
tain route? 

Answer.  AVe  think  that  more  reliance  on  the  free  enterprise  system  and  more 
comi)etition  are  preferable  to  expanding  the  powers  of  the  CAB.  Encouraging 
the  Board  to  regulate  all  asi^ects  of  commercial  aviation  would  benefit  neither 
consumers  nor  the  airlines  themselves. 

Question  12.  How  do  you  evaluate  the  effectiveness  of  the  Office  of  Consumer 
Advocacy  within  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board? 

Answer.  Its  establishment  was  an  encouraging  sign.  In  addition,  the  Board 
should  be  commended  for  a  number  of  other  recent  actions,  such  as  ending  its 
unofficial  moratorium  on  route  awards  and  expanding  consumer  options  by 
approving  "no-frills"  fares.  Nevertheless,  while  .such  steps  are  clearly  desirable, 
they  do  not  get  to  the  heart  of  the  problem — too  much  regulation  and  too  little 
competition. 

Question  IS.  Do  you  feel  that  the  authorizing  legislation  now  on  the  books 
for  the  CAB  fails  to  give  it  enough  power  to  insure  the  traveling  public  of 
adequate  service  at  reasonable  prices,  that  it  forces  the  Board  to  exei-cise  powers 
which  actually  work  to  the  detriment  of  those  goals,  or  do  you  feel  that  current 
law  is  just  right,  but  could  be  administered  better? 

Answer.  We  believe  that  the  CAB,  and  its  authorizing  legislation,  served  well 
when  an  umbrella  of  federal  protection  was  needed  to  promote  the  development 
of  a  new  industry.  However,  now  that  the  airline  industry  is  mature,  we  believe 
that  the  authorizing  legislation  should  be  changed  so  as  to  provide  less  regula- 
tion and  more  competition.  We  are  preparing  legislative  proposals  to  do  so. 

We  anpreciate  the  subcommittee's  interest  in  these  areas  and  its  courtesy 
to  our  witnesses  and  staff.  If  we  may  be  of  further  assistance,  please  let  us  know. 
Sincerely, 

John  W.  Snow, 
Acting  Assistant  Secretary  for 
Congressional  and  Intergovernmental  Affairs. 


Mr.  SusMAN.  The  subcommittee  will  come  to  order. 

Senator  Kennedy  will  return  in  a  moment,  and  perhaps  INIr.  Gaf?non, 
you  would  commence  your  prepared  testimony. 

Our  last  witness  represents  the  Airport  Operators  Council,  an  as- 
sociation of  all  major  American  airports.  Mr.  Gajnion  is  the  general 
manager  of  the  Louisyille  and  Jefferson  Air  Board  in  Louisville,  Ky., 
and  has  had  a  wide  range  of  experience  in  the  aviation  industry. 

Perliaps  you  will  begin  by  introducing  your  associates. 

STATEMENT  OF  JAMES  GAGNON,  CHAIRMAN,  AD  HOC  COMMITTEE 
ON  AIR  SERVICE,  AIRPORT  OPERATORS  COUNCIL  INTERNA- 
TIONAL, ACCOMPANIED  BY  KENNEDY  HELM,  COUNSEL;  BARRY  S. 
CRAIG,  DIRECTOR  OF  AVIATION,  GREATER  CINCINNATI  AIR- 
PORT: MARSHALL  P.  ARNOLD,  DIRECTOR  OF  ECONOMIC  PRO- 
GRAMS, LOUISVILLE  AND  JEFFERSON  COUNTY  AIR  BOARD 

Mr.  Gagxox.  I  Avould  like  to  do  that,  Mr.  Chairman.  On  my  left  is 
Mr.  Kennedy  Helm  who  is  counsel  to  the  air  board.  On  my  right  is 
Mr.  Barry  Crai.i  wlio  is  a  member  of  my  air  .service  committee  of  the 
AOCI,  and  on  his  right  is  Mr.  Marshall  Arnold  who  is  a  member  of 
my  staff  in  Louisville, 

It  is  in  the  capacity  as  chairman  of  the  ad  hoc  committee  on  air 
service  of  the  Airport  Operators  Council  that  I  come  here  today.  In 


this  capacity  I  offer  the  following  testimony  to  the  Subcommittee  on 
Administrative  Practices  and  Procedures  of  the  Senate  Judiciary 
Committee. 

We  appreciate  the  invitation  to  testify  before  this  subcommittee. 
It  is  most  gratifying-  to  see  Congress  expressing  such  timely  concern 
for  the  current  status  of  air  transportation  regulation  in  this  country. 

In  October  1974,  the  AOCI  membership,  at  its  annual  business  meet- 
ing, adopted  a  resolution  that :  (1)  Requests  and  urges  the  Civil  Aero- 
nautics Board  to  rededicate  its  efforts  in  the  spirit  and  intent  of  the 
Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as  amended,  to  further  develop  the 
domestic  air  transportation  system  in  the  public  interest;  (2)  resolves 
that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  shoulcl  immediately  reinstate  the 
judicial  and  evidertiary  processes  contained  in  its  rules  of  practice  in 
economic  proceedings,  involving  the  potential  authorization  of  new, 
altered  and/or  competitive  air  services;  and,  (3)  directs  the  AOCI 
ad  hoc  air  service  committee  to  prepare  and  implement  a  program  in- 
volving the  e^^.tire  domestic  membership  in  an  effort  to  bring  to  the 
attention  of  Congress  that  the  public  convenience  and  necessity  for 
adequate  air  services  can  no  longer  be  met  by  continuation  of  the 
moratorium  on  air  route  proceedings. 

This  action  was  taken  after  the  AOCI  air  service  committee,  based 
upon  careful  study,  reached  several  firm  conclusions  relative  to  the 
public  interest  in  air  transportation  matters. 


First,  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  has  for  the  past  5  years  main- 
tained a  moratorium  on  airline  route  strengthening  and  community 
air  service  improvements. 

The  Board  has  concentrated  almost  entirely  on  regulatory  and  de- 
velopmental responsibilities  on  improving  the  profitability  and  eco- 
nomic strength  of  the  scheduled  airlines,  setting  aside  virtually  every 
other  public  interest  consideration. 

Secondly,  the  moratorium  is  in  clear  conflict  with  the  law  and  the 
intent  of  Congress, 

A  concentration  on  carrier  interests  ignores  every  other  considera- 
tion mandated  by  Congress  as  being  in  the  public  interest,  and  in 
accordance  with  the  public  convenience  and  necessity. 

A  moratorium  also  clearly  contravenes  the  requirement  under  the 
law  that  applications  for  new  or  amended  air  service  certificates  or 
for  improved  public  air  service  are  required  to  be  set  down  for  public 
hearing  and  to  be  decided  as  speedily  as  possible. 

Lastly,  the  moratorium  has  had  a  major  adverse  impact  on  the 
public  interest. 

It  is  our  firm  conviction  that  the  moratorium  has  been  a  major  con- 
tributor to  rising  unit  costs  for  the  airlines,  repeated  fare  increases, 
reduced  competition,  reduced  public  service,  ex  parte  decisions  regard- 
ing excess  competition,  and  route  master  planning  that  usurps  the 
Board's  statutory  authority  and  responsibilities. 

Further  adverse  consequences  may  be  identified  as  follows:  an  un- 
healthy dependei^ce  by  the  airlines  on  the  CAB,  stifling  carrier  ini- 
tiative, efficiency,  and  discipline;  abandonment  of  route  strengthening 


697 

as  a  means  for  economic  benefit  to  carriers  and  cities  alike ;  an  end  to 
carrier  and  Board  effort  to  seek  out  and  develop  new  market  poten- 
tials; and  almost  complete  disregard  of  the  needs  of  the  cities  of 
America  for  air  service  improvements  and  related  economic 
strengthening. 

The  Board's  concentration  on  and  accommodation  to  the  financial 
health  of  the  carriers  has  produced  milestone  profit  results  for  the  in- 
dustry. It  has  done  more  than  return  the  carriers  to  profitability,  it 
has  returned  them  to  an  alltime  record  in  profitability.  And  this  re- 
sult was  achieved  in  the  face  of  record  high  fuel  prices,  record  high 
wage  levels  and  record  high  costs  in  virtually  every  other  category  in 
an  airline  operation. 

We  do  not  propose  the  abolition  of  the  CAB,  the  transfer  of  its 
functions  or  the  deregulation  of  the  industi-y.  From  1938  to  1970, 
under  the  aegis  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  this  Nation  has  pro- 
duced the  finest  civil  air  transportation  system  in  the  world. 

We  can  only  say,  however,  that  had  the  policies  of  the  last  5  yeara 
prevailed  during  the  first  33  years,  we  would  scarcely  have  progressed 
beyond  the  DC-3  era.  In  this  circumstance  we  have  and  will  present 
some  specific  suggestions  for  returning  the  Board  to  its  responsibilities 
for  enlightened  regulation.  The  Board  has,  over  the  years,  generally 
been  regarded  as  one  of  the  best  administrative  agencies  in  our  system 
of  government.  We  believe  our  objectives  and  our  proposals  are  de- 
signed to  help  ensure  that  it  achieve  its  full  potential. 

The  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI,  meeting  in  San  Diego  in  October 
of  last  year,  reviewed  the  extensive  work  and  analysis  of  its  air  serv- 
ice committee  and  completely  endorsed  the  committee's  recommenda- 
tion that  AOCI  seek  congressional  support  for  an  immediate  and 
complete  termination  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's  moratorium. 
Pursuant  to  that  action,  the  board  of  directors  directed  its  air  service 
committee  to  prepare  and  implement  a  program  to  that  end. 

Among  the  air  service  committee's  recommendations  on  which  the 
board  of  directors'  action  was  premised  were :  That  the  CAB  should 
lift  its  moratorium,  immediately  and  totally;  that  the  CAB  also 
launch  investigations  looking  toward  the  elimination  of  unnecessary 
public  service  restrictions  in  airline  certificates;  the  more  effective  use 
of  existing  air  carrier  authority,  some  of  which  has  lain  dormant  for 
many  years;  and  the  possibility  of  transferring  a  carrier's  unused  or 
poorly  used  operating  authority  to  a  carrier  with  more  incentive  and 
aptitude  for  its  more  effective  use. 

CAB  STAFF  STUDY  ON  ROUTE  ENTRY  POLICY :  THE  DOMESTIC  ROUTE  SYSTEM 

Work  went  forward  by  the  air  service  committee  toward  further 
definition,  refinement,  and  implementation  of  these  objectives.  How- 
ever, on  January  3,  1975,  the  air  service  committee  received  a  copy  of 
a  study  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Eights  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board  which  was  released  New  Year's  Eve,  1974.  The  study  was 
entitled  "The  Domestic  Route  System:  Analysis  and  Policy  Eec- 
ommendations,"  a  staff  study  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights, 
October  1974. 

A  superficial  glance  at  the  study  suggested  that  the  Bureau's  staff 
was  recommending  a  termination  of  the  moratorium  and  a  full  re- 


698 

sumption  of  the  Board's  route  and  service  developmental  respon- 
sibilities. Such  a  proposal  would  have  lent  substantial  impetus  to  the 
recommendations  of  the  air  service  committee,  and  eased  significantly 
its  burden.  Further  examination  of  the  study,  however,  gave  strong 
indication  that  the  BOR  staff  might  be  striving  for  the  exact  op- 
posite results,  that  is.  a  further  solidifying  of  the  moratorium. 

That  strong  possibility  made  it  urgently  incumbent  upon  the  air 
service  committee  to  determine  as  precisely  as  possible  the  full  im- 
pact that  the  Bureau's  recommendations  could  have  on  the  moratorium 
and  on  the  interests  of  the  population  clusters  represented  by  AOCI. 
Since  the  study,  the  first  of  its  type  released  by  the  Board's  staff,  was 
some  2  years  or  so  in  the  process  of  development  and  was  extremely 
broad  in  its  scope  and  implications,  it  required  a  substantial  amount 
of  time  for  evaluation. 

As  a  product  of  our  assessment,  one  fact  can  be  stated  without  any 
equivocation.  If  the  staff  recommendations  were  to  be  implemented 
by  the  CAB,  the  moratorium  would  effectively  become  permanent 
Board  policy. 

It  therefore  became  alarmingly  clear  to  the  subcommittee  that  the 
Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  staff  proposals  would  violate  each  of 
the  AOCI  public  service  objectives  enumerated;  and  this  was  the 
imanimous  conclusion  of  the  air  service  committee  meetin.<T  in  Phoenix 
in  Januarv  after  a  romprehensive  review  of  the  Bureau's  study  and 
the  objectives  of  AOCI. 

Further,  and  on  the  basis  of  this  comprehensive  review  and  evalu- 
ation, specific  statements  of  position  and  specific  legislative  recom- 
mendations were  unanimously  adopted  by  the  air  service  committee 
and  forwarded  to  the  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI  with  a  recommen- 
dation for  its  approval  at  its  meeting  scheduled  for  February  20, 1975. 

In  the  discussion  of  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  staff  study 
that  follows,  the  views  expressed  are  those  resulting  from  the  unan- 
imous conclusions  reached  by  the  air  service  co^^Tmittee  in  conse- 
quence of  its  extensive  evaluation  of  the  study.  The  essence  of  this 
discussion  is  containerl  in  the  recoi''Tmendations  whic^^.  ns  stated,  have 
been  forwarded  to  the  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI  for  considera- 
tion and  approval. 

The  study  conduc*"ed  bv  the  Bureau  of  Operatin.^;  Rights  formalizes 
as  future  policy  of  the  CAB.  the  route  moratorium  which  has  been 
in  effect  since  1970.  Generally,  the  proposed  rules  create  a  circum- 
stance which  prevents  the  CAB  from  proceeding  on  a  case-bv-case 
basis  by  establishing  certain  economic  obstacles,  or  standards,  de- 
signed ito  block  any  requirement  for  re.frulatory  action.  In  effect,  the 
standards  proposed  in  the  study  preclude  all  other  consi^lerations  with 
regard  to  the  determination  as  to  who  should  be  oertificated  to  pro- 
vide service  in  a  market.  They  prevent  certification  in  markets  that 
need  the  service  with  no  incumbent  authority  or,  more  importantly, 
in  the  markets  where  nonstop  authority  exists,  but  no  service  is 
provided. 

A  prejudgment  of  such  issues  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights 
by  proposing  this  technique  stronglv  suggests  that  the  Board  mem- 
bers themselves  should  be  precluded  from  assessing  and  deciding  serv- 
ice improvement  proposals  under  the  public  interest  guidelines  set 
down  by  Congress. 


ATIACHMENT     C 


CAB   PROCEDURE   FOR  ROUTE   APPLICATIONS 

At  this  point,  INIr.  Chairman,  I  would  like  to  invite  your  attention 
to  this  flow  chart.  We  have  taken  the  recommendations  of  the  Bureau 
of  Operating  Rights. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Why  don't  you  hold  it  up  again. 

[See  flow  chart  as  inserted  here.] 

Mr.  Gagnon.  AVe  have  taken  the  recommendations  of  the  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights  and  attempted  to  structure  them  in  a  flow  diagram 
relative  to  the  critevi:!.  or  standards  as  they  are  called,  for  service 
application.  Just  a  glance  indicates  how  complicated  this  process  can 
be.  We  are  deeply  concerned  that  the  criteria  and  so-called  standards 
depicted  here  are  not  only  expensive  and  time-consuming,  but  they 
are  virtually  unattainable. 

One  particular  area  through  this  chart  indicates  that  by  the  time 
you  have  done  all  of  these  things,  if  it  were  possible  to  do  them,  there 
is  one  opportunity,  a  last  opportunity  for  the  Board  to  set  aside  the 
whole  process  before  you  reach  the  hearing  opportunity.  This  scarcely 
conforms  in  any  respect. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  would  you  simplify  that? 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Simplify  this,  sir? 

Senator  Kennedy.  Yes,  sir. 

Mr.  Gagnon,  We  would  leave  the  hearing  process  the  way  it  is, 
which  takes  it  from  this  point  to  this  point  and  around  all  of  these 
criteria,  which  are  rather  like  a  clearinghouse  of  ideas,  and  back  over 
to  this  point,  which  is  the  hearing  process.  That  hearing  process  is 
one  that  has  been  established  over  time  and  has  been  quite  efficient 
over  time.  All  we  are  trying  to  do  is  get  that  hearing  process  to  un- 
stick itself  and  start  moving. 

Now  this  scarcely  conforms  in  any  respect  to  the  intent  of  Con- 
gress. It  is  the  Board  members  themselves  in  whom  the  public  trust 
has  been  vested  by  the  Congress,  and  by  Presidential  appointment 
confirmed  by  the  Senate.  It  is  the  individual  members  who  bear  the 
burden  and  the  privilege  of  decisional  responsibility  with  respect  to 
the  ultimate  issues  of  public  convenience  and  necessity  and  the  need 
for  changes  in  operating  authority. 

The  industry,  all  carriers,  and  the  public  are  entitled  to  the  Board 
members'  fair  "consideration  of  air  service  improvement  proposals  and 
to  the  full  exercise  of  their  responsibilities  within  the  spirit  and  the 
explicit  criteria  of  the  law  under  which  they  are  granted  the  right 
and  the  duty  to  function.  The  members  can  neither  be  prevented  nor 
protected  from  the  exercise  of  this  responsibility. 

Senator  Kennedy.  Are  you  satisfied  that  the  Board  has  the  resources 
to  hold  these  hearings,  for  all  qualified  meritorious  applicants? 

Mv.  Gagnon.  Yes,  I  am.  They  have  a  policy  of  procedure  by  which 
they  have  set  in  the  past,  distant  past  to  be  sure,  priorities,  but  they 
certainly  have  the  mechanism  for  setting  applications  for  hearings 
and  consolidating  applications  and  hearings. 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  can  you  really  regulate  the  nurnber  of  hear- 
ings, the  quality  of  the  hearings?  You  have  to  give  quite  extensive 
discretion,  do  you  not,  to  the  Board  in  these  areas?  Or  do  you  think 
that  you  can  draw  up  sufficient  guidelines  to  insure  that  legitimate 
applicants  get  a  reaction  or  a  response  by  the  Board  in  the  form  of  a 
hearing? 


700 


LEGISLATIVE    PROPOSALS 


Mr.  Gagnon.  We  have  suggested  seven  legislative  initiatives,  Sena- 
tor, and  we  are  suggesting  that  the  law  needs  a  little  bit  of  fine  tuning. 
Some  of  the  things  we  are  suggesting  as  legislative  initiatives,  to  be 
sure,  might  be  able  to  be  taken  into  regulatory  policy.  But  there  is  no 
assurance  that  that  regulatory  policy  will  be  consistent  in  its  appli- 
cation. We  need  some  legislation  and  some  regulatory  authority  for  all 
seasons.  We  need  it  (the  CAB)  to  have  a  regulatory  system  that  works 
in  good  times  as  well  as  bad  times.  So  we  feel  that  enlightened  regu- 
lation can  develop  the  commercial  air  transportation  industry  as  the 
primary  mass  tran'^^portation  moans  for  intercity  travel.  It  is  obvious  to 
us  tliat  this  capacity  ^s  present  witliin  tho  existing  regulatory  frame- 
work. The  first  step  called  for  is  to  pla^e  the  operating  authority  in  the 
hands  of  the  air  carr'ers  fit,  willing  and  able  to  provide  the  service.  We 
need  ppec^fic  direction  from  Congress  to  the  CAB  to  move  forward. 

The  air  service  committee  in  January  unanimously  proposed  to  the 
AOCI  Board  of  Directors  that  AOCI  support  seven  key  legislative 
amendments  to  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as  amended.  The 
amendments  are  designed  to  emphnsize,  in  specific  terms,  the  intent  of 
Congress  with  iTspect  to  the  n^ed  for  continuin.^  df'velopment  and  im- 
provement of  the  air  route  structure  and  the  public  air  services  of  this 
country,  and  to  ensure  that  the  language  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act 
permits  no  misunderstanding  or  misinterpretation  of  Congressional 
policy  and  intent  in  these  matters.  It  is  our  belief  that  the  basic  data 
contained  in  the  Bureau's  study  supports  our  recommended  legislative 
initiatives  completely. 

Three  of  the  key  legislative  recommendations  are  as  follows : 

First,  amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to 
require  prompt  and  expeditious  hearing  for  any  application  for  new 
or  improved  air  service  in  a  market  in  which  at  least  one  of  the  two 
cities  principally  affected,  and  at  least  one  certificated  air  carrier,  re- 
quest such  a  priority  hearing. 

Two,  amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  pro- 
vide that  nonstop  authority  which  is  not  exercised  for  1  year  will  be 
presumed  to  be  abandoned.  At  any  time  thereafter,  the  authority  to 
provide  such  service  should  be  granted  to  any  carrier  fit,  willing,  and 
able  to  exercise  the  autliority,  upon  application  of  any  party  in  interest. 

And,  to  amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to 
require  the  award  of  new  competitive  authority  wherever  it  can  be 
shown  that  the  carriers'  operations  in  the  market  will  produce  reason- 
able results.  This  proposed  amendment  is  predicted  upon  the  demon- 
strated fact  that  competition  develops  traffic,  improves  service,  lowers 
fares,  and  lowers  unit  costs  by  expanding  service  and  promoting 
efficiency,  all  for  the  public  benefit. 

In  conclusion,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  the  present  economic 
condition  of  the  industry  or  the  country  should  not  influence  the  de- 
sign of  regulatory  policies  which  must  necessarily  look  forward  to 
a  future  period  in  which  such  circumstances  will  no  longer  prevail. 
A  positive  regulatory  program  will  prove  effective  for  the  industry 
in  good  times  as  well  as  in  bad  times.  Decisions  made  today  will  effect 
the  industry  .for  many  years  to  come. 


701 

The  regulatory  environment  should  be  one  that  permits,  stimulates 
and  directs  substantial  growth  in  our  air  transport  industry,  the 
growth  that  is  so  vital  to  the  achievement  and  maintenance  of  maxi- 
mum efficiency.  It  is  from  this  achievement  that  so  many  fare,  traffic, 
service,  and  technological  benefits  have  historically  flowed.  When  these 
occur,  they  provide  substantial  stimuli  to  the  national  economy 
through  expansion  of  employment  in  the  airlines,  the  manufacturing 
companies,  airports  and  all  other  air  transport  related  industries. 
This  has  been  summary  testimony.  We  do  have  written  testimony 
on  file  with  the  subcommittee. 

Thank  you. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  want  to  acknowledge  in  the  record  your  full 
testimony.  Of  course,  it  will  be  made  a  part  of  the  record,  and  it  is 
really  enormously  comprehensive,  very  responsive  to  the  interests  of 
this  subcommittee.  I  think  it  entailed  a  great  deal  of  work.  We  just 
want  you  to  know  that  it  is  going  to  be  of  great  value  to  our  subcom- 
mittee, and  I  think  to  the  Congress,  generally. 

Manv  of  these  specific  recommendations,  in  terms  of  amendments  to 
the  Federal  Aviation  Act  and,  of  course,  legislative  proposals,  should 
go  through  the  Commerce  Committee.  We  are  going  to  bring  those 
to  their  attention  and  Ave  are  working  closely  with  the  Commerce 
Committee  and  others,  on  the  amendments  to  the  Administrative  Pro- 

But  this  is  an  enormously  constructive  document,  very  thoughtful 
and  comprehensive.  All  of  'your  organization  and  those  that  support 
your  organization  ought  to  understand  it.  It  is  really  a  very  construc- 
tive piece  of  work. 

Let  me  just  touch  on  a  few  areas.  As  I  understand  it,  you  mentioned 
that  a  more  liberal  entry  policy  could  mean  a  more  efficient  kind  of  air 
transportation  system. 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Yes. 

FREE   entry   and   AIRPORT   MANAGEMENT 

Senator  Kennedy.  Now,  what  is  going  to  happen  to  all  of  your  op- 
erators Avhen  you  get  fly-by-night  operations  coming  into  business, 
trying  to  rent 'space  in  the  various  airports,  trying  to  set  up  various 
gates  and  all  of  the  rest,  operators  that  may  be  here  today  and  gone 
tomorrow. 

What  is  this  going  to  mean,  in  terms  of  the  basic  kind  of  manage- 
ment problems  that'  your  people  are  facing  in  running  many  of  the 
airports  and  facilities  in  the  country?  Are  you  not  concerned  about 

We  heard  Professor  Jordan  indicate  that  there  might  be  100  to  200 
new  airlines  in  a  deregulated  industry.  Is  it  not  going  to  be  a  night- 
mare for  anv  of  vour  i)eop1e  to  try  and  make  a  decision  as  to  who  is 
legitimate,  who  is  not?  And  space,  how  can  you  deal  with  that 
problem.  Are  you  not  concerned?  Are  you  not  a  lot  better  oft  ]ust 
dealing  with  these  major  trunklines  that  you  have  known  and 
worked  with  for  some  period  of  vears,  and  know  exactly  what  to  ex- 
pect from?  You  know  that  thev  are  secure,  that  the  CAB  is  not  going 
to  let  them  get  in  too  bad  a  shape.  Does  not  this  make  your  lite  a  lot 
easier  and  less  complex  ? 


702 

Mr.  Gagxon.  Senator,  let  me  first  say  that  our  position,  with  respect 
to  free  entry,  is  one  in  which  we  say  that  regulated  free  entry  is  a 
possibility.  We  do  not  advocate  a  permissive  and  chaotic  approach  to 
entry.  Your  question  also  indicates  to  me  that  we  already  have,  to  some 
degree,  perhaps,  what  is  in  your  mind,  in  many  cities  and  on  many 
segments,  shorter  segments,  we  have  larger  airlines,  both  regional  and 
trunklines  backing  away  from  frequencies  and  conveniences  in  sched- 
uling that  would  constitute  real  quality  service.  This  is  inviting  other 
levels  of  operators  in,  not  nearly  so  sophisticated,  not  nearly  so  deeply 
capitalized.  These  people  operate  within  the  published  standards  of 
the  FAA,  which  is  essentially  the  watchdog  of  airworthiness.  And 
they  come  to  us  and  say  we  would  like  to  do  these  things.  From  my  part, 
from  my  own  personal  experience,  we  are  eager  to  have  these  people 
make  the  attempt. 

We  have  heard  today,  for  instance,  that  North  Central,  I  believe, 
started  with  a  couple  of  Cessna's  many,  many  years  ago.  I  still  per- 
sonally believe  that  this  is  a  viable  approach,  that  our  third-level 
industry  has  started  that  way.  We  do  have  one  now.  It  will  be  a  recog- 
nized and  honored  third  level  of  carrier  in  the  immediate  future.  There 
are  a  lot  of  them.  A  lot  of  them  go  broke. 

As  yet,  the  CAB  has  not  regulated  this  area  of  carrier.  But  speaking 
as  an  airport  operator,  we  do  not  see  the  proliferation  of  those  who 
really  want  to  compete  and  can  compete  financially  having  a  great 
problem  with  getting  the  job  done  at  airports. 

'secondary"  airports 

Senator  Kennedy.  Let  us  assume,  for  example.  World  Airways  were 
to  get  certification  to  fly  across  the  country,  serving  secondary  rather 
than  primary  airports.  Do  you  think  adequate  facilities  exist  in  most 
of  the  major  market  areas  to  be  able  to  provide  services  for  the  people, 
in  terms  of  transportation,  and  parking,  and  counter  space,  as  well  as 
other  airport  space. 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Senator,  I  heard  that  testimony  and  I  have  devoted, 
I  guess,  most  of  my  adult  life  to  this  industry.  I  have  never  heard  of 
a  secondary  airport.  Now,  he  mav  be  using  very  loosely  a  term  that  he 
is  not  too  familiar  with.  Any  airport  that  supports,  on  a  scheduled 
basis,  regular  transportation,  commercial  transportation,  has  to  be  a 
certificated  airport  under  the  law.  Now,  he  may  be  referring  to  smaller 
airports,  smaller  airports,  yes.  I  think  that  there  are  some  good  po- 
tentials for  smaller  airports,  excellent  potentials  for  smaller  airports. 
I  know  that  on  our  board  of  directors  there  is  a  particular  situation 
where  there  is  a  smaller  airport  operator  who  has  some  scheduled 
service,  but  the  scheduled  service  is  at  a  time  of  day  and  at  a  fre- 
quency that  really  is  not  very  cost  beneficial  to  that  community. 

CAB   PROCEDURE   FOR   ROUTE   APPLICATIONS 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  outlined  some  of  the  procedures  requiring 
the  CAB  to  hold  hearings  and  reach  decisions  when  the  applicant 
requests  priority  of  hearings.  Could  that  not  be  abused? 

Could  the  CXB  not  be  inundated  with  various  applicants,  which 
apply  for  priority  of  hearings.  We  heard  the  request  for  certification 
to  fly  to  the  Moon,  which  was  given  as  an  example  of  possible  abuses. 


703 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Well,  sir,  I  can  only  just  make  some  sort  of  conjectural 
approach  to  that.  We  have  discussed  it  to  some  degree. 

I  would  think  that  the  CAB  has,  perhaps,  to  expand  its  staff  a  bit 
to  prepare  this  material,  and  they  may  have  to  establish  some  regional 
facilities  in  order  that  evidence  can  be  gathered.  This  may  be  necessary. 
There  is  a  great  backlog. 

Senator  Kennedy.  1  suppose  it  would  be  reasonable  to  think  that  if 
you  had  an  expeditious  handling  of  any  of  the  requests,  that  you  could 
have  a  summary  dismissal  of  any  of  these  requests  with  the  reasons  for 
it.  That  would  be  the  best  way  to  handle  it.  If  it  is  a  spurious  kind  of 
application,  you  can  dismiss  it  quickly,  easily,  with  a  brief  explanation, 
and  at  least  have  the  issue  resolved,  rather  than  having  these  inordinate 
delays.  I  suppose  that  is  what  we  are  talking  about. 

Mr.  Gagnon.  This  is  a  question  that  we  would  like  to  make  further 
input  to.  We  have  not  discussed  it  on  the  subcommittee,  but  we  feel  that 
under  the  quoted  policy,  I  believe  it  is  -399.60,  that  the  Board  does  have 
authority  to  set  priorities  and  to  establish  standards  for  hearing  appli- 
cations. 

That  is  fine  on  the  one  hand.  We  think  that  probably  has  to  have 
some  change.  We  would  like  to  suggest,  officially  suggest  to  the  Board, 
the  methods  of  doine:  that.  We  recosrnize  their  legal  right  to  do  these 
things,  to  set  priorities,  to  set  standards.  But  this  is  a  standard  we  feel 
cannot  occur,  the  standard  set  forth  as  a  recommendation  of  policy  in 
the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  analysis  of  the  domestic  route  system 
just  cannot  occur.  It  is  a  stone  wall  as  far  as  we  are  concerned  to  appli- 
cations. 

FREE   ENTRY   AND   SMALL-TOWN    SERVICE 

Senator  Kennedy.  You  do  not  think  that  the  policy  which  you  have 
talked  about  this  afternoon  is  going  to  adversely  affect  the  integrated 
air  transportation  system  in  such  a  way  that  it  could  bring  rather 
serious  hardships  to  the  people  that  you  represent  ? 

Mr.  Gagnon.  "What,  sir  ? 

Senator  Kennedy.  That  freer  entry  system. 

Mr.  Gagnon.  No.  sir.  No  indeed.  This  free  entry,  and  what  we  call  a 
use-it-or-lose-it  policy  here,  we  believe,  will  adjust  the  system  of  vari- 
ous carriers  operating  today  to  a  very  beneficial  extent ;  that  there  may 
be  some  opportunities  for  new  carriers  to  come  into  markets  that 
already  are  established  for  them.  They  will  have,  if  they  can  keep  the 
pace  tiiev  will  have,  probably,  a  monopoly  opportunity  for  a  while. 
They  will  have  an  opportunity  to  buiM  a  market.  We  do  not  see  the 
free*  entry  as  a  result  of  Board  approval  as  causing  the  airports  or 
those  kinds  of  facilities  in  the  national  airport  system  any  problems 
whatsoever. 

description  of  aoci 

Senator  Kennedy.  How  many  people  do  you  represent  in  your  or- 
ganization? . 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Mv  individual  organization,  or  in  AOCI.  Speakmg 
as  AOCI,  we  represent  186  cities,  counties.  States,  and  other  regional 
organizations,  which,  in  turn,  accounts  for  approximately  60  percent 
of  the  U.S.  population.  Our  airports,  in  1974,  also  accounted  for  ap- 
proximately 90  percent  of  the  enplaned  passengers  in  that  year.  So  we 
have  some  very  substantial  public  interest  base  in  these  matters. 


704 

Senator  Kennedy.  Thank  you  very  much  for  your  very  helpful 
testimony. 

Mr.  Gagnon.  Thank  you. 

Senator  Kennedy.  We  would  like  to  feel  that  we  could  stay  in  touch 
with  you  as  we  move  through  the  course  of  these  hearings.  I  want  to 
thank  you  and  your  associates  very  much. 

The  subcommittee  stands  in  recess  until  9  o'clock,  tomorrow  morning. 

[Whereupon,  at  -t  p.m.,  the  subconunittee  adjourned,  to  reconvene 
at  9  a.m.  the  next  day.] 

[The  prepared  statement  of  Mr.  Gagnon  follows:] 

Summary  of  Prepared  Statement  of  James  Gagnon 

My  name  is  James  Gagnon.  I  am  general  manager  and  chief  executive  oflBcer 
of  the  Louisville  and  Jefferson  County  Air  Board,  Louisville,  Kentucky.  I  am 
chairman  of  the  ad  hoc  committee  on  air  service  of  the  Airport  Operators 
Council  International.  It  is  in  this  latter  capacity  that  I  offer  the  following 
testimony  to  the  Subcommittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure  of 
the  Senate  Judiciary  Committee.  We  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  testify  before 
this  subcommittee.  It  is  most  gratifying  to  see  Congress  expressing  such  timely 
concern  for  the  current  status  of  air  transportation  regulation  in  this  country. 

In  October,  1974,  the  AOCI  membership,  at  its  annual  business  meeting, 
adopted  a  resolution  that : 

(1)  requests  and  urges  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  rededicate  its 
efforts  in  the  spirit  and  intent  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as 
amended,  to  further  develop  the  domestic  air  transportation  system  in  the 
public  interest ; 

(2)  resolves  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  should  immediately  re- 
instate the  judicial  and  evidentiary  processes  contained  in  its  Rules  of 
Practice  in  Economic  Proceedings,  involving  the  potential  authorization  of 
new,  altered  and/or  competitive  air  services  ;  and 

(3)  directs  the  AOCI  ad  hoc  air  service  committee  to  prepare  and  imple- 
ment a  program  involving  the  entire  domestic  member^tiip  in  an  effort  to 
bring  to  the  attention  of  Congress  that  the  public  convenience  and  necessity 
for  adequate  air  services  can  no  longer  be  met  by  continuation  of  the  mora- 
torium on  air  route  proceedings. 

This  action  was  taken  after  the  AOCI  air  service  committee,  based  upon 
careful  study,  reached  several  firm  conclusions  relative  to  the  public  interest  in 
air  transportation  matters. 

THE  CrVIL  AERONArTICS  BOARD  HAS  FOR  THE  PAST  5  YEARS  MAINTAINED  A 
MORATORIUM  ON  AIRLINE  ROUTE  STRENGTHENING  AND  COMMUNITY  AIR  SERVICE 
IMPROVEMENTS 

The  Board  has  concentrated  amost  its  entire  regulatory  and  developmental 
responsibilities  on  improving  the  profitability  and  economic  strength  of  the 
scheduled  airlines,  setting  aside  virtually  every  other  public  interest 
consideration. 

THE   MORATORIUM    IS    IN    CLEAR    CONFLICT   WITH    THE   LAW    AND   THE 
INTENT   OF   CONGRESS 

A  concentration  on  carrier  interests  ignores  every  other  consideration  man- 
dated by  Congress  as  being  "in  the  public  interest"  and  "in  accordance  with 
the  public  convenience  and  necessity." 

A  moratorium  also  clearly  contravenes  the  requirement  under  the  law  that 
applications  for  new  or  amended  air  service  certificates  or  for  improved  public 
air  service  are  required  to  be  set  dowTi  for  public  hearing  and  to  be  decided 
as  speedily  as  possible. 

THE   MORATORIUM,  HAS   A    MAJOR   ADVERSE   IMPACT  ON   THE   PUBLIC   INTEREST 

It  is  our  firm  conviction  that  the  moratorium  has  been  a  major  contributor 
to:  1)  rising  unit  costs  for  the  airlines;  2)  repeated  fare  increases;  3)  reduced 
competition;  4)  reduced  public  service;  5)  ex  parte  decisions  regarding  excess 


705 

competition;  and  6)  route  master  planning  that  usurps  the  Board's  statutory 
authority  and  responsibilities.  Further  adverse  consequences  may  be  identified 
as  follows:  a)  an  unhealthy  dependence  by  the  airlines  on  the  CAB  stifling  car- 
rier initiative,  efficiency  and  discipline;  b)  abandonment  of  route  strengthening 
as  a  means  for  economic  benefit  to  carriers  and  cities  alike;  c)  an  end  to  carrier 
and  Board  effort  to  seek  out  and  develop  new  market  potentials;  and  d)  almost 
complete  disregard  of  the  needs  of  the  cities  of  America  for  air  service  improve- 
ments and  related  economic  strengthening. 

The  Board's  concentration  on  and  accommodation  to  the  financial  health 
of  the  carriers  has  produced  milestone  profit  results  for  the  industry.  It  has 
done  more  than  return  the  carriers  to  profitability,  it  has  returned  them  to  an 
all-time  record  in  profitability.  And  this  result  was  achieved  in  the  face  of 
record  high  fuel  prices,  record  high  wage  levels  and  record  high  costs  in  virtually 
every  other  category  in  an  airline  operation. 

We  do  not  propose  the  abolition  of  the  CAB,  the  transfer  of  its  functions  or 
the  deregulation  of  the  industry.  From  1938  to  1970,  under  the  aegis  of  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board,  this  nation  has  produced  the  finest  civil  air  transportation 
system  in  the  world.  We  can  only  say,  however,  that  had  the  policies  of  the  last 
5  years  prevailed  during  the  first  33  years,  we  would  scarcely  have  progressed 
beyond  the  DC-3  era.  In  this  circumstance  we  have  and  will  present  some  spe- 
cific suggestions  for  returning  the  Board  to  its  responsibilities  for  enlightened 
regulation.  The  Board  has,  over  the  years,  generally  been  regarded  as  one  of  the 
best  administrative  agencies  in  our  system  of  government.  We  believe  our  objec- 
tives and  our  proposals  are  designed  to  help  insure  that  it  achieve  its  full 
potential. 

The  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI,  meeting  in  San  Diego  in  October  of  last  year, 
reviewed  the  extensive  work  and  analysis  of  its  air  service  committee  and  com- 
pletely endorsed  the  committee's  recommendation  that  AOCI  seek  Congressional 
support  for  an  immediate  and  complete  termination  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board's  moratorium.  Pursuant  to  that  action  the  Board  of  Directors  directed  its 
air  service  committee  to  "prepare  and  implement  a  program"  to  that  end. 

Among  the  air  service  committee's  recommendations  on  which  the  Board  of 
Directors'  action  was  premised  were  : 

That  the  CAB  should  lift  its  moratorium,  immediately  and  totally ; 
That  the  CAB  also  launch  investigations  looking  toward : 

the   elimination   of   unnecessary  public  service  restrictions  in  airline 
certificates ; 

the  more  effective  use  of  existing  air  carrier  authority,  some  of  which 
has  lain  dormant  for  many  years  ;  and 

the  ix)ssibility  of  transferring  a  carrier's  unused  or  poorly  used  operat- 
ing authority  to  a  carrier  with  more  incentive  and  aptitude  for  its  more 
effective  use. 
Work  went  forward  by  the  air  service  committee  toward  further  definition, 
refinement  and  implementation  of  these  objectives.  On  January  3.  1975,  however, 
the  air  service  committee  received  a  copy  of  a  study  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating 
Rights  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  which  was  released  New  Year's  Eve,  1974. 
The  study  was  entitled  :  The  Domestic  Route  System :  Analysis  and  Policy  Rec- 
ommendations, a  staff  study  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  October  1974. 

A  superficial  glance  at  the  study  suggested  that  the  Bureau's  staff  was  recom- 
mending a  termination  of  the  moratorium  and  a  full  resumption  of  the  Board's 
.route  and  service  developmental  responsibilities.  Such  a  proposal  would  have 
lent  substantial  impetus  to  the  recommendations  of  the  air  service  committee, 
and  eased  significantly  its  burden.  Further  examination  of  the  study,  however, 
gave  strong  indication  that  the  BOR  staff  might  be  striving  for  the  exact  opposite 
results,  i.e.,  a  further  solidifying  of  the  moratorium. 

That  strong  pos.*^ibility  made  it  urgently  incumbent  upon  the  air  service  com- 
mittee to  determine  as  precisely  as  possible  the  full  impact  that  the  Bureau's 
re  ommendations  could  have  on  the  moratorium  and  on  the  interests  of  the 
population  clusters  represented  by  AOCI.  Since  the  study,  the  first  of  its  type 
released  bv  the  Boards  staff,  was  some  two  years  or  so  in  the  process  of  develop- 
ment and  was  extremely  broad  in  its  scope  and  implications,  it  required  a  sub- 
stantial amount  of  time  for  evaluation. 

As  a  proiluet  of  our  assessment,  one  fact  can  be  stated  without  any  equivo- 
cation:  If  the  staff  recommendations  were  to  be  implemented  by  the  CAB,  the 
moratorium  would  effeetivelv  become  iiermanent  Board  policy.  If  therefore  be- 
came alarminglv  clear  to  the  committee  that  the  BOR  staff  proposals  would  vio- 


706 

late  each  of  the  AOCI  public  service  objectives  enumerated ;  and  this  was  the 
unanimous  conclusion  of  the  air  service  committee  meeting  in  Phoenix  in  January 
after  a  comprehensive  review  of  the  Bureau's  study  and  the  objectives  of  AOCI. 
Further,  and  on  the  basis  of  this  comprehensive  review  and  evaluation,  specific 
statements  of  position  and  specific  legislative  recommendations  were  unanimously 
adopted  by  the  air  service  committee  and  forwarded  to  the  Board  of  Directors 
of  AOCI  with  a  recommendation  for  its  approval  at  its  meeting  scheduled  for 
February  20,  1975. 

In  the  discussion  of  the  BOR  staff  study  that  follows,  the  views  expressed  are 
those  resulting  from  the  unanimous  conclusions  reached  by  the  air  service  com- 
mittee in  consequence  of  its  extensive  evaluation  of  the  study.  The  essence  of  this 
discussion  is  contained  in  the  recommendations  which,  as  stated,  have  been  for- 
warded to  the  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI  for  consideration  and  approval. 

AIR   SERVICE   COMMITTEE   EVALUATION,   BUREAU   STUDY:    "THE   DOMESTIC   ROUTE 
SYSTEM  :    ANALYSIS    AND   POLICY    RECOMMENDATIONS" 

The  study  condu  ted  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  formalizes,  as  future 
policy  of  the  CAB,  the  route  moratorium  which  has  been  in  effect  since  1970. 
Generally,  the  proposed  rules  create  a  circumstance  which  prevents  the  CAB  from 
proceeding  on  a  case-by-case  basis  by  establishing  certain  economic  obstacles 
(standards)  designed  to  block  any  requirement  for  regulatory  action.  In  effect, 
the  standards  proposed  in  the  study  preclude  all  other  considerations  with  regard 
to  the  determination  as  to  who  should  be  certificated  to  provide  service  in  a 
market.  They  prevent  certification  in  markets  that  need  the  service  with  no  incum- 
bent authoriy  or,  more  importantly,  in  the  markets  where  nonstop  authority 
exists,  but  no  service  is  provided. 

A  preiudgment  of  such  issues  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  by  proposing 
this  technique  strongly  suggests  that  the  Board  members  themselves  should  be 
pre-luded  from  assessing  and  deciding  service  improvement  proposals  under  the 
public  interest  guidelines  set  down  by  Congress.  This  scarcely  conforms  in  any 
respect  to  the  intent  of  Congres.s.  It  is  the  Board  members  themselves  in  whom  the 
public  trust  has  been  vested  by  the  Congress,  and  by  Presidential  appointment 
confirmed  by  the  Senate.  It  is  the  individual  members  who  bear  the  burden  and 
the  privilege  of  decisional  responsibility  with  respect  to  the  ultimate  issues  of 
public  convenience  and  necessity  and  the  need  for  changes  in  operating  authority. 
The  industry  (all  carriers)  and  the  public  are  entitled  to  the  Board  members' 
fair  consideration  of  air  service  improvement  proposals  and  to  the  full  exercise 
of  their  responsibilities  within  the  spirit  and  the  explicit  criteria  of  the  law  under 
which  they  are  granted  the  right  and  the  duty  to  function.  The  members  can 
neither  be  prevented  nor  protected  from  the  exercise  of  this  responsibility. 

Recommendations 

Enlightened  regulation  can  develop  the  commercial  air  transport  industry  as 
the  primary  mass  transportation  means  for  intercity  travel.  It  is  obvious  to  us 
that  this  capacity  is  present  within  the  existing  regulatory  framework.  The 
first  step  called  for  is  to  place  the  operating  authority  in  the  hands  of  the  air 
carriers  fit,  willing  and  able  to  provide  the  service.  We  need  specific  direction 
from  Congress  to  the  CAB  to  move  forward. 

The  air  service  committee  in  January  unanimously  proposed  to  the  AOCI  board 
of  directors  that  OACI  support  seven  key  legislative  amendments  to  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act.  The  amendments  are  designed  to  emphasize,  in  specific  terms,  the 
intent  of  Congress  with  respect  to  the  need  for  continuing  development  and  im- 
provement of  the  air  route  structure  and  the  public  air  services  of  this  country, 
and  to  insure  that  the  language  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  permits  no  misunder- 
standing or  misinterpretation  of  Congres-sional  policy  and  intent  in  these  matters. 
It  is  our  belief  that  the  basic  data  contained  in  the  Bureau's  study  supports  our 
recommended  legislative  initiatives  completely. 

Three  of  the  kev  le-rislative  recommendations  are  : 

(1)  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require 
prompt  and  expeditious  hearing  for  any  application  for  new  or  improved  air 
service  in  a  market  in  which  at  least  one  of  the  two  cities  principally  affected, 
and  at  least  one  certificated  air  carrier,  request  such  a  priority  hearing ; 

(2)  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  provide  that 
nonstop  authoritv  which  is  not  exercised  for  one  year  will  be  iiresumed  to  be 
abandoned.  At  any  time  thereafter,  the  authority  to  provide  su?h  service 


707 

should  be  granted  to  any  carrier  fit,  willing,  and  able  to  exercise  the  author- 
ity, upon  application  of  any  party  in  interest ; 

(3)   Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require  the 
award  of  new  competitive  authority  wherever  it  can  be  shown  that  the  car- 
riers' operations  in  the  market  will  produce  reasonable  results.  This  proposed 
amendment  is  predicated  upon  the  demonstrated  fact  that  competition  devel- 
ops traffic,  improves  service,  lowers  fares,  and  lowers  unit  costs  by  expand- 
ing service  and  promoting  efficiency,  all  for  the  public  benefit. 
In  conclusion,  it  should  be  emphasized  that  the  present  economic  condition  of 
the  industry  or  the  country  should  not  influence  the  design  of  regulatory  policies 
which  must  nece.'^sarily  look  forward  to  a  future  period  in  which  such  circum- 
stances will  no  longer  prevail.  A  positive  regulatory  program  will  prove  effective 
for  the  industry  in  good  times  as  well  as  in  bad  times.  Decisions  made  today  will 
affect  the  industry  for  many  years  to  come. 

The  regulatory  environment  should  be  one  that  permits,  stimulates  and  di- 
rects substantial  growth  in  our  air  transport  industry,  the  growth  that  is  so 
vital  to  the  achievement  and  maintenance  of  maximum  efficiency.  It  is  from  this 
achievement  that  so  many  fare,  traffic,  service  and  technological  benefits  have 
historically  flowed.  When  these  occur,  they  provide  substantial  stimuli  to  the 
national  economy  through  expansion  of  employment  in  the  airlines,  the  manufac- 
turing companies,  airports  and  all  other  air  transport  related  industries. 


Prepared   Statement  of  James   Gagnon 

My  name  is  James  Gagnon.  I  am  general  manager  and  chief  executive  officer 
of  the  Louisville  and  Jefferson  County  Air  Board,  Louisville,  Kentucky.  I  am 
also  chairman  of  the  ad  hoc  committee  on  air  service  of  the  Airport  Operators 
Council  International.  It  is  in  this  latter  capacity  that  I  offer  the  following 
testimony  to  the  Subcomittee  on  Administrative  Practice  and  Procedure  of  the 
Senate  Judiciary  Committee. 

The  Airport  Operators  Council  International  is  an  organization  of  public 
entities  that  have  the  responsibility  and  authority  to  accommodate  air  trans- 
portation within  their  respective  communities.  The  domestic  membership  numbers 
187  cities,  counties,  states  and  regional  public  agencies  serving  metropolitan 
areas  which  account  for  more  than  60  iiercent  of  the  total  U.S.  population.  For 
the  year  ended  March  31,  1974,  airports  operated  by  the  domestic  membership 
of  AOCI  accounted  for  about  90  percent  of  the  total  U.S.  passenger  enplanements 
on  the  certiflcated  air  carriers.  With  this  vast  constituency,  the  AOCI  is  the 
organization  best  suited  to  represent,  at  first  hand,  the  public  interest  in  air 
transportation  matters  before  the  Congress  and  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

In  October,  1974,  the  AOCI  membership,  at  its  annual  business  meeting,  adopted 
a   resolution   that : 

(1)  requests  and  urges  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  rededicate  its 
efforts  in  the  spirit  and  intent  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as 
amended,  to  further  develop  the  domestic  air  transportation  system  in  the 
public  interest ; 

(2)  resolves  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  should  immediately  re- 
instate the  judicial  and  evidentiary  processes  contained  in  its  Rules  of 
Practice  in  Economic  Proceedings,  involving  the  potential  authorization  of 
new,  altered  and/or  competitive  air,  services ;  and 

(3)  directs  the  AOCI  ad  hoc  air  service  committee  to  prepare  and  imple- 
ment a  program  involving  the  entire  domestic  membership  in  an  effort  to 
bring  to  the  attention  of  Congress  that  the  public  convenience  and  necessity 
for  adequate  air  services  can  no  longer  be  met  by  continuation  of  the 
moratorium  on  air  route  proceedings. 

This  action  was  taken  after  the  AOCI  air  service  committee,  based  upon  care- 
ful study,  reached  several  firm  conclusions  relative  to  the  public  interest  in  air 
transportation  matters.  These  conclusions  were : 

(1)  Since  1970,  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  has  overtly  engaged  in  a 
moratorium  on  its  regulatory  activities,  which  moratorium  has  prevented 
the  authorization  of  new,  altered  and/or  competitive  domestic  air  service 
patterns  within  the  U.S.  domestic  air  transportation  system. 

(2)  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's  moratorium  on  regulatory  activities 
relative  to  domestic  air  carrier  routes  is  in  confiict  with  the  law  and  legis- 
lative mandate  of  the  Congress  of  the  United  States. 


708 

(3)  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's  moratorium,  although  it  may  or  may 
not  be  in  the  best  economic  interests  of  the  U.S.  certificated  air  carriers,  is 
in  fact  detrimental  to  the  public  interest  as  provided  for  by  the  Congress. 

(4)  The  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's  moratorium  on  regulatory  activities 
relative  to  domestic  air  carrier  routes  is  contrary  to  established  AOCI 
objectives  and  policies  as  set  forth  in  the  organization's  bylaws  and  policy 
handbooli. 

(5)  There  currently  is  and  always  has  been  a  lack  of  public  interest 
representation  before  the  Congress  and  at  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

(6)  There  is  a  vital  need  for  effective  public  interest  representation 
before  the  Congress  and  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  in  the  adjudication  of  and 
policy  determinations  in  air  transportation  matters  of  broad  national  concern. 

(7)  The  service  requirements  and  interests  of  the  smaller  communities 
of  the  Nation  are  in  particular  need  of  effective  national  representation. 

(8)  The  Airport  Operators  Council  International  is  best  suited  to  rep- 
resent the  public  interest  in  air  transportation  matters  before  the  Congress 
and  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

Attachment  A  to  this  testimony  is  the  initial  report  of  the  AOCI  air  service 
committee  to  the  organization's  board  of  directors,  submitted  October  6,  1974. 
Attachment  B  is  the  supporting  documentation  for  the  conclusions  and  recommen- 
dations contained  in  attachment  A. 

It  is  widely  recognized  thnt  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  is  a  developmental  statute ; 
and  it  will  remain  so  until  Congress  says  otherwise.  We  strongly  adhere  to  the 
belief  that  a  great  deal  of  development  remains  to  be  done  in  this  industry.  Not 
one  of  the  Act's  fundamental  objectives  has  been  rendered  obsolete.  One  of  its 
principal  aims  is  to  make  certain  that  an  air  transportation  system  is  developed 
that  will  properly  accommodate  the  "present"  and  "future"  needs  of  this  nation. 
This  is  a  living,  ongoing  requirement.  In  the  Congressional  declaration  of  policy 
in  the  Act,  it  is  stated  that  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  in  carrying  out  its 
responsibilities  under  the  law,  "shall  consider"  certain  factors,  among  others, 
"as  being  in  the  public  interest,  and  in  accordance  with  the  public  convenience 
and  necessity."  The  listing  includes  the  Board's  responsibility  to  "foster  sound 
economic  conditions"  in  the  airline  industry.  No  one  will  deny  that  a  healthy  air 
transportation  industry  is  one  of  the  Board's  major  considerations.  But  not  to 
the  exclusion  of  several  other  major  considerations  declared  to  be  "in  the  public 
interest  and  in  accordance  with  the  public  convenience  and  necessity." 

The  "encouragement  and  development  of  an  air  transportation  system  properly 
adapted  to  the  present  and  future  needs  of  the  .  .  .  domestic  commerce  of  the 
United  States"  is  a  major  responsibility ;  the  recognition  and  preservation  of 
"the  inherent  advantages"  of  air  transportation  is  another ;  the  "promotion  of 
adequate  .  .  .  service  by  air  carriers"  is  still  another.  Finally,  in  dealing  with 
the  matter  of  air  transportation  services,  the  Congressional  declaration  of  policy 
underscores  the  most  basic  tenet  of  the  American  free  enterprise  system,  the 
Board's  responsibility  to  provide  for  "competition  to  the  extent  necessary  to 
assure  the  sound  development  of  an  air  transportation  .system  properly  adapted 
to  the  needs  of  the  .  .  .  domestic  commerce  of  the  United  States."  The  intent 
of  Congress  when  it  directs  the  Board,  through  the  very  law  which  created  the 
Board,  to  hold  a  hearing  on  a  certificate  application  and  to  authorize  the  services 
sought  if  they  are  required  by  the  public  convenience  and  necessity,  is  that  the«e 
concepts,  principles  and  standards  must  be  considered  by  the  Board.  When  a  public 
hearing  is  held,  the  standards  by  which  a  proposed  service  will  be  adjudged  are 
known  factors.  How  then  can  the  Board  escape  the  application  of  those  standards 
and  deny  the  authority  requested,  by  the  simple  expedient  of  refusing  to  hear? 

Section  401(c)  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  (1958)  expressly  requires  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  set  down  for  public  hearing  any  certificate  applica- 
tion filed  with  it  and  to  "dispose  of  such  application  as  speedily  as  possible." 
Further,  if  it  finds  that  the  service  for  which  a  certificate  is  sought  is  "required 
by  the  public  convenience  and  necessity,"  it  is  incumbent  upon  the  Board  to 
issue  a  certificate  authorizing  and  requiring  the  performance  of  such  service 
by  an  air  carrier  ( Sections  401  ( k )  and  404  ( a ) ) . 

It  is  not  possible  to  weigh  and  evaluate  the  public  convenience  and  necessity 
by  inaction  or  default.  Inaction,  default  or  moratorium  can  only  constitute  a 
denial  without  due  process  of  law — a  law  which  very  carefully  details  what  must 
be  considered.  It  cannot  reasonably  be  assumed  that  no  proposal  for  public 
service  improvement  or  for  route  improvement  could  offer  any  real  opportunity 


709 

for  solid  and  substantial  public  or  carrier  benefit.  It  cannot  properly  be  assumed 
that  none  could  survive  intelligent  examination  and  evaluation,  through  the 
hearing  process.  For  the  Board  to  fail  and  refuse  to  provide  this  hearing  op- 
portunity does  in  effect  constitute  the  repeal  of  an  Act  of  Congress  by  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board — a  creature  of  Congress  established  to  carry  out  the  vpill  of 
Congress. 

The  elements  of  the  statutory  mandate  which  I  have  very  briefly  enumerated 
can  scarcely  countenance  a  moratorium.  On  the  contrary  it  is  clear  that  a  mora- 
torium is  repugnant  to  the  intent  of  Congress.  Yet,  since  1970  the  CAB  has 
admittedly  been  following  a  policy  of  concentrating  its  regulatory  and  develop- 
mental responsibilities  on  improving  the  profitability  and  economic  strength  of 
the  scheduled  airlines  of  the  nation.  It  has  avowed  also,  in  effect,  that  any  other 
public  interest  considerations  would  be  set  aside  until  the  carriers'  economic 
needs  had  been  fully  satisfied.  That  policy  has  been  continued  and  repeatedly 
emphasized  to  this  date.  For  all  practical  purposes,  the  Board  has  for  several 
years  now  rejected  any  real  consideration  of  the  "public  interest"  in  matters 
pertaining  to  possible  route  or  public  service  improvements,  even  though  that 
is  the  paramount  purpose  of  the  developmental  statute  under  which  the  Board 
operates. 

Present  Board  policy  is  a  complete  abdication  of  this  function  and  responsi- 
bility. Not  only  has  it  stagnated  the  public  interest  process  and  its  intended 
b.^nefits,  it  appears  to  be  destroying  the  initiatives  and  incentives  that  are  so 
fundamental  to  a  developmental  statute.  The  vacuum  created  by  this  policy  is 
literally  obliterating  vast  opportunities  for  economic  growth  by  carriers  and 
cities  alike,  and  at  the  same  time  the  need  in  this  nation  for  air  service  growth 
and  for  improved  air  services  continues  to  grow  at  an  accelerating  pace. 

The  membership  of  the  AOCI  is  aware  that  the  matters  over  which  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board  has  purview  are  complex  and  we  acknowledge  the  need 
for  careful  deliberation  into  the  effect  of  regulation  or  lack  thereof  in  the  air 
transportation  industry.  We  do  not,  on  the  other  hand,  acknowledge  or  accept 
that  the  regulation  of  air  transportation  need  be  so  sophisticated  as  to  defy 
understanding  nor  so  esoteric  as  to  be  performed  without  public  knowledge  or 
consultation. 

It  is  our  further  view  that  the  imposition  of  this  moratorium  has  frozen,  and 
in  many  instances,  degraded  an  imperfect  air  transportation  system  in  the 
United  States.  During  the  time  that  the  public  voice  has  been  silenced  at  the 
CAB  through  the  moratorium  on  public  hearing  processes,  the  following  con- 
sequences, adverse  to  the  public  interest  and  in  conflict  with  the  intent  of  Con- 
gress, have  become  manifest:  (1)  increasingly  higher  unit  costs  for  the  airlines; 
(2)  repeated  fare  increases;  (3)  reduced  competition;  (4)  reduced  public  air 
service;  (5)  ex  parte  decisions  regarding  excessive  competition;  and  (6)  the 
concent  of  master  air  route  system  planning  without  the  legal  requirement  for 
evidentiary  process :  worse  yet,  the  Board's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  con- 
tenioiates  a  predetermination  of  the  shape  and  substance  of  the  nation's  air 
service  network  by  the  staff  through  a  propose  1  rulemaking  proceeding  that 
would  foreclose  the  Board  members  from  the  exercise  of  their  quasi- judicial 
responsibilities  on  a  case-by-case  basis. 

It  may  be  said  that  these  consequences  have  further  consequences  in  that 
they  have  produced:  (a)  an  unhealthy  dependence  by  the  airlines  on  the  CAB 
which  has  had  the  affect  of  stifling  carrier  initiatives,  efficiency,  and  good  man- 
agement discipline:  (b)  the  abandonment  of  route  strengthening  which  has 
historically  been  successful  as  a  means  for  better  economic  health  for  the 
carriers  and  the  communities  alike;  (c)  an  indifferent  effort  by  the  carriers  and 
the  CAB  to  seek  out  and  develop  new  markets  and  new  communities  of  interest ; 
and  (d)  almost  complete  disregard  of  the  needs  of  the  cities  of  America  for 
air  service  improvements  and  strengthening. 

The  Board's  continuing  eagerness  to  concentrate  on  and  accommodate  to  the 
carriers'  financial  health  has  produced  milestone  results  for  the  airline 
industry. 

I  am  advised  that  while  this  moratorium  has  been  perpetuated,  and  in  light 
of  the  standards  developed  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation,  the 
domestic  trunkline  industry  earned  a  12.4  percent  rate  of  return  on  its  invest- 
ments in  fiscal  year  1973  (CAB  73-19(),  dated  October  12,  1973),  and  a  12.1  i)er- 
cent  return  on  investment  in  calendar  year  1973,  (CAB  74-188,  dated  August 
23,  1974).  This  exceeds  the  12  percent  rate  established  by  the  CAB  as  "fair 


710 

and  reasonable  .  .  .  (and)  suflBcient  to  compensate  the  carriers  for  their  cost 
of  capital,  provide  the  equity  owner  with  returns  comparable  to  returns  on 
investments  in  enterprises  having  conipnrali'e  risks,  and  enable  the  carrier  to 
maintain  their  credit  and  to  attract  capital."  (CAB  order  71-4-58).  The  earn- 
ings for  the  domestic  trunkline  carriers  have  further  improved  dramatically  in 
1974  with  operating  profits  up  73  percent  to  $761  million,  and  net  income  up 
114  percent  to  $359  million  for  fiscal  year  ended  September  1974,  (Interim 
financial  report,  September  1974).  Even  before  tbe  adjustments  to  the  stand- 
ards developed  by  the  CAB,  there  are  five  domestic  carriers  earning  the  full 
rate  of  return  or  substantially  more  than  the  full  rate  of  return  on  investments. 
The  eight  regional  carriers'  earning  for  the  same  period  are  at  14.3  percent  and 
climbing. 

Thus  we  see  that  the  CAB's  concern  for  the  airlines'  profitability,  to  the 
exclusion  of  the  public  need,  has  jjrovided  the  carriers  with  nrit  just  a  return 
to  profitability,  but  a  return  to  an  all-time  record  in  profitability,  while  the 
public  requirements  for  improved  service  go  begging.  It  should  be  noted,  too, 
that  these  all-time  profit  records  were  achieved  in  the  face  of  record  high  fuel 
prices,  record  high  wage  levels  and  record  high  costs  in  virtually  every  other 
category  in  an  airline  operation.  Little  wonder  then,  with  such  all-time  high 
profits  bestowed  by  the  benevolent  hand  of  the  CAB,  that  the  airlines,  individ- 
ually and  collectively,  have  been  hesitant  to  protest  th"  Board's  abandonment 
of  the  processes  of  route  strengthening  and  public  service  improvement.  There 
is  a  basic  reluctance  to  disturb  things  in  this  "too  good  to  believe"  world. 

With  the  Board's  abdication  of  its  public  service  responsibilities,  the  public 
interest  has  gone  unattended ;  public  Interest  consideration  has  been  virtually 
shut  out.  That  situation  must  be  changed !  The  public's  essential  right  to  repre- 
sentation, participation  and  a  just  determination  on  the  merits  must  be  restored 
at  the  earliest  possible  time. 

The  AOCI  is  represented  by  professional  people  operating  facilities  which 
serve  millions  of  the  American  public  day  in  and  day  out.  From  their  quasi-nublic, 
quasi-governmental  posture,  they  are  directly  involved  in  a  number  of  air'trans- 
portation  matters  every  day  in  nearly  every  city  of  any  size  across  the  nation. 
Accordingly,  AOCI  has  a  vital  interest  and  responsibility  in  air  transportation 
matters  of  broad  national  concern. 

Their  is  a  deep-seated  public  interest  In  expanding  and  strengthening  air 
routes  and  services.  In  recognition  of  its  own  public  responsibility  in  these  mat- 
ters, the  AOCI  is  endeavoring  to  insure  that  there  is  provided  for  the  communities 
and  the  public  that  it  represents  a  climate  within  which  each  city,  actins:  on  its 
own,  will  have  the  opportunity  to  obtain  whatever  quality  and  quantity  of  air 
service  that  it  can  justify  ;  an  atmosphere  in  which  both  the  cities  nnd  the  carriers 
will  have  an  opportunity  to  achieve  substantial  economic  strengthening  through 
air  route  and  air  service  improvements. 

The  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI,  meeting  in  San  Diego  in  October  of  last  year, 
reviewed  the  extensive  work  and  analysis  of  its  all  service  committee  and  com- 
pletely endorsed  the  committee's  recommendation  that  AOCI  seek  Congre.-sional 
support  for  an  immediate  and  complete  termination  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board's  moratorium.  Pursuant  to  that  action  the  board  of  directors  directed  its 
air  service  committee  to  "prepare  and  implement  a  program"  to  that  end. 

Among  the  air  service  committee's  recommendations  on  which  the  board  of 
directors  action  was  premised  were  the  following : 

That  the  CAB  shouM  lift  its  moratorium,  immediately  and  totally ; 
That  the  CAB  should  resume  the  use  of  the  numerous  public  interest  pro- 
cedures provided  for  it  under  the  law,  and  .'^everal  that  it  devised  itself  for 
the  purpose  of  expediting  public  service  improvements  and  carrier  route 
strengthening ; 

That  the  CAB  also  lauch  investigations  looking  toward  : 

the  elimination  of  unnecessary  public  service  restrictions  in  airline 
certificates; 

the  more  effective  use  of  existing  air  carrier  authority,  some  of  which 
has  lain  dormant  for  many  years  ; 

the  possibility  of  transferring  a  carrier's  nnused  or  noorly  I'sed  oper- 
ating authority  to  a  carrier  with  more  incentive  and  aptitude  for  its  more 
effective  use ;  and 

further  route  consolidation  proceedings  designed  to  streamline  car- 
riers' operating  authority  in  the  public  interest. 


711 

Work  went  forward  by  the  air  service  committee  toward  further  definition, 
refinement  and  implementation  of  these  objec*^ives.  On  January  3,  1975,  however, 
the  air  service  committee  received  a  copy  of  a  CAB  staff  study  by  the  Bureau  of 
Operating  Rights  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  which  was  released  New  Year's 
Eve,  1974.  The  study  was  entitled,  "The  Domestic  Route  System:  Analysis  and 
Policy  Recommendations,"  a  staff  study  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights,  Octo- 
ber 1974. 

A  superficial  glance  at  the  study  suggested  that  the  Bureau's  staff  was  recom- 
mending a  termination  of  the  moratorium  and  a  full  resumption  of  the  Board's 
route  and  service  developmental  responsibilities.  Such  a  proposal  would  have 
lent  substantial  impetus  to  the  recommendations  of  the  air  service  committee, 
and  eased  significantly  its  burden.  Further  examination  of  the  study,  however, 
gave  strong  indication  that  the  BOR  staff  might  be  striving  for  the  exact  opposite 
result,  i.e.,  a  further  solidifying  of  the  moratorium. 

That  strong  possibility  made  it  urgently  incumbent  upon  the  air  service  com- 
mittee to  determine  as  precisely  as  possible  the  full  impact  that  the  Bureau's 
recommendations  could  have  on  the  moratorium  and  on  the  welfare  of  the  popula- 
tion clusters  represented  by  AOCI.  Since  the  study,  the  first  of  its  type  released 
by  the  Board's  staff,  was  some  two  years  or  so  in  the  process  of  development  and 
was  extremely  broad  in  its  scope  and  implications,  it  required  a  substantial 
amount  of  time  for  evaluation. 

As  a  product  of  our  assessment,  one  fact  can  be  stated  without  any  equivoca- 
tion:  If  the  staff  recommendations  were  to  be  implemented  by  the  CAB,  the 
moratorium  would  effectively  become  permanent  Board  policy.  It  therefore  be- 
came alarmingly  clear  to  the  committee  that  the  BOR  staff  proposals  would 
violate  each  of  the  AOCI  public  service  objectives  enumerated ;  and  this  was  the 
unanimous  conclusion  of  the  air  service  committee  meeting  in  Phoenix  on  Janu- 
ary 23  and  24  of  this  year,  after  a  comprehensive  review  of  the  Bureau's  .study 
and  the  objectives  of  AOCI. 

Further,  and  on  the  basis  of  this  comprehensive  review  and  evaluation,  specific 
statements  of  position  and  specific  legislative  recommendations  were  unanimously 
adopted  by  the  air  service  committee  and  forwarded  to  the  board  of  directors  of 
AOCI  with  a  recommendation  for  its  approval  in  its  meeting  scheduled  for  Febru- 

^^In  the  discussion  of  the  BOR  staff  study  that  follows,  the  views  expressed  are 
those  resulting  from  the  unanimous  conclusions  reached  by  the  air  service  com- 
mittee in  consequence  of  its  extensive  evaluation  of  the  study.  The  essence  of  this 
is  contained  in  the  recommendations  which,  as  stated,  have  been  forwarded  to 
the  Board  of  Directors  of  AOCI  for  consideration  and  approval. 

AIR  SERVICE  COMMITTEE  EVALUATION,  BUREAU  STUDY:  "THE  DOMESTIC  ROUTE  SYSTEM  : 
ANALYSIS   AN  D   POLICY   RECOMMENDATIONS" 

The  study  conducted  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  formalizes,  as  future 
policy  of  the  CAB,  the  route  moratorium  which  has  been  in  effect  since  19  rO.  Gen- 
erally the  proposed  policy  creates  a  circumstance  which  prevents  the  CAB  from 
proceeding  on  a  case-by-case  basis  by  establishing  certain  economic  obstacles 
(standards)  designed  to  block  any  requirement  for  regulatory  action.  In  essence, 
the  standards  proposed  in  the  study  preclude  all  other  considerations  with  regard 
to  the  determination  as  to  who  should  be  certificated  to  provide  service  in  a 
market  Thev  prevent  certification  in  markets  that  need  the  service  with  no 
incumbent  authority  or,  more  importantly,  in  the  markets  where  nonstop  au- 
fhnritv  exists  but  no  such  Service  is  provided. 

The^'opolal  in  this  study  create  a  regulatory  obstacle  for  the  development 
of  operating  authority  in  the  future  that  is  vital  to  the  public,  as  well  as  the  air 
carriers  themselves.  There  were  4,112  markets  studied  which  represented  all 
city-pairs  generating  more  than  2,500  nondirectional  O&D  passengers  in  1972. 
Of  thSe  2,928  have  certificated  nonstop  service.  However,  only  590  received  com- 
petitive nonstop  service.  Another  639  received  monopoly  nonstop  service  ^^ich 
leave  1,699  markets  with  no  nonstop  service  where  such  service  has  been 
certificated.  It  is  this  area  that  the  bulk  of  the  economic  opportiinities  for  growth 
and  development  exist.  Most  of  these  markets  are  not  conducive  to  efficient 
operations  by  the  incumbent  carrier  but  would  represent  valid  economic  op- 
porSXs  for  other  carriers.  The  incumbent  carrier  does  not  feel  compelled 
to  develop  this  service  nor  is  it  pressured  by  the  regulatory  policies  effective  to- 
day or  by  those  proposed  in  the  BOR  study. 


712 

The  preconceived  objective  of  the  study  appears  to  emphasize  the  concept 
that  competition:  (i)  creates  most  of  the  problems  in  the  air  transportation 
industry;  (ii)  should  be  avoided  in  the  future;  and  (iii)  should  be  eliminated 
wherever  possible.  A  conclusion  of  the  study  is:  "The  system  has  offered,  in 
general,  an  overall  volume  of  service  that  is  excessive  in  relation  to  demand  in 
competitive  markets."  It  was  further  held  that  competition  drives  load  factors 
below  the  reasonable  level,  preventing  carriers  from  achieving  a  12  percent 
return  on  investment;  and,  therefore,  that  the  CAB  should  adopt  a  policy, 
through  the  implementation  of  standards  of  avoiding  this  in  the  future  in  order 
to  improve  the  economic  condition  of  the  industry.  The  analysis  also  concludes 
that  the  key  to  developing  the  improved  economic  condition  of  the  industry  is 
to  increase  load  factors;  the  key  to  increasing  load  factors  is  to  eliminnte  com- 
petition as  much  as  possible  by  discouraging  competition  in  markets  today,  en- 
couraging capacity  restriction  agreements;  and  denying  consideration  for  the 
authorization  of  competitive  services  in  the  future.  The  analysis  states,  "if  any 
real  improvement  in  load  factors  is  to  be  achieved  by  a  lessening  in  degree  of 
competition,  it  is  necessary  to  establish  monopoly  status  for  the  markets  in  ques- 
tion" (page  89,  emphasis  added) .  This  is  a  gross  oversimplification  of  the  problem 
with  regard  to  competition  versus  profits.  No  one  denies  that  excessive  competi- 
tion or  destructive  competition  hurts  the  industry  and  is  not  in  the  public  inter- 
est. However,  nowhere  in  the  study  is  there  any  support  for  the  idea  that  two- 
carrier  competition  creates  these  problems. 

This  study  itself  does  not  support  the  conclusions  and  recommendations  made 
with  regard  to  the  establishment  of  standards.  There  are  many  inconsistencies 
and  many  conclusions  drawn  in  the  study  itself  that  do  not  support  the  overall 
policy  and  philosophy  proposed  for  the  future.  Generally,  the  study  took  an  in- 
depth  look  at  what  took  place  in  the  industry  between  1960  and  1972  to  determine 
whether  it  was  good  or  bad  for  the  traveling  public,  as  well  as  the  carriers 
involved. 

The  study  itself  supports  the  fact  that  it  was  the  rate  policy  prevalent  in 
1970-1972  that  created  most  of  the  load  factor  problems.  It  is  the  rate  level  that 
creates  a  capability  of  the  carriers  in  the  long-haul  markets  to  provide  service 
at  low-load  factors.  The  study  developed  the  fact  that  in  two-carrier  competitive 
markets  the  load  factors  are  generally  the  same  as  they  are  for  all  service  on  an 
industrywide  basis  in  all  mileage  categories.  In  other  words,  carriers  generally 
conform  the  level  of  service  to  the  overall  breakeven  load  factor  requirement. 

Since  the  analysis  of  load  factors  designed  to  support  the  conclusions  of  the 
study  was  conducted  during  a  period  prior  to  the  implementation  of  the  fare 
structure  resulting  from  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation,  the  projection 
to  the  future  encompasses  an  air  carrier  operation  substantially  different  in  rate 
structure  characteristics  than  that  which  prevailed  in  the  past.  Since  the  im- 
plementation of  the  fare  structure  is  due  to  take  place  in  June  of  this  year,  the 
correction  in  load  factor  characteristics  should  respond  to  the  changing  rate 
structure  and  not  to  the  changing  circumstances  involving  competitive  service. 

The  study  was  conducted  over  a  period  of  two  years  ending  in  February  of 
1974.  It  was  dated  October,  1974,  and  released  on  December  31,  1974.  The  content 
provided  insufficient  information  for  complete  analysis  and  evaluation.  Standards 
are  proposed  for  the  purpose  of  screening  applications  to  determine  whether  or 
not  the  CAB  should  conduct  an  investigation  into  the  need  for  the  service  con- 
tained in  an  application.  However,  the  standards  do  not  allow-  a  route  applica- 
tion to  pass  through  this  preliminary  te-t  of  economics  and  load  factor  in  order 
to  be  processed  on  the  case-by-case  method  envisioned  by  the  Federal  Aviation 
Act,  which  is  the  only  judicious  method  for  adequate  examination.  Since  these 
are  not  the  only  features  that  the  CAB  should  consider  when  determining  the 
need  for  service,  they  prevent  recognition,  by  the  Board  itself,  of  the  necessary 
information  relevant  to  other  factors,  such  as,  carrier  strengthening,  need  for 
service,  economic  viability  under  realistic  conditions,  traffic  stimulation  and 
development,  etc. 

The  overall  rationale  u«ed  to  develop  the  standards  is  keyed  to  the  Domestic 
Passenger  Fare  Investigation  for  the  55  percent  load  factor  and  the  12  percent 
rate  of  return.  However,  these  standards  are  misused  in  that  they  are  considered 
minimums  when  applied  to  the  route  poMcies  proposed.  Since  the  12  percent  rate 
of  return  is  considered  a  minimum,  very  few  airline  markets  can  generate  exces- 
sive earnings  and,  therefore,  warrant  regulatory  action  by  the  Board. 

In  essence,  standards  should  not  be  developed  to  prevent  the  CAB  from  doing 
its  job.  The  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights'  recommendations  establish  standards 


713 

that  would  prevent  any  significant  new  air  service  improvement  proposals  from 
coming  before  the  Board  members  themselves  for  a  decision  on  public  convenience 
and  necessity  issues.  A  prejudgment  of  such  issues  by  the  Bureau  of  Operating 
Rights  by  proposing  this  technique  strongly  suggests  that  the  Board  members 
themselves  should  be  precluded  from  assessing  and  deciding  service  improvement 
proposals  under  the  public  interest  guidelines  set  down  by  Congress.  This  scarcely 
conforms  in  auv  respect  to  the  intent  of  Congress.  It  is  the  Board  members  them- 
selves in  whom  the  public  trust  has  been  vested  by  the  Congress,  and  by  Presiden- 
tial appointment  confirmed  by  the  Senate.  It  is  the  individual  members  who  bear 
the  burden  and  the  privilege  of  decisional  responsibility  with  respect  to  the  ulti- 
mate issues  of  public  convenience  and  necessity  and  the  need  for  changes  in 
operating  authority.  The  industry  (all  carriers)  and  the  public  are  entitled  to 
the  Board  members'  fair  consideration  of  air  service  improvement  proposals  and 
to  the  full  exercise  of  their  responsibilities  within  both  the  spirit  and  the  explicit 
criteria  of  the  law  under  which  they  are  granted  the  right  and  the  duty  to  func- 
tion. They  can  neither  be  prevented  nor  protected  from  the  exercise  of  this 
responsibility. 

EVALUATION   OF   BUREAU'S   PEOPOSED    STANDARDS 

The  Bureau's  study  of  the  domestic  route  ssytem  proposed  that  the  Board  go 
forward  with  a  route  program  (page  iii).  However,  when  the  proposals  are  ana- 
lyzed the  route  program  does  not  "go  forward"  ;  the  moratorium  is  perpetuated. 
The  study  has  this  to  say  about  its  objectives  :  "In  these  circumstances  regulatory 
joute  and  route-related  policies  should  be  directed  to  improving  the  eflBciency 
and  quality  of  the  system  through  a  careful  expansion  of  route  authority  when 
required  by  traflSc,  and  through  route  rationalization.  The  latter  will  require 
direct  action  by  the  Board  and  creation  of  incentives  for  ca.rrier-initiated  actions. 
In  so  doing,  civic  interests  should  play  an  important  role.  This  dual  program  of 
route  expansion  and  route  rationalization  is  intended  to  make  available  new 
services  whenever  sufficient  demand  has  been  established,  to  correct  serious  de- 
ficiencies, and  generally,  to  minimize  the  need  for  fare  increases  by  encouraging 
efl3cien?y"  (page  9).  It  is  stated  that  the  route  i)olicies  recommended  are  derived 
from  the  premise  that  the  overall  statutory  scheme  in  respect  to  economic  regula- 
tion shall  continue  (page  147).  It  further  suggests:  "that  the  Board  proceed,  as  it 
has  historically,  on  a  case-by-case  basis  with  a  view  to  making  gradual  adjust- 
ments in  the  linear  route  system.  This  means  that  each  case  will  be  decided  on 
its  own  merits  in  accordance  with  the  statutory  standards  of  public  interest  and 
public  convenience  and  necessity  as  determined  by  the  Board"  (page  147) . 

However,  when  we  look  at  the  study  proposals,  the  logic  stated  in  the  objectives 
loses  its  coherency.  The  BOR's  recommendations  suggest  "that  the  Board  estab- 
lish, by  rule,  evidentiary  requirements  that  would  be  applicable  to  all  route  and 
route-related  applications,  as  well  as  benchmark  criteria  for  determining  which 
route  authority  applications  and  adequacy  petitions  should  be  afforded  priority 
hearing"  (page  148).  Only  after  these  applications  have  met  such  criteria  will 
a  hearing  be  conducted  (see  attachment  C).  It  is  all  too  apparent  that  these 
procedural  requirements  and  economic  standards,  as  graphically  depicted  in  at- 
tachment C,  are  excessively  expensive,  unduly  time  consuming,  and  virtually 
unattainable. 

This  process  places  the  economic  standards  between  the  carrier  applicant  or 
civic  party  and  the  Board  itself.  The  proces.sing  of  the  application  and  the  evalua- 
tion of  the  economics  in  the  application,  as  they  apply  to  the  standards,  will  take 
place  at  the  CAB  staff  level  prior  to  the  Board  concerning  itself  with  the  need 
for  regulatory  action.  If  these  standards  are  not  met,  the  Board  will  never  deal 
with  the  petition  or  application. 

The  study  recommends  that  the  CAB ;  ".  .  .  undertake,  on  the  basis  of  pub- 
lished standards,  a  continuing  program  of  route  expansion :  to  hear  and  adjudi- 
cate route  ca.ses  to  improve  and  perfect  existing  authority  consistent  with  the 
Board's  DPFI  economic  goals  and  in  accordance  with  developing  traflSc  require,'- 
ments  .  .  ."    (page  149). 

A  brief  examination  of  these  standards  demonstrates  that  practically  no  new 
route  opportunities  would  survive  these  economic  tests.  This,  of  course,  then 
points  to  a  perpetuation  of  the  route  moratorium  program. 

FIRST    OR    ADDITIONAL    COMPETITIVE    AUTHORITY 

The  proposed  standard  is.  "That  the  proposed  operations  will  earn  at  least  12 
percent  rare  or  return  in  the  first  year  of  operations"  (page  159) . 


714 

The  operation  of  competitive  service  in  the  first  year  simply  cannot  generate 
a  12  percent  rate  of  return  under  reasonable  circumstances.  This  clearly  implies 
service  deficiencies  in  the  market  even  after  the  proposed  services  are  placed 
into  operation.  Other\vi.se,  as  the  gradual  improvement  of  identity  and  market 
penetration  of  the  newly  certificated  carrier  occurs,  by  the  end  of  this  first 
year  of  operation,  the  actual  rate  of  return  would  exceed  the  12  percent  level 
to  a  substantial  degree.  This  indicates  that  excess  profits  can  be  generated 
in  a  competitive  market  in  the  early  stages  of  development  and  that  the  second 
year  will  produce  excessive  profits  for  both  competitors  in  the  market. 

This  standard  cannot  be  met  when  using  reasonable  forecasting  techniques. 
Therefore,  the  only  conclu.sion  which  can  be  drawn  is  that  no  such  market  will 
survive  this  test,  the  route  moratorium  will  be  perpetuated,  and  the  CAB  itself 
will  not  face  a  decision  regarding  the  need  for  service  in  these  markets. 

There  is  no  support  in  the  study  itself  for  this  standard.  The  study  estab- 
lislied  that  in  the  past,  many  markets  in  the  medium  mileage  ran^e  category 
were  served  with  a  carrier  averaging  approximately  a  55  percent  load  factor. 
This  does  not  releate  to  the  actual  circumstances  encountered  by  a  carrier  in 
its  first  year  of  operation  in  a  competitive  market.  Also,  the  standard  assumes 
that  carriers  should  operate  in  succeeding  years  at  load  factors  much  higher 
than  55  percent  and,  therefore,  encourages  excess  profits  at  high  load  factors 
as  a  norm  for  service  quantity  and  quality.  Therefore,  the  55  percent  coacli 
load  factor  standard  neces.sary  to  produce  the  12  percent  rate  of  return  found 
to  be  reasonable  for  airline  operations  in  the  domestic  passenger  fare  investi- 
gation is  being  used  as  a  minimum  standard.  This  is  a  substantial  protective 
device  for  the  incumbent.  It  is  also  obvious  that  such  a  condition  is  not  con- 
ducive to  growth  and  development  of  traffic  for  the  future  period  to  be  covered 
by  these  standards.  This  standard  goes  to  the  heart  of  the  regulatory  process 
in  the  future  since  the  development  of  competitive  service  is  an  underlying 
objective  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act. 

The  basis  for  the  study  clearly  demonstrates  that  competition  has  been  the 
key  to  the  development  of  growth  and  eflSciency  in  the  air  transportation 
industry  in  the  past.  This  study  was  primarily  confined  to  the  development  in 
the  industry  from  1960  through  1972  (appendix  B). 

The  major  route  case  expansion  during  this  period  involved  primarily  non- 
stop monopoly  markets  operated  by  trunk  carriers,  and  looked  toward  the 
authorization  of  first  competitive  service.  Unlike  the  earlier  programs,  the 
general  program  did  not  involve  the  issue  of  the  need  for  increasing  the  num- 
ber of  competitive  authorizations  in  markets  already  served  by  two  or  more 
unrestricted  carriers.  Multiple  competitive  awards  were  made  in  only  a  few 
markets  and  these  generally  resulted  from  considerations  taken  into  account 
in  the  decisional  process  in  relation  to  the  carrier  selection,  or  in  the  entry 
mileage  situation.  During  this  period  the  Board  exercised  control  over  the 
general  program  by  setting  cases  through  orders  of  investigation,  rather  than 
carrier  applications.  This  program  enabled  the  Board  to  direct  a  more  systematic 
basis  for  route  authorization  during  this  period  (page  44) . 

During  the  sixties,  the  Board  frequently  selected  applicants  primarily  on 
the  basis  of  features  other  than  purely  economic  results.  Many  reasons  were 
given  for  carrier  selection,  such  as  strengthening,  subsidy  need  reduction,  single- 
plane  service  benefits,  and  other  selection  criteria  developed  in  a  case-by-case 
approach.  In  commenting  on  the  prosperity  of  the  sixties,  the  study  states : 
"The  combination  of  abundant  operating  authority  and  service,  particularly 
in  competitive  markets,  has  also  influenced  traflic  development  and  the  rate  of 
technological  change.  Trafl5c  has  been  stimulated  by  the  high  level  of  service 
made  possible  by  the  rate  leve',  and  even  hicrher  level  of  service  in  competitive 
markets  has  had  a  further  stimulative  impact"  (pages  58  and  59).  Competition 
generally  means  premium  service,  including  promotional  fares,  advertising,  and 
other  major  efforts  made  to  stimulate  the  development  of  the  markets  directly 
to  the  benefit  of  the  traveling  public  which  produces  an  overall  lower  average 
fare.  Of  equal  importance,  the  resulting  development  accrues  directly  to  the 
benefit  of  the  regional  carrier  seeking  improved  operating  authority  and  geared 
to  the  pursuit  of  expansion  and  development  as  the  key  to  achieving  maximum 
productivity  and  eflSriency. 

"Although  numerous  factors  have  influenced  the  rate  of  technological  change, 
competitive  rivalry  has  itself  played  an  important  and  possibly  primary  role" 
(rage  59).  Technological  change  in  addition  to  growth  has  been  the  key  to  the 
development  of  the  traflBc  increases  which  took  place  in  the  sixties.  "Because  these 


715 

aircraft  have  been  responsible  for  the  long-term  decline  in  unit  costs  and  prices, 
it  is  possible  that  the  regulated  competitive  system  has  produced  lower  prices  and 
a  higher  quality  of  service  than  would  have  occurred  under  either  monopoly  or 
unregulated  conditions"  (page  60).  This  statement  is  absolutely  true.  However, 
the  proposals  of  this  study,  if  adopted,  will  point  this  industry  in  the  opposite 
direction. 

NEED   FOR   ADDlTIONATv    NONSTOP    SERVICE 

The  standard  proposed  to  indicate  inadequate  nonstop  service  is:  "The  load 
factor  in  this  market  on  all  nonstop  service  must  exceed  75  percent  for  the 
previous  twelve  months"  (page  165). 

This  load  factor  standard  is  extremely  difficult  to  achieve  in  light  of  the  fact 
that,  "most  markets  show  pronounced  variation  by  season,  by  day  of  week,  and 
often  by  time  of  day.  During  peak  travel  periods,  load  factors  can  be  expected 
to  rise  above  the  average.  Only  when  aggregate  load  factors  climb  about  a  rea- 
sonable level  for  protracted  periods  does  scarcity  of  available  seats  become  an 
adequacy  of  service  problem"  (page  166).  The  establishment  of  a  75  percent  load 
factor  as  the  standard  is  anything  but  reasonable.  The  study  itself  indicates  that 
there  were  only  three  markets  that  reached  this  load  factor  experience  for  the 
12  months  ended  August  31,  1974.  This  period  embraced  the  fuel  crisis  which  led 
to  unusually  high  load  factor  conditions  on  many  nonstop  markets  across  the 
country.  In  addition,  the  Ontario-San  Francisco  market  was  affected  by  the  strike 
of  the  intrastate  carrier  in  this  market  creating  an  abnormal  traffic  condition  for 
the  incumbent  CAB  carrier. 

The  findings  in  support  for  this  load  factor  standard  itself  established  the 
unreasonableness  of  this  condition  and  the  fact  that  no  carrier  will  be  under  any 
strain  to  increase  service  in  a  nonstop  market  since  the  standard  will  never  be 
surpassed. 

The  establishment  of  this  standard  creates  several  significantly  detrimental 
public  convenience  and  necessity  features  to  air  service  today.  The  operation  at 
such  an  excessive  load  factor  is  not  conducive  to  growth  and  development  of 
airline  passenger  traffic.  Many  extremely  high  density  markets  today,  well 
known  for  being  unable  to  adequately  accommodate  many  passengers  due  to 
excessive  load  factor  conditions,  cannot  meet  this  standard.  Attachment  D, 
demonstrates  the  actual  experience  in  five  of  these  markets.  The  fact  that  first- 
class  service  is  averaged  into  the  total  produces  a  condition  that  prevents  the 
overall  load  factors  and  actual  markets  known  to  us  at  this  time  to  be  extreme 
high  load  factor  problems. 

This,  of  course,  overtly  encourages  the  carriers  to  operate  in  markets  with  load 
factors  up  to  75  percent.  The  standard  tells  the  carrier  that  the  CAB  expects 
operations  at  this  level  to  be  maintained  in  order  to  improve  "efficiency"  since 
it  considers  a  75  percent  load  factor  "reasonable".  The  domestic  passenger  fare 
investigation  established  the  fact  that  a  55  percent  load  factor  standard  is  a 
reasonable  load  factor  when  conducting  regularly  scheduled  airline  service.  The 
rate  structure  of  the  carriers  has  been  designed  to  achieve  a  full  rate  of  return  of 
12  percent  at  the  55  percent  load  factor.  Therefore,  the  encouragement  of  the 
carriers  by  the  CAB  to  operate  with  load  factors  in  excess  of  55  percent  up  to  75 
percent  produces  an  excessive  profit  condition  and  at  the  same  time  stymies  the 
ability  of  the  service  in  the  market  to  develop  traffic  and  service  growth.  When 
looking  at  a  typical  market  that  produces  a  return  of  approximately  12  percent  at 
a  55  percent  load  factor  for  a  Boeing  727  operation  of  653  miles  we  begin  to  see  the 
absurd  financial  results  that  are  encouraged  by  this  standard  (attachment  E).  A 
GO  percent  load  factor  in  this  market  will  produce  an  18  percent  return  on  invest- 
ment. A  65  percent  load  factor  will  produce  a  23  percent  return  on  investment. 
Since  the  criteria  for  the  domestic  pas.senger  fare  investigation  established  the 
fact  that  a  12  percent  rate  of  return  is  reasonable,  these  returns  on  investment  are 
extremely  excessive  and  directly  conflict  with  public  convenience  and  necessity 
in  a  sound  economic  environment.  They  are  conducive  to  a  no-growth  posture  in 
the  industry  and  will  therefore  fail  to  produce  an  efficient  unit  cast  characteristic 
which  will  in  turn,  have  an  extremely  inflationary  impact.  Since  the  unit  cost 
will  ri.se  rapidly  under  this  condition,  fares  must  go  up.  When  fares  go  up,  traffic 
growth  is  adversely  affected. 

This  cycle,  therefore,  will  produce  a  negative  growth  characteristic  in  the 
industry  since  the  upward  cost  trend  will  exceed  the  overall  increase  in  the  con- 
sumer price  index  because  of  the  unreasonable  load  factor  levels.  The  absurdity 
of  the  economic  results  can  be  seen  when  looking  at  the  results  when  load  factors 


716 

achieve  an  average  of  70  percent  which  generate  a  return  on  investment  to  the 
carrier  of  27.9  percent,  more  than  twice  that  considered  reasonable  after  the  com- 
pletion of  the  formal  investigation  to  determine  the  financial  needs  of  the  air 
transportation  industry.  Again,  this  still  is  not  the  load  factor  level  that  is  con- 
sidered reasonable  by  this  75  percent  standard.  The  carriers  are,  therefore,  en- 
couraged to  operate  as  close  to  the  75  percent  level  as  possible  and,  therefore, 
should  be  experiencing  an  overall  load  factor  level  in  the  markets  of  70-75  per- 
cent which  allows  their  return  on  inveslmcnt  to  rise  to  between  28  and  32  percent. 

The  75  percent  load  factor  standard  simply  cannot  be  achieved  on  a  regular 
basis  under  reasonable  circumstances.  When  looking  at  the  load  factor  charac- 
teristics of  the  airline  operating  in  the  highest  routes  in  the  world,  PSA  in  the 
California  corridor  markets,  the  75  percent  load-factor  standard  represents  a 
totally  unreasonable  level.  PSA  operating  under  ideal  circumstances  in  a  high 
frequency  market  carrying  thousands  of  passengers  daily  in  each  direction  on 
services  designed  to  maximize  traffic  has  never  exceeded  an  average  load  factor 
above  60  percent  for  a  12-month  period  since  1967.  At  that  time  PSA  operated 
Electra  aircraft.  Attachment  F  i'lu-trates  PSA's  experience  in  its  top  three 
markets,  two  of  which  are  noncompetitive. 

The  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation  did  not  support  the  establishment 
of  a  75  percent  load-factor  standard.  PSA's  operation  in  the  world's  largest  mar- 
ket under  ideal  circumstances  cannot  come  close  to  supporting  the  establishment 
of  a  75  percent  load-factor  standard.  The  study  itself  dealing  with  the  load  factor 
characteristics  developed  in  the  industry  during  the  sixties,  a  period  of  substan- 
tial trafiic  growth,  does  not  support  a  75  percent  load-factor  standard.  The  75 
percent  load-factor  .standard  is  not  conducive  to  efficient  operations.  This  stand- 
ard will  constrict  traffic  growth  and  place  the  industry  in  a  position  of  not 
being  able  to  accommodate  inflationary  cost  increases  and  other  economic 
problems  of  the  future;  it  will  not  allow  the  carriers  to  phase  out  obsolete 
equipment  on  a  rational  basis ;  but  it  will  create  lower  utilization  due  to  lack 
of  service  expansion,  accelerate  increasing  unit  costs  because  of  a  no-growth 
or  negative  growth  condition  in  the  market  place,  which  in  turn  creates  a  sub- 
stantial increase  in  fair  requirement  on  a  regular  basis  which  in  turn  depresses 
the  demand  for  air  service  thereby  p'acing  a  greater  cost/price  pres.sure  on  the  in- 
dustry. The  ability  of  the  air  transportation  system  to  evolve  into  the  most  effec- 
tive and  efficient  intercity  mass  transportation  system  possible  is  defeated  by  a 
standard  not  supported  by  the  study  nor  any  other  analysis  available. 

FIRST    NONSTOP    SERVICE 

The  standard  proposed  by  the  Bureau  to  encourage  the  carriers  to  provide 
first  nonstop  service  is  that,  "True  O&D  plus  flow  traffic,  for  the  previous  12 
months  was  sufficient  to  maintain  a  55  percent  load-factor  on  two  round  trips 
with  the  smallest  aircraft  type  commonly  used  in  city  pairs  of  similar  mileage 
range"  (page  165).  "Nonstop  service  is  the  level  at  which  air  travel  has  Its 
greatest  advantage  and  it  is  incumbent  upon  the  Board  to  assure  the  availability 
of  such  service  whenever  economically  possible"  (page  167). 

The  standard,  if  adopted,  will  not  create  an  environment  conducive  to  providing 
first  nonstop  service  in  a  market.  A  careful  review  of  this  standard  indicates  that 
compliance  will  encourage  abnormally  high  load-factors,  reluctance  to  provide 
nonstop  service,  and  only  when  conditions  become  unbearable  ;  one  nonstop  round 
trip  can  be  provided  for  almost  an  indefinite  period  before  the  Board  would  be 
in  a  position  to  investigate  the  service  deficiency  under  this  rule. 

This  is  an  extremely  important  area  for  air  service  since  it  is  the  most  desir- 
able form  of  service  and  since  so  much  authority  exists  to  provide  such  service 
today  that  is  not  being  used.  This  study  dealt  with  all  airline  markets  in  the 
IT.S.  producing  more  than  2,500  nondirectional  O&D  passengers  in  1972  (approx- 
imately 6.8  per  day)  (page  70).  There  were  4,112  markets  analyzed,  of  which 
2,928  have  nonstop  authority.  This  is  one  of  the  mo.st  important  statistics 
developed  in  this  study  representing  the  most  significant  regulatory  challenge 
for  the  future.  Of  the  airline  markets  71  percent  today  have  nonstop  authority 
that  has  been  granted  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

When  the  quality  of  service  provided  in  the«e  markets  is  analyzed,  several 
dramatic  features  become  apparent.  First  of  all,  the  numbers  used  in  the  study 
should  be  qualified  as  follows :  "A  more  serious  over.statement  of  the  levels  of 
service  provided  stems  from  the  classifications  of  markets  on  the  basis  of  the 
best  level  of  service  provided.  A  single  nonstop  flight,  for  example,  was  sufficient 


717 

to  identify  a  market  as  nonstop,  regardless  of  the  possible  existence  of  unmet 
additional  demand  for  nonstop  service"  (page  72) . 

Therefore,  keeping  in  mind  that  the  service  classifications  are  overstated  by 
some  unknown  degree,  we  find  that  for  this  group  of  2,928  markets,  only  590 
received  competitive  nonstop  service.  This  means  that  only  14  percent  of  the 
markets  served  today  received  competitive  nonstop  service  and  only  20  percent 
of  the  markets  eligible  to  receive  nonstop  service  received  competitive  nonstop 
service.  In  addition,  another  639  markets  received  noncompetitive  nonstop  serv- 
ice. Therefore,  another  22  percent  of  tho.se  markets  which  have  nonstop  authority 
receive  nonstop  service  on  a  noncompetitive  basis.  So,  we  see  that  a  total  of 
1,229  markets  receive  nonstop  service  of  some  form,  which  is  only  42  percent  of 
those  markets  where  nonstop  authority  exists  and  was  found  to  be  necessary 
at  one  time  or  another  in  the  past  by  the  CAB.  When  we  look  at  the  1,699  markets 
where  nonstop  authority  exists  but  is  not  provided,  on  either  a  noncompetitive 
or  competitive  ba.sis,  we  can  begin  to  focus  on  the  extent  of  the  need  for  the 
development  of  a  regulatory  policy  designed  to  create  the  incentive  and  the 
initiative  to  ]ilace  this  authority  in  the  hands  of  willing  carriers. 

The  standard  developed  to  encourage  carriers  to  provide  this  service  is  truly 
counterproductive.  The  standard  is  based  upon  the  actual  traffic  flows  in  a 
market  prior  to  the  receipt  of  such  service.  The  initiation  of  nonstop  service 
in  a  mirkit  will  oliviously  stimulate  the  development  of  traffic  in  the  local 
market,  as  well  as  improve  the  ability  of  the  market  to  accommodate  through 
traffic.  None  of  this  traffic  is  considered  when  determining  the  need  for  non- 
stop service.  In  addition,  the  market  is  judged  on  its  traffic  flows  over  a  past 
period  to  require  nonstop  service  when  it  is  large  enough  to  support  two  non- 
stop round  trips  at  a  55  percent  load  factor.  Therefore,  a  carrier  can  provide 
service  in  a  market  almost  indefinitely  without  being  affected  by  this  standard. 
One-stop  service  in  this  market  can  be  provided  until  the  market  is  practically 
shouting  for  the  need  for  nonstop  service.  At  that  point,  the  incumbent  carrier 
which,  as  we  have  seen,  already  has  the  authority,  can  install  one  nonstop 
round  trip  without  ever  facing  the  prospect  of  having  this  market  meet  the 
need  for  additional  nonstop  service.  The  rule  governing  the  determination  in 
a  market  requiring  additional  nonstop  service  would  then  come  into  play.  In 
other  words,  the  one  nonstop  round  trip  must  exceed  75  percent  load  factor  over 
the  previous  12  months  before  additional  service  is  required.  Therefore,  the 
interplay  of  these  two  standards  is  not  conducive  to  traffic  development  (even 
accomniPdaMon  of  normal  ijrowth).  improved  (juality  of  service,  or  incentive  for 
the  carrier  to  operate  and  provide  service  in  markets  where  authority  already 
exists.  The  study  concedes  that  "managements  will  tend  to  .schedule  within  the 
standards  enunciated  under  the  rule"  (page  151).  Truly,  this  condition  formalizes 
as  a  Board  policy  the  moratorium  that  has  been  in  existence  since  1970  and  is 
in  direct  conflict  with  public  convenience  and  necessity  and  the  stated  intent 
of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act. 

SINGLE-PLANE    SERVICE     (1-    OR    2-STOP) 

The  minimum  service  quality  required  in  an  airline  market  is  single-plane 
service.  Whi'e  comecting  servi  e  is  possH)le,  this  is  the  lowest  form  of  service 
quality  that  can  be  provided.  Effective  single-plane  service  should  be  encouraged 
and  developed  in  order  to  cultivate  the  growth  and  development  of  the  air  trans- 
portation industry  in  the  low  and  medimn  density  market.  Again,  effective  reg- 
ulatory policy  in  this  area  can  directly  encourage  further  technological  develop- 
ment in  the  industry  designed  to  make  such  service  economically  feasible.  If 
regulatory  policy  discourages  the  development  of  service  in  this  area,  there 
is  no  incentive  to  pursue  effective  aircraft  designed  to  meet  this  need. 

The  standard  to  determine  the  adequacy  of  single-plane  service  (one  or  two- 
•stopl  is  tl'at  "the  market  should  generate  not  less  than  40  true  O&D  passengers 
per  day  and : 

(a)  no  single-plane  service  available,  or 

(b)  single-plane  service  used  by  less  than  i/o  of  the  true  O&D  passengers 
during  the  previous  12  months"  (page  166). 

It  is  stated  that  for  a  market  to  receive  first  single-plane  service,  it  must  ex- 
ceed the  40  true  O&D  passengers  per  day  criteria  (page  166).  "Few  city  pairs 
whifh  do  not  nlrendy  rffeive  sing'e-plane  servir-e  are  likely  to  generate  suffi- 
cient O&D  traffic  to  justify,  of  itself,  new  single-plane  service"   (page  76).  It 


718 

appears  that  this  standard  was  developed  after  the  information  regarding  traflSc 
volumes  in  such  markets  was  known  rather  than  following  the  rationale  in 
this  study  that  supported  the  development  of  this  standard.  There  are  1,474 
markets  today  receiving  connecting  service  only  (page  74).  Of  these,  on'y  34 
markets  exceed  the  40-passenger  criteria.  This  represents  but  two  percent  of 
the  total  markets  not  now  receiving  single-plane  service.  However,  if  the  stand- 
ard develoi)ed  at  the  conclusion  of  a  formal  CAB  investigation  (Washington- 
Baltimore  investigation  in  1960)  was  applied  to  these  markets,  906  markets 
would  warrant  single-plane  service.  This,  of  course,  would  call  for  very  active 
regulatory  pursuit  to  determine  the  ways  and  means  of  implementing  the  needs 
for  the  minimum  quality  of  air  service  in  these  markets.  This  also  dramatically 
demonstrates  that  the  regulatory  practices  of  the  CAB,  especially  since  1970,  are 
not  conducive  to  implementing  such  service  improvement  since  no  demonstrated 
concern  for  service  quality  in  this  category  of  market  has  been  made  by  the 
CAB. 

The  development  of  the  40-passenger  standard  is  extremely  arbitrary  and  not 
relevant  to  material  developed  in  this  study  itself.  In  1960,  the  CAB  determined 
that  effective  single-plane  service  was  the  rule  in  markets  exchanging  approxi- 
mately 10  passengers  per  day  and  located  less  than  750  miles  apart.  It  is  im- 
portant to  note  at  this  point  that  these  were  low  density  markets  within  a 
750-mile  range  and  not  markets  served  by  the  largest  airplanes  in  the  com- 
mercial airline  fleet  over  long  distances.  However,  in  establishing  the  40-passenger 
standard,  the  CAB  dropped  the  mileage  criteria  established  as  a  result  of  the 
formal  CAB  investigatiim  with  no  supporting  rationale.  In  addition,  the  10- 
passenger  standard  was  adjusted  to  19  with  the  reasoning  that  the  average 
aircraft  size  providing  service  today  in  all  markets  has  almost  doubled  versus 
the  average  that  prevailed  in  1960  (123.8  versus  65.4).  This  rationale  ignores 
the  fact  that  the  smaller  aircraft  type  is  the  appropriate  aircraft  type  to  deter- 
mine the  feasibility  of  providing  service  in  the  medium  and  low  density  markets. 

A  major  portion  of  service  responsibility  in  this  type  of  market  should  rest 
in  the  h;inds  of  the  regional  carriers.  In  1960,  the  average  aircraft  capacitv  for 
the  trunkline  carrier  was  71  seats.  In  1972,  the  average  aircraft  capacity  of 
the  local  service  carrier  was  72  seats  (page  19).  Therefore,  we  see  that  there 
has  been  very  little  change  in  the  overall  capacity  of  the  aircraft  designed  to 
meet  the  needs  of  the  air  service  in  the  medium  and  low  density  markets.  We 
see  merely  that  the  overall  capacity  of  the  trunk  carriers  has  grown  sub- 
stantially due  to  the  service  inauiruration  of  very  large  equipment  designed 
to  meet  the  needs  of  the  long-haul  high-density  markets.  This  development  should 
not  adversely  affect  the  air  service  quality  in  the  low  and  medium  density  markets 
and  most  certainly  should  not  be  used  in  the  rationale  to  support  the  standard 
to  meet  such  service  needs. 

The  standaid  is  then  further  adjusted  by  the  fact  that  the  number  of  online 
stops  per  passenger  trip  decreased  from  2.57  to  1 62  and  has  remained  stable 
around  the  latter  figure  for  the  pa^t  three  years.  Therefore,  to  adjust  for  this 
difference  in  service  quality,  the  19-passenger  level  was  divided  by  .63  (the 
ratio  of  1.62  to  2.57)  to  provide  a  revised  minimum  of  30  passengers.  This  is 
another  arbitrary  adjustment  with  no  support  in  the  study.  Generally,  circum- 
stances governing  the  ability  to  provide  single-plane  service  in  markets  of  this 
size  depend  upon  the  equipment,  traffic  in  the  local  markets,  flow  characteristics 
of  other  traffic  in  the  market  and  the  mileage. 

The  traffic  flow  proportions  in  these  markets  vary  dramatically  ^^■ith  mileage. 
"For  city  pairs  at  distances  less  than  100  miles,  there  is  only  one  origin-destina- 
tion passenger  for  every  10  passengers  transported"  (page  65).  In  markets 
ranging  from  300  to  500  miles  there  are  4  origin-destination  passengers  for  every 
10  passengers  transported.  In  markets  up  to  800  miles,  the  rationale  becomes 
5  local  passengers  for  every  10  passengers  transported.  This  trend  continues  until 
we  see  that  in  markets  over  2,000  ini^es.  there  are  9  local  O&D  passengers  for 
every  10  passengers  transported.  At  this  point,  it  is  apparent  that  there  is  no 
analytical  justification  for  removing  the  initial  7.50-mile  limitation  developed 
by  the  CAB  in  1960.  A  standard  varying  with  mileage  would  have  been  far 
more  relevant  to  the  material  contained  in  the  study  (page  66).  Since  this 
type  of  information  was  not  known  relative  to  the  transportation  of  passengers 
in  1960,  there  is  no  support  for  the  rationale  for  the  adjustment  made  moving 
the  standard  from  19  passengers  up  to  30  passengers. 

The  study  then  proceeds  to  develop  the  jump  from  30  to  40  passengers  as 
follows  :  "Because  not  all  O&D  passengers  are  likely  to  prefer  single-plane  service 


719 

to  connecting  service,  the  minimum  level  of  O&D  passengers  may  be  increased 
to,  perhaps,  40"  (page  168).  This  again,  is  extremely  arbitrary  and  is  based 
on  no  evidence  developed  in  the  analysis. 

The  standard  for  evaluating  the  effectiveness  of  single-plane  service  once  a 
market  has  exceeded  the  40  true  O&D  passengers  is  "single-plane  service  used 
by  less  than  half  of  the  true  O&D  passengers  during  the  previous  12  months." 
No  information  in  the  study  was  produced  developing  this  type  of  information. 
Therefore,  we  are  limited  in  our  comments  with  regard  to  the  reasonableness 
of  such  a  standard.  Again,  in  our  judgment,  it  appears  that  such  a  standard 
should  vary  by  mileage  since  it  is  extremely  inconvenient  for  short-haul  or 
medium-haul  passengers  to  be  forced  to  use  connecting  service  because  of  the 
inadequacies  of  single-plane  services. 

In  conclusion  we  believe  that  the  study  states  many  things  which  sound  good, 
such  as  :  ''The  authority  of  any  incumbent  carrier  whose  service  is  con.'«idered 
to  be  deficient — whether  or  not  legally  'adequate'  in  the  statutory  sense — would 
be  considered  for  outright  de'etion  or  deletion  in  conjunction  with  the  issuance 
of  replacement  authority  to  another  carrier"  (page  153).  Surely  the  development 
of  service  and  economic  opportunities  in  the  future  should  be  encouraged  by 
the  regulatory  policies  of  the  CAB.  However,  the  proposal  here  goes  in  the  other 
direction.  It  is  worth  a  moment  of  conjecture  to  consider  the  catastrophic  results 
to  the  industry  had  the  proposed  policies  of  the  BOR  been  in  effect  since  1960. 

We  believe  that  the  establishment  of  a  regulatory  environment  that  is  con- 
ducive to  growth  and  development  of  the  industry  is  essential.  Further,  that  an 
effective  and  responsive  regulatory  program  will  not  be  detrimental  to  any  air 
carrier,  either  individually  or  collectively.  Future  emphasis  should  be  given  to 
placing  the  operating  authority  in  the  hands  of  the  carriers  fit,  willing  and  able 
to  provide  service  under  a  condition  whereby  the  carrier  can  generate  reasonable 
results  where  identifiable  economic  opportunities  exist.  Most  of  the  major  mar- 
kets in  the  rountry  have  carriers  which  have  the  authority  but  have  never  exer- 
cised it.  This  is  the  major  impediment  to  the  development  of  the  industry  in  the 
future,  and  the  CAB  should  take  steps  to  deal  with  this  deficiency. 

RECOMMENDATIONS 

Enlightened  regulation  can  develop  the  commercial  air  transport  industry  as 
tl  e  primary  mass  transportation  means  for  intercity  travel.  It  is  obvious  to  us 
that  this  capacity  is  present  within  the  existing  regulatory  framework.  The  first 
step  called  for  is  to  place  the  operating  authority  in  the  hands  of  the  air  carriers 
fit,  willing  and  able  to  provide  the  service.  "We  need  specific  direction  from  Con- 
gress to  the  CAB  to  move  forward. 

The  air  service  committee  in  January  unanimously  proposed  to  the  AOCI  board 
of  directors  that  AOCI  support  seven  key  legislative  amendments  to  the  Federal 
Aviation  Act.  The  amendments  are  designed  to  emphasize,  in  specific  terms,  the 
intent  of  Congress  with  respect  to  the  need  for  continuing  development  and 
improvement  of  the  air  route  structure  and  the  public  air  services  of  this  country, 
and  to  insure  that  the  language  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  i)ermits  no  misunder- 
standing or  misinterpretation  of  Congressional  policy  and  intent  in  these  matters. 
It  is  our  belief  that  the  basic  data  contained  in  the  Bureau's  study  supports  our 
recommended  legislative  initiatives  completely. 

The  seven  legislative  recommendations  are  : 

1.  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require  prompt 
and  expeditious  hearing  for  any  application  for  new  or  improved  air  service  in  a 
market  in  which  at  least  one  of  the  two  cities  principally  affected,  and  at  least 
one  certified  air  carrier,  request  such  a  priority  hearing.  In  the  absence  of  objec- 
tion, the  authority  may  be  granted  without  hearing. 

This  recommendation  is  far  more  compatible  with  the  statements  made  in  the 
Bureau  of  Operating  Rights'  study  than  the  economic  standards  proposed  in  that 
study.  The  study  recommends,  ".  .  .  to  undertake,  on  the  basis  of  published  stand- 
ards, a  continuing  program  of  route  expansion:  to  hear  and  adjudicate  route 
cases  to  improve  and  perfect  existing  authority  consistent  with  the  Board's  DPFI 
economic  goals  and  in  accordance  with  developing  traffic  requirements;"  (page 
149). 

This  legislative  reminder  will  go  a  long  way  in  establishing  effective  regula- 
tory incentives  for  the  development  of  a  complete  air  transportation  system.  The 
air' service  committee  is  in  complete  agreement  with  the  following  statements 
made  in  the  study :  "In  these  circumstances  regulatory  route  and  route-related 
policies  should  be  directed  to  improving  the  efficiency  and  quality  of  the  system 


720 

through  a  careful  expansion  of  route  authority  when  required  by  traffic,  and 
through  route  rationalization.  The  latter  will  require  direct  action  by  the  Board 
and  creation  of  incentives  for  carrier-initiated  actions.  In  so  doing,  civic  interests 
should  play  an  important  role.  This  dual  program  of  route  expansion  and  route 
rationalization  is  intended  to  make  available  new  service  whenever  a  sufficient 
demand  has  been  established,  to  correct  service  deficiencies,  and  generally,  to 
minimize  the  need  for  fare  increases  by  encouraging  efficiency"  (page  9).  This 
initial  legislative  proposal,  ".  .  .  requires  that  the  Board  proceed,  as  it  has  his- 
torically, on  a  case-by-case  basis  with  a  view  to  making  gradual  adjustments  in 
the  linear  route  system.  This  means  that  each  case  will  be  decided  on  its  own 
merits  in  accordance  with  the  statutory  standards  of  public  interest  and  public 
convenience  and  necessity  as  determined  by  the  Board"  (page  147) . 

This  proposal,  of  course,  eliminates  the  economic  obstacles  created  by  the 
establishment  of  arbitrary  -standards  that  sliould  be  achieved  prior  to  a  route 
hearing  being  pet  down  by  the  CAB.  The  fact  that  the  city  has  expressed  a  need 
for  service  and  that  a  carrier  is  willing  to  pro.secute  an  application  for  such 
service  .should  be  sufficient  indication  to  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  that  an 
investigation  should  be  conducted.  The  investigation  will  produce  the  economic 
data  that  is  specifically  relevant  to  the  market  in  question  in  order  for  the  Board 
to  find  the  economic  feasibility,  as  well  as  the  need  for  service,  on  all  of  the  other 
public  convenience  and  neces^ty  factors  that  should  he  considered  by  the  Board. 

No  obstacles  should  be  placed  before  the  carriers  who  are  willing  to  prosecute 
or  the  city  who  has  expressed  a  need  for  such  service.  This  puts  the  Board  in  a 
position  of  administering  an  industry  in  the  proper  environment  and  deciding  the 
need  for  service  on  a  case-by-case  basis  in  order  to  prevent  significant  service 
deficiencies  and  to  encourage  the  development  of  future  service  opportunities  in 
the  air  transportation  industry. 

2.  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  provide  that  non- 
stop authority  which  is  not  exercised  for  one  year  will  be  presumed  to  be  aban- 
doned. At  any  time  thereafter,  the  authority  to  provide  such  service  should  be 
granted  to  any  carrier  fit,  willing,  and  able  to  exercise  the  authority,  upon 
application  of  any  party  in  interest.  The  application  should  be  processed  in  a 
prompt  and  expeditious  manner,  and,  in  the  absence  of  objection,  should  be 
granted  witl  out  hearing. 

"Nonstop  service  is  the  level  at  which  air  travel  has  its  greatest  advantage 
and  it  is  incumbent  upon  the  Board  to  assure  the  availability  of  such  .service 
wherever  economically  possible"  (page  167).  This  is  one  of  the  most  critical  areas 
for  regulatory  activity  affecting  the  future  development  of  the  air  transportation 
industry.  The  study  dealt  with  all  airline  markets  in  the  U.S.  producing  more  than 
2,500  nondirectional  O&D  passengers  in  1972  (approximately  6.8  per  day)  (page 
70).  There  were  4,112  analyzed,  of  which  2,928  have  nonstop  authority.  In  other 
words,  71  percent  of  the  airline  markets  studied  have  nonstop  authority  that  has 
been  srranted  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  Of  this  group  or  2,928  markets,  only 
590  receive  competitive  nonstop  service.  In  addition,  another  639  markets  receive 
noncompetitive  nop.stop  service.  Therefore,  we  see  that  a  total  of  1,229  markets 
receive  nonstop  service  of  some  form,  which  is  only  42  percent  of  those  markets 
where  nonstop  authority  exists  and  was  found  to  be  necessary  at  one  time  or  an- 
other by  the  CAB. 

When  we  look  at  the  1,699  markets  where  nonstop  authority  exists  but  is 
not  provided,  on  eitlier  a  noncompetitive  or  competitive  basis,  we  begin  to  focus  on 
the  extent  of  the  need  for  the  development  of  a  regulatory  policy  designed  to 
create  the  incentive  and  the  initiative  to  place  this  authority  in  the  hands  of 
carriers  fit,  willing  and  able  to  provide  such  services.  The  regulatory  conditions 
established  by  the  CAB  should  i>ermit  new  entry  into  the  the  markets.  The  in- 
cumbent carriers  have  had  years  to  provide  such  service  and  has  found  that  their 
system  or  their  equipment  is  impractical  to  the  provision  of  nonstop  service.  This 
is  the  key  legislative  proposal  designed  to  rationalize  the  route  system  for  the 
future.  "The  authority  of  any  incumlient  carrier  whose  service  is  considered  to  be 
deficient — whether  or  not  legally  'adequate'  in  the  statutory  .sense — would  be 
considered  for  outright  deletion  or  deletion  in  conjunction  with  the  issuance 
of  replacement  authority  to  another  carrier"  (page  153).  This  language  in  the 
study  clearly  supports  our  recommendation. 

3.  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require  an  ex- 
peditious review  by  the  CAB  of  all  scheduled  air  carrier  certificate  restrictions 
that  have  not  been  imposed  or  specifically  renewed  within  the  past  5  years  on 


721 

the  basis  of  a  public  record  affirmatively  establishing  a  public  convenience  and 
necessity  requirement.  The  statute  should  further  require  that  no  restriction 
may  be'imposed  for  a  period  longer  than  5  years;  and  that  in  order  to  renew 
it  for  additional  periods  of  up  to  5  years  each,  an  affirmative  showing  must 
be  made  that  each  such  renewal  is  required  by  the  public  convenience  and 
necessity.  .  . 

Restrictions  in  an  air  carrier's  certificate  generally  represent  recognition  of 
conditions  affecting  other  carriers,  especially  with  regard  to  impact  on  serv- 
ices provided  by  other  carriers.  Since  such  action  is  permanently  imbedded  into 
the  air  carrier's  certificate,  a  restriction  has  a  tendency  to  remain  in  a  carrier's 
certificate  without  change  until  a  formal  CAB  investigation  has  been  conducted 
to  investigate  the  need  for  perpetuating  such  service  conditions.  Since  the  CAB's 
route  moratorium  has  been  effective,  there  is  no  opportunity  for  the  public  to 
be  heard  with  regard  to  the  need  for  a  change  in  such  restrictions  nor  is  there 
an  incentive  for  the  carriers  to  pursue  the  elimination  of  such  restrictions.  How- 
ever, if  restrictions  were  made  temporary  in  nature,  the  CAB  would  automati- 
cally focus  its  attention  on  the  need  for  the  retention  of  such  conditions.  The 
burden  of  proof  for  the  need  to  retain  restrictions  would  be  placed  upon  the 
individuals  who  would  be  adversely  affected  if  the  restriction  were  removed.  If 
no  demonstration  by  such  individuals  is  made  under  the  circumstances  that 
prevail  at  the  end  of  such  5-year  period,  then  that  restriction  would  be  removed 
from  a  carrier's  certificate.  This,  of  course,  enables  the  carrier  to  provide  a  more 
effective  level  of  service  in  the  market. 

Tiie  conditions  that  prevailed  at  the  time  of  the  imposition  of  a  restriction 
often  times  change  in  such  a  volatile,  and  growing  industry.  Therefore,  this 
allows  the  regulatory  process  to  maintain  a  timely  evaluation  of  such  conditions 
in  order  to  allow  the  CAB  to  keep  pace  with  technological  developments. 

4.  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require  the  award 
of  ne^v  competitive  authority  wherever  it  can  be  shown  that  the  carriers'  opera- 
tions in  the  market  will  produce  reasonable  results.  This  proposed  amendment 
is  predicated  upon  the  demonstrated  fact  that  competition  develops  traffic,  im- 
proves service,  lowers  fares,  and  lowers  unit  costs  by  expanding  service  and 
promoting  efficiency,  all  for  the  public  benefit. 

El'iective  and  constructive  competition  is  the  key  to  the  complete  develop- 
ment of  the  air  transportation  system  operating  with  maximum  efficiency 
with  the  lowest  unit  costs  possible  and.  therefore,  charging  the  lowest  prices 
possible  to  tlie  pass-engers.  The  CAB's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights  study  de- 
veloped an  extensive  analysis  of  the  air  transiX)rtation  industry's  operations 
between  1960  to  1972.  The  development  of  competitive  routes  produced  solid  bene- 
fits to  the  traveling  public  as  well  as  economic  benefits  to  the  carriers. 

Constructive  two-carrier  competition  did  not  destroy  the  economic  viability  of 
the  carriers.  Constructive  two-carrier  competition  improved  service,  lowered  fares, 
lowered  break-even  load  factor  requirements,  stimulated  traffic  development,  stim- 
ulated technological  development,  lowered  unit  costs  and  extended  significant  air 
service  improvement  into  other  noncompetitive  markets. 

AVhile  the  study  did  not  conclude  that  competition  was  beneficial  to  the  indus- 
trv,  the  information  in  the  study  clearly  demonstrates  that  this  is  the  case.  The 
growth  of  scheduled  airline  passenger  traffic  from  1960  to  1972  is  overwhelmingly 
dominated  by  the  growth  experienced  in  the  competitive  markets.  Comparative 
revenue  passenger  miles  grew  at  14.1  per  year  is  competitive  markets  versus  11.6 
percent  per  year  in  monopoly  markets.  An  illustration  of  chart  10  (page  102) 
(if  the  study'is  a  dramatic  display  of  the  difference  in  development  between  the 
two,  irdicating  that  substantial  market  development,  growth  and  stimulation 
takes  place  in  competitive  markets.  Also,  there  has  been  no  growth  in  the  monop- 
oly markets  since  the  CAB's  route  moratorium  started.  When  the  moratorium 
began  in  1970,  traffic  fell  from  the  1969  level  in  the  monopoly  markets  (appendix 
A,  table  7). 

Competitive  authorizations  in  the  sixties  often  produced  new  single-plane 
service  in  monopoly  markets  causing  traffic  stimulation.  The  comi)etitive  route 
awards  during  the  late  sixties  were  the  primary  reason  for  most  of  the  growth 
experienced  in  the  monopoly  markets  during  this  period.  Had  it  not  been  for 
this  policy,  not  even  the  moderate  growth  experienced  in  the  monopoly  markets 
prior  to  1969  wouUl  have  been  achieved. 

"Moreover,  growth  rates  in  ?ompetitive  markets  are  higher  since,  generally, 
they  tend  to  be  larger,  rapid  growth  markets  with  higher  traffic  levels  and  lower 


722 

yields  than  monopoly  markets"  (page  105).  Thi?,  in  itself,  is  a  very  strong 
endorsement  for  competitive  operations  when  possible.  Prior  to  the  CAB's 
route  moratorium,  after  a  service  investigation  in  the  market,  the  CAB  found : 
"In  some  cases,  however,  competitive  service  was  authorized  simply  because  a 
market  was  large  enough  to  support  competitive  service — on  the  theory  that 
competitive  service  is  per  se,  better  than  monopoly  service"  (page  50). 

"Competition  tends  to  reduce  the  actual  yield  received  by  a  carrier,  i.e.,  the 
dilution  factor  in  competitive  markets  tends  to  be  greater  than  noncompetitive 
markets"  (page  97).  Also,  "Since  competitive  markets  are  on  average  of  higher 
density  than  noncompetitive  markets,  route  density  should  favor,  again  assuming 
other  things  equal,  a  lower  break-even  point  in  competitive  markets"  (page  97). 

The  extension  of  flights  to  additional  cities  usually  inaugurates  single-plane 
service  between  the  new  city  and  each  of  the  other  cities  in  the  itinerary.  This 
change  in  service  is  often  the  result  of  the  award  of  new  competitive  service 
(page  75).  The  first  single-plane  beyond  area  proposals  considered  during  the 
route  cases  of  the  sixties  constituted  a  primary  method  by  which  the  linear 
network  was  extended,  and  in  many  cases  resulted  in  service  patterns  which 
could  not  have  been  sustained  by  other  than  a  combination  of  traffic  flows  in 
several  markets  including  the  markets  directly  at  issue  (page  52).  These  beyond 
area  benefits  flow  directly  from  the  authorization  of  competitive  service  and 
contributed  greatlv  to  the  growth  in  the  monopoly  market  between  1960  and 
1972. 

The  mandate  in  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  regarding  the  development  of  com- 
petition should  be  particu'arly  important.  The  findings  in  the  CAB's  BOR  study 
are  not  related  to  the  material  contained  in  the  study  and  point  the  Civil 
Aeronautics  Board  on  a  course  in  the  opposite  direction  with  regard  to  competi- 
tive policy.  The  objective  of  the  study  appears  to  isolate  on  the  principle  that 
competition  creates  most  of  the  problems  in  the  air  transportation  industry, 
should  be  avoided  in  the  future,  and  should  be  eliminated  wherever  possible. 

The  conclusion  of  the  study  is  :  "The  system  has  offered,  in  general,  an  overall 
volume  of  service  that  is  excessive  in  relation  to  demand  in  competitive  markets" 
(page  8).  With  some  hesitation  the  study  concludes  that  competition  drives  load 
factors  below  the  reasonable  level  and  prevents  carriers  from  achieving  a  12 
percent  return  on  investment.  Therefore,  the  CAB  should  adopt  a  policy  through 
the  implementation  of  standards,  of  avoiding  this  in  the  future  in  order  to 
improve  the  economic  conditions  of  the  industry. 

The  study  indicates  that  the  key  to  developing  the  improved  economic  condi- 
tion of  the  indu.stry  is  to  increase  load  factors ;  and  that  the  key  to  increasing 
load  factors  is  to  eliminate  competition  as  much  as  possible  by  discouraging 
competition  in  markets  today,  encouraging  capacity  restriction  agreements  and 
denying  considerati(>n  for  the  authorization  of  competitive  service  in  the  future. 
The  study  concludes :  "If  any  real  improvement  in  load  factors  is  to  be  achieved 
by  a  lessening  in  the  degree  of  competition,  it  is  necessary  to  establish  monopoly 
status  for  the  markets  in  question"  (page  89).  This,  of  course,  is  a  gross  over- 
simplification of  (he  problem  with  regard  to  competition  versus  profits.  No  one 
denies  that  excessive  competition  or  destructive  competition  hurts  the  industry 
and  is  not  in  the  public  interest.  However,  nowhere  in  the  study  is  there  any 
support  for  the  concept  that  two-carrier  competition  creates  these  problems. 
Destructive  competition  creates  thes^e  problems.  Constructive  competition  has 
proven  to  be  beneficial  to  the  industry,  the  carriers  and  the  traveling  public.  The 
particular  features  with  regard  to  the  determination  for  the  need  for  competition 
on  a  route  can  only  be  obtained  through  the  hearing  process  established  by  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board.  Of  course,  if  not  contested,  competitive  route  awards 
should  be  made  automatically. 

5.  Amend  or  supplement  the  existing  statutory  provisions  to  require  the  board 
to  adopt  procedures  for  the  prompt  and  expeditious  handling  of  route  eases 
similar  to  the  present  subpart  m  and  n  and  show  cause  procedures,  and  to  facili- 
tate the  expeditious  processing  of  cases  wherever  possible. 

The  Board  has  within  its  rules  and  regulations  at  the  present  time  methods  to 
handle,  expeditiously,  route  applications  in  order  to  avoid  a  prolonged  adminis- 
trative procedure  dealing  with  every  change  in  operating  authority.  These  ad- 
ministrative vehicles  are  timely  and  efficient  and  far  less  costly  for  both  the 
carriers  and  communities  in  terms  of  time  and  expenses  when  compared  to  par- 
ticipating in  a  normal  CAB  investigation. 


723 

When  route  case  applications  are  uncontested,  no  hearing  should  be  required. 
However,  when  there  is  a  contested  route  case  application,  a  quick  determination 
should  be  made  with  regard  to  the  scope  of  an  investigation,  and  wherever  pos- 
sible expeditious  treatment  should  be  given  consistent  with  the  interests  of  the 
public. 

Determining  priority  with  regard  to  route  policies  has  always  been  a  monu- 
mental problem  at  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  and  is  a  necessary  part  of  the 
agency's  discharge  of  its  responsibilities.  However,  the  effective  handling  of  this 
area  is  both  feasible  and  desirable  and  the  CAB  should  be  allowed  to  pursue  the 
development  of  regulatory  practices  which  permit  it  to  function  in  this  manner.  If 
additional  staff  is  to  be  required,  we  urge  that  the  Congress  support  such  a  re- 
quest. It  may  even  be  practical  for  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  consider  the 
possibility  of  maintaining  a  limited  scale  of  operation  outside  of  Washington 
similar  to  the  manner  of  other  government  agencies  in  order  to  process  more 
expeditiously  the  need  for  regulatory  action  in  the  other  parts  of  the  country. 

6.  Adopt  legislation  that  will  recognize  air  transportation  as  the  basic  func- 
tioning mass  transportation  system  for  intercity  travel  in  this  nation.  As  such 
there  should  be  a  legislative  requirement  that  it  be  accorded  a  top  priority  fuel 
allocation  that  will  meet  the  full  need  of  the  system  and  thereby  encourage  the 
most  efficient  use  of  available  fuel  supplied.  Fuel  limitations  will  cause  a  further 
shriveling  and  riddling  of  the  nation's  air  transport  services.  This  is  the  route  to 
higher  unit  costs,  higher  air  fares,  higher  load  factors  because  of  less  available 
service,  higher  profits,  a  severe  shrinkage  in  overall  public  accommodation,  and  a 
greater  dependence  upon  the  private  automobile.  Fuel  shortages  have  provided 
and  may  soon  again  provide  a  primary  excuse  for  a  failure  to  respond  to  urgently 
needed  new  air  transport  services  and  in  many  instances  will  lead  to  a  literal 
reduction  in  required  public  service. 

The  air  transportation  industry  is  the  mass  transportation  system  that  is  de- 
signed to  meet  the  needs  for  the  present,  as  well  as  for  the  future,  of  intercity 
travel.  The  cultivation  and  development  of  this  industry  can  accomplish  enor- 
mous economic  benefits  for  our  country,  as  well  as  create  a  condition,  whereby  we, 
as  a  country,  can  conserve  fuel  in  a  logical  and  sensible  manner.  The  availability 
of  fuel  at  a  reasonable  price  is  critical  for  the  industry  to  grow  and  develop  to 
meet  the  present  and  future  needs  of  this  nation.  An  effective  regulatory  atmos- 
phere combined  with  this  feature  can  produce  an  industry  that  can  contribute 
greatly  to  the  economic  recovery  of  this  country. 

Growth  has  always  been  the  key  ingredient  in  the  long  history  of  decreasing 
unit  costs  in  air  transportation.  Growth,  resulting  in  lower  unit  costs,  has  en- 
abled the  airline  industry  in  the  past  to  offer  a  pricing  structure  that  has  made 
air  transportation  one  of  the  highest  quality  and  least  inflationary  services  of 
any  in  this  nation.  Growth  means  lower  unit  costs  and  consequent  ability  to  pro- 
vide lower  fares,  which  in  turn  means  more  traffic  and  more  need  for  additional 
and  better  aircraft.  This  leads  to  more  technological  advancement  resulting  in  the 
production  of  aircraft  with  lower  seat  mile  costs,  which  again  permits  lower 
fares  (or  at  least  a  lower  rate  of  increa.se  than  nearly  everything  else)  ;  thus, 
more  traffic,  more  growth,  etc.  When  this  occurs,  it  provides  substantial  additional 
stimuli  to  the  national  economy  through  expansion  of  employment  in  the  airlines, 
the  manufacturing  companies,  airports  and  all  other  air  transport-related  in- 
dustries. Expansion  and  growth  are  absolutely  vital  to  the  industry. 

7.  Adopt  legislation  directing  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  establish  classi- 
fications of  markets  or  cities  whereby  priority  of  hearing  can  be  decided  within 
each  such  classification.  The  most  urgent  need  in  a  small  or  medium  market  or 
small  or  medium  sized  city  should  be  heard  as  quickly  as  the  most  urgent  need 
in  the  nation's  largest  markets  and  largest  cities.  Without  such  a  system,  the 
critical  needs  of  any  less  than  the  biggest  may  never  be  heard,  for  they  will  be 
constantly  submerged  further  from  the  top. 

The  need  for  air  transportation  is  not  confined  in  any  special  category  of  cities. 
The  need  for  air  transportation  exists  in  cities  that  are  remote,  as  well  as  cities 
closely  located  to  major  metropolitan  areas.  The  ability  of  the  air  transportation 
system  to  function  effectively  is  to  recognize  this  need  on  a  timely  basis  for  all 
types  of  cities  in  all  types  of  circumstances. 

At  the  present  time.  18  airlines  are  certificated  by  the  Federal  government  to 
meet  this  transportation  need.  Every  opportunity  should  be  granted  to  these 
carriers  under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  Federal  government  to  meet  this  need. 
However,  if  these  carriers  are  not  fit,  willing  or  able  to  meet  this  need,  the  cer- 
tification of  other  carriers  must  be  considered  in  order  for  the  air  transportation 


724 

industry  to  properly  develop  under  a  sensible  regulatory  atmosphere.  The  industry 
needs  regulation.  The  industry  needs  positive  incentives  in  order  to  develop  the 
potential  that  presently  exists.  The  potential  of  this  industry  is  still  in  its 
infancy. 

Enlightened  Federal  regulation  is  the  key  to  the  effective  development  of  the 
air  transportation  industry.  Air  service  to  the  small  community  must  be  developed 
as  effectively  as  air  service  to  the  large  community.  This  can  only  be  done  in  a 
regulatory  environment  conducive  to  the  complete  development  of  an  air  trans- 
portation'industry  under  a  uniform  system  of  regulatory  incentives. 


725 


ATTACHMENT  D 


sO    vO    vD   LA    lT)    vO    r^  I  0\ 


'-\  -\ 


^1  ^I 


r^  r^  00  r~- 


^\ 


r-  r^  CO  vol 


3|       ^1  ^  ^  t-.  CO  M  ol       -^l 

-I       vol  CO  oo  i^  t^  CO  r~-|       [^1 


cnrs]cOLO(Nr^C7>coi 


SI       ?| 


^1    Si 


o  \o  \o  \o 


I  SI 


CO     r-<     ^     OO    -HJ  \0\ 


\0   00   O   O   ' 


tel    SI 


?^\ 


D     •«     u   -H  t>    X   3    i-i    O 

CXI   ^l   ^.   xc--"   coo.*-! 

rl     O     rl     O.  O     3    3 


<  u)  o  ;-  Q 


rt  3  jir  ^ 

3  t.  U  H 

.  c  jo  >-i  ^1  : 

o  O  rl  n^  I 


726 


ATTACHMENT  E 


o       r^        c\» 


to        r-~        •-< 


CM    U^  p-  .-I 

Ol    LO    LO  O 


Irsi  j       o 


rt  tfP  vO 


•-H  in  o 

--I     rr     LO 


^Ji" 


727 


c3  t^ 


ATTACHMENT   E 


p  +J  14-I       1/1 

•H     0) 

0         0     •  ■*-• 

cv.  C         in   y) 

X)  -3 

^.H  cN°    0    0 

rt   c 

0         0    (H    0 

4J    rt 

e  -r)  CO   rt 

■  HO          ^  ^ 

+j   w    bo        rt 

3    C  fO    C 

^H     +J       X          • 

Ai        -H  r-    0 

0  x:  -H  \o 

0    -P     6    Ol     H 

to  CO  6 

0    C    3  -H    *J      . 

C    -rt             4-> 

0  -1  <->   rt 

10  («    c 

a,  rt    M   3  Ol 

u)         0  -3 

a  u  e  0 

in  '3     -  x>       '" 

P,  0     4->    4J 

rt  a*  0  E  c:   c 

&  w   rt 

M    0)    3    0    0  -H 

0        c  > 

0  0    >    3 

M   4->    0    0  -3  -O 

&,o    C   0 

•H     C     >   ^     0     0 

rt    rt    0         «    0 

\D  Ln          rt 

C    1-c   C    rt    C 

CSI    ^     C     0 

0    -H              0    XI     0 

.   in     0 

to  E  '-'               ■'^ 

vO       ~           C 

r-l     ^     -0      M 

2-3     3    0    ^     0 

</^^</>    0    3 

0   0  *->   w  u)   a. 

>    M   0   rt   0    K 

♦J  4->    rt   0 

<   D.    <  ^   U     0 

<   <   03    M 

728 


PSA  LOAD  FACTOR  HISTORY 
1967  -  FY  1972 


ATTACHMENT  P 


Load  Factor 


Los  Angeles 


Period 

San 
Francisco 

San 
Jose 

Oakland 

i7 

68% 

63% 

67% 

i8 

59 

59 

63 

.9 

54 

51 

54 

0 

56 

53 

59 

1  -  1st  Quarter 
2nd  Quarter 
3rd  Quarter 
4th  Quarter 

53 
58 
61 
60 

48- 
55 
48 
54 

57 
60 
63 
59 

'2  -  1st  Quarter 
2iid  Quarter 

60 
61 

54 
58 

60 
64 

Source:  California  Public  Utilities  Conunission 
Form  No.  1504 


729 

Airport  Operators  Council  International,  Inc., 

March  4,  1975. 
Hon.  Edward  M.  Kennedy, 
U.S.  Senate, 
Washington,  D.C. 

Dear  Senator  Kennedy:  On  February  18,  your  subcommittee  received  testi- 
mony on  the  subject  of  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  Regulation  of  Airline  Route 
Awards  from  Mr.  James  Gagnon,  Chairman  of  the  AOCI  ad  hoc  committee  on 
air  service  and  general  manager  of  the  Louisville  and  Jefferson  County  (Ken- 
tucky) Air  Board. 

Because  of  the  subcommittee's  need  to  receive  the  prepared  testimony  a  num- 
ber of  days  in  advance  of  the  public  hearing,  the  draft  text  of  Mr.  Gagnon's 
presentation  and  the  many  attachments  to  his  prepared  testimony  could  not  be 
reviewed  by  the  AOCI  Board  of  Directors  in  advance  of  his  scheduled  appearance 
on  February  18. 

The  AOCI  Board  of  Directors  at  its  meeting  on  February  20  did,  however, 
review  the  testimony  of  Mr.  Gagnon  with  a  view  toward  determining  whether 
his  position,  as  presented  to  the  subcommittee,  reflected  the  views  of  all  AOCI 
members. 

The  AOCI  Board  concluded,  and  directed  that  we  so  communicate  to  you,  that 
the  views  expressed  by  Mr.  Gagnon  on  the  issue  of  the  CAB  route  moratorium 
are  supported  by  the  "full  AOCI  membership  to  the  extent  consistent  with  the 
attached  resolution  of  October  6.  1974. 

All  other  issues  addressed  by  Mr.  Gagnon  at  this  time  reflect  only  his  individual 
views  or  those  of  the  ad  hoc  committee  he  presently  chairs  and  should  not  be  con- 
sidered the  official  views  of  this  association  or  its  entire  U.S.  membership.  Specifi- 
cally, the  CAB  staff  study  on  the  "Domestic  Route  System :  Analysis  and  Policy 
Recommendations"  (October  1974),  on  which  Mr.  Gagnon  commented,  has  not 
been  reviewed  by  AOCI  at  this  time.  Copies  of  our  formal  comments  on  the  study, 
due  to  the  Board  by  May  1,  will  be  forwarded  to  your  subcommittee  for  its  infor- 
mation. Further,  the  AOCI  membership  at  this  time  does  not  endorse  any  of  the 
specific  legislative  recommendations  set  out  in  Mr.  Gagnon's  text.  While  AOCI 
may  well,  after  review  of  the  ad  hoc  committee's  findings,  support  some  or  all 
of  its  legislative  proposals,  they  do  not  have  any  AOCI  endorsement  at  the  cur- 
rent time. 

Should  AOCI  support  any  legislative  proposals  for  improving  the  process  for 
CAB  action  on  air  route  matters,  you  may  be  assured  that  these  would  be  com- 
municated to  your  subcommittee  as  well  as  to  the  Senate  Aviation  Subcommittee 
which  has  substantive  jurisdiction  over  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board. 

We  would  request  that  this  clarification  of  AOCI's  views  on  the  issues  before 
your  subcommittee  be  placed  in  the  printed  record  of  your  hearings,  in  conjunc- 
tion with  Mr.  Gagnon's  testimony,  to  minimize  any  confusion  resulting  from  the 
testimony. 

We  apologize  for  any  inconvenience  that  might  have  been  caused  to  the  sub- 
committee by  the  inability  of  our  Board  of  Directors  to  review  the  prepared  testi- 
mony of  its  Air  Service  Committee  in  a  timely  manner  prior  to  its  presentation 
on  February  18. 

Sincerely,  _  ^    ^ 

Donald  G.  Shay, 

President. 

Attachment. 

Moratorium  on  Air  Route  Hearings 

Whereas,  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  is  engaged  in  a  moratorium  on  its  regu- 
latory activities  involving  the  potential  authorization  of  new.  altered  and/or 
competitive  air  service  patterns  within  the  U.S.  domestic  air  transportation  sys- 
tem ;  and  .  , 

Whereas,  it  is  the  conviction  of  AOCI  that  this  moratorium  is  in  conflict  with 
the  law  and  legislative  mandate  of  Congress  ;  and 

Whereas,  this  moratorium  has  detrimental  impact  upon  the  public  interest, 
contrary  to  the  provisions  of  Congress  through  its  legislation  ;  and 

Whereas,  the  AOCI  does  represent  the  broadest  single  segment  of  public  inter- 
ests in  aviation  matters,  and  therefore  is  best  suited  to  represent  the  public  in- 
terest before  the  Congress  and  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  ; 

Now,  Therefore,  Be  It  Resolved,  by  the  Airport  Operators  Council  Interna- 
tional in  meeting  assembled,  that 


730 

1.  The  AOCI  Policy  Handbook  be  further  amended  by  the  addition  of  a 
new  section  6.15,  Moratorium  on  Air  Route  Hearings,  as  follows : 

6.15      MOBATORIUM  ON  AIR  BOUTE  HEARINGS 

AOCI  requests  and  urges  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  to  rededicate  its  efforts 
in  the  spirit  and  intent  of  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of  1958,  as  amended,  to 
futher  develop  the  domestic  air  transportation  system  in  the  public  inter- 
est. In  the  view  of  airport  operators,  the  CAB  should  immediately  rein- 
state the  judicial  and  evidentiary  processes  contained  in  its  rules  of  practice 
in  economic  proceedings,  involving  the  potential  authorization  of  new,  al- 
tered and/or  competetive  air  service  ;  and 

2.  The  AOCI  ad  hoc  committee  on  air  service  is  urged  to  prepare  and  im- 
plement a  program  involving  the  entire  domestic  membership  in  an  effort 
to  bring  to  the  attention  of  Congress  that  the  public  convenience  and  neces- 
sity for  adequate  air  services  can  no  longer  be  met  by  continuation  of  the 
moratorium ;  and 

3.  The  executive  vice  president  is  directed  to  forward  copies  of  this  resolu- 
tion to  the  Chairman  and  members  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  and  to 
the  President  of  the  United  States,  the  Vice  President  of  the  Ignited  States  in 
his  capacity  as  President  of  the  Senate,  and  to  the  Speaker  of  the  House  of 
Representatives. 

Adopted  at  the  general  membershin  business  meeting  of  the  Airport  Operators 
Council  International  on  October  10,  1974. 


[The  following  prepared  statement  by  Robert  J.  Aaronson,  State 
Aviation  Administrator,  Maryland  Department  of  Transportation, 
was  also  submitted  for  the  record.] 

Federal  Regulation  of  Route  Awards 
Robert  J.   Aaronson 

The  State  of  Maryland  is  the  owner  and  operator  of  Baltimore-Washington 
International  Airport.  The  management  of  the  airport  rests  with  the  State  Avia- 
tion Administration,  Maryland  Department  of  Transportation. 

Baltimore-Washington  International  Airport  (BWI)  was  first  opened  to  com- 
mercial airline  service  in  June  of  1950.  At  the  time  the  facilities  were  constructed, 
the  airport  was  the  most  advanced  in  the  nation.  For  many  years  the  airport 
served  the  airlines  and  the  traveling  public  well.  When  the  Baltimore- 
Washington  Parkway  was  built  in  1954,  a  high-speed  connector  road  was  pro- 
vided directly  into  the  terminal,  facilitating  access  to  the  airport  from  all  direc- 
tions. This  development  was  to  attain  greater  importance  in  the  following  years, 
with  the  introduction  of  commercial  jet  services  at  the  facility.  The  airport  was 
the  enst  coast  terminus  of  the  recordbreaking  transcontinental  flight  by  the 
first  Boeing  707  ietliner  in  1957.  and  2  years  liter  in  1959.  was  the  scene  of 
federal  certification  ceremonies  for  the  Douglas  DC-8.  The  foresight  of  the  City 
of  Baltimore  in  building  this  airport,  with  its  extensive  facilities,  provided  the 
Baltimore-Washington  art  a  with  its  only  jet  airport  until  the  opening  of  Dulles 
Airport  in  1962. 

However,  by  the  late  sixties.  Friendship  International  Airport,  as  the  airport 
was  then  called,  had  not  kept  pace  with  industry  growth  and  its  facilities  were 
generally  considered  inadequate  by  both  passengers  and  airlines.  Recognizing 
the  importance  of  the  airport  facility  to  the  Maryland/Virginia/D.C./central 
Pennsylvania  region,  the  State  of  Maryland  purchased  the  airport  in  July  of 
1972. 

In  January  of  1973,  Secretary  of  Transportation  Harry  R.  Huehes,  and  State 
Aviation  Administrator  Robert  J.  Aaronson,  announced  an  ambitious,  two-fold 
plan  to  upgrade,  improve  and  modernize  all  airport  facilities  and  service.  The 
$50  million  improvement  and  modernization  program  will  create  an  airport  which 
presents  an  entirely  new  face  to  the  traveler.  The  entire  program  is  planned  for 
completion  in  time  for  the  nation's  bicentenial  celebration. 

On  November  16,  1974,  the  airport  was  renamed  Baltimore- Washington  Inter- 
national Airport,  a  name  which  readily  identifies  the  important  regional  character 


731 

of  the  airport  service  area.  As  attachment  1  indicates,  Baltimore-Washington 
International  Airport  is  the  only  airport  among  the  three  serving  this  area  which 
conveniently  serves  both  Baltimore  and  Washington.  While  both  National  Airport 
and  Dulles  Airport  provide  important  public  benefits  to  the  Washington,  D.C. 
air  traveler,  neither  airport  conveniently  serves  the  Baltimore  traveler.  The  basis 
for  these  statements  is  a  recent  survey  of  air  passengers  departing  the  area's 
three  airports.  The  survey  was  conducted  through  the  cooperative  efforts  of  the 
Maryland  Department  of  Transportation,  the  Commonwealth  of  Virginia  and  the 
Washington  Council  of  Governments.  . 

In  addition  to  initiating  a  program  for  the  development  of  airport  facilities, 
the  State  of  Maryland  has  also  undertaken  a  program  to  improve  and  expand  the 
air  services  which  are  required  at  Baltimore-Washington  International  Airport. 
The  State  has  recently  completed  a  comprehensive  review  of  air  service  in  the 
Baltimore/Washington  consolidated  metropolitan  area  and  has  projected  sched- 
uled air  service  requirements  at  Baltimore-Washington  International  Airport, 
requirements  which  recognize  the  unique  role  played  by  this  airport. 

The  air  service  analysis  centers  upon  the  top  50  ranking  Baltimore/Washing- 
ton markets.  These  are  all  large  and  important  markets,  with  even  the  50th  rank- 
ing market,  Columbia,  S.C,  generating  in  excess  of  150  daily  passengers.  Mary- 
land's analysis  indicates  that  nonstop  service  between  Baltimore -Washington 
International  Airport  and  each  of  these  50  cities  is  currently  requiretl  by  the 
public  and  can  be  operated  at  a  profit.  Attachment  2  tabulates  by  market  1975 
passengers  who  would  use  BWI,  provided  adequate  nonstop  service  is  available. 

Attachment  3  lists  Baltimore/Washington's  top  50  markets  and  indicates  the 
nonstop  authority  possessed  by  each  of  the  12  airlines  serving  this  area  differ- 
entiating between  Baltimore-Washington  International  Airport,  National  Air- 
port, and  Dulles  Airport.  The  attachment  also  indicates  where  nonstop  authority 
is  not  currently  being  used ;  that  is,  where  no  nonstop  round-trip  service  is  oper- 
ated by  the  subject  carrier,  as  of  February  1,  1975.  This  attachment  clearly  shows 
the  inadequate  service  level  at  BWI.  For  example,  United  Airlines  has  BWI  non- 
stop authority  in  31  of  the  top  50  Baltimore/Washington  markets.  However, 
United  operates  nonstop  service  in  only  8  of  these  31  markets.  Both  American 
Airlines  and  TWA  have  nonstop  authority  to  and  from  BWI  in  15  markets,  but 
only  operate  in  two.  As  can  be  seen,  this  pattern  is  reflected  in  the  BWI  operations 
of  other  carriers. 

Maryland's  program  to  improve  air  service  at  Baltimore-Washington  Inter- 
national Airport  is  based  in  part  upon  efforts  by  the  state  to  persuade  airlines 
with  existing  authority  to  provide  the  needed  service.  Maryland  believes  that 
this  approach  will  be  successful  in  developing  some  of  the  needed  service.  Where 
nonstop  service  has  been  authorized  and  is  economically  feasible,  nonstop  service 
should  be  provided.  However,  where  a  CAB-authorized  airline  is  unwilling  or 
unable  to  provide  the  required  service,  Maryland  will  seek  new  authority  for  an- 
other interested  carrier.  This  new  authority,  of  course,  requires  CAB  action. 

1970-1975  Route  Award  Moratorium 

Unfortunately,  through  the  actions  of  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  which  sup- 
port statements  made  by  Board  members  and  staff,  there  has  been,  since  1970,  a 
moratorium  in  the  granting  of  new  route  authority,  or  even  hearing  applications 
for  new  route  authority.  For  example,  the  CAB's  Bureau  of  Operating  Rights 
(BOB)  study.  The  Domestic  Route  Syst^tn,  states  in  the  foreword: 

"Since  approximately  1970,  cases  involving  new  domestic  route  authority  have 
generally  not  been  set  for  hearing,  and  applications  filed  under  subpart  M  and  N 
have  been  stayed  or  dismissed.  Instead,  the  Board  has  accorded  priority  to  other 
matters,  principally  in  the  area  of  rates  and  enforcement,  as  well  as  certain  other 
route  and  route-related  actions." 

The  Domrotic  Route  System  Analysis  and  Policy  Recommendation  By  the  Bureau 
of  Operating  Rights 

The  CAB  staff  study  conducted  by  the  BOR  contains  recommendations  which, 
if  adopted,  would  formalize  in  CAB  regulations  the  now  informal  moratorium  on 
route  awards.  Generally,  the  proposed  regulations  or  standards  present  severe 
economic  obstacles  to  the  continued  development  of  air  transportation  in  this 
country.  As  can  be  seen  by  the  situation  at  Baltimore-Washington  International 
Airport  (attachment  3)  certain  sectors  of  the  United  States'  air  transportation 


732 

system  require  further  development,  including  new  route  awards  and  redistribu- 
tion of  unused  authority.  Maryland's  program  of  air  service  development  will 
be  seriously  damaged,  not  only  by  the  inability  to  gain  favorable  CAB  action 
on  requests  for  new  market  entry  by  willing  and  able  carriers,  but  also  in  carrier 
negotiations  because  carriers  with  unused  authority  will  feel  protected  by  the 
CAB. 

For  example,  there  are  an  estimated  228  dnily  passengers  available  to  support 
nonstop  service  between  BWI  and  St.  Louis,  Baltimore/Washington's  15th  rank- 
ing market  (attachment  2). 

Eastern  .'ind  TWA  possess  nonstop  authority  but  nonstop  service  is  not  pro- 
vided by  either  carrier  (attachment  .3).  This  level  of  traffic  would  support  two 
round-trip  nonstop  flights  in  DC-9  or  B  727  aircraft  and  develop  a  61  percent 
passenger  load  factor.  The  passenger  load  factor  required  to  cover  all  costs  plus 
a  full  12  percent  return  on  investment  is  only  53  percent,  indicating  that  two 
round-trip.s  should  be  profitable  to  either  carrier. 

Maryland  plans  to  discuss  this  analysis  with  Eastern  and  TWA  in  an  attempt 
to  persuade  one  or  both  carriers  to  provide  nonstop  service  (in  the  past,  as 
many  as  2%  round-trip  nonstops  have  been  provided  by  TWA).  If  this  effort  is 
unsuccessful,  Maryland  will  approach  Allegheny  which  now  has  onestop  author- 
ity (and  service)  in  this  market  to  see  if  this  carrier  is  interested  in  providing 
nonstop  service.  If  so,  a  request  for  a  restriction  removal  will  be  made  at  the 
CAB.  If  not,  another  carrier  will  be  approached. 

If,  because  of  either  a  formal  or  an  informal  route  moratorium,  there  is  little 
likelihood  that  the  CAB  would  award  new  BWI-St.  Louis  nonstop  authority — 
and  this  is  known  in  advance  by  Eastern  and  TWA — these  two  carriers  will  feel 
no  pressure  during  discussions  with  us  to  agree  to  operate  the  required,  profit- 
able BWI-St.  Louis  nonstop  service.  Their  unused  authority  would  be  protected 
by  the  CAB  and  an  economic  opportunity  denied  another  willing  carrier.  And  of 
course,  a  public  need  goes  unserAed. 

I  will  now  briefly  review  these  "standards"  proposed  by  the  Bureau  of  Operat- 
ing Rights,  indicating  how  they  would  further  the  current  moratorium  on  route 
development. 

First  Nonsiop  Service  Standard 

The  standard  proposed  by  the  Bureau  before  allowing  first  nonstop  service  in 
a  market  is : 

"♦  *  *  true  O&D  plus  flow  traffic,  for  the  previous  12  months  .  .  .  sufficient  to 
maintain  a  55  percent  load  factor  on  two  roundtrips  with  the  smallest  aircraft 
type  commonly  used  in  city-pairs  of  similar  mileage  range."  (page  165) ^  "Non- 
stop service  is  the  level  at  which  air  travel  has  its  greatest  advantage  and  it  is 
incumbent  upon  the  Board  to  assure  the  availability  of  such  service  whenever 
economically  possible."  (page  167) 

This  standard  is  counterproductive  if  the  CAB  truly  seeks  to  maximize  non- 
stop services.  It  is  based  upon  the  actual  traffic  flows  in  a  market  prior  to  first 
nonstop  service.  New  nonstop  service  will  obviously  stimulate  the  develo>ment 
of  traffic  in  the  local  market,  as  well  as  improve  the  amount  of  through  traffic 
travelling  over  the  city-pair  segment  to  or  from  other  cities.  This  new  traffic 
is  not  considered  by  the  study  standard  in  determining  the  need  for  nonstop 
service  despite  the  fact  that  the  CAB  has  historically  relied  on  this  traffic  in 
granting  new  authority. 

In  addition  the  proposed  standard  allows,  to  a  large  extent,  the  incumbent 
carrier  to  control  market  entry  instead  of  the  CAB.  For  example,  since  historic 
traffic  controls  the  requirement  for  first  nonstop  service,  the  incumbent  carrier 
can  restrict  local  market  development  by  operating  at  very  high  lond  factors  (but 
under  75  percent)  and  can,  through  schedule  manipulation,  redirect  or  minimize 
beyond  passenger  flows.  Onestop  service  can  be  operated  until  passengers 
practically  beat  down  the  carrier's  doors  demanding  nonstop  service.  Thus 
the  carrier  can  operate  ju-^t  one  nonstop  service,  but  carefully  control  the  load 
factor  with  multistop  flights,  without  ever  facing  the  real  prospect  of  having 
this  market  meet  the  requirements  for  additional  nonstop  service. 

1  For  markets  over  2,000  miles  In  length,  high  capacity  wide-body  aircraft  are  used  for 
tnls  st.Tndard.  Insuring  no  new  long  range  markets  will  be  adequately  developed.  The 
BOR  study,  in  fact,  indicates  frst  nonstop  service  would  be  required  In  only  one  new  long 
range  market  by  1985.  (page  144) 


733 

First  or  Additional  Competitive  Authority 

Under  this  standard,  one,  the  proposed  operations  must  earn  a  full  12  percent 
return  on  investment  in  the  first  year;  two,  traffic  diversion  from  incumbent  car- 
riers cannot  exceed  35  percent ;  and  three,  the  incumbent  carriers'  return  on  in- 
vestment cannot,  because  of  the  new  authority,  be  reduced  either  below  6  percent 
by  1/2  or  more. 

The  first  comment  on  this  standard,  of  course,  is  that  it  is  simply  unreasonable 
to  exi>cct  such  a  high  return  on  investment  in  the  very  first  year  of  operation. 
At  the  beginning  of  the  lirst  year,  because  of  lack  of  market  identity,  the  new 
carrier  will  earn  less  than  a  12  percent  ROT.  As  the  year  progresses,  the  new 
carrier  must  progressively  improve  its  ROI  so  that  the  year  will  average  12 
percent.  This  means  a  greater  tha:i  12  percent  ROI  by  year's  end  (and  a  load 
factor  higher  than  55  percent).  If  for  some  unusual  reason,  the  new  carrier 
could  achieve  a  12  percent  ROI  in  the  first  year,  the  second  year  will  clearly 
result  in  excess  profits  and  public  disservice  in  the  form  of  high  load  factors — 
particularly  if  the  CAB  considers  annual  load  factors  up  to  75  percent  as  re- 
flecting adequate  public  service. 

Secondly,  few  markets,  if  any,  can  meet  this  requirement  using  reasonable, 
accepted  traffic  forecasting  methods  and,  thus,  the  route  moratorium  will  be 
automatically  perpetuated. 
The  55-Percent  Load  Factor  Standard 

The  BOR  study  professes  to  adopt  the  rate-making  benchmarks  established  in 
the  domestic  passenger  fare  investigation  (DPFI).  In  actuality,  what  the  BOR 
has  done  is  to  take  the  DPFI  industry  average  55-percent  load  factor  standard 
and  make  it  the  carrier  and  market  minimum  load  factor  standard.  The  55  percent 
passenger  load  factor  standard  is,  in  reality,  a  CAB  desired  average  for  trunk 
carrier  coach  service.  It  was  not  a  flat  standard,  but  varies  by  mileage  block,  with 
long-haul  and  short-haul  markets  having  lower  load  factor  standards  (approxi- 
mately 50  percent  at  transcontinental  distances). 

The  BOR  study  has  used  55  percent  as  a  minimum  load  factor  at  all  mileage 
blocks  and  has  expanded  it  to  include  first-class  service  and  local-service  car- 
riers— an  action  the  Board  specifically  refused  to  take  in  the  DPFI. 
The  12-Percent  Return  on  Investment  Standard 

A!?ain,  the  BOR  twists  the  meaning  of  the  ratemaking  standards  adopted  by  the 
CAB  in  the  DPFI.  The  12  percent  ROI  standard  is  an  industry  average,  based  on 
trunk  carrier  operations.  The  BOR  study  includes  local  service  carriers  and  makes 
this  standard  a  by-carrier,  by-market  minimum  and  not  an  industry  average. 

General  Comments 

The  objective  of  the  BOR  study  appears  to  develop  the  principle  that  competi- 
tion is  bad  and  has  been  the  cause  of  the  air  transportation  industry's  financial 
problems. 

"The  system  has  offered,  in  general,  an  overall  volume  of  service  that  is  exces- 
sive in  relation  to  demand  in  competitive  markets."  (page  8) 


"However,  the  load  factor  analysis  conducted  as  part  of  this  study  together 
with  the  results  of  other  studies,  supports  the  general  conclusion  that  competition 
does  limit  profitability."  (page  8) 

AND 

".  .  .  the  present  trunk  system  is  so  highly  competitive,  in  terms  of  service,  that 
there  is  some  question  whether  trunk  cariers  will  be  able  to  achieve  average  load 
factors  sufficient  to  enable  to  earn  a  12-percent  return  on  investment  on  a 
consistent  basis."  (page  8) 

AND 

"If  any  real  improvement  in  load  factors  is  to  be  achieved  by  a  lessening  in 
degree  of  competition,  it  is  necessary  to  establish  monopoly  status  for  the  markets 
in  question."  (page  89) 

No  one  will  argue  that  excessive  or  destructive  competition  is  good  for  this 
country's  air  transportation  system.  However,  there  is  no  support  in  the  study 


734 

for  the  fact  that  two  carrier  competition  has  these  characteristics.  In  fact,  the 
study  presents  the  main  reason  for  excessive  capacity  at  page  56 : 

"The  overall  level  of  service  provided  in  relation  to  demand  is,  however,  pri- 
marily a  function  of  rate  policy." 

Contrary  to  the  tone  of  the  recommendations  at  the  end,  the  BOR  study 
strongly  supports  the  position  that  the  CAB's  route  development  policy  of  the 
1965-69  period  created  enormous  benefits  for  the  industry  and  the  travelling 
public  through  lower  unit  costs,  lower  fares,  and  improved  air  service.  The 
authorization  of  competitive  service  was  given  much  of  the  credit. 

"Moreover,  growth  rates  in  competitive  markets  are  higher  since,  generally, 
they  tend  to  be  the  larger,  rapid  growth  markets  with  higher  traffic  levels  and 
lower  yields  than  monopoly  markets."  (page  105) 

Thus,  viewing  the  study  from  an  overall  standpoint,  it  displays  a  troublesome 
degree  of  inconsistency  between  its  basic  study  analyses  and  its  recommended 
standards. 

One  of  the  most  dangerous  features  of  all  is  that  the  BOR-recommended 
standards  would  operate  effectively  to  block  the  Board  members  from  exercising 
fundamental  responsibilities  placed  upon  them  by  the  Federal  Aviation  Act  of 
1958.  Under  the  recommended  standards,  the  staff — not  the  Board — would  decide 
what  applications  would  (or  would  not)  reach  the  Board  for  decision.  Such 
prejudgment  by  the  CAB's  staff  hardly  conforms  to  the  intent  of  Congress  that 
the  Board  members  themselves  should  bear  the  decisional  responsibility  with 
respect  to  all  route  applications. 

Further,  the  airlines  should  fear  the  domination  of  their  affairs  now  proposed 
by  the  BOR.  While  today,  these  standards  may  favor  the  financial  interests  of  the 
airlines,  tomorrow  the  standards  may  not — but  the  carriers  will  be  powerless  to 
change  the  process. 

One  shudders  to  think  of  the  type  of  air  transportation  system  this  country 
would  have  if  these  standards  had  been  in  effect  the  past  25  years. 

Recommended  Legislation 

Historically,  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board  has  been  the  finest  and  most  expertly 
run  of  this  government's  regulatory  agencies.  The  development  of  air  transporta- 
tion in  this  country,  as  compared  with  other  countries,  is  a  testament  to  the 
soundness  of  the  law  which  created  the  CAB.  Radical  changes  will  be  destructive 
and  costly  to  the  travelling  public  in  terms  of  poorer  service  and  higher  fares 
which  would  inevitably  be  created  by  the  resulting  turmoil.  However,  in  recent 
years  the  CAB  has  become  so  concerned  with  the  financial  well-being  of  the 
industry,  that  genuine  public  interest  considerations  are  hard  to  discern  in  the 
CAB's  majority  opinions.  There  is  also  rising  concern  that  the  CAB  staff  is 
assuming  responsibilities  granted  to  the  CAB  which  by  law  can  only  be  exercised 
by  the  Board  members.  While  the  basic  law  remains  sound.  Congress  should  pro- 
vide greater  direction  for  the  CAB  through  more  specific  policy  guidelines.  The 
following  suggestions  are  respectfully  submitted  : 

1.  Public  interest  considerations  must  be  faced  and  dealt  with  effectively  as 
a  major  factor  in  the  decisional  process.  This  country's  commerce  depends  upon 
reliable,  reasonably  prictd,  and  convenient  air  service.  While  the  carriers'  finan- 
cial well-being  is  important,  the  provision  of  adequate  air  service  to  the  public 
remains  the  underlying  goal. 

2.  Competition  helped  build  the  finest  air  transportation  system  in  the  world. 
To  maintain  and  expand  this  quality  of  air  service,  the  CAB  shall  authorize 
competitive  service  whenever  a  market  grows  to  the  point  where  competitive 
service  is  economically  feasible. 

3.  In  recognition  of  the  fact  that  numerous  unjustified  and  outmoded  CAB- 
imposed  restrictions  currently  encumber  carriers'  ability  to  operate  nonstop 
service  and  that,  in  many  cases,  these  restrictions  were  imposed  without  an 
affirmative  showing  of  need,  provisions  shall  be  made  for  immediate  review  of 
all  restrictions.  None  should  be  renewed  unless  an  affirmative  public  convenience 
and  necessity  showing  is  made.  Further,  any  restriction  so-renewed  and  newly 
imposed  restrictions  shall  be  for  a  set  period  of  time  after  which  an  additional 
showing  of  need  shall  be  required  for  subsequent  renewal. 

4.  Where  an  air  carrier  possesses  unused  authority  and  refuses  to  use  such 
authority,  after  a  reasonable  period  of  time,  it  shall  be  transferred  to  any  willing 
carrier  who  can  demonstrate  that  the  proposed  service  will  be  economical. 


735 

5.  In  recongition  of  the  fact  that  air  transportation  is  the  basic  mass  trans- 
portation mode  for  intercity  passenger  travel,  the  Board  shall  give  precedence  to 
the  public  interest  in  adequate  air  transportation  whenever  making  any  decision 
or  taking  any  action  that  involves  fuel  policy,  including  disposition  of  route 
applications. 

Attachments. 


736 


Attachment  l 


DULLES  INTERNATIONAL  AIRPOHT'S  PRIMAHT  AND  SECONDARY 
SERVICE  AREAS  ^^'ITHIN  ^STROPOLITAN  BALTIH0REA.'/'.SHIKGT0N 


I  //-to. 

0 


59?5  of 
Metropolitan 
Baltimore/ 
Washin^on 
Population 


Notet 
>•^,Y■^  Secondary  service 

t-^'^^f;^  *^^  ^s  shaded. 


737 


BALTIKORE-WASHINGTCN  INTEiWATIONAL  AIHPORT'S  PHIKAEY  AHB  SECONDARY 
SKRVICS  AfiS.'^S  VflTrilN  HBTROPOLITAN  B.'aTIMORE/HASHINGTON 


of 

Metropolitan 
Baltimore/ 
Washington 
Population 


Note  I  Secondary  service  area  is  shaded 


738 


WASHINGTON  NATIONAL  AIRPOST'S  Paii^ASY  AM)  SECONDARY 
SERVICE  AflEAS  WITHIN  :-[grROPOLIT,\N  BALTIM0R3/v;ASHTNr.Tnw 


Note  I     Secondaiy  service  area  Is  shaded. 


739 


Attachment  2 

estimated  1975  baltimore/kasiiington 
passengers  using  baltimore- iwxskington  international 
airport  under  adequate  nonstop  service  conditions 

Top  50  Markets 


Bet'v'een  Baltimore/ 
Washington  and: 


1975  Daily  Passengers 
Through  BUT  Airport 


1 

NewYork/Newark 

2 

Boston 

3 

Chicago 

4 

Miami/Ft.  Lauderdale 

5 

Los  Angeles 

6 

Atlanta 

7 

San  Fiancisco 

8 

Detroit 

9 

Pittsburgh 

10 

Philadelphia 

11 

Da  11  as/ Ft.  Korth 

12 

Cleveland 

13 

Hartford 

14 

Norfolk 

15 

St.  Louis 

16 

Denver 

17 

Minneapolis/St.  Paul 

18 

Providence 

19 

Raleigli/Durham 

20 

Butfalo 

21 

Houston 

22 

Cincinnati 

23 

Coluir.bus,  OH. 

24 

New  Orleans 

25 

Minneapolis 

26 

Tampa 

27 

Kansas  City 

28 

Orlando 

29 

Richjiiond 

30 

Albany 

31 

Dayton 

32 

Rocliester 

33 

Louisville 

34 

Newport  News 

35 

MeiT.phis 

36 

Seattle 

37 

Roanoke 

38 

San  Diego 

39 

Syracuse 

40 

Charlotte 

41 

Greensboro 

42 

Jacksonville 

43 

Kno.w  i  1 1  e 

44 

Nashville 

45 

Charleston, S.C. 

46 

Milwaukee 

47 

Charleston,  K.VA. 

48 

Huntsville 

49 

Phoenix 

50 

Coluiiibia 

Local  Market  Plus 

Local  Market 

Beyond  Market  Flown 

1,111 

1,390 

765 

997 

1,109 

1,241 

486 

503 

515 

561 

1,028 

1,197 

384 

410 

245 

249 

453 

540 

137 

757 

313 

461 

306 

326 

260 

545 

203 

372 

151 

228 

365 

409 

134 

153 

179 

308 

136 

263 

147 

241 

222 

372 

189 

452  . 

125 

170 

250 

440 

185 

383 

113 

189 

174 

478 

141 

256 

116 

201 

249 

431 

81 

111 

67 

97 

73 

90 

110 

229 

64 

146 

108 

113 

173 

264 

120 

213 

71 

128 

86 

110 

81 

94 

68 

205 

73 

119 

61 

117 

66 

115 

49 

78 

87 

140 

74 

74 

94 

187 

79 

90 

740 


Attachment  3 


usnD  Avj  L)i;rs:;D  Nc:ovnp  AirnartiTY 


Bctwoon 
[i-lti:7.oro/'.'.'aihin^toa 


1 

N'o-.v  York 

7 

ioiitoa 
Cr.ica  .0 

4 
5 

Lo^  Aajcles 

0 

Atlanta 

7 

San  Francisco 
Detroit 

9 
10 
11 
12 

Pittsburiih 
;T.iiaJolphia 
Dallas 
Clo'.'cl.-.nd 

13 
14 
IS 
16 

Hartio.-ci 
Norfolk 
St.    Louis 
Denver 

17 
IS 
10 
20 

;:in:;e:.polis 
froviuencc 

:;uti:aio 

21 
22 

Kousvon 
Cincinnati 

23 

Co:u..jus,    0. 

24 

Kew  Orleans 

2o 
27 
23 
29 
30 
31 
32 

InJii.iiapolis 

Kan'sas   City 
Orlando 
Rich,-..ond 
Albany,   NY 
Dayton 
Rochester,    NY 

33 

Louisvillc 

34 

Kc'./port   News 

35 

Kc-.7i;jhis 

36 

Seattle 

37 

Soanokc 

33 

San   DiCi:o 

59 

iyracube 

^.0 

Charlotte 

41 

Greeniboro 

42 

J..cksoaviilc 

-■.3 

!;r.Gxville 

44 

.\a',;,villo 

45 

Cliarieston.S.C. 

45 

Milwaukee 

47 

Charlcston.V.'.Va. 

43 

Iluntbvillc 

49 
50 

I'AOcnix 
Colu;v,bia,   S.C. 

,>;vc 

•a-c    -      - 

EOS 

lios  Eos'r.os* 

CHI 

Hi  A 

L\X 

ATL 

S~0 

DTi- 

PIT 

PI"    - 

?'.:L 

PKL-PHL  PilL'  ! 

DAL 

CLE 

ZZiL 

BD.*  BDL   EDL* 

0?'- 

STL 

DIN 

KSP 

PVD 

PVI,*PVD   PVD' 

!;du 

I 

;iiji" 

EL;:--'^yF  blv*  ' 

ia;; 

c\c 

CVG      -        - 

C''~i 

.'■..SY 

I.\D      - 

VPA 

MCI 

:--;co 

RIC 

AL? 

ALU*ALa*AL:i-| 

DAY 

1 

ROC 

-      ROC   ROC* 1 

SOI- 

1 

VWV 

1 

SEA 

1 
i 

ROA 

1 
1 

SAN 

SYR 

-      SYR  SYR* 1 

CLT 

1 

GSO 

1 

JAX 

TYS 

3XA 

1 

CHS 

M:ct 

CRW 

CRW      -        - 

HSV 

?:ix 

CAC 

PHL'PHL'PHL* 
DAL  -   DAL 


PVD  PVD  PVD 


TYS  TYS  TYS 
B.'sA*  ENA  C.\'A" 


,VY(.'  NYC  ::yc 

BOS  BOS  ECS* 


MIA*KIA*MIA* 
ATL  ATL  ATL 


PHL  PHL'  PHL* 
BDL*  BDL*  BDL* 


KSY   -  MSY 
TPA*TPA*TPA' 


CLl*  CLT*  CLT* 
JAX*JA.\'  JAX* 


*Ko  nonstop  round-trip   service    (February   1,1975)    by  the   subject    carrici 

B'.'/I  =  Calf.:norc-li'as:.  :nt;ton  Inrcrnational  Airport 

DCA  ■=  National  Air;;ort 

IAD  •=   Dulles  International  Airport 


741 


US::D  AND   UNUSED   S'ONSTOl'   ALrn:ORITY    IN 

EAi.Ti'-::..-;:  /i.-ashixmcn 's  top  so  markf.t.s 


Between 

^a:ik 

Bjltir.ore/Wr>s) 

anJ: 

injton 

tUI    i^3\  'iAJ 

v.-..'   York 

NYC 

NYC   N-.C   N.J* 

Boston 

BOS 

zos^os  i,i;s 

Chicaso 

."•i.'A 

1 

MIA  KIA  >;IA*    1 

Los  Anjoics 
Atlanta 

LAX 

ATL  AVL  .\TL*    ! 

S 

9 
10 

San  Francisco 

?itt-;.v.:r,:h 
i'/.il.iJ.-iphia 

sr-0 

1 

i 

P::L   PHL*P>!L*    ! 

11 
12 
1,^ 

Dr.  11  as 

Clcvclar.d 

Kartford 

DAL 
CLb 
r.D!. 

DDL   BDL'BDL'    I 

14 
IS 

Norfolk 
St.    l.ouis 

0\lr 
STL 

STL*  STL   STL' 

16 

Denver 

l;:;n' 

17 
18 

Minno.-polis 
ProviJwnco 
Ralci   h 

MS? 

.■'VD 
RD'J 

PVD*  PVD*  pvi;-   1 
KDU   RDLJ   RDU*    I 

20 

25 
24 

Suffalo 
ilea  3 -.on 
Cincir.nati 
Colur.;n;^,   0. 
Mew  0;-lca.-.s 

BIjF 
I.\H 
CVG 

.-..SY 

1 

lAH*  -    ia;-! 
MSI*  -    ;-:sY*  ; 

2S 

Or:„r-Jo 

29 

Richr.-.ond 

30 

Albany,    NT 

31 

Dayton 

52 

Rochester, 

NT 

33 

Louisvillc- 

34 

NtuCL-r.   Ne 

IS 

35 

Me::.-x::s 

36 

Scaltlo 

57 

Roar.ol.c 

33 

San  DiPso 

59 

Syracu.so 

40 

&arlotto 

4! 

Grcc-s-nc-o 

42 

J.C.oOi.Vll 

e 

43 

Knoxville 

44 

Nashville 

45 

Charier,  cc.-i 

S.C. 

46 

MiluMukee 

47 

Charieivon 

W.Va 

4S 

i;jjiisville 

49 

K.ocnix 

SO 

Colu:,:bia, 

;.c. 

:ico 

MCG  MCG 

y.cci 

RIC 

RIC'RIC 

RIC"   , 

AL3 

DAY 

1 

ROC 

! 

SDP'SDF 

SDP* 

KcK 

SEA 

ROA 

S.VJ 

SYR 

SYR*  SYR 

SYR" 

c;-T 

CLT'CLT 

CLT 

GSO 

GSO*  GSO 

GSO-    ' 

J  AX 

JAX'JAX 

JAX' 

VYS 

EN' A 

CIS 

c:  IS*  CHS" 

CHS* 

c\:: 

HSV 

PriX 

CAE 

CAE   CAE 

CAE 

NYC  NYC  NTC 
SOS*  EOS'  EOS* 


PKE* 

PHL 

PHL* 

ORF* 

ORF 

ORF- 

PVD* 

PVl?  PVD* 

1 

TPA- 

TEA 

1 
TPA' 

'■■'"' 

,v.CO 

.vco' 

PHF* 

PrlF 

PHF* 

JAX* 

JAX 

JAX* 

CHS' 

CHS 

CHS* 

'NYC*  ! 


DTT  D'l T 
PIT  PIT" 


MKE  MKE  MKt 


nonstop  round-trip   service    (Fcbruaryl ,1975)   by  subject  carri 
International   Airport 


Baltiraore-Wash: 

National  Airport 

Dulles  International  Airport 


742 


USrO  A.-.T)   UN'DSnO   SO.'vVrC?   AUTIIOraTY 


Daltir.-.orc/WasMr 
.-.r.d: 

\cv  Yor). 

Los   Ar.i^cles 

Atlanta 

Sar.  rr.:ncisco 

Detroit 

?ittsb^,r-h 

Phil;-.t!ul?hia 

D;:ll..s 

Clcvjland 

i:-.rtvord 

Korx'olk 

St.    Louis 


Ho„:,tc.i 
CJ.;c::;n:.li 

Coici.,1  '.^,    0. 
Now  Orlc;;iis 


c.;i 


S'l'L 


IAD 
NYC 


3Wi    DCA    lAO 


25 

Indi.-:r,apolis 

INI) 

26 

Ta;.-.K. 

TIW 

27 

Ka.i.-.as   City 

.••:ci 

2o 

Cr!:.r,ao 

y.co 

29 

Rici,;..or.d 

RiC 

30 

Albar,/,    NY 

AL.i 

M 

Dayton 

r^\Y 

32 

tochcstcr,   NY 

iiOC 

33 

LouiiviUe 

sj;- 

34 

Newport  News 
Muiriphis 

PIV.- 

:-:::y, 

36 

Seattle 

SLA 

37 

Roanoke 

ROA 

3S 

San   Dic-o 

SAN 

39 

Syracuse 

sv:i 

40 

Charlotte 

CLT 

41 

Greensboro 

GCO 

42 

Jacksonville 

JAX 

43 

Kjioxvillc 

TYS 

44 

Nashville 

uNA 

45 

Charlesto...   S.C. 

Ci:s 

46 

Milw..u>.oe 

^:^1I 

47 

Ciiaricbton,    W.Va. 

C.J 'A' 

4S 

lluncsviUe 

tiSV 

49 

Hhoonix 

P1L\ 

50 

Colu,nbia,S.C. 

CA!; 

ROA  ROA   ROA 


NTC* 
ECS* 

NYC* 
EOS* 

NYC 
LOS* 

Oil 

an 

Ciil* 

V\\ 

- 

LAX 

SFO 

- 

sro 

HhL* 

PHL* 

PHL 

1 

BDL* 

EOL* 

».- 

STL 

•STL 

STL*    ' 

PEN^ 

DEN 

CVG* 

CVCfCVG*    i 

Cv.li' 

C.--iH 

c.--^\'  1 

IND" 

(ND 

!ND* 

MCI* 

- 

MCI* 

DAY- 

DAY 

DAY* 

PHX*    - 

PHX 

NYC'  '.YC 

!-;os'  aos 

CHI    CHI 

EO.T     1 
CHI 

LAX*    - 
ATL*  ATL 

sro    - 

urr  DTT 

PIT*PiT 

r'iiL'riiC 

UX 
ATL*    1 

VI- 

cl::  CLP, 

LL-L*  EuL" 
Clii-*  0\<7- 

0R|.-* 

KSi*  MSP 

D.N 
MSP*    1 

RDlf  r:.i! 

B'Jf-'  EJF 

MSY-     - 

CM 

y.s-f 

MCI       - 

MCI 

R1C"RIC   RIC 

OAY':-|AY    DAY 


PHP 

PriF 

SL/\ 

SLA* 

S,VS' 

- 

SAN. 

CLl' 
GSO' 

CLr  CLl' 
GSJ  csd 

TYS* 

VYS 

TYS* 

;;Kh* 

vkl' 

::i.L* 

HSV' 

IISV 

HSV* 

*No  nonstop  round-trip  service  (February  1,  1975)  by  subject  carrier. 


EWI  =  taltl:..o-e-Wa^hin^ton  Iiitcrnatic 

DCA  =  Nati'inal  Airport 

IAD  =  Dullt,.  International  Airport 

Source:   Official  Airline  Guide 


743 
[The  following  was  also  submitted  for  the  record.] 

Prepared  Statement  of  Rafael  Hernandez-Colon,  Governor  of  the 
Commonwealth  of  Puerto  Rico 

I  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  speak  for  the  people  of  Puerto  Rico  in  these 
hearings. 

You  have  described  your  purpose  as  seeking  an  answer  to  two  questions: 
whether  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board's  practices  and  procedures  result  in  reason- 
ably priced  air  transportation  for  the  consumer  and  reasonable  incentives  for 
the  airlines  to  provide  service ;  and  whether  the  public,  and  the  airlines,  are  given 
a  fair  opportunity  to  present  their  views  to  the  CAB  before  important  decisions 
are  made  affecting  their  interests. 

Both  questions  are  important  to  all  Americans  who  use  and  provide  air  service. 
Both  are  crucial  to  Puerto  Rico— particularly  today,  when  our  links  with  the 
mainland  may  be  significantly  reduced  by  Pan  Am's  recent  proposal  to  curtail 
services  in  the  Boston,  New  York,  Philadelphia  and  Baltimore  markets  on 
April  9th.  While  the  Commonwealth  has  no  wish  to  force  Pan  Am  to  serve  Puerto 
Rico,  Pan  Am's  action  should  not  be  at  the  expense  of  the  airline  competition 
and  adequate  service  that  is  so  essential  to  our  island. 

Air  transportation  is  not  a  luxury  for  the  people  of  Puerto  Rico.  It  is  a  neces- 
sity. Commerce  with  the  mainland — for  purposes  of  business,  employment,  tourist 
travel,  and  the  maintenance  of  family  ties — depends  on  reliable,  plentiful,  and  low 
cost  air  transportation.  That  in  turn  depends  in  large  part  on  the  existence  of 
adequate  competition.  If  the  CAB's  policies  inhibit  competition  on  the  Puerto 
Rican  routes,  the  island  is  hurt.  If  those  policies  foster  competition,  Puerto  Rico 
benefits.  It  is  about  that  simple. 

Consider  these  facts.  Nearly  40  percent  of  the  annual  traflBc  moving  from  major 
gateways  on  the  mainland  to  Puerto  Rico  involves  persons  of  Puerto  Rican  des- 
cent or  background.  The  median  income  of  Puerto  Rican  families  living  here  on 
the  mainland  is  about  60  percent  of  the  national  median  family  income.  On  the 
island,  median  family  income  is  far  below  that  of  the  poorest  state.  So  if  these 
families  are  to  be  able  to  travel  to  and  from  Puerto  Rico  and  the  mainland,  air 
fares  must  be  kept  reasonably  low. 

Tourism  continues  to  be  vilai  to  the  Puerto  Rico  economy.  The  tourist  industry 
generates  nearly  5  percent  of  our  income,  and  provides  employment  for  10  percent 
of  our  labor  force.  We  must  have  plentiful  low-cost  service  if  that  income  and 
employment  is  to  continue  and  grow.  Maintaining  sufii^ient  air  service  is  espe- 
cially crucial  during  the  current  recession.  Our  unemployment  rate  in  Puerto  Rico 
Is  very  high — 17  percent — reflecting  in  part  the  recession  in  the  mainland  United 
States  and  its  impact  on  our  important  tourism  industry.  If  Puerto  Rico  is  to 
hold  its  own  during  this  economic  crisis,  visitors  from  the  mainland  must  not  be 
discouraged  by  inadequate  air  service.  That  requires  competition. 

The  history  of  air  transportation  in  the  mainland-Puerto  Rico  markets  pro- 
vides a  vivid  demonstration  of  the  importance  of  competition  in  developing  a 
system  that  meets  the  public's  needs.  Before  1957,  when  Trans-Caribbean  Air- 
ways (American  Airlines'  predecessor)  was  authorized  to  provide  scheduled 
service  between  New  York  and  San  Juan,  the  two  entrenched  carriers  in  the 
market,  Pan  American  and  Eastern,  provided  modest  service  and  emphasized 
first-class  travel.  This  was  so  even  though  Pan  American  had  served  San  Juan 
as  far  back  as  1929,  and  Eastern  had  served  New  York-San  Juan  since  1951. 
When  the  CAB-certificated  Trans-Caribbean,  neither  Pan  American  nor  Eastern 
had  been  meeting  peak  period  needs  in  the  New  York-San  Juan  market,  and 
neither  had  made  any  significant  effort  to  develop  low-cost  transportation 
alternatives. 

The  infusion  of  competition  by  a  small  but  innovative  airline,  Trans-Caribbean, 
improved  mainland-Puerto  Rico  air  transportation  tremendously.  In  order  to 
meet  TCA's  aggressive  competition.  Pan  American  and  Eastern  had  to  make 
serious  efforts  to  offer  and  promote  reliable  low-fare  services  for  the  first  time. 
The  traveling  public  responded.  The  number  of  passengers  from  the  ma'nland 
to  Puerto  Rico  increased  even  more  dramatically  than  it  had  in  the  past  and 
the  thrift-class  fare  became  the  most  widely  used  fare  by  far.  Thrift  clas^j  pas- 
sengers went  from  32  percent  of  the  total  market  in  1958  to  94  percent  during 
the  year  ended  September  30.  1964.  Although  the  thrift  fare  level  has,  of  course, 
increased  since  1958,  it  is  still  one  of  the  lowest  air  fares  for  the  distance  in  the 
United  States.  Nevertheless,  the  airlines  earned  reasonable  profits  during  the 


744 

intervening  years,  and  tiie  New  Yorlt-San  Juan  market  grew  into  the  largest 
long  distance  air  travel  marlvet  under  CAB  regulation.  The  Civil  Aeronautics 
Board  reaffirmed  the  benefits  of  this  three-carrier  competition  in  the  New  York- 
San  Juan  market  in  December,  1970,  when  it  approved  the  American-Trans- 
Caribbean  merger. 

The  relatively  low  fares  have  not  been  and  should  not  be  an  impediment  to 
profitable  operations  by  three  carriers.  The  New  York-San  Juan  market  is 
extremely  dense,  involving  more  passengers  than  other  markets  where  the  CAB 
has  certificated  three  or  more  carriers.  About  1.52  million  passengers  moved 
between  New  York  and  San  Juan  in  fiscal  1974,  compared  to  1.12  million  for 
New  York-Los  Angeles  (3  carriers),  818,000  for  New  York-San  Francisco  (3 
carriers)  and  685,000  for  Chicago-Los  Angeles  (4  carriers). 

The  market's  size,  distance  (1,600  miles)  and  established  travel  patterns 
provide  opportunities  for  the  carriers  to  take  maximum  advantage  of  the  effi- 
ciencies of  modern  aircraft  types.  The  carriers  are  able  to  use  highly  efficient 
wide-bodied  aircraft  extensively.  I  am  told  that  for  markets  of  this  distance, 
the  costs  of  operating  a  Boeing  747  are  at  least  15  to  33  percent  lower  than  those 
of  narrow-bodied  aircraft.  Moreover,  New  York-San  Juan  passengers  have  dem- 
onstrated time  and  again  a  willingness  to  accept  high  load  factors  and  less  than 
elaborate  amenities  as  a  trade-off  for  relatively  low  fares.  Though  planes  often 
fly  half-empty  in  domestic  markets.  New  York-San  Juan  flights  have  load  factors 
in  the  65-70  range,  and  many  flights  are  sold  out  during  peak  periods  (see 
appendix  A). 

Airlines  other  than  Pan  Am  have  earned  reasonable  profits  on  Puerto  Rican 
services  at  the  relatively  low  fares  in  effect  (see  appendixes  B  and  C).  While 
Pan  Am  reports  huge  losses  for  Puerto  Rico  services,  its  competitors  are  oper- 
ating in  the  black.  In  the  year  ended  June  30,  1974,  American  earned  a  $2.8 
million  profit,  and  Eastern  broke  even.  Pan  Am  showed  a  $10.8  million  loss  (see 
appendix  D).  In  the  New  York-San  Juan  market,  American  has  told  the  CAB 
that  it  will  earn  a  10  percent  return  on  investment  under  current  fares.  The 
Commonwealth  has  provided  studies  showing  that  American  will  earn  in  excess 
of  the  CAB'S  12-percent  standard  rate  of  return  in  this  market  even  without 
the  revenues  from  a  recent  8-percent  fare  increase. 

These  comparisons,  moreover,  understate  the  profit  potential  of  Puerto  Rico 
markets  under  current  fare  levels  because  American  and  Eastern  are  far  from 
the  most  efficient  airlines  in  the  U.S.  Were  truly  low-cost  carriers  like  Delta, 
National,  or  Northwest  operating  in  these  markets,  they  would  earn  profits 
well  above  the  CAB's  standard  rate  of  return  at  the  curernt  fare  levels.  Clearly, 
the  difficulty  does  not  lie  in  any  of  the  unique  characteristics  of  the  Puerto 
Rican  air  transportation  market  or  the  fare  level.  The  problem  seems  to  rest  in 
Pan  Am's  own  operation. 

A  few  comparisons  of  Pan  Am's  operating  costs  with  those  of  its  competitors 
in  the  very  same  markets  provides  a  clear  demonstration  of  the  failure  of  Pan 
Am's  management  to  control  its  operating  costs.  For  approximately  the  same 
level  of  capacity  production,  Pan  Am's  total  operating  costs  were  41  percent 
higher  than  American's  for  the  year  ended  June  30,  1974.  Excluding  fuel,  an 
element  that  was  less  controllable  by  airline  managers  during  the  period,  Pan 
Am's  operating  costs  per  available  ton  mile  were  144  percent  of  American's.  The 
comparison  is  even  more  striking  when  one  focuses  on  nonflight  related  ex- 
penses which,  I  am  told,  are  highly  influenced  by  individual  management  tech- 
niques. Pan  Am's  advertising  and  publicity  costs  were  372  percent  of  American's. 
What  makes  this  so  remarkable  is  that  the  total  number  of  passengers  Pan  Am 
carried  was  only  122  percent  of  American's.  While  American  was  spending  89 
cents  per  passenger  on  advertising  and  publicity.  Pan  Am  spent  $2.70.  Pan 
Am's  passenger  services  expenses  per  revenue  passenger  mile  were  166  percent 
of  American's. 

This  inefficiency  has  a  dramatic  impact  at  the  "bottom  line"  (see  appendix 
F).  In  order  for  Pan  Am  to  achieve  the  CAB's  standard  12  percent  rate  of  re- 
turn on  its  Puerto  Rico  services,  it  won'd  require  a  45  percent  increase  over 
present  fares.  American,  on  the  other  hand,  can  achieve  the  standard  rate  of 
return  at  fares  somewhat  lower  than  those  presently  being  charged.  If  the 
CAB  were  to  grant  an  increase  of  the  magnitude  needed  by  Pan  Am  just  to 
break  even  in  New  York-San  Juan,  American's  rate  of  return  on  this  route 
would  be  in  excess  of  25  percent. 

Our  purpose  is  not  simply  to  attack  Pan  Am.  Nor  does  the  Commonwealth 
seek  to  force  Pan  Am  out  of,  or  compel  it  to  stay  in,  Puerto  Rican  markets. 


745 

However,  these  markets  require  competitive  services — at  least  3  carriers  in  New 
Yorlv-Sau  Juan,  and  2  carriers  in  Boston  and  I'liiladelpliia.  11"  Pan  Am  is  to  be 
relieved  of  its  service  obligations  because  of  its  inability  to  operate  profitably 
in  the  market,  it  should  not  be  permitted  to  stand  in  the  way  of  replacement 
service. 

Unfortunately,  Pan  Am  has  structured  its  suspension  proposal  in  a  way  that 
is  calculated  to  foreclose  any  substitutions  of  a  competitive  carrier.  It  has  not 
asked  to  have  San  Juan  deleted  from  its  certificate.  Rather,  it  has  requested  a 
"permissive"  service  suspension  under  section  401(j)  of  the  Federal  Aviation 
Act  for  a  period  of  20  months.  No  new  carrier  without  present  East  coast- 
Puerto  Rico  routes  would  apply  for  authority  to  substitute  for  Pan  Am  for  a 
period  of  20  months  or  possibly  less — the  period  being  totally  dependent  on  Pan 
Am"s  whims.  Representatives  of  20  months.  No  rational  carrier  would  apply 
for  authority  to  substitute  for  Pan  Am  for  a  period  of  20  months  or  possibly 
less— the  period  being  totally  dependent  on  Pan  Am's  whims.  Representatives 
of  the  Commonwealth  have  been  in  touch  with  a  number  of  other  airlines.  While 
several  have  expressed  interest  in  replacing  Pan  Am,  none  would  apply  to  the 
Board  for  replacement  authority,  considering  the  start-up  expense  involved,  if 
the  suspension  period  were  20  months  or  less.  In  order  for  a  new  carrier  to  enter 
the  market,  it  must  have  assurance  that  it  will  be  able  to  operate  in  the  market 
indefinitely  or  for  at  least  3-5  years. 

The  Commonwealth  of  Puerto  Rico  is  pursuing  its  remedies  before  the  CAB. 
Puerto  Rico  is  petitioning  the  CAB  to  suspend  Pan  Am's  routes  for  three  to 
five  years,  or  permanently  to  delete  Pan  Am  from  these  Puerto  Rico  routes,  so 
that  strong  new  carriers  will  be  in  a  po.sition  to  replace  Pan  Am  in  the  markets. 
We  are  requesting  that  new  applicants  be  allowed  to  replace  Pan  Am  on  April 
9th  without  any  gap  in  the  service  competition  that  is  so  important  to  Puerto 
Rico. 

We  are  also  asking  the  Board  to  require  Pan  Am  to  meet  its  obligations  to 
its  employees  in  Puerto  Rico.  Our  information  is  that  as  many  as  300  workers 
out  of  the  400  now  employed  by  Pan  Am  in  Puerto  Rico  may  be  laid  off  as  a 
result  of  this  suspension.  These  men  and  women  all  have  more  than  six  or  seven 
years'  service,  in  some  cases  much  more.  We  think  Pan  Am  should  give  them 
preference  when  it  hires  new  workers  on  the  Eastern  seaboard,  and  that  they 
should  be  entitled  to  severance  pay.  The  savings  that  Pan  Am  will  derive  from 
ending  service  should  be  shared  with  its  employees. 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  would  respoctfully  suggest  that  Congress  consider  amending 
the  Federal  Aviation  Act  in  such  a  way  as  to  encourage  competition  when-  a 
carrier  suspends  operations  on  a  route  for  economic  reasons.  Today,  under  sec- 
tion 401(j)  of  the  Act,  the  Board  is  authorized  to  permit  such  temporary  sus- 
pensions of  service  without  public  hearing  "as  may  be  in  the  public  interest" — a 
very  broad  standard  indeed.  Should  a  carrier  propose  to  suspend  for  a  brief  period, 
as  Pan  Am  proposes  here,  the  Board  should  consider  whether  the  terms  and 
duration  of  the  suspension  are  such  as  to  discourage  applications  for  replacement 
service. 

There  is,  to  be  sure,  in  the  Act's  declaration  of  policy  (.section  102d)  a  require- 
ment that  the  Board  consider  as  being  in  the  public  interest  "competition  to  the 
extent  necessary  to  assure  the  sound  development  of  an  air-transportation  .sys- 
tem properly  adapted  to  the  needs  of  the  foreign  and  domestic  commerce  of  the 
United  Statues."  But  we  are  concerned  that  this  broad  injunction  may  not  be 
applied  to  a  determination  as  to  whether  a  suspension  of  service  will  serve  com- 
petition or  not.  I  am  not  suggesting  that  the  Board  should  compel  a  carrier  to 
operate  at  a  heavy  loss,  ^^imply  to  provide  competitive  .service.  I  am  suggesting 
that  the  Board  condition  its  approval  of  a  su.spension  in  such  a  way  as  to  attract 
viable  competition  into  the  suspended  market.  Otherwise  the  effect  of  the  suspen- 
sion may  be  to  discourage  competition,  and  ultimately  to  raise  fares. 

Mr.  Chairman,  I  recognize  that  one  way  of  curing  the  lack  of  competition  is  to 
eliminate  all  entrance  requirements — to  permit  any  and  all  carriers  who  wish  to 
serve  a  market  to  do  so.  I  shall  not  comment  on  that,  except  to  say  that  presently 
we  live  and  operate  under  rules  that  do  regulate  entry  into  markets  ;  that  carriers 
will  not  attempt  to  serve  areas  which  they  believe  are  already  fully  served  by 
other  carriers ;  and  that  a  new  carrier  would  not  seek  to  serve  any  market  if  it 
felt  that  Pan  Am  might  return  to  it  at  any  moment.  So  in  this  case,  and  under 
present  regulatory  law.  the  cause  of  competition  is  best  advanced  by  requiring  a 
suspending  carrier  to  make  way  for  another. 


51-146   O  -  76  -  pt.  1 


746 

I  appreciate  the  opportunity  to  present  these  views,  Mr.  Chairman.  And  I  would 
hope  that  your  concern  for  increased  competition  and  low  fares  will  be  heard 
loudly  and  clearly  by  the  Civil  Aeronautics  Board — both  with  regard  to  this  pro- 
posed suspension,  and  in  future  proceedings  before  the  Board. 


747 


Appendix  A 


H 

3 

H 

H 

UJ 

o 

0^ 

< 

2 

P^ 

^ 

^ 

1 

>-) 

>< 

§ 

g 

ca 

B 

W 

1 

g 

>H 

^ 

s 

w 

^ 

;zi 

59 

K 

»-H  in 


-5 

hJ 

4 

<; 

< 

fH 

o 

<: 

< 

o 

H 

H 

Ph 

H 

<: 

1 

u 

a 

C 

m 

2 

-§ 

^ 

.a 

si 

w 

cn 

.3 

QJ 

to 

1 

< 

1 

g 

CS 

a 

os" 

,Q 

e 

t- 

u< 

o 

o 

UJ 

o 

s 

^ 

CQ 

a 

3 

0) 

13 

< 

<3 

o 

0) 

u 

< 

li 

S 

IH 

(Ml        eol        rfl 


748 


APPEIJD] 


INCREASES  IN  LOWEST  REGULAR  NEW  YORK -SAN  JU/ N  FARES 
AND 
-     PROPOSED  1Q75_NEW  YORK-SAN  JUAN  FARES 


MIDWEEK 
Seasoii 

Off-Peak    Peak 

March  1966  45.00  45.00 

March  1968 

March  1969 

January  1970 

April  1972 

May  1974 

November  1974 


Proposed  1975 

AA  81.00  107.00  86.00  113.00 

EA  92.00  121.00  97.00  127.00 

PA  83.00  88.00  88.00  93.00 

Actual  Increases 

1966-75  (%)  62  62  78  78 


7.5  41.3 

21.3         ^58.8 
10.0  16.2 


45.00 

45.00 

51.00 

51.00 

57.00 

57.  00 

62.00 

62.00 

68.00 

68.00 

73.00 

73.00 

Proposed  Additional 
Increase  1975  (%) 
by: 

AA 

11.0 

46.6 

EA 

26.0 

65.8 

PA 

13.7 

20.5 

WEEKEND 

Season 

Off-Peak 

Peak 

45.00"      ... 

45.00 

49..  00 

49. .00 

55.00 

55.00 

61.00 

61.00 

67.00 

67.00 

74.00 

74.00 

80.00 

80.00 

749 


APPENDIX  C 


Comparison  of  New  York-San  Juan  Fares 

With  Other  Vacation  Markets 

February  1975 


Round  Trip  Fares 


NYC  SJui^ 

CHI-SJui/     NYC-NAS^/ 

NYC-MBJ-/ 

NYC-POS^/ 

LAX-HNI^ 

in-stop  Mileage 

3,194 

4,144               2,194 

3,088 

4,408 

5,112 

Y 

YL 
YH 

YN 

KL 

KH 

KNMW 

KNWE 

$186^^-^^ 
196 
146 
160 

$    304              $  223 
278 

$  308 

$  440 

$246 
278 

232 
262 

x  32  All  Year 
/inter  Ex  58  WE 
Vinter  Ex  59  MW 

\ 

261               ^"^^^ 

192    "-\ 

166 

256 
\^^220 

345 
296 

'-10  DayllT 

\^                         150 

202^^-v^ 

269 

5  Pax  3-14  Day 
GIT 

MW 
WE 

\ 

194 
216 

^ 

10  Pax  3 -14  Affinity 
GIT 

\, 

176 

10-35  Pax  Group 

\^^ 

Off  Days 
Shoulder  Days 
Peak  Days 

\ 

231 
246 
263 

}roup  40  Pax 

Off  Days 
Shoulder  Days 
Peak  Days 

219 

234 

\^    249 

,/     PerATC53 
;/     Per  ATC  54 
!/     Per  ATP  194 

^ 

750 


AFa:NDIX  c 


Comparison  of  New  York-San  Juan  Yields 

With  Other  Vacation  Markets 

February  1975 


Non-Stop  Mileage 

Y 

YL 

YH 

YN 


Round  Trip  Yields 


NYC-SJU     CHI  SJU  NYC-NAS  NYC-MJB  NYC-POS 

3,194          4,144            2,194  3,088  4,408 

7.34(;          10.301^  9.97(^  9.98^ 

6.71 


LAX-HNL 
5,112 


4.8U 
5.44 


KL 
KH 


6.14 


4.54 
5.13 


KN  MW 
KN  WE 


4.57 
5.01 


Ex  32  All  Year 
Winter  Ex  58  WE 
Winter  Ex  59  MW 


8.75  8.29 

7.57  7.12 


7.83 
6.72 


7-10  Day  HT 

15  Pax  3-14  Day  GIT 


MW 
WE 


40  Pax  3-14  Affinity  GIT 


10-35  Pax  Group 

Off  Days 
Shoulder  Days 
Peak  Days 

Group  40   Pax 

Off  Days 
Shoulder  Days 
Peak  Days 


6.28 
6.99 


4.52 
4.81 
5.14 


4.28 
4.58 
4.87 


751 


APPENDIX  D 


AIRLINE  UNADJUSTED  RESULTS 
MAINLAND  U.  S.  -PUERTO  RICO/ VIRGIN  ISLANDS  MARKETS 
Year  Ended  June  30,  1974 


American  Eastern  Pan  Am 

Operating  Profit  (Loss)($)(000)                    $4,339  $(6,718)  $(23,113) 

Return  ($)  (000)                                                 2,815  836  (10,791) 

Rate  of  Return  (%)                                               6.40  0.05  '     (17.65) 


AIRLINE  UNADJUSTED  RESULTS 
NEW  YORK  -  SAN  JUAN  MARKET 
Annualized  1974 

Passenger  Revenue  (000)  $55, 036  $51, 570  $27, 713 

Operating   ProfitALoss)  (000)  5,351  3,415  (10,253) 

Return   (000)  3.194  3,295  (4,791) 

Return  on  Investment    (%)  9.9  5.4  (17.8) 


Source  :      Mainland  U.  S.  -Puerto  Rico/Virgin  Islands  Fares  Case, 
Docket  24353:     AA  Item  9,  EA  Exhibit  J,  PA  Appendix  9, 
American  Exhibit  m,  p.  1. 


752 


APPENDIX  E 


Pan  American's  Own  Projections  Indicate  that  Passenger 
Fare  Increases  Ranging  from  27  to  67  Percent  Would  be 
Required  at  Pan  American's  High  Expense  and  Investment 
Levels  to  Achieve  a  12  Percent  Rate  of  Return 


Mainland- PR/VI 

Services 

Passenger  Services     $  (000) 

NYC- 
SJU 

All 
aher 

Total 

Investment  (PA  Item  10) 

28,020 

26,498 

54,518 

Return  Needed  @  12% 

less  Interest  (PA  Item  10) 

3,362 

1,172 

3,180 
1,109 

6,542 
2,281 

Net  Income  after  taxes 

Taxes  @  48% 
Taxable  Income  Before  tax 

Add  Interest 

2,190 
2,021 
4,211 
1,172 

2,071 
1,912 
3,983 
1,109 

4,261 
3,933 
8,194 
2,281 

Operating  Profit  Required  5,383 

I>rojected  Operating  Expense 

(PA  Item  10)  39,794 

Required  Psgr.  Revenue  for 
12%  ROI 


PA  Projected  Revenue  with 

8%  Fare  Increase  (PA  Item  10) 

Required  Fare  Increase  in 
additjon  torecent  8% 
to  achieve  a  127o  RDI   (%)  66.8 


5.092 


10,475 


45,177      42,474       87,651 
27,079       33,490       60,569 


26.  i 


44.7 


Source : 


Comments  of  the  Commonwealth  of  Puerto  Rico, 
Docket  24353,    February  21,  1975,   PR-Table  11. 


753 


APPENDIX  F 

American,   Eastern,   Pan  American 
Comoarative  Indirect  Exuense  Levels  Fiscal  1974  vs.  Calendar  1971 


American 
Unit  Cost 

Eastern 
Unit  Cost      %AK~ 

Pan  American 
Unit  Cost        "MA 

Passenger  Service  Unit  Costs 

?/RPM 

1971 
1974 

0.543 
0,549 

0.520 
0.608 

96 
111 

0.831 
0.913 

153 
166 

^/ASM 

1971 
1974 

0.299 
0.376 

0.311 
0.384 

104 
102 

0.466 
0.538       . 

156 
143 

Aircraft  Servicing 

$  per  Avail.  Ton  Daptr 

1971 
1974 

17.54 
17.16 

20.12 
23.08 

115 

134 

33.01 
27.34 

192 
159 

Traffic  Servicing 

$  per  Ton  Enplaned 

1971 
1974 

46.57 
55.89 

43.48 
63.60 

93 
113 

100.66 
105.87 

216 
189 

(?/per  RTM 

1971 
1974 

2.92 
3.47 

3.04 
4.14 

104 
119 

6.90 
6.81 

236 
196 

Reservations  and  Sales 

$  per  Ton  Enplaned 

1971 
1974 

58.37 
76.62 

54.58 
63.44 

93 
83 

91.48 
81.55 

157 
106 

%  of  Operating  Revenues  1971 
1974 

9.90 
10.93 

9.59 
9.41 

97 
.     86 

16.85 
15.23 

170 
139 

Advertising  and  Publicity 

%  Operating  Revenues 

1971 
1974 

3.35 
1.14 

4.06 
3.24 

121 

284 

3.95 

4.44 

118 

389 

General  and  Administrative 

$  per  ton  Enplaned 

1971 
1974 

28.47 
27.93 

28.14 
32.95 

99 
118 

32.28 
41.83 

113 

150 

Source:         Comments  of  the  Commonwealth  of  Puerto  Rico, 
Docket  24353,   February  21,   1975,     PR-Table  10. 


754 

[The  following  was  also  submitted  for  the  record.] 

Extracts  From  Address  to  the  World  Conference  on  Tourism  and  Air 
Transport  in  Manila 

Mr.  Knut  Hammarskjold, 
Director  General,  International  Air  Transport  Association 

February  10,  1915. 

The  basic  values  and  elements  of  any  economic  venture,  especially  of  the  magni- 
tude of  international  air  transportation  and  tourism,  have  undergone  revolution- 
ary changes  during  the  last  two  years — one  could  also  term  it  a  revolution  of 
international  air  transport — and  the  sooner  we  recognize  fu^ly  that  we  now  live 
in  a  new  and  different  world,  the  better  for  all  concerned.  In  other  words,  the 
fundamental  concepts  of  international  airline  economics  have  changed.  The 
change  is  continuing  and  it  must  be  recognized  that  new  approaches  are  needed  to 
compensate  for  conditions  in  the  new  environment. 

The  time  has  come  for  sharing  ideas  in  an  international  air  transport  system 
where  problems  are  so  complex  that  no  suggestions  for  remedying  them  should 
go  ignored.  We  must  overcome  the  obstacles  in  our  path,  while  continuing  to 
provide  economically  viable  and  necessary  scheduled  and  programmed  services, 
both  for  individual  and  bulk  travel,  which  are  vital  to  keeping  the  political,  social 
and  economic  wheels  turning. 

This  implies  reexamining  some  of  the  "sacred  cows"  standing  in  the  way  of 
progress.  Exami)les  of  these  include  outmoded  definitions,  artificial  market  segre- 
gation and  excess  capacity.  To  obtain  maximum  benefits  from  existing  resources, 
the  challenge  of  these  problems  must  be  met.  I  am  convinced  that  this  is  possible 
in  the  interest  of  both  the  public  and  the  industry — if  the  artificial,  man-made 
obstacles  can  be  removed. 

A  realistic  appraisal  of  the  airlines'  response  to  an  unprecedented  combination 
of  adverse  economic  forces  during  the  past  year  leads  me  to  conclude  that,  given 
the  necessary  determination  by  all  concerned  to  overcome  existing  man-made 
obstacles  of  all  natures  to  new  and  ima?;inative  solutions,  air  transport  will  over- 
come the  present  problems  and  face  constructively  the  new  world  within  which 
it  has  to  provide  its  international  public  service. 

In  the  world  of  today,  common  sense  and  public  opinion  cannot  tolerate  con- 
tinued wastage  of  resources,  no  matter  what  form  they  take.  The  sooner  we  all 
realize  this  and  adjust  accordingly  the  better.  Therefore  maximum  use  has  to  be 
made  of  all  existing  re.^ources,  including  utilization  of  aircraft  in  international 
traflSc,  thereby  insuring  the  lowest  possible  bulk  and  individual  fares  to  the  public 
and,  at  the  same  time,  maintaining  satisfactory  services  necessary  for  the  vital 
international  commercial,  economic  and  political  relations.  This  objective  obvi- 
ously requires  both  imagination  and  the  abandonment  of  dogmatic  regulatory  and 
legal  concepts. 

[The  following  was  also  submitted  for  the  record.] 


755 


Cha,r,r,.n                                                  AVIATION    TRANSPORTATION    AND   AIRPORTS  comm7.,ioo  Coun„i 

°*v'c\'"c°.km.'!l'^'"'^''  STUDY   COMMISSION 

^.To^  ="".'"„=  oo„K,  STATE    CAPITOL                                                                                            CONSTANCE  SPHOUSE 

HOWARD  P,  ANDERSON  Lofliilafive  Resssrch 

/VARBEN    E      BAHRV  POST  OFFICE  BOX   3   AC                                                                                                                   AttOCr.t. 

ADELAHD   L     BRAULT  RICHMOND.  VIRGINIA    J320S 

=AUL  B     BHICE  I"""!    "04254 

LESLIE  D    CAMPBELL,  JH  WESLEY   R,  ELLMS 

?'^'-'d"^^s''°°''"  February   11,    1975 


FORD 


E«  0«ic 


JONES 


The  Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy,  Chairman 
Senate  Administrative  Practices  and  Procedure 

Subcommittee  -  The  Judiciary  Committee 
The  United  States  Senate 
Washington,  D.  C. 


JTOPHEHSEN 
.  COMNOCIt 


William  H.  Forst 
Robert  C.  Watts,  Jr. 


Dear  Sir: 

In  view  of  the  current  interest  of  the  Senate  Adminis- 
trative Practices  and  Procedure  Subcommittee  concerning  the 
effectiveness  of  the  policies,  regulations  and  procedures  of  the 
Civil  Aeronautics  Board,  we  wish  to  submit  certain  views  and 
findings  of  the  Virginia  Aviation  Transportation  and  Airports 
Study  Commission.   The  studies  and  activities  of  this  Commission 
go  back  more  than  three  years  and  we  feel  our  conclusions  repre- 
sent both  a  seasoned  collective  judgment  and  a  perspective  which 
encompasses  the  varied  interests  concerned  with  aviation  trans- 
portation at  the  state  level.   Although  the  following  statements 
and  conclusions  are  my  own,  I  believe  a  majority  of  our  Commission 
would  agree  with  me. 

The  CAB  does  not  concern  itself  with  the  systemic  aspects 
of  air  transportation  at  either  the  national  or  state  levels.  Never- 
theless, this  is  exactly  where  the  greatest  favorable  effect  upon 
the  public  interest  could  be  fostered,  where  a  federal  regulatory 
function  is  vitally  needed  and  where  the  present  law  clearly  places 
a  responsibility  on  the  CAB.   The  Board  rules  on  matters  in  this 
domain  almost  entirely  as  the  air  carriers  vish  and  I  believe  in 
doing  so  ignores  the  public  interest. 


756 


The  Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy     -2-        February  11,  1975 

Our  frustrating  experience  in  Virginia  provides  a  clear 
example  of  the  CAB's  failure  to  consider  systemic  factors.   The 
local  and  regional  air  transportation  systems  of  the  United  States 
are  dependent  upon  their  connectivity  with  external  points  in  the 
national  and  international  systems.   The  quality  and  degree  of 
such  connectivity  is,  in  turn,  dependent  upon  the  effective  use  as 
gateways  of  hub  airports  in  the  localities  and  regions.   In  the  case 
of  the  northern  East  Coast  states,  the  CAB  has  encouraged  the  over- 
whelmingly predominant  utilization  of  the  New  York  hub  airports. 
This  has  stunted  the  growth  of  other  hub  airports  along  the  coast, 
including  Boston,  Philadelphia,  Baltimore,  Washington  and  Norfolk- 
Newport  News.   The  underdevelopment  of  these  airports  has  reduced 
their  connectivity  with  the  external  points  on  the  national  and 
international  systems  and  therefore  reduced  the  traffic  potential 
for  local  and  regional  systems.   Thus  regional  systems  remain  as 
stunted  as  the  gateways  upon  which  they  largely  depend. 

How  gross  a  distortion  has  the  CAB  permitted?   The  "second 
morning  truck  delivery"  market  (i.e.  a  radius  of  about  600  miles)  of 
Dulles  International  is  greater  than  that  of  John  F.  Kennedy  Inter- 
national at  New  York,   Yet,  because  of  discriminatory  freight  rates  - 
and  possibly  other  factors  -  JFK  handles  about  ten  times  the  Dulles 
freight  business.   The  glut  at  JFK  is  inimical  to  good  service, 
while  an  increase  in  volume  at  Dulles  would  tremendously  improve  the 
potential  for  air  service  to  the  smaller  cities  of  Virginia  and  its 
nearby  sister  states.   The  same  effect  would  benefit  the  New  England 
and  Pennsylvania  regions  through  increasing  the  volume  and  schedules 
of  their  airports. 

Despite  the  obvious  "public  interest"  need  for  equal  trans- 
atlantic freight  rates,  the  CAB  has  overruled  its  own  staff's  recom- 
mendations and  sided  with  the  airlines. 

If  there  is  any  situation  where  a  common  sense  regulation 
is  essential,  it  is  in  our  national  transportation  systems.   At  the 
same  time  there  are  vital  state  interests  in  these  same  systems.  It 
is  unfortunate  that  the  CAB  has  seldom  given  more  than  cursory  ac- 
knowledgment to  the  states'  interest  nor,  for  that  matter,  to  local 
and  regional  system  requirements.   In  fact,  the  CAB  seems  to  be  en- 
tirely lacking  in  understanding  the  advantages  or  significance  of 
transportation  systems  analysis. 

We  wish  to  make  the  opinions  of  Virginia  known  to  your  sub- 
connnittee  and  therefore  would  appreciate  this  communication  being 
made  a  part  of  the  record.   We  believe  our  sister  states  on  the  East 
Coast  -  with  the  possible  exception  of  New  York  -  agree  with  our 
views.   If  helpful,  we  shall  be  glad  to  furnish  further  details  in 
respect  to  the  views  expressed  above. 


757 


The  Honorable  Edward  M.  Kennedy     -2-      February  11,  1975 

We  hope  your  subcommittee  will  find  the  means  to 
rectify  the  serious  flaws  we  find  in  the  policies  of  the  CAB 
which  have  impeded  the  development  of  an  effective,  environ- 
mentally sound  air  transportation  system  in  this  country.   As 
opposed  to  the  present  narrowly  legalistic  approach,  both  the 
air  carriers  and  the  public  would  benefit  from  one  based  on 
a  systemic  foundation.   Above  all,  however,  we  believe  ways 
should  be  found  to  encourage  and  assist  states  to  develop  their 
local  and  regional  systems.   We  believe  the  clearly  evident 
failure  of  the  CAB  to  foster  an  optimum  transportation  system 
constitutes  a  total  disregard  of  the  public  interest. 

Sincerely 


c;^.«.ot^e.^- 


Paul  W.  Manns 

PWM/dp 

Copies  to:  All  Members  of  the  Commission 

Honorable  Mills  E.  Godwin,  Jr.,  Governor  of  Virginia 
Honorable  Wayne  A.  Whitham,  Secretary  of  Transportation 
and  Public  Safety 

o 


BOSTON  PUBLIC  LIBRARY 


i 
3  9999  05706  6902 


GENERAL    BOOKBINDING    CO. 


-7  1     .    P